A Test of Theories Underlying the Japanese Lifetime Employment System Author(s): Jeremiah J. Sullivan and Richard B. Peterson Reviewed work(s): Source: Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 22, No. 1 (1st Qtr., 1991), pp. 79-97 Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/155241 . Accessed: 07/11/2011 07:39 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of International Business Studies. http://www.jstor.org A TEST OF THEORIESUNDERLYINGTHE JAPANESE LIFETIMEEMPLOYMENTSYSTEM JeremiahJ. Sullivan*and RichardB. Peterson** Universityof Washington Abstract. One of the unique features of Japanese management is the lifetime employment system found in large firms. In a study of two samples, Japaneseexecutivesand personnel directors, severaltheoreticalmodels of the causes and effects of lifetime employmentwere tested. A control model received strong support. Lifetime employment is offered within a rhetorical context of loyalty and benevolencebased on culturalvalues. Its impact, however, is to increase the control of Japanese employeesby managers. The permanent,or lifetime,employmentsystemfound in large Japanese firms has been viewed by many writersas one of the importantfactors contributing to the success of the Japanese economy in recent years [Rehder1983].Whatdo we meanwhenwe talk about the Japaneselifetime employmentsystem?Forthe purposeof our research,weuse a narrowdefinition. Lifetimeemploymentrefersto the practicewherebylargeJapanese firmshiremanyof theiremployeesdirectlyfromhigh school or university, employeeswho are expectedto staywith the firm or its subsidiarycompanies until at least the time of normal retirementbetween55 and 60 years of age [Woronoff1983,Billesbachand Rives 1985]. In return,this special group of employeesand managersis assuredthat only in the direstset of circumstanceswill they be laid off. This permanentcadre is limited to males. Women,employeeshiredfrom other firms, and employeesretained after retirementare rarelygiven such assurances. This researchstudy is designedto test the relativeimportanceof various theoriesin explainingthe rationalefor the permanentemploymentsystem used by large Japanesecompanies.Specifically,we will look at cultural, *JeremiahJ. Sullivanis AssociateProfessorin the Departmentof Marketingand InternationalBusinessat the Universityof WashingtonSchool of Business.He specializesin researchon Japanesemanagementand is currentlyfinishinghis third book on Japan, The GentleInvaders:JapaneseManagersin America. **RichardB. Peterson is Professor of Managementand Organizationat the Schoolsof BusinessAdministrationat the Universityof Washingtonin Seattle.His primaryresearchinterestsare in InternationalManagementand IndustrialRelations with specialattentionon Japanesemanagement,problem-solving bargaining, and union/nonuniongrievancesystems. Received: October 1989; Revised: March & June 1990; Accepted: June 1990. 79 80 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER1991 economic,power-control,and motivationtheoriesas possibleexplanations for its use. Webegin by brieflydiscussingthe backgroundliteratureon the permanentemployment system. The next section looks at the specific theories that may explain the use of permanentemploymentin Japan. Sections three and four present the researchdesign used as well as the survey results. Finally, we discuss the implications of our findings for future research. THE DEVELOPMENTOF THE LIFETIMEEMPLOYMENTSYSTEM There is considerableevidencethat lifetime employmenthas operatedin largeJapanesefirmsfor most of the postwarperiod[Abegglen1958, 1973; Dore 1973;Cole 1979;Clark1979].Thereis some consensusthat the Japanese permanentemploymentsystemas we know it today emergedshortly after World War II, though some argue that examplescould be found duringthe inter-waryears. A numberof expertstrace its originsback to the Tokugawaperiod (1615-1868).Abegglen[1958],for instance,believed that lifetimeemploymentcould be linkedwith the pre-Meiji(before1868) feudalsystem.Dore [1973]mentionsthe old "housetraditions"(referredto as the ie conceptlaterin this paper)of such firmsas Mitsuiand Sumitomo wherebythe young apprenticemight end up as a trusted manager or founder of a new "branch house" (p. 391). Clark [1979] traces the permanentemploymentsystem's origin to the merchanthouses in the Tokugawaperiod-at least indirectly.Odaka [1984]sees the roots of the presentlifetimeemploymentsystemin close-knitagriculturalcommunities, and later in the merchanthouses in the Osakavicinity in the eighteenth century.Finally, Levine [1958]and Karsh [1984]see its origins in traditional familybehaviorpatterns.The essentialelementsin pre-Meijitimes includedsubordinationto patriarchalauthority(basedon Confucianideology) and cooperationamong peasant family members[McMillan1984]. Japaneseeconomistsin the 1950sand 1960swereinclinedto say that the permanentemployment system, imbedded in the feudal frameworkof Japan,wouldultimatelymovetowardsa morerationalsystembasedon fluctuating supply-demandfor workers. However, with continuing rapid economic growthin the 1970sand 1980s, Japanesewritersbecame more positivein extollingthe strengthsof permanentemploymentand its compatibility with historicculturaltraditions.Specific strengthscited include:a stable work force of experiencedemployees; loyal cadres due to job securityguarantees;and bettertrainedworkers,sincelong servicejustifies on companytrainingprogramsthanwhenturnmorecompanyexpenditures over is high [Odaka 1984;Christopher1984;Cole 1979]. Nevertheless, there has been increasing criticism of the Japanese permanentemploymentsystemin the 1980s. The most seriouscriticisms revolvearoundthe fact that secureemploymentfor the permanentstaff comes at the expenseof temporaryworkerslike women,part-timers,midcareeremployees,and retirees.Moreover,permanentemploymentmay not THE JAPANESE LIFETIME EMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 81 be able to survivein the face of the aging of the labor force;the changing valuesof youthtowardsindividualneeds;andthe particularneedfor highly skilledtechnicalstaff in high-techindustries.Thesecriticismsare madeby Japaneseand Westernersalike.Yetwith all the debatein the literatureon permanentemploymentover some thirty years, there are relativelyfew examples that can be shown where large Japanese companies have renouncedtheir implicitemploymentguaranteesto the permanentcadre. However,thereis some indicationthat many employeesin such firms are moving slowly in the directionof changingfirms ratherthan stayingwith the same firm throughouttheir work life [Kambara1989]. Several theories have been advanced to explain the presence of, and possible likely changesin, the Japaneselifetimeemploymentsystem.The two most prominenttheoriesareculturalrelativismand convergencetheory (see Sullivan and Peterson [1989] for a more detailed discussion of the various theories that have been used in previousresearch). Culturalrelativismarguesthat each societydevelopsa particularpatternof individual,group, and institutionalbehaviorbased on historicaldevelopments different from those in other countries. While there is variance within each culture,there are also importantcommonalitiesin behavior within a given nation. Much of the earlypostwarliteratureon the Japaneselifetimeemployment systememphasizedthe distinctivenatureof the group-orientedJapanese cultureas an explanationfor the lifetimeemploymentsystem(e.g., Levine [1958], Abegglen [1958, 1973], Dore [1973]). Historical roots for the presentsystemwereshown to be tracedback to featuresof the Tokugawa period such as the "household system." However,duringthis sameperiodone found Japanesewritersextollingthe needfor largeJapanesecompaniesto borrowmorefromthe advancedindustrial nations like the United States and West Germany(see Petersonand Sullivan[1990forthcoming]for a detailedhistoricaltreatmentof the literature on the Japaneseemploymentsystem). More recently,some Japanese writers have been inclined to praise the culturallydistinctivefeaturesof the lifetimeemploymentsystemgiven the success of the Japaneseeconomy (see Befu [1980]for a summaryof this viewpoint). The secondmajortheorythat appliesis convergencetheory.Its proponents arguethat the inner logic of industrializationrequiresthat nations at the samelevelof industrializationexhibitsimilarorganizationalstructuresand processes;and that individualbehaviorwill become more common in the worksetting[Harbisonand Myers1959].Therefore,the Japaneseeconomy wouldshed itself of its feudaltraditionsin favorof modernstructuresand processesfound in the U.S. and other post-industrialnations. Researchby Cole [1979], and others (e.g., Dunphy [1987]), provides only limited supportfor convergencetheory.Ourintentis not to test culturalrelativism vs. convergencetheory,sincea truetest wouldrequirelongitudinalresearch 82 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER 1991 in Japanand the United Statesto see whetheror not the two employment systemswere convergingover a period of ten to twenty-fiveyears. Our study tests specific cultural, control, economic, and motivational theoriesthat mightexplainthe use and impactof permanentemployment at the firm levelbasedon responsesfrommanagersand personnelofficials in largeJapanesecompanies.Each of the theorieswill be discussedbriefly in the following section. MODELSOF LIFETIMEEMPLOYMENT The CulturalModel Much of the literatureon Japanesepracticesdescribesa model in which managementis responsiveto a set of importantculturalvaluesin Japanese society [Hofstede 1980, 1984;Lebra1976;Baba, Perloff, Baba, Lewisand Iwade 1983].Thesevaluesinspireharmony,trust, paternalism,and familialismin the workforce,whichin turnlead to performancewhich is better than could be expectedin countrieswithout similarvalues [Ouchi 1981; Cole 1979]. In this model lifetime employmentguaranteesare a natural outgrowthof culturalvalues. The impact of lifetime employmentis an increasein loyaltyand commitmentby employees,a strongmotivationto help the firm succeed, high quality relationsamong employeesborn of long associationwith each other, and high performance. One of the fullest discussionsof this model applied to a large Japanese corporationis H. Tanaka'sPersonalityin Industry[1988],a study of the development of ASICS, an $800 million sporting goods company. KihachiroOnitsuka,the founder,preachesa corporatephilosophyrootedin a faith that the companyis a family-likestructureexistingfor the benefit of society and the welfareof its employees.Lifetimeemploymentguarantees are importantindicatorsto employeesthat managersand ownershave a communal outlook and a "humanistic"focus. The company'sunion existsto promotecoexistenceand co-prosperitybetweenmanagementand labor, as does a clan-likeapproachto managing, in-house promotions, strong socializationactivities, bottom-up decisionmaking,and elaborate trainingopportunitiesfor workers.TheculturalmodelsuggeststhatASICStype managementis pervasivein largeJapaneseorganizations,and that the prevalenceof lifetimeemploymentwill be greatestin these kinds of firms. Basedon this model, we hypothesizedthat the desireto developemployee loyaltywouldpositivelyinfluencethe use of lifetimeemployment,and that the increaseduse of lifetimeemploymentwouldlead to increasesin loyalty, good relationsin the firm, and high performance. The ControlModel An alternativetheoryof Japaneselifetimeemploymentemphasizeshistorical processes,institutionalarrangements,and the powerof a managerialclass as determinantsof the practiceratherthan culturalvalues [Gordon1985; THE JAPANESELIFETIME EMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 83 Moore 1983;Mosk 1988]. In this view, large Japaneseorganizationswere facedwith a rapidlydevelopinglabormovementin the post-PacificWarera [Tanaka1981].Militantleft-wingunions wereseen to be threateningorganizationalcontroloverproductionimprovements and technologydeployment and thus hinderingthe re-industrializationof Japan. The managementunion conflict was defused by the emergenceof enterpriseunions which traded off control over white and blue collar workersin large firms for informalguaranteesof lifetimeemploymentand a seniority-based systemof wages [Moore 1983]. Managerialcontrol expanded to cover job assignments,hours worked, training,and geographicallocation.Internallabormarketsdevelopedin the large firms, based on hiring only at graduation from school. Once employeeswere hired as lifetime workers,their options to markettheir skills to other firms became severelylimited. Forced to look inwardto their own organizations,these employeeswere more easily controlledby managers. By offeringlifetimeemploymentand wagestied to seniority,management took negotiatingpower out of the hands of unions. The developmentof enterpriseunions paperedover the decline in union power,although the enterpriseunionsdid (anddo) serveto monitorthe firms'adherenceto lifetime employmentand the seniority-basedwage system [Taira1986;Shirai 1983;Hanami 1979;Ayusawa1966]. VanWolferen[1989]arguesthat the controlmodel is but a part of a larger societalmodel in whichsocial and economicrelationsarenot as important as powerrelations.In his versionof the control model, employersdesire workers who are willing to be loyal to their organizationswithin the contextof deeplyheld societalvaluesfocusedon communal,familialrelations. The firms use lifetime employmentto createa sense of such relationshipsexisting,but its realfunctionis to increasemanagerialpowerand control overperformance."Familisticrhetoric"[VanWolferen1989, 164] based on the ie concept of the firm as a "household" createsan image of culture-boundprocessesto concealthe realityof powerbeneaththe surface. We hypothesized, following Van Wolferen,that a desire for employee loyalty would influence the use of lifetime employment,with a resulting increasein managerialcontrol and performance. The EconomicModel Some Japaneseeconomists flrira 1970;Aoki 1984;Koike 1988]view the evolutionof the Japaneseinternallabor market(ILM) since the 1930sas basedon economicrationality,ratherthan on specialculturalfactorsof the Japanese.They arguethat what is distinctiveabout the Japaneseinternal labormarketis the fact that throughdemocratizationof the workplaceand use of extensivecareerladders,there has been a "white-collarizationof blue-collarworkers"in Japan.The blue-collarworkforcein largeenterprises has gained through the firm providinggreaterspecific skill acquisition, 84 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER1991 while the more skilled workerhas contributedto desiredeconomic goals of the firmto a greaterextentthanin othernations.Thus,treatmentof bluecollar workersin Japan is similar to that of white-collaremployeesin Western Europe [Koike 1988]. However, fewer links exist with the Americanlabor marketsituation. Accordingto the economicmodel, the prevalenceof internallabormarkets in manylargeJapaneseorganizationsis not due to culturalfactorsor managerialcontrolneeds. Indeed,internallabor marketsare the byproductsof widespreademployer-employeeexchangerelationshipsin which lifetime employmentis offered in exchangefor the servicesof high-qualitywork force [Koike 1988; Koshiro 1984]. These ILMs are not characterizedby particularlyhigh levelsof employeeloyalty,commitment,and malleability, as one would expect in the other models; this is because the economic exchangeis a trade-offof employeepowerovertask assignmentsand work conditions in return for security of tenure [Baron 1988; Whitehill and Takezawa1978]. The economic model says that Japaneseworkers,when theyhavebargainingpower,tend to seek securityguarantees.Management respondsto this power with lifetime employment.When economic and labor marketconditions change, accordingto this explanation,lifetime employment guarantees will change rraira 1970; Alston 1983]. Some evidencefor the model existsin the researchof Marshand Mannari[1971]. They found that long-termemployment(presumablyevidenceof lifetime employmentguarantees)seemed to be ail incentive offered by firms to attractand keepskilledworkers.Theycautionedresearchers,however,that employmentto retirementratesmaybe highnot becauseof guarantees,but because employeesare simplynot mobile, they lack transferableskills, or they have family obligationsto remainin place. Based on the economic model, we hypothesizeda positive relationship betweendemandfor labor and lifetimeemployment,and betweenlifetime employmentand performance. The Motivation Model In termsof Americantheoriesof motivation,lifetimeemploymentoughtto inspirehighlycreative,innovative,committedemployees.A motivatorcan be describedin terms of its impact on (a) the choice to perform, (b) the amountof effort expended,and (c) the choiceto persistin behavior[Price and Mueller 1986]. In the model, direction,strength,and persistenceof workbehaviorshouldbe affectedby an employee'ssensethat he or she has a job for life. The idea here is that expectationsof future securityand regularpay increasesgainedthroughseniorityought to be powerfulmotivators [Campbelland Pritchard1976]. Lifetimeemployeesmay be better disposedto accept the hardgoals which, accordingto goal-settingtheory, invokeimprovedperformance[Lockeand Latham1984].Lifetimeemployment may spur the acceptanceand use of motivating feedback [Ilgen, Fisherand Taylor1979].It maycreateconditionsin whichemployeesenjoy THE JAPANESE LIFETIME EMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 85 variedwork assignments,a key ingredientof job design theory [Dunham 1979]. All in all, lifetime guaranteesmay foster exceptionallyhigh levels of motivationand performance.Thus, we hypothesizeda model in which lifetime employmentis positivelyrelatedto motivation. CHANGESIN THE SYSTEM It appearsthat the lifetimeemploymentsystemin Japaneselargefirms is changing[Sethi,Namikiand Swanson1984a, 1984b].It is not clearwhy it is happeningor how firmsarerespondingto it. Accordingto Haitani[1978] lifetimeemploymentpracticescannotbe sustainedwhenJapaneseeconomic growthlevelsoff and whenolderworkersbecametoo numerous.Moreover, as Japaneseorganizationsseek to developflexibilityin a rapidlychanging global environment,lifetimeemploymentwill becomea terribleburdenfor management[Abegglenand Stalk 1985].On the employeeside, mid-career managersand workersnow find themselveswaitingin long lines for promotion. The temptationmay be strongto abandonsecurityfor the chanceto obtain betterpositions in other firms. As for entry-levelworkerswho are able and skilled, they have developeda new confidence that a job will alwaysbe available,given the low level of unemploymentin recentyears. In this situation there is no reason to seek job securityguarantees. If the lifetime employmentsystem is threatened,what are firms doing about it? Some companiesare abandoningthe system, accordingto the flood of news reportson the topic in the Japanesepress. Most, however, are taking steps to retain the practice, either for cultural, control, economic, or motivationalreasons. We attemptedto develop and test a change model in our research.Not only would it help researchersunderstandchangesin Japanesemanagementpractices,but also the steps firms are taking to save the system might provide useful information in explainingwhy lifetime employmentis used in the first place. RESEARCHDESIGN Subjects It is possiblethat people holdingdifferentpositionsin Japaneseorganizations may view lifetime employmentdifferently.Thus we felt that two sampleswererequired,one of executivesnot involvedin personnelmatters and one of personneldirectors.The first sample was based on a list of 3,000 managersrepresentingabout2,500 small, mid- and large-sizedfirms. Of these 300 were randomlysampled. Responseswere receivedfrom 54 (18Wo). The second sampleconsistedof 160 personneldirectorsrandomly chosenfroma list of all Japaneselargecompanies[JapanCompanyHandbook 1987].Samplesizes werea functionof researchfundingavailable.Of these, 30 responded(19%).Table 1 describesthe samples. The managers wereolder than the personneldirectorsand representedsomewhatsmaller firms. There were no significant differences in type of organization, 86 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER1991 TABLEI Demographic and Organizational Comparisons of Japanese Samples Managers (N=54) Personnel Directors (N=30) 51.08 2888 41.76 6193 15% 22 15 15 17 5 4 7 13% 60 13 10 0 0 0 4 35% 15 43 7 40% 13 40 7 Sample Characteristics Respondents' age (mean)* Organizationsize (employee mean)** Type of organization Agriculture,mining, construction Manufacturing(excluding electronics) Manufacturing(electronics) Transport,communications Trade Finance, real estate, insurance Health, law, education, gov't Multiplebusinesses Economic environment Stable market,stiff competition Stable market, moderate competition Growingmarket,stiff competition Growingmarket, moderate competition Company enterprise union 59% Yes 41 No *Sample means significantly different at p<.05 level. 93% 7 **p<.01 perceivedenvironment,or presenceof an enterpriseunion in the company. Both samplesrepresentedmanufacturingto a greaterextentthan is present in the Japaneseeconomy [Abegglenand Stalk 1985]. The Questionnaire The survey questionnaireemployed in the researchwas developed in English.Then it was translatedinto Japaneseby a professionaltranslator. backinto Englishby anotherprofessionaltransFinally,it was re-translated lator. No discrepancieswere noted. Each manageror personneldirector was contactedby mail in Japaneseand askedto takepartin a studyof lifetime employment,whichwas definedas a formalor informalguaranteeof employmentuntilretirement.The firstset of itemswerethe dependentvariables. Next came the independentvariables,and finally questionson age, companysize, type of company,economic environment,and whetheror not the firm has an enterpriseunion. Table2 describesthe variables,the items from which each variable'sscore was aggregated,the means, and the reliabilityalpha coefficientsfor reliaandtherewereno signifbility.Both samplesrankedthe variablessimiilarly, icant differencesbetweenthe two samplesfor anyvariable.Thesevariables THE JAPANESELIFETIMEEMPLOYMENTSYSIrEM 87 TABLE2 Descriptions of Aggregate Causal, Effect, and Change Variables Managers Causes of Lifetime Employment Economic (5 items): need for skilled workers; desire for low turnover;we offer other incentives; desire of employees to move; we constantly do research on labor markets 4.93* (alpha= Personnel Directors 4.45 (.53) .82) Culture (2 items): employee loyalty is desired; entrylevel workers are treated like apprentices 5.30 (.67) 4.94 (.71) Desire for Control (3 items): importance of managerial power to move workers to jobs and iocations; importance of training workers to see management's interests as their own interests; importance of control systems in the firm 5.43 (.46) 5.40 (.76) 5.08 (.59) 4.56 (.71) Effects of Lifetime Employment Performance (5 items): current industry ranking; No.1 status over last five years; higher market share than competitors; most challenging work in the industry; we have low turnover Good Relations (2 items): trust is high; communication processes are good 5.30 (.95) 5.00 (.84) Loyaity (5 items): employees are loyal; i want to keep working for my company; my company is more rewarding to me than in other companies; this company brings out my best efforts; I am realiy happy to work here 5.14 (.66) 4.68 (.79) Motivation (8 items): we attract creative empioyees with high expertise who are hard workers; they are very sensitive to product quailty; they easiiy adapt to new technology; they have high productivity (plus several other items) 5.56 (.91) 5.43 (.83) Control (5 items): wage increases are strictly controiied; employees seidom complain; managers have great power over subordinates; frequent performance appraisais occur with written records kept 4.98 (.51) 5.10 (.70) Change Variable (3 items); not as important as it used to be; Deciine in 3.27 3.20 Lifetime L.E. has been reduced; not as important in (.79) (.66) Empioyment the future Notes: Means were not significantly different between samples for any variable Scale 1 = disagree, 7 = agree *Aggregate mean divided by number of items. were chosen within the context of the exhaustiveliteraturesearch. They also were those variables which were needed to explore the models describedabove. 88 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER1991 Table3 lists two types of employmentmeasures.Measures1, IA and lB referto employeeswho joined the firm from school. Measures2, 2A, and 2B focus on employees joining the firm from other organizations. Employeesin both sets of measuresmayor maynot enjoylifetimeemployment. Question 5 directlysought the percentof total regularemployees who havebeen grantedlifetimeemploymentin the respondingfirm. Questions 3 and 4 sought measuresof the managerialattitudetowardslifetime employment. The samples were not significantly different in variable means.Moreover,both samplestendedto see lifetimeemploymentas more useful in favorableeconomicconditions.By collectingseparatemeasuresof long-termemploymentand lifetime employment,we hoped to be able to differentiateconditionsof lifetimeemploymentfromconditionsof merely stable employment.Responsesto question 5 in our models served as a measureof the impact of the causal variableslisted in TIble 2. In turn, this measurewas the cause of the likely effects of lifetime employment listed in TIble 2. RESULTS Models of Lifetime Employment Table3 lists only significantPearsonproduct-momentcorrelationsbetween the variables.Forthe managers,culture(thedesirefor loyalty)is the important causalvariableassociatedwith the prevalenceof lifetimeemployment (question 5). The impact of lifetime employmentis on increasedcontrol and betterperformance.For the personneldirectors,who havemoreof an externallabormarketfocus, the greaterthe demandfor high qualitylabor, the less prevalentlifetimeemploymentis. It appearsthat for personneldirectors lifetime employmentmay be less prevalentin conditionsof a strong labor marketthan in a weak labor market. It is interestingto examinethe responsesfor the other variablesin Table3 which measuredthe extentof stableemployment(questions1, lA, iB, 2, 2A, and 2B). Clearlyfor the managersstronglabor marketdemand(the ''economic"'variable)playsa part in fosteringlong-termemployment,but culturalvalues and the desirefor control are somewhatmore important. For the personneldirectorseconomicconditionsseemmoreimportant,but in an inverserelationship.Whereasmanagersreportstronglabor demand as associatedwithincreasedlong-termemployment,the personneldirectors reportweak labor demand. As for the impact of long-term,stable employment,only the managers' responseswererevealing.Stableemploymentyieldsincreasedloyalty,managerial control, good relations, and performance.It does not increase motivation. Responsesto questions3 and 4 explorethe strengthof commitmentto lifetime employment.For both managersand personneldirectors,a strong commitment to lifetime employment (question 3) is associated with increasedloyalty.The pictureis less clearregardinga weakercommitment THE JAPANESELIFETIME EMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 89 to lifetimeemployment(question4). Managerssee such commitmentas a responseto a desirefor controlresultingin increasedloyalty.Forpersonnel directors, a weak commitment is driven by economic conditions and culturalvalues. RegressionAnalysis We tested each model in a series of regressionsfor both samplesrelating causal variablesto the prevalenceof lifetime employment,and lifetime employmentto its effects.No model was supportedfor the personneldirectors. Figure 1 describesthe model which was supportedfor the managers. This model is the result of regressingthe prevalenceof lifetime employment measureon all the likely causal variablesspecified in our literature reviewand model development(culture,the economicvariable,and desire for control). Culturewas the only variableto emergeas significant.The second part of the model reportsthe resultof regressingperformanceon control, good relations,loyalty,motivation,and the prevalenceof lifetime employment measure. None of these except lifetime employment was relatedto performance,and so a path wasdrawnfromlifetimeemployment to performance.Similarregressionsresultedin a path fromlifetimeemployment to control. Culturalvaluesare associatedwith the prevalenceof lifetime employment in the firms studied, and lifetime employment is associatedwith a strong managerialcontrol focus and with strong longterm performance.The Van Wolferencontrol model hypothesisthus was supported. Changesin LifetimeEmployment Figure2 reportsthe resultsof regressions,investigatinglikelycausesof the decliningimportanceof lifetimeemploymentand organizationalresponses to protectthe lifetime employmentsystems.Figure2a can be considered the result of a model developing process, and Figure 2b as a test supportingthe proposedmodel using a differentsample.In both samples the declinewas associatedwith an ageingworkforceand with a decline in the allegianceof employeesto their companies.The other variablesin the survey, which were not associated with the decline, were stagnant economic conditions and a decline in the motivationalvalue of lifetime employment.Given the correlationsnoted in Table3, these resultsmake good sense. Lifetimeemploymentis a responseto culturalvalues, not to the conditionof the economyor to motivationalschemes.Its declinethus is a response to changes in culturalvalues (and to concerns about the expenseof paying employeeswho enjoy high seniority-basedpay). In responseto a decline in the importanceof lifetime employment,we asked respondentswhat their organizationsdid to protectthe system(see the third set of variablesin Figure2). The models show that firms foster retirements,engage in temporarylayoffs (of employeeswithout lifetime employment),and send excess permanentemployeesto affiliates. Other 90 00 00 oEo E~ Ea) 0 ow a) C E 0 ' o = E = C~~~~~ $0 0- &3 ~~~ ~~~~~ CI 0).= 0' 4 E C CD 0'n cqcn11-v 0 a) 0 L coCCDC 0 - 80 C L 0 0~~~0 - 0 4 0 WO C.)~ ~ 1 11. C, 5 c - DOL _ E 01 o C o C.) 0 -n (E1 DOL)W 0 "0 = 0. 0 DO - 0 t- C C 0 C.) 0= 0 a JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER1991 It a) 0 0 a.~~~~a E 0 a) C.a ) ' ?Eo ? 0~~~~~~~~~c (I) o LLJ C E )CE 4w -) 0 C~~_~C -- o E w 0~~ 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 CI) 0 0 *0 CL w 0 E owo It) LO) 0 Ci C'J C4 0 E 0 n C14 Ci E0 o0 > U CUc co -~ii0- =CUm co~ * 6 C.) .- 0 C 0- 0 Z7~~~~~~~~~~ 0- 0 Eco Cr Eo 0~ C- 0- E wOWW r- E 0~ 0 -I..,M 20 2 II 0~~~~~ID0 c 0OCflI)n0 E 2 0 %- 0 r 00 0 oE o C coC ~~~~l V) >%C ~~cO)Co -92 E~ wi 0~~~~~~ 0 13I, oLnE 0 0 0 Ct ~o -~~~~~ * U THE JAPANESE LIFETIMEEMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 0 o *- 0 U C COOT- 0 c~~~.. -9 M 04~~~~~~~~~~ *9~~~~~~~~~CiC (3S& o 0 2 c 0 0 C C C-) 91 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C C ~~0 92 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER 1991 FIGURE1 Path Model for Causes and Effects of Lifetime Employment Culture .2 .7 ) / Prevalence of a lifetimeemployment < ~~~~in theorganization \ b Performance Notes: aResults of stepwise regression (.27 is the beta coefficient) of lifetime employmenton culture,the economic variable,desire forcontrol,and organizationsite. Culturewas the only significant variable entered in the equation (p<.06). Adj. R2=.07. bSignificantcorrelationcoefficients (p<.05) fromTable3. A regression of performance on control,lifetimeemployment,and otherkeyvariablesresultedonly in lifetimeemployment enteringthe equation.Thus no pathwas drawnbetweencontroland performance. responses,whichwerenot employed,areemploymentfreezes,bonusreducand doingnothing. tions, reducedovertime,decreaseduse of subcontractors, ClearlyJapanesefirms want to save some form of lifetime employment, and they are doing it throughearly retirementsand occasionallayoffs of temporarystaff. None of the variablesin the model wererelatedto type of industry,economicconditions,or to the presenceof an enterpriseunion. Thus the decline in lifetime employment is not due to labor market demandor competitiveconditions.It appearsto be the effect of an ageing, costly workforce,and of changes in work values in Japanesesociety. DISCUSSION The Japanesemanagerswe studiedsee lifetimeemploymentas associated with culture. This variable (see Table 2) was measuredby two items focusedon the organizationaldesirefor employeeloyaltyand on the treatment of entry-level employees as apprentices. These measures were employedto detectthe extentto whicheach respondentsawhis firm within the context of a firm as a household(ie). The householdconcept is very old in Japan, and it has been re-energizedby modern large Japanese corporations. Ie requires organizations to be run with benevolence from above and submission(called "loyalty") from below. As we found, the stronger the ie concept,the strongeris organizational"benevolence"in the form of lifetime employment. The cultural (ie) basis for lifetime employmentmight be interpretedas supportfor the culturalmodel describedearlier.If this wereso, we would expect lifetime employmentalso to be associated with good employeremployeerelations,loyalty,and motivation.Clearlythis was not the case THE JAPANESE LIFETIME EMPLOYMENT SYSTEM 93 FIGURE2 Path Models for Causes and Responses to Decline in Lifetime Employment (significant correlations, p<.05) (a) Managers Directors L some cmployeesto desrie eatly l Inecasing age of elo p b employ .32 ~~< / f / / ~~~~~~~~~~~Decline ekning trust nbenteenemployers 1 in mlportnce of lifenime u retorand\ 34 prblmsardmpneb ,/ Tcmpomy~~~~~~~~layoffs ou 37 Send employuis ~~~~~~~~to Strong oafrAiates pressure onA \.~~~~36 Youngemployesr more self-orientedthnr <compny-oneted 2\ Encourageearly retirement (b) PersonnelDirectors ~~~~~~~~~~~~some ~~~~~ ( employees ago Inhcreasing 'AI ^f socaldobpligatiosofhueod35 / Wcakenigoftrust>3 betweenemployer andemployee (of an lifetinxmev hmpousehol employment, mebes recamely Posil uno r ~~< Ecouragecay tirement in our research. Instead, the control model was supported (see Figure 1). Lifet'imeemployment provides a highly malleable workforce which can be directed towards strong performance. This model 'is described at great length by Van Wolferen [1989]. In the model, large Japanese organizations fear the decline in their power posed by trade unionism. To maint;ainpower over labor they offer lifetime employment 'in return for increased managerial control over task assignments for employees and geographic ass'ignments. The bargain is struck wi'thinthe context of rhetoric about i'eand the social obligatilons of households and household members. Possible union problems are dampened by this rhetoric and by creating company unions, 94 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER1991 whose main task is to monitor the security-flexibilitybargain between employerand employee. We would expect, then, that where lifetime employmentis prevalent,an enterpriseunion would be present.We found that this was the case. On average,96.6%of the total workforceenjoyedlifetimeemploymentin those firmsthat also had enterpriseunions. Withouta union, only 78.8% of the workforceenjoyedtenure(F(1,73)= 13.7,p =.0004). Since most unionized firms are large,we would expectthe controlmodel to be strongerin large firms. However,the same model emergedfor both small and large firms. Organizationalsize was not a significant variable. Firms under 500 employeesofferedlifetimeemploymentto an averageof 800/oof employees. The averagefor largerfirms was 96%. Both small and large firms, then, offer job securityto well over 50Gbof employees. Notice that firms facing a tight labor marketaccordingto the personnel directors(see the negative correlationsfor the "economic" variablein Table3) did not use employeelifetime employmentto the same extentas firms facing a weak labor market. Why is this so? First, workersin a strongposition are not easily controlledand not very submissive.In this condition lifetimeemploymentas a control mechanismis not likelyto be very effective.Second, a tight labor marketsuggeststhat firms may need highlymotivated,innovativeemployees.Wefound no strongevidencethat lifetimeemploymentis associatedwith employeemotivation.In summary, when demandfor laboris high, lifetimeemploymentis nothingspecialfor workersand does not seem to providethe highlymotivatedworkforcethe companyneeds. Since it is not attractiveto either side, it is not used as much as in a weak labor market,accordingto our interpretationof the personneldirectors'responses. The controlmodel, then, receivedmoresupportthanthe culturalmodel or the motivationmodel. Lifetimeemploymentmay not lead to increasesin employeeloyalty or motivation. However,Table3 revealsthat increased levelsof employeeloyaltyto the firm do seem to resultfrom high percentages of long-termemployeeswho are likely to retirefrom the firm (see responsesto questions 1 to 2B). A stable workforcethus tends to inspire relations,regardlessof the presenceof loyaltyand good employer-employee lifetime guaranteesto entry-levelworkers.Indeed, question 2 in Table3 suggeststhat employeeswho join firms after workingelsewhere-people who do not have lifetime guarantees-make up a significantpart of the currentJapaneseworkforce.These workers,if they expect to stay until as lifetime retirement,maybe just as loyal,malleable,and high-performing employees. Wehastento add that data frompersonneldirectorsdid not revealsupport for any model of lifetimeemployment.Futureresearchclearlywill haveto focus on furthertestingof the VanWolferenpowermodelas an explanation of lifetime employment. The commitmentto a strongform of lifetimeemploymentmay not be as solid as a commitmentto a weakerform. In Table3, question3 measured THE JAPANESELIFETIME EMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 95 commitmentto lifetime employmentregardlessof economic conditions. Question 4 measuredcommitmentto the practicein favorableeconomic conditionsonly.The meanresponsessuggesta strongercommitmentto lifetimeemploymentin good timesonly,ratherthanin anycircumstances. Japanese employeesmay find that their guaranteesdo not stand up very well in economic downturns. As they see their tenure become less secure, employees'willingnessto engage in ie relations may fade. As Figure 2 shows, a decline in trust and a growingindividualismare associatedwith a declinein the adherenceto lifetime employment.In a rapidlychanging global environmentrequiringgreat flexibility by large firms, Japanese organizations'commitmentto a rigidinternallabormarketsupportedby lifetime employmentis declining.With it will go the ie concept, whichin turn will open the door for more self-oriented,perhapsadversarialrelations betweenemployeesand employers.Figure2 hints at suchdevelopments.To prop up the systemby puttingpressureon some employeesto retireearly will only hasten the demise of ie, of the employees'faith in the lifetime employmentbargain, and of the extraordinarycontrol over employees enjoyedby large Japanesefirms. REFERENCES Abegglen,JamesC. 1958.TheJapanesefactory:Aspectsof its social organization.Glencoe,Ill.: Free Press. . 1973. Management and the worker. lbkyo: Sophia University Press. & GeorgeStalk. 1985.Kaisha,the Japanesecorporation.New York:Basic Books. Alston, Jon P. 1983.Japanas no. one?Socialproblemsof the nextdecades.Futures,October:342-56. Aoki, Masahiko.1984.Aspectsof the Japanesefirm. In M. Aoki, editor,The economicanalysisof the Japanesefirm, 3-43. Amsterdam:North-Holland. Ayusawa,Iwao F. A historyof labor in modernJapan. Honolulu, Haw.:East WestCenterPress. Baba, Masao,R. Perloff,F. Baba, M. Lewis& H. Iwade.1983.A comparativestudy on the managerialclimatein the US. and Japanesebusinessorganization.Instituteof IndustrialManagement Research,College of Economics,Nichon University. Baron,JamesN. 1988.Theemploymentrelationas a socialrelation.Journalof theJapaneseandInternationalEconomies,2: 492-525. Befu, Harumi.1980.A critiqueof the groupmodel of Japanesesociety.SocialAnalysis,5/6: 29-43. Billesbach,ThomasJ. & JanetM. Rives.1985.Lifetimeemployment:Futureprospectsfor Japanand the U.S. SAM AdvancedManagementJournal,Autumn:26-30 & 46. Campbell,John P. & RobertD. Pritchard.1976.Motivationtheoryin industrialand organizational psychology.In M. Dunnette,editor,Handbookof industrialand organizationalsociety.Chicago: Rand McNally. Christopher, Robert.1984.TheJapanesemind:Thegoliathexplained.NewYork:SimonandSchuster. Clark, Rodney.1979. The Japanesecompany.New Haven:YaleUniversityPress. Cole,RobertE. 1979.Work,mobility,andparticipation.Berkeley,Calif.:Universityof CaliforniaPress. Dore,Ronald.1973.Britishfactory-Japanesefactory.Berkeley,Calif.:Universityof CaliforniaPress. Doshe, K., U. Jurgens& T. Malsch. 1985.From'fordism'to 'toyotism'?The social organizationof the labor processin the Japaneseautomobileindustry.Politics and Society, 14: 115-46. Dunham,RandallB. 1979. Job designand redesign.In StevenKerr,editor,Organizationbehavior. Columbus,Ohio: GridPublishing. 96 JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESS STUDIES, FIRST QUARTER 1991 A temporalreviewof the Japaneseenterpriseand its Dunphy,Dexter.1987.Convergence/divergence: management.Academyof ManagementReview,12:445-59. Gordon,A. 1985. Theevolutionof laborrelationsin Japan:Heavy industry,1953-1955.Cambridge: HarvardUniversityPress. of the Japaneseemploymentsystem.AsianSurvey,10:1029Haitani,K. 1978.Changingcharacteristics 145. Hanami,Tadashi.1979.Laborrelationsin Japan today.Tokyo:KodanshaInternationalLtd. Harbison,Frederick& CharlesA. Myers.1959.Managementin the industrialworld:An international analysis.New York:McGraw-Hill. values.Beverly Internationaldifferencesin work-related Hofstede,Gert. 1980.Culture'sconsequences: Hills, CA: Sage. . 1984.Culturaldimensionsin managementandplanning.Asia PacificJournalof Management, January:51-80. Ilgen, DanielR., C.D. Fisher& S.M. Taylor.1979.Consequencesof individualfeedbackon behavior in organizations.Journalof AppliedPsychology,64: 349-71. 'Japanesetryjob hopping.TheChristianScience K. 1989.Abandoning'lifetimeemployment: Kamnbara, Monitor,February24: 9. Karsh,Bernard.1984.Humanresourcemanagementin Japaneselarge-scaleindustry.Journalof Industrial Relations,June:226-45. industrialrelationsin modernJapan.NewYork:St. Martin'sPress. Koike,Kazuo.1988.Understanding Koshiro,Kazutoshi.1984.Lifetimeemploymentin Japan:Threemodelsof the concept.MonthlyLabor Review,August:34-35. Lebra,TakieS. 1976.Japanesepatternsof behavior.Honolulu, Haw.:Universityof HawaiiPress. Levine,SolomonB. 1958.Industrialrelationsin postwar Japan.Urbana,Ill.: Universityof Illinois Press. structuresin JapaneseandU.S.manuLincoln,James,M. Hanada&K. McBride.1986.Organizational facturing.AdministrativeScienceQuarterly,31: 338-64. Locke, Edwin A. & Gary P. Latham. 1984. Goal setting:A motivationaltechniquethat works. EnglewoodCliffs, N.J.! Prentice-Hall. Marsh,RobertM. & HiroshiMannari.1971.Lifetimecommitmentin Japan:Roles,normsandvalues. AmericanJournalof Sociology,76: 795-812. McMillan,CharlesJ. 1984. The Japaneseindustrialsystem.New York:Walterde Gruyter. Moore,J. 1983.Japaneseworkersand thestrugglefor power.Madison:Universityof WisconsinPress. of postwarJapaneselabor in comparative Mosk, Carl. 1988. Flexiblecontrol:Internationalization perspective.Paperpresentedat the Associationof JapaneseBusinessConference,San Francisco, January1989. Odaka,Kunio.1984.Japanesemanagement:A forward-lookinganalysis.Tokyo:Asian Productivity Organization. Ouchi,William.1981.TheoryZ: HowAmericanbusinesscan meet the Japanesechallenge.Reading, Mass.:Addison-Wesley. Peterson,RichardB. & Jerry Sullivan.Forthcoming.The Japaneselifetime employmentsystem: Whitherit goest?In S. BenjaminPrasad,editor,Advancesin internationalcomparativemanagement, Vol. 5. Greenwich,Conn.: JAI Press. Price,JamesL. & CharlesW. Mueller.1986.Handbookof organizationalmeasurement.Marshfield, Mass.:Pitman. Rehder,RobertR. 1983.Educationandtraining:Havethe Japanesebeatenus again?PersonnelJournal, January:42-47. Sethi, S. Prakash,NobuakiNamiki& Carl L. Swanson.1984a.The declineof the Japanesesystem of management.CaliforniaManagementReview,Summer:35-46. . 1984b. The false promise of the Japanese miracle. Boston: Pitman. industrialrelationsin Japan.Madison,Wisc.:University Shirai,iishiro, editor,1983.Contemporary of WisconsinPress. THE JAPANESE LIFETIME EMPLOYMENTSYSTEM 97 Sullivan,Jerry& RichardB. Peterson.1989.Japanesemanagementtheories:A researchagenda.In S. BenjaminPrasad,editor,Advancesin internationalcomparativemanagement,Vol.4. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 255-76. In K. Tlira,editor,EconomicdevelThira,Koji.1970.The labormarketoriginsof employerpaternalism. opment and the labor marketin Japan. New York:ColumbiaUniversityPress, 79-127. Tanaka,Fujio T. 1981.Lifetimeemploymentin Japan. Challenge,July/August:23-29. Tanaka,Hiroshi. 1988.Personalityin industry.Philadelphia:Universityof PennsylvaniaPress. VanWolferen,Karel.1989. The enigmaof Japanesepower.New York:Knopf. Whitehill,ArthurM., Jr.& Shin-IchiTikezawa.1978.Workplaceharmony:AnotherJapanese'miracle'? ColumbiaJournalof WorldBusiness,Fall: 25-39. Woronoff,Jon. 1983.Japan'swastedworkers.London:Allenheld,Osmun.