To Strictly Maintain the Salomon Principle or Not: That is the question? By Vivek Khanna LLB, LLM, Barrister at Law Introduction The purpose of this paper is to discuss the apparent failure by the courts to maintain the principle that the company is a separate legal entity, which was established in the case of Salomon v A Salomon & Co Ltd1. In the light of the formalistic approach taken towards the Companies Act by the House of Lords in Salomon, it would seem particularly difficult to pierce the strict legal rule of the separate legal entity of the company. However, in the absence of any statutory regulations it has been the role of the courts to deviate from the legal fiction. Firstly, this paper will examine the case of Salomon v Salomon to determine the exact nature and importance of the Salomon principle of separateness often referred to as the ‘veil of incorporation’. Secondly, this paper will examine how when limited liability is coupled with the Salomon principle a company may be used as a vehicle for fraud. Thereafter, this paper will briefly introduce some of the mechanisms, which are in place to prevent an abuse of the corporate form. Third, this paper turns its focus on when the courts are prepared to disregard the Salomon principle to combat fraud or abuse of the corporate form. This paper differentiates between ‘lifting’ and ‘piercing’ the metaphoric veil of incorporation. It is submitted that ‘lifting veil’ does not in any true sense erode or derogate from the Salomon principle because the courts in ‘lifting the veil’ are merely suspending the application of the rule in Salomon. On the other hand, it is submitted that ‘piercing the veil’ is the offensive act which unsettles the rule in Salomon. Fourthly, this paper begins its discussion of piercing the corporate veil with an insight into how contemporary authors have approached the subject. Ottolenghi, in his article ‘From Peeping behind the corporate veil to ignoring it completely’,2 has provided a refined analysis of the cases concerning the corporate veil. In an attempt to unearth fresh ideas in the discussion of the corporate veil, this paper has selected to adopt the headings used by the Court of Appeal in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd, 3 i.e. ‘agency’, ‘single economic entity’, and the ‘corporate-veil’. Penultimately, this paper shall consider to what extent the law has been clarified. On this point the paper shall conclude that although it is impossible to extract an all encompassing principle it is possible to distil three separate occasions where the court may pierce the veil. However, without the guiding hand of legislation it remains impossible to lay out the exact parameters of the rules, and to that extent difficult to pre-empt exactly when the courts will pierce the veil. Finally, this paper will conclude that it is undesirable to allow companies to take the benefits of the corporate entity principle without having to suffer the consequences and to that extent it is necessary to limit judicial inroads to instances of bad faith. 1 [1897] AC 22 [1990] 53 MLR 338 3 [1990] Ch. 433 2 The Salomon Principle: The Veil of Incorporation The doctrine of separate legal personality is the cornerstone of modern company law.4 It established that an incorporated company is an entity separate from its shareholders and directors but not entirely free from their existence. The case of Salomon v. Salomon & Co Ltd.5 is universally recognised as authority for the principle that a corporation is a separate legal entity.6 It created the idea that companies operate behind a metaphoric ‘veil of incorporation’ which separates members from the company and permits the company to be completely independent, with rights and duties distinct from those possessed by its shareholders, directors and employees. The company is deemed an artificial legal person,7 with independent existence.8 As Lord Macnaghten put it: ‘The company is at law a different person altogether from the subscribers…’ 9 The practical need for a separation between a company and its members has never been doubted since the decision in Salomon's case.10 The need for the separate corporate entity has been justified on different grounds. Concession theorists, for example, regard corporate personality as a privilege granted by the state ‘thereby underlining the state's claim to control over the process of incorporation and its subsequent use’.11 Similarly, the contractarian school argues that ‘[c]orporation law reduces transaction costs by implying in every corporate charter the normal rights on which shareholders could be expected to insist’, such as separate legal status.12 In theory, Salomon's case was a good decision. By establishing that corporations are separate legal entities, Salomon's case blessed the company with all the necessary attributes with which to become the motivating force of capitalism. However in practice and reality the separation of a legal entity from its members can be problematic. By extending the benefits of incorporation to small private enterprises, Salomon's case has provided a loophole through which subscribers of a company can evade their legal obligations. Despite its problems, the Salomon principle has stood the test of time and remained in tact to preserve various practical functions for the commercial market. Some of these functions include: perpetual existence, flexibility, financing methods, specialised management and majority rule of the corporation.13 Also available to subscribers of an incorporated company is the option of forming a company with ‘limited liability’.14 Limited liability allows the members of a company to limit their responsibility for a company’s debts. 4 Williams, ‘Fraudulent Trading’ [1986] 1 Companies and Securities Journal 14 at p. 14 (1897) AC 22 HL 6 This principle was already discussed in the earlier case of R v. Arnaud (1846) 9 QB 806. 7 Lee v. Lee’s Air framing [1961] AC 12, demonstrates the artificiality of the concept of separate legal personality. 8 Ireland, P., ‘The Triumph of the Company Legal Form, 1856-1914’, in Adams, J., (ed), Essays for Clive Schmitthoff, (1983), p.30 9 [1897] AC22, HL, at p. 51 10 Gower, Gower's Principles of Modern Company Law, (5th ed), (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1992), p 88. 11 Bottomley, S., ‘The Birds, The Beasts, and The Bat: Developing a Constitutionalist Theory of Corporate Regulation’ (1999) 27 F L Rev 243. 12 Posner, R., Economic Analysis of Law, (1977), (2nd ed.), Boston: Little, Brown & Co, Boston, p. 302. 13 Pettet, B., ‘Limited Liability- A Principle for the 21st Century?’ [1995] CLP 125, p.151 14 s. 2(3) Companies Act 1985 5 1 This means the members of an insolvent company do not have to contribute their own personal assets in the liquidation to meet the debts of the company. Liability may be limited to a predetermined sum, payable on winding up,15 or to the nominal value of the shares held, unless this sum has been paid by the current or a former shareholder.16 Since most shares are issued fully paid, shareholders have, effectively, no liability for the company’s debts. Limited liability stimulates the economy as a whole, through investment and business activity. It reduces the cost of separation of management and control and reduces the need to monitor control. Limited liability encourages companies to take on the optimal investment and diversification of holdings that may be deemed negative risk taking by an unincorporated trader.17 The Difficultly with Limited Liability and the Salomon Principle Limited liability was very controversial when it was introduced because of its effect of shifting the hazard of business breakdown away from investor(s) to creditor(s) who had to bare the consequences of liquidation. This was perceived to be unfair.18 The idea behind the controversy is whether limited liability should be available for what is effectively a ‘one-man company’ often used to ‘defraud creditors’.19 Khan-Freund criticised Salmon as a ‘calamitous decision’20 and adhered to the view it is unjust to attribute limited liability to a small company, where there is no business risk or need to encourage outside investment.21 The Salomon principle when coupled with the consequential attribute of limited liability provides an ideal vehicle for fraud.22 It has been argued the Salomon principle is malleable and provides a facility for protecting directors and members against the claims of creditors. The corporate form has been responsible for the development of many different forms of fraudulent activity. An example of corporate fraud is where subscribers set up a limited liability company that is ‘wafer-thin’ and undercapitalised. The owners then cause the corporation to incur large debts in it’s own name, with little or no prospect of being able to meet these debts. When the creditors seek repayment, the owners argue that they are not liable for the debt because the company as a separate legal person is the debtor. A second example of corporate fraud is where assets of a corporation are transferred to a new corporation for the purposes of avoiding tax liability.23 This transfer is often framed in a confusing series of transactions to conceal the real design of the scheme. When funds are traced back to the new ‘vehicle corporate shell’, investigators will find ‘straw men’ have been 15 s. 2(4) Companies Act 1985 - A company limited by guarantee s. 2(5) Companies Act 1985 - A company limited by shares 17 Easterbrook, and Fischel, ‘Limited Liability and the Corporation’ (1985) 52 University of Chicago Law Review 89, p. 94 18 Ireland, P., ‘The Triumph of the Company Legal Form’, 1856-1914’, in Adams, J., (ed), Essays for Clive Schmitthoff, (1983), p. 32 – 33. 19 Khan-Freund, ‘Some Reflections on Company Law Reform’, (1944), 7 MLR 54 at p. 56 20 Ibid. p. 54. 21 Goulding, S., Principles of Company Law (1996), London: Cavendish Publishing Limited, p. 49 22 Tomasic and Bottomley, Corporations Law in Australia, (Sydney: The Federation Press, 1995), pp 42 and 46 cited in Puig, G., V., ‘A Two-Edged Sword: Salomon and the Separate Legal Entity Doctrine’, E Law - Murdoch University Electronic Journal of Law at www.murdoch.edu.au/elaw/issues/v7n3/puig73a.html 23 This is termed the ‘Phoenix Syndrome’. 16 2 appointed in the place of original directors. The new asset rich corporation will attempt to dissipate the assets by granting unsecured, interest-free loans by the corporation to the directors or to companies in which they have an interest and the payment of astronomical fees to directors for management services or living expenses.24 Today for a small business the Salomon principle coupled with limited liability is an illusory advantage, to some extent because creditors have developed different capacities to protect themselves.25 Moreover, s. 213, 214 and 215 of the Insolvency Act 1986 impose liability for the debts of a company where its subscribers have been engaged in fraudulent or wrongful trading. Furthermore, negative aspects of the decision in Salomon's case, have (arguably) been neutralised, through the understanding ‘The courts can and often do draw aside the [corporate] veil. They can, and often do, pull off the mask. They look to see what really lies behind.’26 This is a difficult decision to make, because the courts have to decide whether to obey the principle of the separate legal entity or recognise the need for ‘lifting’ or ‘piercing’ the corporate veil. Lifting and Piercing the Veil It is important at this stage to draw a distinction between ‘lifting’ and ‘piercing’ the corporate veil. In the case of Atlas Maritime Co. SA v Avalon Maritime Ltd (No. 1)27 Staughton LJ deemed ‘lifting’ or ‘peeping behind’28 the corporate veil to mean having ‘regard to the shareholding in a company for some legal purpose’.29 An example of this can be seen in Daimler Co Ltd v Continental Tyre and Rubber Co (GB) Ltd30 where the court (after war broke out with Germany), was prepared to lift the corporate veil of a tyre company, to determine who was in control of the company. If the company was controlled by enemy aliens, the company could also be regarded as an enemy alien. It is submitted that the court when ‘lifting the veil’ is momentarily suspending the Salomon principle to determine who controls the company. Lifting the veil has been described as an act which is the ‘least offensive to separate entity theory’ and is merely an ‘act of curiosity’.31 In no true sense can we say that lifting the veil constitutes a decomposition of the rule in Salomon.32 On the other hand, ‘piercing’ the corporate veil is an expression, which describes where the court ignores the separateness of the company and regards the rights, liabilities or activities of a company as those of its shareholders. 33 Therefore, this paper seeks to address when the courts are prepared to ‘pierce’ the corporate veil and derogate from the Salomon principle, their reasons for doing so and their current legal stance. 24 DTI, Modern Company Law For A Competitive Economy: Final Report, (The Company Law Review Steering Group, July 2001), paragraph 15.55 at www.dti.gov.uk/cld/final_report/ch_15.pdf 25 For example, the requirement, for small-incorporated companies to give guarantees in respect of the company’s indebtedness. 26 Littlewoods Mail Order Stores Ltd. v. Inland Revenue Commissioners [1969] 1 W.L.R. 1241 at 1254 per Lord Denning M.R. 27 [1991] 4 All ER 769 28 As referred to by Ottolenghi, S., ‘From Peeping behind the corporate veil to ignoring it completely’, [1990] 53 MLR 338 29 Ibid. at p. 779 per Staughton LJ 30 [1916] AC 307 31 Ottolenghi, op.cit. p. 340 32 This point is arguable, but for the benefit of this paper lifting the veil is not regarded as having a significant effect on the Salomon principle. 33 Ibid. at p. 779 per Staughton LJ 3 Furthermore is it possible or desirable to reduce these inroads into some consistent principle? How do we go about answering this question and what principles can we rely on to determine when the veil will be disregarded? Ottolenghi highlights there can be no restriction on the number of cases where the court will lift the corporate veil.34 He feels the problem lies in trying to explain the judgments that deviate from the strict Salomon principle.35 He proposes a re-categorisation of the common nomenclature and detects four different ‘attitudes’ the court will adopt when deciding whether to ‘lift’ or ‘pierce’ the corporate veil.36 It is submitted the analysis he offers goes some way towards reconciling the common law in this area.37 As this paper seeks to critically discuss caselaw where the courts have apparently failed to maintain the Salomon principle, it is more appropriate to adopt the three categories laid down by the Court of Appeal in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd, i.e.:38 ‘agency’, ‘single economic entity’, and the ‘corporate-veil’. These headings represent the circumstances in which the court may be prepared to pierce the veil and they are each discussed below: Agency The principle of agency provides the first way of circumventing the corporate entity rule while acknowledging the separate legal personality of the company. The principle of inferring an agency - principal relationship between a sole owner and a company, was envisaged by Vaughan-Williams at first instance39 but expelled later by the House of Lords in Salomon. Lord Herschell said: ‘In a popular sense, a company may in every case be said to carry on business for and on behalf of its share-holders; but this certainly does not in point of law constitute the relation of principal and agent between them…’.40 Thus it would seem bold for subsequent cases to infer such a relationship. However, this was the exact approach adopted by the court in Smith, Stone & Knight v Birmingham Corporation.41 The case concerned a local government authority compulsorily acquiring a location inhabited by The Birmingham Waste Co. Ltd., a wholly owned subsidiary of Smith, Stone and Knight Ltd. In order to claim compensation for loss of business, the parent company had to establish that the subsidiary was its agent in conducting business on the premises. All but five shares of the subsidiary were owned by the parent company, and the residuary were held on trust by the directors for the parent company. Furthermore, the parent company was in effectual and constant control of the subsidiary, and its profits were treated as those of the parent company. Akinson J considered that in certain circumstances agency relationship might be inferred and proceeded to lay down a six point criteria which would tend to establish agency; viz,42 1) Were the profits of the subsidiary 34 ‘[T]here can be no numerus clauses’, Ottolenghi, op.cit. p. 354 Ibid. 338 36 ‘Pepping Behind the veil’, ‘Penetrating the Veil’, ‘Extending the Veil’, and ‘Ignoring the Veil’. 37 This method of looking at the subject of lifting the veil is also adopted by Lowry & Watson, Company Law, (London: Butterworths, 2001), Chapter 3. 38 [1990] Ch. 433 39 Broderip v. Salomon (1895) 2 Ch. 323 at 332 40 Salomon v Salomon & Co Ltd [1897] AC 22 at 43 41 [1939] 4 All ER 116 42 [1939] 4 All ER 116 at 121 B 35 4 treated as the profits of the parent? 2) Were the persons conducting the subsidiary’s business appointed by the parent company? 3) Was the parent company the head and brain of the venture? 4) Did the parent company govern the venture, decide what should be done and invested, etc.? 5) Did the parent company make the profits from the venture by its own skill and direction? and 6) Was the parent company in effectual and constant control? The creation of such a six-point criteria test would clearly enable the courts to infer agency where justice demands it. However, as Sealey notes ‘ if a judge were, free to infer agency from the mere facts of control, more or less at will, then the result would be that the veil could be lifted as often as [the court] chooses and the law would be unpredictable.’ 43 Indeed, to make such an inference where one has not been expressly stated as between the parties would greatly dilute the Salomon principle. Furthermore, it is submitted that any attempt to define the conditions from which agency may be inferred, in terms of a test, results in its application to the facts of Salomon. The decision in Smith, Stone & Knight v Birmingham Corporation can be differentiated and reconciled with Salomon in terms of ‘capitalist control’ and ‘functionalist control’ of a company.44 Farrar highlights that Salomon’s case concerned the control of the company by ownership of share capital, which did not therefore invoke an agency.45 Conversely, functional control is concern with who is running the company (this is the focus of five of Akinson J’s criteria), and thus relevant to the determination of agency. This reconciliation can be criticized because the precise nature of ‘capitalistfunctional’ division of control and ownership is not apparent and it cannot be established from other cases before or since Smith, Stone & Knight v Birmingham Corporation. 46 An attempt to solve the problem of agency was considered in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd 47 where Slade LJ considered that although the court is bound to investigate the relationship between the subsidiary and the parent company, there was no presumption that a subsidiary was the company's alter ego.48 This would indicate that agency must be proved on the evidence to exist and may not be inferred from the control of a company or ownership of its shares.49 Gower recognises in the absence of express agreement it would be difficult to prove an agency relationship.50 This suggests in certain circumstances, albeit rarely, an agency relationship may be inferred. However, the question, which remains to be answered, is the extent to which Smith, Stone & Knight v Birmingham Corporation is still applicable? It is perhaps therefore not helpful to regard agency as a method of piercing the veil but rather a device the courts use to piece the veil when they deem it expedient to do so. 43 Sealy, L. S., Cases and Materials in Company Law, (6th ed.), (London: Butterworths, 1996) at p. 62 A distinction drawn by Professor Otto Kahn Freund in [1940] 3 MLR 226 cited in Farrar, Furey & Hannigan, Farrar's Company Law, 4th ed., (London: Butterworths, 1998), p 7, also Pickering, M., A., ‘The Company as a Separate Legal Entity’, (1968) 31 MLR 483, at p 494. 45 Farrar, Furey & Hannigan, op.cit. p 71 46 Pickering, M., A., ‘The Company as a Separate Legal Entity’, (1968) 31 MLR 483, at p 494 47 [1990] Ch. 433 48 [1990] Ch. 433 at 537 49 J. H. Rayner (Mincing Lane) Ltd. v. DTI [1989] Ch 72. 50 Gower, L., C., B., Principles of Modern Company Law, (6th ed.), (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1997), p. 173. 44 5 Single Economic Entity A fundamental principle of company law is that within a group of companies, each member is a separate legal entity. However the court will when deemed appropriate ignore the separateness of its members and treat them as one entity. Slade LJ51 in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd held that there was no general principle that a group of companies is regarded as one. On the contrary he concluded that the fundamental principle provided that each company within a group is a single entity.52 Furthermore he considered that the contention that the distinction will be ignored is fallacious.53 Although it is clear from the decision that regard to the economic realities will, in certain circumstances, permit the court to hold a group of companies to be one, the exact parameters of this rule remain unclear. The ambiguity arises under the courts’ analysis of DHN Food Distributors v Tower Hamlets London Borough Council.54 The Court of Appeal in Adams 55 considered DHN to have been decided upon the relevant statutory provisions: i.e. for the purpose of the statute the court, having regard to the economic realities, concluded that parent and subsidiary were one unit.56 However, in DHN Goff L.J. clearly considered (relying ‘on the facts of this particular case’) that the court was ‘entitled to look at the realities of the situation and pierce the veil.’57 As Gower recognises this would fit more appropriately under the corporate veil heading.58 The problem arises as the court clearly in Adams59 accepted the House of Lords Judgement in the Scottish case of Woolfson v Strathclyde Regional Council60 that held that the corporate veil might only be pierced where the company is a façade.61 What then remains unclear is whether the court while examining the document or statute, having regard to the economic realities, needs to apply the façade test? In Adams the court recognised ‘the relevant parts of the judgment in the D.H.N. case …must we think, likewise be regarded as decisions on the relevant statutory provisions for compensation…’.62 Gower concludes that a façade concealing the true facts is not an essential element in interpretation cases. He submits an additional analysis of whether a company is a façade, is what distinguishes interpretation cases from ‘corporate veil’ cases.63 Some indication of the narrowness of the courts’ application of the single economic entity rule may be extracted from the courts decision in Re Polly peck International Plc (in administration).64 In that case the court rejected the claim that the subsidiary and parent company were a single entity, notwithstanding the fact that this allowed the bondholders to circumvent the purpose of the document and claim separately against each company. 51 [1990] Ch. 433 at 532 He cited the Roskill L.J. as authority of this in the case of The Albazero [1977] A.C. 774, 807. 53 [1990] Ch. 433 at 536 54 [1976] 1WLR 852 55 [1990] Ch. 433 at 536 56 DHN Food Distributors v Tower Hamlets London Borough Council [1976] 1WLR 852 per Lord Denning MR at p. 860 and per Shaw LJ at p. 867 57 [1976] 1WLR 852 at p. 861 58 Gower, L., C., B., Principles of Modern Company Law, (6th ed.), (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1997), p. 168 59 [1990] Ch. 433 at 539 60 [1978] SLT 159 61 [1978] SLT 159 per Lord Keith of Kinkel at p. 161 62 [1990] Ch. 433 at 536 63 Gower, L., C., B., op.cit. p. 169 64 [1996] 2 All ER 433 52 6 The Corporate Veil The courts have come to accept a well-recognised exception to the rule, that they are able to pierce the corporate veil where special circumstances suggest that the corporate structure is a mere facade obscuring the true facts.65 The term façade has been interchangeably used with numerous descriptions, such as ‘device’, ‘sham’, ‘mask’, ‘cloak’, ‘stratagem’, and ‘puppet’ to highlight that the company has been controlled by a member who has used the company for his own desired ends, which may well involve the ‘abuse of the corporate form’. 66 The circumstances and the extent to which the court will pierce the corporate veil and refuse to acknowledge the separate legal personality of the company have long been unclear. Although some commentators might claim that the mist has cleared in the light of the Court of Appeal’s ‘mammoth decision’ in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd.67 It is submitted that this is not the case. The ambiguity arises from the Court of Appeal's categorisation of previous caselaw and its attempt to reduce the ambit of the rule to a single principle, while failing to provide a comprehensive definition of it. Firstly, prior to the decision of Adams v Cape Industries Ltd the courts were confronted with two opposing decisions, that of the Court of Appeal in DHN Food Distributors v Tower Hamlets London Borough Council and the House of Lord’s decision in the Scottish case of Woolfson v Strathclyde Regional Council. In the former case the premises from which the company traded where compulsorily acquisitioned. However, as the premises were owned by a wholly owned subsidiary of the company, the local authority contended under the principle of Salomon that no business of the owner had been disrupted. The Court of Appeal unanimously held that ‘it was entitled to look at the realities of the situation and pierce the corporate veil’.68 Thus, the company although not actually the owner, was able to recover for loss of trade. Lord Denning MR69 quoting Gower considered that there was ‘evidence of a general tendency to ignore the separate legal entities of various companies within a group, and to look instead at the economic entity of the whole group'.70 The case of Woolfson similarly concerned the compulsory acquisition of property by an authority and the claim for loss of business by the trading company, notwithstanding the fact that the company itself did not own the premises. The case of Woolfson was distinguished from DHN on the fact that the company owning the property was partially, rather than wholly, owned by the claimant company. Moreover, the House of Lords hinted that the decision of DHN was incorrect. Lord Keith doubted ‘whether the Court of Appeal [in DHN] properly applied the principle that it is appropriate to pierce the corporate veil only where special circumstances exist indicating that it is a mere façade concealing the true facts.’71 Despite the Woolfson decision stemming from the House of Lords, it was questionable whether the case laid down a binding precedent for English courts (because of its status as a Scottish decision). Furthermore, the Court of Appeal failed to 65 Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional Council [1978] S.L.T. 159 at 161 per Lord Keith of Kinkel Schmitthoff, ‘Salomon in the shadow’ [1976] JBL 305 67 Griffiths, M., ‘Lifting the Corporate Veil’, ACCA: Corporate Sector Review, (2003) issue 44 at www.acca.co.uk/publications/corpsecrev/44/895748 68 DHN Food Distributors v Tower Hamlets London Borough Council [1976] 1WLR 852 per Goff LJ at p. 861 69 [1976] 1WLR 852 at p. 860 70 Gower, Principles of Modern Company Law, 3rd ed. (1969), p. 216 71 [1978] SLT 159 per Lord Keith of Kirkel at p. 161 66 7 acknowledge it in Re A Company72 where it was held, that the court should pierce the corporate veil whenever justice so requires.73 Instead of confronting the conflicting approaches directly, the Court of Appeal circumvented the problem, (while expressly approving the decision of Woolfson), by claiming DHN to have been decided on the relevant statutory provision. In the light of the ambiguity of previous caselaw the courts’ failure to reject outright the principle that the court could examine the reality of the situation and pierce the veil is unfortunate. Furthermore, (as shall be examined later), it is questionable whether it is desirable to retain the principle, however limited, that the court is able to consider economic realities and conclude that a group of companies is one. Secondly, Slade LJ, with whom the rest of the Court of Appeal agreed, stated that there was ‘one well recognised exception to the rule prohibiting the piercing of “the corporate veil”’.74 He was referring to the House of Lords decision in Woolfson, which considered that the corporate veil could only be pierced when the company was a `facade concealing the true facts’.75 The approach taken by the court in Adams was confirmed by the subsequent Court of Appeal decision of Ord v Bellhaven Pubs Plc.76 Clearly the reduction of the principle to a single rule dispels a certain amount of uncertainty. However, ambiguity remains as the court in Adams expressly stated that it did not intend to provide a comprehensive definition of ‘façade’.77 Furthermore, it is equally unhelpful to return to the House of Lords decision in Woolfson who were similarly vague in the discussion of the term. What can be distilled from both cases is the approval of the Court of Appeal’s decision in Guilford Motor Co Ltd v Horne,78 and Russell J's decision in Jones v Lipman.79 In both cases companies were formed and used as a ‘cloak or sham’, a ‘device’ enabling the individual controlling the company to avoid binding legal obligations. As Russell J colourfully put it in Jones v Lipman the company was ‘the creature of the first defendant, a device, a sham, a mask which [he] held before his face to avoid recognition by the eye of equity.’80 However, in the light of Creasey v Breachwood Motors Ltd81 it remains questionable whether the corporate veil can be pierced on grounds of the fraud exception, in a case where a company has already been incorporated prior to a transfer, which had the effect of facilitating members from escaping their current legal obligations. Payne in her article ‘Lifting the corporate veil: a reassessment of the fraud exception’ comments that a ‘fraud is no less of a fraud’, simply because a pre-existing company was used. She further submits that Creasey should 72 [1985] BCLC 333 The suggestion that the Court will use its powers to pierce the corporate veil whenever it thinks necessary to achieve justice was later disproved in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd, where it was held that: ‘save in cases which turn on the wording of particular statutes or contracts, the Court is not free to disregard the principle of Salomon… merely because it considers that justice so requires.’ [1990] Ch 433 Per Slade LJ. This has been affirmed as the current position by Robert Walker J in Re Polly Peck International plc (No. 3) [1996] 1BCLC 428 and by Morritt V-C in Trustor AB v Smallbone (No. 2) [2001] 1 WLR 1177. 74 Adams v Cape Industries Ltd [1990] Ch. 433 at 539 75 Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional Council [1978] SLT 159 per Lord Keith of Kinkel at p. 161 76 [1998] 2 BCLC 447 77 [1990] Ch. 433 at 543 78 [1933] Ch 935 79 [1962] 1 All ER 442 80 [1962] 1 All ER 442 at 445 c -d 81 [1993] BCLC 480 73 8 have been decided on the basis the ‘existence of a legal right must pre-date the use of the corporate form and not the incorporation of that vehicle’.82 The judge in Creasey refused to apply the fraud exception, as he understood it because he felt there was no intention to defraud; he held that ‘it would be wrong to draw so strongly adverse an inference’.83 Commentators have taken the view that making such a distinction is ‘arbitrary’, ‘irrelevant' and nonsensical.84 To what extent this represents the law is unclear as the case was disproved, albeit on a separate ground, by the Court of Appeal in Ord v Bellhaven Pubs Plc. However, the Court of Appeal’s treatment of Creasey raises further doubt as to the true extent of the 'facade' test. In Ord the Court of Appeal considered Creasey to have been decided on the basis that the court considered it possible to pierce the corporate veil whenever justice required. This, if true is clearly contrary to the authority of Adams v Cape Industries Ltd. However, it has been suggested by Broreilow that although the court in Creasey stated this, read in its true context it was ‘not intended to be a statement of general principle’ rather it was an ‘observation that there is no general principle as to when this power should be applied’. 85 The true basis of the decision in Creasey was that ‘the transfer was a breach of the directors’ fiduciary duties to [the company]’.86 As the facts of Creasey were distinguished87 from Jones v Lipman and Guilford Motor Co Ltd v Horne it would seem Creasey cannot therefore be considered within the line of authority supporting the fraud exception (as conventionally understood), as the case does not fall within the factual boundaries of the exception. It would seem clear that Creasey has extended the ‘façade principle’ (which if so extended, it would surely require a change of name). Although the decision is unlikely to be resurrected after its treatment by Ord it exemplifies the uncertainty resulting from the courts failure to set out clearly the notion of ‘façade’. Conclusion: Does the Current Legal Position Adopt an AllEncompassing Consistent Principle? This paper has shown that caselaw has failed to produce an allencompassing principle as to when the court is able to lift the veil. Rather the circumstances in which the courts will draw upon the three exceptions remain unclear. The principles of agency and single economic entity, despite being narrowly defined and limited in scope, permit the court to circumvent the principle of separate corporate entity, notwithstanding the absence of bad faith. Conversely the principle of piercing the corporate veil would seem to have been limited to cases where there has been a deliberate concealment of the identity of the incorporator in order to avoid incumbent and binding legal obligations. Although the exact ambit of the principle remains unclear it seems that the court will be unwilling to lift the corporate veil in the absence of bad faith and not simply where justice demands it. It remains to be considered whether it is desirable to reduce the courts power in such a way. It is arguable that the development of the principle of piercing the corporate veil where justice demands it is appropriate. Indeed, the notion of adopting such a rule on a case-by-case basis allows justice to succeed in each individual case. However, can justice be encompassed within an uncertain 82 Payne, J., ‘Lifting the corporate veil: a reassessment of the fraud exception’, [1997], Cambridge Law Journal, 284, p.290 83 [1993] BCLC 480 at 492-493 per Mr Richard Southwell QC (deputy judge of the High Court) 84 Bromilow , D., ‘Creasey v Breachwood Motors: Mistaken Identity Leads To Untimely Death’ [1998] Company Lawyer 198 at p. 198 85 Ibid. at p. 198 86 Ibid. at p. 199 87 [1993] BCLC 480 at 490 9 rule? It is submitted that justice can only be achieved when parties are able to depend upon clear and certain principles. Caselaw has been able to provide such a principle although its clarity remains questionable. But as Lord Parker in Daimler Co Ltd v Continental Tyre and Rubber Co (GB) Ltd88 stated, the ‘legislature might, but no court could possibly, lay down a hard and fast rule’. Thus it is desirable for parliament to expressly set out the conditions when the corporate veil may be pierced, as ‘the legislature can forge a sledgehammer capable of cracking open the corporate shell.’89 Aside from this, there would seem a more important reason why the development of judicial inroads should be halted. The corporate entity rule as established in the case of Salomon v. Salomon & Co Ltd. provides the fundamental principle of the separate legal entity of the company. Although some commentators have pointed to the ‘jurisprudential ineptitude’ of the court in rejecting the clear intentions of the parliament, it must now be recognised that parliament has had ample time to reject it and thus it must be inferred that the rule is the intention of parliament.90 In the case of companies which seek to benefit from a piercing of the corporate veil such as Smith, Stone & Knight v Birmingham Corporation, DHN, and Woolfson, the companies should not take the benefit of the incorporation i.e.: limited liability, without the disadvantages: in those cases separate legal personality.91 Following from this it would seem unfortunate that the Court of Appeal in Adams v Cape Industries Ltd rather than limit their ambit, did not expel completely the principles of agency and single economic entity. If inroads into the principle are desirable at all, they must be limited to circumstances of bad faith. As noted previously it must be concluded that this may be best achieved through legislation. 88 [1916] AC 307 at p. 346 Per Devlin LJ in Bank voor Handel en Scheepvaart NV v. Slatford [1953] 1 QB 248 at 278. 90 Hicks, A., ‘Limiting the rise of limited liability’, in Baldwin and Cane (eds), Law and Uncertainty: Risks and Legal Processes, (Kluwer, 1997) in Hicks & Goo, Cases & Materials on Company Law, (3rd ed.), (London: Blackstone, 2001), p. 100 91 Rixon, F., G., ‘Lifting the Veil Between Holding and Subsidiary Companies’ (1986) 102 LQR 415 89 10 Bibliography Bottomley, S., ‘The Birds, The Beasts, and The Bat: Developing a Constitutionalist Theory of Corporate Regulation’ (1999) 27 F L Rev 243. Bromilow , D., ‘Creasey v. Breachwood Motors: Mistaken Identity Leads To Untimely Death’ [1998] Company Lawyer 198 DTI, Modern Company Law For A Competitive Economy: Final Report, (The Company Law Review Steering Group, July 2001), paragraph 15.55 at www.dti.gov.uk/cld/final_report/ch_15.pdf Easterbrook and Fischel, Limited Liability and the Corporation (1985) 52 University of Chicago Law Review 89 Farrar, ‘Frankenstein Incorporated or Fools’ Parliament? Revisiting the Concept of the Corporation in Corporate Governance’, (1998) 10 BOND LR at www.bond.edu.au/law/blr/vol10-2/2-Farrar.pdf Farrar, Furey & Hannigan, Farrar's Company Law, (4th ed.), (London: Butterworths, 1998) Gallagher & Ziegler, ‘Lifting the Corporate Veil in the Pursuit of Justice’, [1990] JBL 292 Gower, Gower's Principles of Modern Company Law, (5th ed), (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1992) Gower, Principles of Modern Company Law, (6th ed.), (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1997) Goulding, S., Principles of Company Law (1996), London: Cavendish Publishing Limited Griffiths, M., ‘Lifting the Corporate Veil’, ACCA: Corporate Sector Review, (2003), issue 44 at www.acca.co.uk/publications/corpsecrev/44/895748 Halpern, Trebilcock and Turnbull, An Economic Analysis of Limited Liability (1980) 30 University of Toronto Law Journal 117 Hicks & Goo, Cases & Materials on Company Law, (3rd ed.), (London: Blackstone, 2001) Ireland, P., ‘The Triumph of the Company Legal Form, 1856-1914’, in Adams, J., (ed), Essays for Clive Schmitthoff, (1983) Khan-Freund, ‘Some Reflections on Company Law Reform’, (1944), 7 MLR 54 Lowry & Watson, Company Law, (London: Butterworths, 2001) Mason, French & Ryan, Company Law, (13th ed.), (Hampshire: Blackstones Press, 1996) Mitchell, ‘Lifting the Corporate Veil in the English Courts: An Empirical Study’ (1999) 3 Company, Financial and Insolvency Law Review 3 pp15-28 Ottolenghi, S., ‘From Peeping behind the corporate veil to ignoring it completely’, [1990] 53 MLR 338 Payne, J., ‘Lifting the corporate veil: a reassessment of the fraud exception’, [1997], Cambridge Law Journal, 284 Pettet, B., ‘Limited Liability- A Principle for the 21st Century?’ [1995] CLP 125 Pickering, M., A., ‘The Company as a Separate Legal Entity’, (1968) 31 MLR 483 Posner, R., Economic Analysis of Law, (2nd ed.), (Boston: Little, Brown & Co, 1977) 11 Puig, G., V., ‘A Two-Edged Sword: Salomon and the Separate Legal Entity Doctrine’, E Law - Murdoch University Electronic Journal of Law at www.murdoch.edu.au/elaw/issues/v7n3/puig73a.html Rixon, F., G., ‘Lifting the Veil Between Holding and Subsidiary Companies’ (1986) 102 LQR 415 Schmitthoff, ‘Salomon in the shadow’ [1976] JBL 305 Sealy, L. S., Cases and Materials in Company Law, 6th ed., (London: Butterworths, 1996) Williams, ‘Fraudulent Trading’ (1986) 1 Companies and Securities Journal 14 Whincup, ‘Inequitable Incorporation’ (1981) 2 Company Lawyer 158 1