Understanding Disinvestment and Decline Tom Carter Canada Research Chair in Urban Change and Adaptation Chesya Polevychok Research Associate January 2006 Canada Research Chair in Urban Change and Adaptation The Department of Geography The University of Winnipeg Table of Contents 1. Introduction 2. Theories Explaining Neighbourhood Decline 2.1. Ecological Models 2.1.1. The Concentric Zone Model 1 1 2 2 2.1.2. The Sectoral Model 3 2.1.3. The Multi-Nuclei Theory 3 2.1.4. White’s Late Twentieth Century Model 4 2.1.5. Urban Realms Model 5 2.1.6. Social Area Analysis 6 2.1.7. Filtering 7 2.1.8. The Life-cycle Model 8 2.1.9. The Bid Rent Theory 11 2.1.10. The Border Models 11 2.1.11. The Vacancy Chain Hypothesis 12 2.1.12. The Cycles of Disadvantage 12 2.1.13. The Broken Windows Theory 13 2.1.14. Urban Underclass 14 2.1.15. The Pull and Obsolescence Hypotheses 16 2.1.16. Environmental Determinism 16 2.2. The Subcultural School 2.3. Political Economists 17 17 2.3.1. The Urban Growth Machine Thesis 17 2.3.2. Urban Structural Change 18 2.3.3. The Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis 19 2.3.4. The Exploitation Hypothesis 20 2.3.5. The Fiscal Crisis Theory 2.4. The Social Capital Model 2.5. Theories Summary 3. Factors that Prompt Neighbourhood Decline 3.1. Poverty 3.2. Racial Conflict 3.3. Ageing of Population 3.4. Suburban Sprawl 3.5. The Spatial Distribution of Affordable Housing 3.6. Decline of Inner-city Schools 3.7. Creative Class 3.8. Unintended Policy Effects 4. Threshold Indicators 4.1. Definition 4.2. The United States Experience 4.2.1. Poverty, Unemployment, Female Headship, and School Dropout Rates 4.2.2. Housing and Homeownership Characteristics 4.3. The Canadian Experience 5. Conclusions List of References 21 21 23 25 27 28 29 29 30 30 31 32 33 33 34 34 38 39 40 41 Causes of Decline 1. Introduction Understanding the circumstances and advancing solutions to arrest urban decline require a sound knowledge of the processes that initiate disinvestment and decline in urban neighbourhoods. Many theories that contribute to an understanding of these processes have been postulated. The explanatory processes include natural evolution, ecological succession and down filtering, middle class flight, ageing of population, obsolescence of the built environment, changes in urban form and the pattern of suburban expansion, the unintended effects of public policy, structural economic change and class and racial conflict among others. This report will examine and explain many of the urban decline theories. The discussion will contribute to a better understanding of the interaction and interdependence of neighbourhood, city wide, regional, national and international influences, and both macro and micro level processes that contribute to disinvestment and decline in urban areas. This document is meant to be a background paper for those interested in issues associated with urban decline and solutions focused on arresting decline in urban areas. 2. Theories Explaining Neighbourhood Decline Scholars generally identify three major schools of thought with regard to our theoretical understanding of how and why neighbourhoods change – ecological, subcultural, and political economy (Pitkin 2001, Ding and Knaap 2002). The following sections will expand on these three schools of thought and the theories they incorporate. Discussion in additional sections will complement these theories and add other concepts proposed to explain neighbourhood decline. Ecological models originate from the work of urban sociologists and economists and focus on exogenous forces that shape the dynamics of neighbourhood change. Such factors include ecological forces, analogous to those in biology, that cause invasion and succession of people with different characteristics and different types of land uses during the life cycle of a neighbourhood; filtering processes in the housing stock that cause neighbourhoods to decline with age; and economic factors that shape the bid-rent functions for urban land. Subcultural models are less deterministic and focus on factors such as social networks, socially determined neighbourhood reputations, and sense of neighbourhood attachment. Finally, political economy models focus on the forces of capital accumulation and the institutions through which accumulation takes place. In these models the type and location of capital investments are critical factors in neighbourhood change (Ding and Knaap 2002). 1 Causes of Decline 2.1. Ecological models Ecologists have developed a series of models of neighbourhood change, which has set the foundation for a better understanding of neighbourhood decline. 2.1.1. The Concentric Zone Model Originated by Earnest Burgess in the 1920s, the Concentric Zone Model or Invasion/Succession theory was fundamental for establishing neighbourhood change as an inevitable, natural result of competition for space. The city, according to Burgess (1925), is made up of six concentric rings: the innermost ring being the central business district (CBD), surrounded by the industrial sector, slum housing, working-class housing, higher-status dwellings and finally commuter housing. As the city grows, each ring places pressure on the ring surrounding it to expand. For example the central business districts expands into the industrial sector which in turn pushes into the area of slum housing displacing people who seek housing in the working-class district. In general, then, residential neighbourhoods deteriorate as land uses of a growing CBD invade the next ring forcing lower-income residents to move and push the growth of the city outward. This is presented as a natural process of competition and selection, similar to theories of evolution in the biological sciences (Pitkin 2001). This theory was more applicable to the pre World War II city which was monocentric in nature (one central commercial/retail district), developed at higher densities, more reliant on public transportation, and less dominated by the automobile. 2 Causes of Decline 2.1.2. The Sector Model The Sector Model, usually attributed to Homer Hoyt (1939), considers the direction, not the distance, as the key factor in determining the spatial organization of a metropolis. It states that, while the growth is still outward, sectors as they expand outward in a particular direction tend to maintain the original socio-economic characteristics of more inner areas. The general picture is that different sectors have different socio-economic and land use characteristics. The movement of high status populations outward from the city centre along the main transport routes has been accompanied by changes in the methods of transport, the shift from public transit to the private automobile, for example. This has led to more expansive settlement patterns in this model. For example the high-income areas where people prefer to use the private automobile for transportation do not always grow out in a linear fashion but form fans loosely centred on the transport links (freeways or major arterials) to the city centre. Based upon a block-by-block analysis of changes in a variety of housing characteristics in 142 US cities, Hoyt notes that: The high rent neighbourhoods do not skip about at random in the process of movement, they follow a definite path in one or more sectors of the city. ... the different types of residential areas tend to grow outward along rather distinct radii, and a new growth on the arc of a given sector tends to take on the character of the initial growth of that sector (ibid.). Controlling factors in this theory tend to be previous patterns of land use, transportation arteries, physical features such as rivers, sites with attractive physical amenities and the desire by some land uses to avoid other land uses. 2.1.3. The Multi-Nuclei Theory The Multi-Nuclei Theory suggests that a city may have more than one nucleus/centre apart from the CBD from which other zones of land use develop (Harris and Ullmann 1945). While Harris and Ullman still saw the CBD as the major centre of 3 Causes of Decline commerce, they suggested that specialized cells of activity would develop according to specific requirements of certain activities, different rent-paying abilities, and the tendency for some kinds of economic activity to cluster together. Separate nuclei include airports, new industrial centres and trading estates, small towns that have become engulfed. Specialized regions may develop, such as industrial clusters. This theory marks the transition of cities from mono-centric to poly-centric urban forms with commercial, retail, industrial and other business and employment nodes outside the CBD. Employment and shopping nodes other than the CBD began to exert an influence on land use patterns around them. 2.1.4. White’s Late Twentieth Century Model There is an increasing shift of North American cities from mono-centric to poly-centric urban forms in White’s Late Twentieth Century Model. In the model the city continues to spread but there is also a growing diversity and separation of activities. Axial and circumferential highways represent an extension of the transportation system. Transportation corridors connect the axial system with all parts of the city. This freeway/beltway network provides "easy and fast access" to all parts of the city by private car, although increasing congestion makes "easy and fast access" a very relative concept. Epicentres (suburban and regional shopping malls and big box development) rival the traditional core. Often they are bigger in terms of retail space and number of functions. There is still a zone of decline (stagnation). Middle class residential areas (MC) have expanded significantly. Cars, which are relatively inexpensive for the individual, have facilitated the growth of middle class suburbs but there are other factors that have contributed to the spread and expansion of these suburbs: • an increase in housing demand, first from returning veterans following WWII, then the baby boomers. This demand was easier to accommodate in "greenfield" suburban development; • more flexible mortgage lending terms such as lower down payment requirements which made home ownership accessible to more households; 4 Causes of Decline • rising incomes relative to costs. More people could afford to own a single detached family home; • the entry of more married women into the workforce also increased incomes; • new building technology that facilitated tract building in suburban areas at affordable prices. Suburban building developed into an almost "cookie cutter" approach; and, • the strengthening of the "North American Dream" - to own one's own house on a plot of land in the suburbs. White’s model characterizes developments in urban form that continued to weaken the central business district and the surrounding older residential areas. 2.1.5. Urban Realms Model The Urban Realms Model represents perhaps the most recent evolution of urban form in North America. What has emerged as cities have evolved is a number of large self-sufficient sectors, each focused on a downtown independent of the traditional downtown and the central city. The entire metropolitan area becomes reorganized into a set of independent urban realms. This is often called the "pepperoni pizza model." Each urban realm is anchored by a major mixed use downtown core. Even in a city as small as Winnipeg you can see elements of this model. St Vital Shopping Centre has certainly become a mixed use "downtown area" that the residents in the south and south-east part of Winnipeg frequent for many services and the same is true for Kildonan Place in the north and north east, for example. 5 Causes of Decline The various realms are connected by major traffic arterials, often freeways and circumferential links circle the entire realm. The automobile is the major form of transportation. Public transportation (buses, subways) are difficult to introduce because there is no particular focus of employment and services - there are many such areas scattered throughout the city. Residential development is generally very low density. In circumstances such as this, ridership on public transportation is so low that fares do not even come close to covering the cost. These cities are designed to accommodate the automobile. The growth of “new” Urban Realms sets up push/pull forces that result in people in the old original city moving to new realms, creating population and business loss and decline in general. These evolving forms of the North American city, in association with dynamic processes that have created and accompanied this evolution, have collectively tended to weaken the older central residential areas and the original central business district. 2.1.6. Social Area Analysis Similar to the previous model is Social Area Analysis, developed by Shevsky and Bell (1955) to relate changing urban social structure and residential patterns to the processes of economic development and urbanization. The analysis concentrates on the social characteristics of the urban population in attempting to explain land use. People tend to cluster or concentrate in residential areas of the city according to: 1) economic status, 2) family status and 3) ethnic composition of its residents. 6 Causes of Decline This clustering has an effect on the nature of residential development – dwelling values, size, design and condition as well as the nature of institutions and type of retail activity. Although clustering by socio-economic characteristics is still very much part of the urban environment it can be argued that retailing trends that have marked the dominance of large enclosed malls and big-box development have weakened the effect of clustering on the diversity of retailing functions. According to Driedger (1991), Canadian cities have a tendency to follow the pattern of ethnic concentration described by Shevsky and Bell rather than the model of neighbourhood change of Park and Burgess (1925). These theories, although they do not in themselves explain disinvestment and decline in neighbourhoods, establish land use patterns and urban form that when combined with other processes can initiate or facilitate neighbourhood deterioration. 2.1.7. Filtering Filtering is another influential theory and one that works in conjunction with some of the theories already explained. Many researchers have used the income-succession model as a basis for their studies of the “filtering” of housing stock though various income and racial groups (Galster et al. 2003). Hoyt (1933) expands Burgess's model by applying economic theory to argue that neighbourhoods naturally decline as property owners invest less in ageing properties due to rising maintenance costs and move to new housing on the periphery. He argued that expansion outward was due, in part, to the attraction of new neighbourhoods on the periphery, not as the result of a push mechanism from the inner circles as in the invasion/succession model. Housing filters down from the rich to the middle class to the poor. Housing deteriorates over time, so the rich periodically move to new housing that is higher quality and incorporates more modern and preferred designs and amenities. Middle-income people can either buy lower priced new housing or slightly used housing that was occupied by the rich. Lower income residents can’t buy new housing, as they can’t afford the cost of construction. They buy used housing that was previously occupied by middle-income people. The price of used housing eventually falls to the point where low-income people can afford it. Housing that used to be occupied by lower income people can’t fall any lower in the income distribution. Often it deteriorates to the point where it is abandoned. The filtering of housing and deterioration in quality and value as housing filters down to lower income households is a contributing factor to neighbourhood decline. Smith (1963) builds on Hoyt’s model to argue that other factors such as the existence of mortgage credit needs to be added to the equation of filtering (Pitkin 2001). As housing declines in quality and price, and ages, it is more difficult to arrange mortgage financing to purchase and renovate. When people cannot get access to credit to purchase or renovate houses they deteriorate and are abandoned at an even more rapid rate. Access to credit becomes more difficult in declining neighbourhoods and tends to hasten neighbourhood decline. 7 Causes of Decline “Stage theory of growth” and the “Life-cycle Model” (see below) are well-known applications of the filtering model, in which neighbourhood decline is viewed as part of a linear, evolutionary process (ibid.). The basic assumption of filtering is also inherent in many current discussions on urban sprawl. Opponents to spreading suburban development argue that the social and spatial mobility brought about by development of housing and transportation facilities on the urban fringe has contributed to the decline of neighbourhoods in central cities (Temkin and Rohe 1996). 2.1.8. The Life-cycle Model Researchers often use the invasion-succession model in combination with a Lifecycle Model of neighbourhood change to describe the decline of neighbourhoods. From this perspective, neighbourhoods are born, age, decline, until they eventually are abandoned and demolished (Galster and Krall 2003). According to this theory, neighbourhood decline is inevitable, unidirectional, and not necessarily bad (Temkin and Rohe 1996). The filtering of housing stock in a given neighbourhood provides an opportunity for potential lower income in-movers to improve their housing conditions by moving into this housing from worse housing (ibid.). John T. Metzger (2000), in his article Planned Abandonment: The Neighborhood Life Cycle Theory and National Urban Policy, presents the evolution of life-cycle theory over the years (Table 1). Table 1. The Stages of Neighbourhood Change: The Evolution of the Life-Cycle Theory, 1935 to 1975. U. S. Home Owners’ Loan Corp. residential security maps (1935) U. S. Home Owners’ Loan Corp. Waverly: A Study in Neighborhood Conservation (1940) First Grade “A” Area (green) Well- planned, homogeneous population First Stage Edgar M. Hoover and Raymond Vernon Anatomy of a Metropolis: The Changing Distribution of People and Jobs within the New York Metropolitan Region (Regional Plan Association of New York, 1959) Stage 1 Real Estate Research Corporation The Dynamics of Neighborhood Change (U. S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, 1975) New residential construction Single- family residential development Homogeneous housing and moderate to upper income, insurance and conventional financing available Second Grade “B” Area (blue) Completely developed, stable Second Stage Stage 2 Normal use and maintenance Transition to higher density, apartment construction Stage 2: Incipient Decline Aging housing, decline in income and education level, influx of middleincome minorities, fear of racial transition Third Grade “C” Area (yellow) Third Stage Stage 3 Stage 3: Clearly Declining Stage 1: Healthy 8 Causes of Decline U. S. Home Owners’ Loan Corp. residential security maps (1935) U. S. Home Owners’ Loan Corp. Waverly: A Study in Neighborhood Conservation (1940) Edgar M. Hoover and Raymond Vernon Anatomy of a Metropolis: The Changing Distribution of People and Jobs within the New York Metropolitan Region (Regional Plan Association of New York, 1959) Downgrading to accommodate higher density through conversion and over-crowding of existing structures, spread of ethnic and minority districts In transition and decline from age, obsolescence, lack of restrictions, lower household incomes and housing values, lack of homogeneity Age, obsolescence, structural neglect Fourth Grade “D” Area (red) Final stage of decline, mostly low-income rental housing, “undesirable population” Fourth Stage Stage 4 Falling investment and rent values, neglect of maintenance, districtwide deterioration Thinning-out or “shrinkage” characterized by population loss and decline in housing units Fifth Stage Stage 5 Slum area with depreciated values, substandard housing, social problems Renewal through public intervention, redevelopment and replacement of obsolete housing with new multifamily apartments Real Estate Research Corporation The Dynamics of Neighborhood Change (U. S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, 1975) Higher density, visible deterioration, decrease in white in-movers, more minority children in schools, mostly rental housing, problems in securing insurance and financing Stage 4: Accelerating Decline Increasing vacancies, predominantly low-income and minority tenants or elderly ethnics, high unemployment, fear of crime, no insurance or institutional financing available, declining public services, absentee- owned properties Stage 5: Abandoned Severe dilapidation, poverty and squatters, high crime and arson, negative cash flow from buildings Source: Metzger, 2000, p.9. Neighbourhood life-cycle theories had an effect on public policy and disinvestment. For example, according to Metzger (2000), a number of urban life-cycle theories facilitated the decline of inner-city, low-income, predominantly AfricanAmerican neighbourhoods. Neighbourhood life-cycle theories caused financial institutions to spurn neighbourhoods defined as "declining" because they constituted risky investments, leading to a guaranteed spiral of decline. He argues that an alternative paradigm of neighbourhood theory emphasizing collective action on the part of community residents would have helped many urban neighbourhoods to avoid decline and abandonment. 9 Decreasing (net) Town house conversions c. Low Luxury highrise apartment b. Increasing (net) Increasing (net) High Public housing a. Medium Declining (net densities may be increasing) Low Non-residential construction – demolitions of existing units 4. Thinning out 5. Renewal Medium (increasing slowly), population total down Very low Conversions of existing dwellings to multi-family 3. Down-rading Medium (increasing slowly or stable) Low, decreasing Multi-family Low (but increasing) High 2. In-filling Population density Level of construction Single-family (lowdensity multiple) Dwelling type Physical changes 1. Suburbanization Stage Table 2. Summary of Neighbourhood Life Cycles. (adapted from Bourne 1976, p. 139) Few children Young families, many children Mixed Older families, few children, non-family households Older families, fewer children Ageing families, older children, more mixing Young families, small children, large households Family structure High net inmigr., high turnover Medium Declining Increasing Low Higher net outmigration, high turnover Declining Increasing Low net outmigration, high turnover Low net inmigration, low mobility turnover High net inmigration, high mobility turnover Migration mobility Medium (declining) High (stable) High (increasing) Social status income Social changes The second transition stage – may take either of two forms depending on conditions Selective nonresidential succession Long period of depreciation and stagnation; some non-residential succession First transition stage – less homogeneity in age, class, housing Initial development stage; cluster development; largescale projects Other characteristics Other changes Causes of Decline 10 Causes of Decline Bourne (1976) provides a concept of a neighbourhood life cycle that links physical and socio-economic changes with residential mobility (Table 2). The concept provides a useful explanation of urban residential structure, although it would be very difficult to test its validity empirically. The next group of ecological models focuses on residential location decisions, predicting that households will move from small housing units in the central city to larger ones in the suburbs as their incomes rise (Alonso 1960, 1964, Galster 1977, Lucy and Phillips 2000, Pitkin 2001). 2.1.9. The Bid Rent Theory According to the Neoclassical, or Bid Rent Theory, urban residents make a tradeoff between land, housing, and transportation costs, between being close to the city centre - where housing costs are highest - and locating in a neighbourhood with relatively affordable housing - that is farther from the centre (Alonso 1960). The residential bid price curve is “the set of prices for land the individual could pay at various distances while deriving a constant level of satisfaction” (ibid. p.59). Middle- and upper-income people can purchase more land and housing at lower per unit costs toward the periphery while affording the transportation costs. The poor occupy smaller and older housing closer to work sites. It should be noted that in Bid Rent Theory a home in the suburbs may cost more than a home in the inner city, however, given size, amenities and quality the price is actually cheaper for the entire package of land and housing. Low-income people often end up renting or buying smaller, poorer quality units with fewer amenities in the inner city but actually pay more per square foot or per unit value. They pay more per unit value for housing but perhaps less for transportation. Similar to other ecological models, the bid rent model helps explain the outward expansion of cities, positing a linear relationship between land costs and proximity to the centre: the more accessible the land, the higher its value. The idea that low-income households pay more per unit of housing in return for reduced transportation costs that is postulated by the Bid Rent Model may be less relevant in today’s North American city than it was in 1960. Low-income people used to be able to access jobs in the inner city. The de-industrialization and loss of retail activities in the inner city and the movement of many manufacturing and retailing jobs to the suburbs, with the associated development of industrial parks and suburban shopping malls, leaves low-income inner city people far from employment. Public transit is not readily available to move people from inner city to suburban locations. This leaves many people trapped in poor quality inner city housing because that is the best they can afford while unemployed because they cannot access the suburban jobs without cheap adequate public transportation. 2.1.10. The Border Models The Border or Tipping Models also focus on the locational decisions of residents but expand the explanatory variables to include social characteristics such as race. Proponents of these models contend that the racial transition of a neighbourhood will 11 Causes of Decline have an impact on existing residents and increase out-migration. These changes will affect how residents from surrounding areas perceive their own neighbourhoods, especially along the “borders” of the neighbourhoods (Pitkin 2001). People often feel uncomfortable when racial transition begins to occur and also fear they will experience declining property values. 2.1.11. The Vacancy Chain Hypothesis The Vacancy Chain hypothesis is consistent with the housing filtering model, which explains the dynamic of new housing construction for wealthy households that sets in motion a chain of vacancies. The vacancy chain causes households to move into higher status neighbourhoods than the ones they leave, and housing units to be successively occupied by lower and lower status occupants. At the end of the vacancy chain, in the least desirable housing stock and the least desirable neighbourhoods, there may be insufficient demand to sustain the housing stock and vacancies go unsatisfied, leading ultimately to housing abandonment. If there is sufficient demand to fill the stock at the bottom of the chain then there will be a group of people living in very poor quality housing. Orfield (1998) contends that the building of new housing at the periphery sets in motion vacancy chains reaching far back into the central core. Thus, the more rapid peripheral growth of middle-class sectors early on creates low demand at the centre of its vacancy chain. Core middle-class neighbourhoods are the first to become impoverished and ultimately ghettoized. As these neighbourhoods become poorer, social and economic decline accelerate and push the middle class out of these neighbourhoods at the same time the vacancy chain initiated by new suburban development is pulling them. Ironically, as the various classes move up and/or flee from central city areas, all the social and economic changes that occur in the core of their sectoral housing markets may eventually follow them through the vacancy chains into the suburbs (ibid.). 2.1.12. The Cycles of Disadvantage The Cycles of Disadvantage thesis had its intellectual origins in America in social area analysis. The basic premise is that physical, economic and social handicaps reinforce one another to ensure life-cycle and inter-generational multiple deprivation on the part of the urban poor, who are often spatially concentrated in declining neighbourhoods. They become an urban underclass. Neighbourhoods do have the potential of shaping the present and future well being of families and individuals in a variety of ways. Wilson (1987) argues that the fortunes of the underclass are strongly shaped by the neighbourhoods in which they reside. As indicated by Jargowsky (1997), the “spatial concentration of poor people acts to magnify poverty and exacerbate its effects” (p. 2). Galster and Hill (1992) draw similar conclusions with a focus on race. Following an extensive review of studies, Ellen and Turner (1997) conclude that neighbourhood characteristics influence a variety of individual characteristics such as educational attainment, criminal involvement, teen sexual activity, and employment, although the mechanisms of causation remain difficult 12 Causes of Decline to identify. There are probably fewer educational opportunities, greater exposure to crime and deviant behaviour, poorer quality of education, poor local infrastructure, difficulty in establishing businesses, and lack of access to information-rich networks in declining neighbourhoods. As noted by Carley (1990), the failure of direct massive environmental intervention to resolve basic problems of poverty, poor quality housing and social disadvantage set in motion more complex human, urban problems. These kinds of interactions lead further to cycles of disadvantage and dysfunction. The study, Deprivation in New Zealand: Regional Patterns and Changes (Maré et al. 2001), also emphasizes the importance of neighbourhood effects. Similar sorts of people tend to choose to live in similar sorts of places because they can only afford similar housing, need similar social services, identify personally or culturally with others in the area, or can provide each other community support. However, when groups of low well-being people live together there may be negative spillovers or “neighbourhood effects” that perpetuate social problems and result in even poorer outcomes for these groups (ibid.). Maré et al. (2001) have found that it is very difficult to document neighbourhood effects empirically, in large part because of the difficulty of determining whether disadvantaged communities appear because disadvantaged people choose to live together, or because living together also worsens their prospects. 2.1.13. The Broken Windows Theory Do areas gather their own momentum of decline, and how does this happen? One of the best documented views of unpopular neighbourhoods is the Broken Windows theory which attributes a loss of social control to the gradual growth in “incivilities”— that is, the lack of informal social control through neighbourhood instability and poor services leading to people tolerating broken windows and other minor damage. This results in a disorderly environment from which more law-abiding people withdraw. The resulting social space becomes increasingly disorganized until more serious crime and disorder take over. At this point the neighbourhood ‘tips’ into steep decline (Glennerster et al. 1999). The theory comes from the article by James Wilson and George Kelling published in the Atlantic Monthly in 1982, entitled The Police and Neighbourhood Safety: Broken Windows. The authors argue that signs of physical and social disorder invite criminal activity; disorder indicates to law-abiding citizens that their neighbourhoods are dangerous places, making these citizens afraid to take an active role in promoting social order in their communities and leading them to withdraw from community life or leaving their neighbourhood entirely. Wilson and Kelling’s definition of “minor” disorder includes such problems and crimes as littering, loitering, public drinking, panhandling, teenage fighting on street corners, and prostitution. Also mentioned are signs of physical disorder, including abandoned cars (with broken windows, naturally) and dilapidated buildings (also with broken windows) (Wilson and Kelling 1982). Disorder invites more disorder in a contagious process that progressively breaks down community standards and ultimately invites criminal invasion (ibid.). 13 Causes of Decline 2.1.14. Urban Underclass The most controversial interpretation of area conditions uses the idea of the culture of poverty and transmitted deprivation to rationalize the existence of a so-called Urban Underclass of people who cannot, or do not want to, help themselves or their children. They have a life-style that conflicts with mainstream values and creates or helps to drive area decline (Glennerster et al. 1999). This underclass is characterized by multiple deprivations, reproduced intergenerationally, and widely thought to be a consequence of the development of a global economy characterized by the deindustrialization of the central city, a polarized employment structure, and a bipolar distribution of wealth (Wilson 1987, Kasarda 1990). Without the skills of work-related experience or education, the support of other adult family members and/or a stable income, members of the underclass are thought to be marginalized from adequately paying jobs, good educational programs, affordable and good quality housing in well-serviced neighbourhoods. It is this isolation that is thought ultimately to bring about the social interactions and norms that shape this subset of the urban poor into a class of its own: ...the communities of the “underclass” are plagued by massive joblessness, flagrant and open lawlessness, and low-achieving schools, and therefore tend to be avoided by outsiders. Consequently the residents of these areas, whether women and children of welfare families or aggressive street criminals, have become increasingly socially isolated from mainstream behaviour. (Wilson 1987, p. 58) Ley and Smith (1997) suggest that concepts of the underclass vary across national boundaries. In the American context, the underclass have most clearly been defined as those who live in extremely poor communities, marked also by high rates of unemployment, welfare dependency, mother-led families, criminal activity, and deficient education or work-related skills. American researchers defined “underclass neighbourhoods” as census tracts with unusually high concentrations – either one standard deviation above the national average or twice the metropolitan median – of lone mothers, men not involved in the labour force, welfare dependants and high-school dropouts (ibid.). Jargowsky (1996) draws attention to the fact that there are certain stereotypes in policy debate about the characteristics of the residents of declining neighbourhoods. He indicates that high poverty areas contain an unexpected social and economic diversity: while some residents clearly engage in “underclass” lifestyles, many of their neighbours are not public assistance recipients and do participate in the labour market, although in lower-skill occupations for fewer hours and lower wages (ibid.). British researchers, rather than defining an underclass on the basis of overlapping patterns of multiple deprivation, or on the spatial concentration of those patterns, have focused on one particular factor – the experience of the long-term unemployed (Ley and Smith 1997). Other European studies also view the creation of an underclass as a function of long-term unemployment and continued exclusion from the labour market and other avenues of upward mobility. But the European underclass, although homogeneous in 14 Causes of Decline terms of labour market position, is socially, politically and culturally heterogeneous (ibid.). In Canada there is no empirical evidence detailing either underclass existence or any critical discussion about whether the underclass provides an appropriate paradigm for the Canadian experience of urban poverty (ibid.). To allow comparison with American research, Ley and Smith define an “underclass” as the population of a census tract whose rates of non-labour force involvement, female-led families, welfare dependency and high school non-completion were notably high, setting thresholds at twice the current CMA median for each variable (Table 3). Table 3. “Underclass” Definition1. American Canadian Proxy 1991 High School Drop Outs Lack of High School Diploma Percentage of 16- 19 year olds who are not enrolled in school and who are not high school graduates. Population 15 years or older whose highest level of education is lower than a high school diploma. Labour Force Activity Male Unemployment Prime- age males not regularly attached to the labour force – males 16 years and over who are not working regularly where working regularly is defined as having a full or part time job for more than 26 weeks a year. Males 15 years and older who during the week of enumeration were without work, actively looked for work in the past four weeks and were available for work; or were on layoff and expected to return to their job and were available for work or had definite arrangements to start a new job in four weeks or less and were available for work. Public Assistance Recipients Government Transfer Recipients Percentage of households receiving public assistance income. Composition of census tract total income from government transfer payments. Female Heads of Families Female Lone Parent Families Households with children, headed by women. Lone parent families with children, headed by women. Source: adapted from Ley and Smith 1997, p. 46. The identification of underclass as distinct from high poverty census tracts has posed severe challenges for researchers. Some of the key data that would identify “underclass” neighbourhoods – such as violent crime rates, drug abuse and rates of outof-wedlock childbirth – are not available on a census tract basis either in the USA or in Canada (Hatfield 1997). Hatfield comments on the article Defining and Measuring the Underclass by Erol Ricketts and Isabel V. Sawhill (1988), indicating that they made the most careful attempt to find statistically measurable indicators of distressed neighbourhoods. The authors 1 Ley and Smith (1997) define an “underclass” community as one in which all four of the Canadian variables score 2x the current CMA median (1991 or 1971). 15 Causes of Decline identify four proxy indicators of the presence of an underclass. These are very high2 incidences of: 1. High school dropouts (the proportion of 16 to 19 year olds who are not enrolled in school and are not high school graduates); 2. Prime-age males not regularly attached to the labour force (the percentage of males 16 and over who worked for pay less than 26 weeks in the previous calendar year); 3. Welfare recipients (the percentage of households receiving Aid to Families with Dependent Children or state or municipal public assistance); and 4. Female lone parents (the percentage of households headed by female lone parents). Hatfield (1997) concludes that it appears worthwhile to study both concentrations of income poverty and concentrations of other indicators of social distress. The first helps to understand the context for the formation of distressed neighbourhoods and, through the second, it may be possible to identify the factors that encourage or act as counterweights to their formation given high rates of income poverty. 2.1.15. The Pull and Obsolescence Hypotheses The Pull and Obsolescence hypotheses interpret decline as an outcome of a socially and physically declining inner city that people want to avoid, and an overriding preference for suburban living. Michael Broadway (1995) insists that this explanation is limited to U.S. metropolitan areas, since the Canadian inner city is still considered as a desirable residential location for the elite as well as educated professionals: Indeed, with a few exceptions, wealth in America has fled the city, but in Canada, elite inner-city residential areas have persisted, and in some cases expanded, with gentrification. Well-established elite neighbourhoods such as Rosedale in Toronto, Westmount, Outremont and Mont Royal in Montreal, Shaughnessy Heights in Vancouver and the South End in Halifax attest to the attractiveness of inner city living. (ibid. pp.2-3) Obsolescence in the inner city pushes people out. They dislike many of the characteristics of the inner city, the characteristics of suburban development, on the other hand, are viewed as attractive. The inner city characteristics push, the suburban characteristics pull. 2.1.16. Environmental Determinism The basic premise of Environmental Determinism is that control and manipulation of the physical environment has a direct and determinate effect on social behaviour. The theory implies that the physical environment is a major determinant of social patterns. It implies a one-way process, in which the physical environment is the independent and 2 Ricketts and Sawhill defined “very high” as a rate more than one standard deviation beyond the mean for all urban census tracts (1998). 16 Causes of Decline human behaviour the dependent variable (Carley 1990). For example, poor quality housing has a detrimental effect on the social well-being of residents. While environmental determinism approaches contain important truths, if overstated they are insufficient as an explanation of interrelated neighbourhood decline problems. They also fail to consider the preferences of different social groups, or the importance of good management and maintenance in housing. Most residential, as opposed to industrial, neighbourhoods are complex social entities, best understood by those who live there (ibid.). 2.2. The Subcultural School The Subcultural School focuses on concepts such as resident confidence, satisfaction, commitment and social networks and their role in the processes of neighbourhood change. It rejects the economic determinism of the ecological models. Places where people live can evoke sentimental ties that bind them to their neighbourhoods, apart from simply economic factors (Temkin and Rohe 1996, Pitkin 2001). Pitkin (2001) contends that the subculturalists object to the ecological way of understanding neighbourhood change because of its almost exclusive focus on exogenous forces. Whereas the ecologists contend that rational, economic choices related to the metropolitan real estate market drive neighbourhood change, the subculturalists add endogenous variables to the equation. While in many ecological models resident mobility and neighbourhood decline are seen as inevitable, natural processes, the subculturalists argue that neighbourhoods can remain stable or even improve if the social structure is strong. The subculturalists deny the ecological assumption that neighbourhoods are homogeneous, contending that there are many subcultures that vary across neighbourhoods. This viewpoint comes from in-depth, ethnographic studies of neighbourhoods that emphasize the role of ethnic identity in helping stabilize neighbourhoods. Other identity-based subcultures have also been shown to increase the potential of residents to defend their neighbourhoods against outside threats (ibid.). At this point the subcultural concept relates to the social area analysis model. 2.3. Political Economists Political economists view urban development as a result of social, economic, and political conflict. This has lead to two influential streams: one focusing on the role of urban “growth machines” in neighbourhood change and another that recognizes that cities have undergone a restructuring process over the past thirty years as the world has become increasingly globalized (Pitkin 2001). 2.3.1. The Urban Growth Machine Thesis The Urban Growth Machine Thesis states that coalitions of urban elites seek to capture and retain economic power by promoting population growth and real estate 17 Causes of Decline development (Jonas and Wilson 1999). Members of growth machines include people who directly benefit from increases in population and land values. In a market economy, the space that we inhabit and use every day is not only a human necessity (use value) but also a commodity that generates revenues (exchange value) (Logan and Molotch 1987). A fundamental component of the growth machine thesis is this distinction between exchange and use values. Place is viewed as a commodity that is socially constructed through competition between those who value the neighbourhood for the “rent” they can gain from it (i.e. exchange value) and those who value it for non-economic reasons (i.e. use value) such as their attachment to it. Growth machines seek to maximize the exchange value of urban space, often leading to land speculation and the encouragement of population growth to drive up property values and, consequently, their return on rent (Pitkin 2001). Another element of the theory is an ideology of growth, which promotes the belief that growth will produce a common benefit for both residents and renters. This discourse, most fundamentally, defines a common set of villains (economic and labour force restructuring, and harsh global realities) and victims (the urban tax base, local culture, and local civic health). Through use of this common discourse, coalitions aggressively and successfully push their development agenda stressing that addressing the villains requires hard choices and sacrifices in areas that often negatively affect the poor and the marginalized (Wilson and Wouters 2003). The growth machine’s exploitation of exchange values and creation of a “valuefree” growth ideology negatively impact neighbourhood residents’ use values. This can lead to the displacement of vulnerable populations in poor neighbourhoods, as in the cases of urban renewal of the 1960s and gentrification today. It also means that even the rich neighbourhoods can decline, as their exchange value often overrides the use value to the growth machine. Institutions working in real estate, such as banks and realtors, are often complicit in this steering of certain people to certain neighbourhoods – especially along racial lines – in order to serve the interests of the growth machine (Pitkin 2001). 2.3.2. Urban Structural Change A second stream of the political economy’s understanding of neighbourhood change is “urban restructuring” or “globalization.” Urban Structural Change has been characterized by two interrelated developments. First, there has been a restructuring of capital, as seen in a concurrent process of globalization and corporate concentration. Capital investment has shifted to new sectors of the economy, to new areas of cities and to new cities of the world. This process has been accelerated by new information and communication technologies that have made it possible for large, dominant firms to globalize production. Financial markets now operate on a global scale that leads to the deregulation of financial institutions, their flexibility and ability to contend with foreign competition. These processes have resulted in a new urban hierarchy in which economic power is concentrated in “global” or “world” cities. In parallel with this restructuring of capital, there has been a general restructuring of labour through mechanisms such as subcontracting and self-employment (Pitkin 2001, Fainstein and Campbell 2002, Gertler 2001, Gregory and Hunter 2003). 18 Causes of Decline There are at least five areas in which the restructuring process has had an impact on urban neighbourhoods in the United States (Pitkin 2001): employment of neighbourhood residents. There have been winners and losers, depending on the skill sets of people; the built environment; de-industrialization has left buildings vacant and areas in decay; social and economic inequality in cities as a result of re-structuring, meaning that residents of low-income neighbourhoods have less access to affordable housing; the demographics of urban neighbourhoods: several studies have shown the uneven impacts of restructuring along racial lines; the social and political life of neighbourhoods has been weakened or strengthened depending on their place in a globalizing economy. Similarly, Structural Analysis focuses on factors such as economic turbulence, the operations of multinational corporations, competition between developed countries and underdeveloped countries, and between levels of government (Carley 1990). Although the theory may seem removed from the daily reality of neighbourhood renewal, there is no doubt that factors like de-industrialization, industrial shift, unemployment and regional disparity are related to neighbourhood decline. There are both winners and losers in structural change. Some cities have benefited while others have lost. Even in those deemed winners there are certain sectors in society (the marginalized, the unskilled) who have lost, creating pockets of decline in global or world cities that overall are economically strong. 2.3.3. The Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis In the same vein the Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis posits that American cities are undergoing transformations from centres of goods and production to centres of information processing. The blue-collar jobs that once formed the economic base of cities have either vanished or moved to the developing suburbs, if not overseas. Central-city low-skilled manufacturing jobs are no longer available. In addition, neighbourhood retail businesses that served the middle class have also, to a large extent, relocated to the suburbs (Wheeler 1990, Orfield 1998). The spatial mismatch theory states that it is not lack of jobs as such that is the problem, since central-city population growth has been as slow as central-city job growth. The problem is that the percentage of central-city jobs with high educational requirements is increasing, while the average education level of central-city residents is dropping relative to the rest of the city. In addition, the net growth in jobs with low educational requirements is occurring mainly in the suburbs and in areas at the very fringe of urban settlement. This low-skilled job exodus to the suburbs disproportionately affects central-city poor people, particularly minorities, who often face a more limited choice of housing location in growing areas. 19 Causes of Decline Franke and Löhr (2001) show how economic structural change has brought farreaching changes in Germany. The consequences are serious: declining manufacturing and the flexibilization of production have been accompanied by a loss of low-skill jobs. As new industries have grown, for example in the hi-tech sector, both high-skill and lowskill jobs have been created in research, development, and management; and in manufacturing. The booming service sector also exhibits a similar dichotomy between high-skill jobs in producer services and low-skill jobs in personal services. Furthermore, flexible employment contracts undermine income security in all sectors of the economy (wages below agreed rates, contracts for works and services, fixed-term contracts, bogus self-employment) (ibid.). These developments tend to divide society in a variety of ways. Poverty and social inequity are increasing, owing to the growing proportion of the long-term jobless and recipients of transfer payments. The consequent fragmentation of social space risks excluding whole districts from citywide processes, particularly inner-city or adjoining old neighbourhoods and large new housing estates in peripheral areas exhibit a complex, interdependent mixture of problems – developmental, ecological, economic, infrastructural, and social. Such neighbourhoods lose their function as social networks; they suffer from a negative image, which can go as far as stigmatization of the neighbourhood and its people (ibid.). Broadway (1995) suggests that Canadian inner cities might conceivably be immune from the structural economic and demographic changes that have affected inner cities in the US and areas of cities in Britain. His study failed to link increases in innercity deprivation with structural economic change, since such increases were not associated with cities in central Canada, which lost manufacturing jobs due to foreign competition and restructuring. This finding is in marked contrast to studies of British cities that identify old industrial cities as having the highest deprivation levels (Robson 1988). In some cities in Canada, regional economic conditions and local perceptions of the inner city as a desirable place to live are more important than a city's economic structure in determining inner-city deprivation levels. 2.3.4. The Exploitation Hypothesis Exploitation, along with structural change hypotheses, is often referred to as one of the most applicable explanations of inner city decline for Canadian cities. The Exploitation Hypothesis contends that urban change is an outcome of economic manipulation by interest groups. The exploitation model is related to structural change, since it views the abandonment of inner city as an inevitable consequence of industrial capitalism processes including the shift from manufacturing to a service based economy and decline in inner-city blue-collar employment, global economic competition, technological advances, and the availability of cheap labour elsewhere. Cities served to secure economies of urban agglomerations and once these economies lose their strength, old inner-city districts are abandoned (Broadway 1995). 20 Causes of Decline 2.3.5. The Fiscal Crisis Theory The Fiscal Crisis theory views inner-city decline as the product of a circular and cumulative causation process: “As people and jobs leave the inner city, the tax base is reduced along with the ability to meet the demands of an increasingly service-dependent population, and so, in order to balance the budget and meet this demand, taxes are raised and services cut, which in turn promotes further outmigration” (Broadway 1995, p. 3). The fiscal crisis hypothesis is more pertinent to US cities. As Broadway notes, the presence of some metropolitan governments in Canada, which share tax revenues between inner city and suburbs, have produced a more equitable distribution of services. 2.4. The Social Capital Model Figure 1. A Social Capital Model of Neighbourhood Change (adapted from Temkin and Rohe 1998) Initial Status of Neighborhood Sources of Change – Metro Area – Neighborhood Sociocultural Milieu of the Neighborhood Absent Present Ecological Change Potential Defensive Measures of Residents Weak Institutional Infrastructure Strong Defended Neighborhood Stable or Gentrifying Neighborhood Status of Neighborhood Increases or Remains the Same over Time Defeated Neighborhood Downward Succession Status of Neighborhood Declines over Time 21 Causes of Decline Temkin and Rohe (1998) propose the Social Capital Model of neighbourhood change that combines earlier discussed ecological, subcultural, and political economy approaches and places those theories within a larger socio-political context that can greatly affect a neighbourhood’s trajectory. The model integrates the concept of social capital into an explanatory framework of neighbourhood change and theoretically explains the observed difference in neighbourhood trajectories over time (Figure 1). The social capital hypothesis suggests that two components of social capital – socio-cultural environment and institutional infrastructure – are critical in determining the evolution of neighbourhoods. Potential causes of change to the initial status of the neighbourhood originate from two sources (ibid.): Broad social and economic trends may alter a region’s employment base and social structure. Trends such as the loss of manufacturing jobs or the influx of a new ethnic group may have an effect on a metropolitan area’s economic and demographic characteristics. Changes occur within the neighbourhood: neighbourhood residents age, marry, and experience other transformations as they move through their life cycles. Therefore, even without large-scale structural changes, neighbourhoods must deal with internal sources of change. Temkin and Rohe (1998) argue that these forces of change do not have the same effect on every neighbourhood. Their impact depends on the strength of the social capital in the area. The two constitutive elements of social capital had positive and significant effects on the measure of neighbourhood stability. Both loyalty and attachment to neighbourhood are higher in neighbourhoods that remain stable over time. Similarly, neighbourhoods where a higher proportion of residents believe they live in a good place tend to remain stable. Thus, neighbourhoods with higher levels of social capital, as measured by greater degrees of a socio-cultural milieu and institutional infrastructure, are more likely to stay stable over time (ibid.). The social capital model is strengthened by the growth of interest in, and the development of, the social economy. According to Williams and Windebank (2001) a strong social economy addresses the needs of those that neither the private and, in some cases, the public sector can fulfill. The social economy possesses six characteristics that can distinguish it from the private and public spheres: - it is based on co-operative or closely-related mutual principles; - it is based on not-for-profit principles in the sense that the initiative does not seek to expropriate a profit from its operations; - it is private (non-public) in nature even if there is sometimes public sector involvement, particularly funding to initiate social economy initiatives; - the tasks conducted by such initiatives include economic activities that seek to fulfill people’s needs and wants through the production and/or distribution of 22 Causes of Decline goods and services. Put another way, it produces and sells services of a collective interest; - relative to associations between kin, neighbours and friends, it is a formal association that provides an organizational framework for the pursuit of collective self-help activities; - activities within the social economy should be structured to build social capital, enhance social networking and build strong, sustainable communities (Williams and Windebank, 2001). An active social economy combined with strong social capital can be a definite asset when trying to revitalize neighbourhoods. 2.5. Theories Summary Summary of the theories aimed at explaining neighbourhood decline and the basic processes that characterize them is presented in Table 4. Table 4. Theories Explaining Urban Decline Theories, Source Processes Concentric Zones or Invasion/Succession Concentric zone residential pattern in which lower-income people would locate toward the centre and higher-income people would locate toward the edge of metropolitan settlements: the central business district, the industrial sector, slum housing, working-class housing, higher-status dwellings and commuter housing Burgess 1925, Lucy and Phillips 2000, Pitkin 2001 Filtering Hoyt 1933, Downs 1981, Lucy and Phillips 2000, Smith 1963, Pitkin 2001, Galster et al. 2003 Sectoral Model Hoyt 1939 Multiple Nuclei Model Harris and Ullman 1945 Social Area Analysis Shevsky and Bell 1955 Housing filters down from the rich to the middle class to the poor as property owners invest less in ageing properties due to rising maintenance costs and move to new housing on the periphery. The direction, not the distance, is the key factor in determining the spatial organization of an area. While the growth is still outward, areas growing in the same direction tend to maintain the original socio-economic characteristics of more inner areas. Suggests that a city may have more than one nuclei/centre apart from the CBD from which zones develop. Specialized cells of activity develop according to specific requirements of certain activities, different rentpaying abilities, and the tendency for some kinds of economic activity to cluster together. The analysis concentrates on the social characteristics of the urban population in attempting to explain land use. "Social areas" clusters of city areas can be defined according to 1) economic status, 2) family status and 3) ethnic composition. 23 Causes of Decline Theories, Source Processes Neoclassical or Bid Rent Theory Resident’s location decision is a trade-off between land, housing, and transportation costs. Middle- and upper-income can purchase more of land and housing at lower unit costs toward the periphery while affording the transportation costs. Poor occupy smaller and older housing closer to work sites. Alonso 1960, 1964, Pitkin 2001, Luger 1996, Morrill 1991, Muth 1969 in Lucy and Phillips 2000 Border or Tipping Model Leven et al., 1976 in Pitkin 2001 Life-cycle Theory Also focuses on the locational decisions of residents, expanding the explanatory variables to social characteristics such as race. The racial transition of a neighbourhood will have an impact on existing residents and increase out-migration; these changes will affect how residents from surrounding areas perceive their own neighbourhoods, especially along the “borders” of the neighbourhoods Neighbourhood change is a life cycle ending in inevitable decline Birch 1971, HUD 1975, Bourne 1982, Metzger 2000 Vacancy Chain Analysis Hartshorn 1992, Knox 1994 in Lucy and Phillips 2000 Subcultural Theories Pitkin 2001 Social Capital Model Temkin and Rohe 1998 Cycles of Disadvantage Carley, 1990 “Broken Windows’ Wilson and Kelling 1982 Urban Underclass Wilson 1987, Kasarda 1990, Ley and Smith 1997, Glennerster et al. 1999 Structural Change Pitkin 2001 Structural Analysis Carley 1990 When a household moves to a new unit at the periphery, it creates a vacancy, which is filled by another household, which leaves a vacancy at its old address and so on. The building of new housing at the periphery sets in motion vacancy chains reaching far back into the central core. Demand and price decline, which in turn leads to opportunities for the region's poor. Resident confidence, satisfaction, commitment and social networks are important for understanding neighbourhood change. There are many subcultures that vary across neighbourhoods and neighbourhoods can remain stable or even improve if the social structure is strong. The forces of neighbourhood change do not affect every neighbourhood in the same way. The effect of these forces depends on the strength of the social capital in the area. Recurring cycles of socio-economic disadvantage. Households are locked in these cycles. A loss of social control is caused by the gradual growth in ‘incivilities’: the lack of informal social control through neighbourhood instability and poor services leads to people tolerating broken windows and other minor damage. This leads to neighbourhood decline. Area problems are created by the people who live there. An underclass is people who have a life-style that conflicts with mainstream values and cannot or do not want to help themselves or their children. Existence of underclass creates or helps to drive area decline. Economic re-structuring and labour force changes impact urban neighbourhoods: employment of neighbourhood residents, social and economic inequality, the built environment, the demographics: uneven impacts of restructuring along racial lines, the social and political life. Focuses on economic turbulence, the operations of multinational corporations, competition between developed countries and underdeveloped countries, and between levels of government, deindustrialization, industrial shift, unemployment and regional disparity. 24 Causes of Decline Theories, Source Processes Jobs and The Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis A spatial mismatch between central city residential location and suburban job growth may result in poor labour market outcomes for inner-city neighbourhoods Wheeler 1990, Orfield 1998 Urban Growth Machine Thesis Pitkin 2001 Exploitation Hypothesis Coalitions of urban elite seek to capture economic power by promoting population growth and real estate development. Growth machines seek to maximize the exchange value of urban space, often leading to land speculation and the encouragement of population growth to drive up property values and their return on rent. Economic manipulation by interest groups Bourne 1982, CMHC 2001 Environmental Determinism Carley, 1990 Obsolescence and Pull Hypotheses Focuses on the physical environment as a major determinant of social patterns. It implied a one-way process in which the physical environment is the independent and human behaviour the dependent variable. Control and manipulation of the physical environment had a direct and determinate effect on social behaviour. Decline is interpreted as an outcome of a physically and socially declining inner city and an overriding preference for suburban living. Bourne 1982, Broadway 1995, CMHC 2001 Fiscal Crisis Under-funding, declining tax base and concentrated poverty Bourne 1982, Broadway 1995, CMHC 2001 3. Factors that Prompt Neighbourhood Decline A considerable body of literature postulated numerous causes of neighbourhood decline and tried to identify specific origins that initiate this decline. A CMHC (2001) publication indicates urban decline does not have a readily identifiable starting point or single isolated cause. Instead, decline is triggered by a set of circumstances that is specific to particular cities. Once underway, decline and disinvestment tend to be evolutionary and accretive. Indeed, urban decline is a complex, self-reinforcing phenomenon in which symptoms of decline themselves become causes. Based on the literature review, the following causes of inner city decline were identified: Social Poverty Racial conflict Perception of decline of inner-city schools Increased inner-city crime Mass in-migration to the inner cities of migrants and immigrants with weak skill sets 25 Causes of Decline Middle class preference for single-family home ownership on large suburban lots Loss of social capital, sense of community Resident perceptions and expectations Demographic High percentage of elderly people High percentage of Aboriginal people with weak skill sets Unemployment Physical Development Urban sprawl Deterioration of inner-city infrastructure Chaotic subdivision of inner-city land, as characterized by irrational lot lines, resulting in odd-shaped or small plots that impede parcel assemblage for modern development Ageing and obsolescence of commercial buildings Decline of inner-city housing stock The spatial distribution of affordable social housing Parking problems and congestion in an increasingly automobile-oriented society The mixing of incompatible land uses, which ultimately blights the affected area and reduces property values Economic Bank redlining Low labour force skills Investor perception of higher inner-city risk Economic restructuring Low “creativity” potential as high-tech industries need to be in entrepreneurial environments that attract highly educated people Public Finance Reduced tax base and tax revenues resulting from disinvestment Reduced quality of inner-city services and fiscal stress because of declining revenue sources Perception of lower suburban taxes Infrastructure that is expensive to repair and/or replace discourages economic development when left unattended through deferred maintenance The following sections will focus on some of the factors that are commonly considered to be the most important in triggering decline. 26 Causes of Decline 3.1. Poverty The research on the effects of poverty shows that they have detrimental economic, social, and physical consequences for individual households and neighbourhoods (Jargowsky 1997, Wilson 1987, 1996, Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy 2000). Poverty pushes away businesses and middle-class families, further undermining those neighbourhoods and fuelling sprawl. As neighbourhoods become dominated by joblessness, the residents become isolated from middle-class society and the private economy. High poverty declining neighbourhoods require increasingly greater levels of governmental and philanthropic resources that rapidly disappear when there is little sign of improvement (Orfield 1998). A distinct society emerges with expectations and patterns of behaviour that contrast strongly with middle-class norms. Studies have found that poor individuals living in concentrated poverty are far more likely to become pregnant as teenagers, drop out of high school, and remain jobless than if they lived in socio-economically mixed neighbourhoods (Driedger 1991). Washington's high-poverty neighbourhoods, for instance, face dramatically more severe challenges with regard to education, employment, and welfare dependency than most other neighbourhoods throughout the region (Turner and Hayes 1997). Specific impacts of poverty concentration on families and children include low birth rates, infant deaths, child misbehaviour, and child abuse (Glennerster et al. 1999). The effects of poverty can also be seen by comparing the experience of the poor living in high poverty areas to that of poor individuals living in mixed-income communities. When poor individuals are freed from poor neighbourhoods and provided with opportunities, their lives can change quite dramatically (Orfield 1998). As the middle class leave, there are fewer customers for local retailers and the assessed value of local housing declines precipitously. In the poorest neighbourhoods, basic private services disappear. Vestiges of the private economy that remain charge exorbitant prices allegedly justified by the "risk of doing business." Social needs and hence property tax rates begin to accelerate on a declining base of property values. As a combination of high local property tax rates and/or low spending on public services concentrates in the most socially stressed parts of the metropolitan area, the flight of the middle class and the private economy increases (ibid.). Larger industrial and service businesses are disadvantaged by high taxes, deteriorating public infrastructure, crime, loss of property value, and the cost of urban environmental issues. Many of these businesses have also grown accustomed to large greenfield sites where they can build huge parking lots, with immediate access to radial highways. They have come to prefer doing business in that environment and must be convinced that there is good business to be done in more transit-oriented, higher density communities (ibid.). Poverty also affects the “geography of opportunity” for those people who remain in inner-city neighbourhoods. Neighbourhoods of extreme poverty are isolated from economic and educational opportunities elsewhere in the city. Poor residents often lack 27 Causes of Decline the means – such as information about suburban jobs and reliable and affordable transportation to work – to access those distant opportunities. As a result of this isolation from opportunity, people who live in very poor neighbourhoods are more likely than residents of moderately poor or non-poor neighbourhoods to drop out of school, become a single or teenaged parent, and receive welfare payments. Living in a very poor neighbourhood exacerbates the difficulties of being poor (Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy 2000). The lack of the economic and social mortar necessary to hold neighbourhoods together and build communities makes community development in concentrated-poverty neighbourhoods difficult. Programs geared at job training or job creation must struggle to incorporate the diversity of human resources and experiences of a social group that has been isolated from the functioning economy and jobs; from adequate nutrition and schools that succeed; and, from a supportive and economically stable family structure. To the extent such programs succeed, individuals – even if they are employed in the neighbourhood – often move to less poor areas. Physical rehabilitation programs, while improving the quality of shelter and neighbourhood appearance, do not address the larger tangle of barriers faced by many residents in areas of concentrated poverty. In some cases such programs act as incentives for gentrification and result in the displacement of existing low-income residents rather than improving their lives (Orfield 1998). In terms of business development, areas of concentrated poverty have great difficulty competing with developing suburbs that have middle-class customers with more money to spend, lower taxes, less crime, cheaper land with increasing values, room for expansion and parking, new highways, and no demands on companies to mitigate previously created environmental problems. Thus, even when enormous financial resources have been devoted to enterprise zones or inner-city tax abatements, it has been very difficult to stimulate viable business opportunities that employ core residents (ibid.). 3.2. Racial Conflict A strong correlation between geographic concentrations of people of colour and geographic concentrations of decline in North American communities is evidence that racism is still a significant factor in these patterns of development. When communities of people of colour are also communities with high rates of poverty, the effect of racism on employment options for individuals, the presence of jobs in local communities and property value assessments are exacerbated by similar dynamics associated with living in areas of concentrated poverty. Wilson (1987) presents theoretical arguments that the social problems of urban life are largely the result of racial inequality. Racism in the form of redlining by banks and insurance companies, steering by real estate agents, exclusionary zoning and related practices in many suburban communities has played a key role in the dynamics of central city and inner suburban disinvestment and the development of geographic concentrations of decline. White ethnic biases and class issues have played similar, though perhaps less pervasive, roles (Orfield 1998). 28 Causes of Decline Wilson (1999) indicates that discrimination in employment opportunities, although representing elements of class bias against poor workers in the inner-city, is also a matter of race. The job prospects of inner-city workers have diminished not only because of the decreasing relative demand for low-skilled labour in the United States economy, the suburbanization of jobs, and the social deterioration of ghetto neighbourhoods, but also because of negative employer attitudes. 3.3. Ageing of the Population Housing and neighbourhood deterioration are often accelerated if an area contains a disproportionate share of elderly homeowners. A high percentage of seniors in a neighbourhood may also lead to a sudden thinning of the area population. Elderly owneroccupiers are frequently unable to maintain their housing due to increasing physical impairment and reliance on a fixed or declining income. Rather than relocating to a smaller unit or one requiring less upkeep, many elderly owner-occupiers age in place. As a consequence, their homes and properties can experience serious disrepair (CMHC 2001). 3.4. Suburban Sprawl Linked to the problems of social polarization and spatial segregation is the continued spread of commercial and residential development into the surrounding countryside. Inherent in the natural evolution hypothesis, the pull hypothesis, the obsolescence hypothesis and the preference structure of North American society for suburban living is the idea that urban growth has created an inner city vacuum. According to this argument, governments have validated suburbanization and created a “vacuum” at the core, which leads to insufficient demand for land and declining relative land values in the inner city (ibid.). The negative consequences of urban sprawl are well known. Investment and population shifts within the metropolitan region leave certain municipalities and neighbourhoods, either inner city or older suburbs, with higher unemployment, reduced revenues, and larger social service needs (Bradford 2002). Downs (1999) contends that no statistically significant relationship exists between sprawl and urban decline. The basic nature of the American urban development process includes core area poverty concentrations even if more compact growth is enforced. However, he also suggests that sprawl exacerbates growth-related problems, one of which is inner city decline. According to Downs, sprawl contributes to the concentration of poor households in certain high poverty inner-city neighbourhoods. These neighbourhoods become high-crime areas, have poor quality schools, dysfunctional bigcity bureaucracies, and lack the fiscal resources to correct the problems. The lack of regional tax base sharing and poor regional co-ordination of land uses are manifestations of the problem. Downs identifies ten characteristics of sprawl and several of these characteristics contribute to inner city decline. These characteristics are: 29 Causes of Decline 1. Unlimited outward extension of development 2. Low-density residential and commercial settlements 3. Leapfrog as opposed to contiguous development 4. Fragmentation of powers over land use among many small localities 5. Dominance of transportation by private automotive vehicles 6. Lack of centralized planning or control of land uses 7. Widespread commercial strip development 8. Great fiscal disparities among localities 9. Segregation of types of land use in different zones, and 10. Reliance mainly on the trickle-down or filtering process to provide housing to low-income households. People living in the inner city want to find safer, more spacious neighbourhoods, better schools, affordable housing on large parcels of land, and less traffic in the suburbs. As people leave the city, those left are those who cannot afford to move and neighbourhoods decay. As the suburbs gradually fill with more people, they bring the problems of the city with them – increased traffic, noise, over crowded, crumbling schools. The suburbanites again look for rural locations further out to escape the problems and the cycle continues. 3.5. The Spatial Distribution of Affordable Housing The spatial distribution of affordable housing plays an important role in shaping urban decline patterns. Subsidized housing tends to be located in distressed inner city and older-suburban neighbourhoods. The concentration of public housing within inner cities can reinforce decline by concentrating the poor and disadvantaged in one area. This may be the case particularly if the housing is provided without the necessary support services that people in poverty, combined with other social problems, need. At the same time wealthier suburbs practice exclusionary zoning and limit affordable housing within their borders. For example, in Atlanta, where low-income families live in the southern part of the metropolitan area, there is almost no affordable housing elsewhere (Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy 2000). The lack of affordable housing in Atlanta’s northern suburban communities clearly limits the educational and employment opportunities of many working families, particularly minority families, in the region. Additionally, the housing imbalance places enormous stresses on the region’s employers by limiting the pool of workers who can live within a reasonable commuting distance (ibid.). 3.6. Decline of Inner-city Schools Schools are both victims and one of the powerful causes of decline. Local public schools often become socio-economically distressed before neighbourhoods themselves become disadvantaged. Deteriorating inner city schools are a problem for the neighbourhood for two reasons. First, the area's children do not get an adequate education and reach adulthood without the skills to access acceptable employment. Second, middle- 30 Causes of Decline class families, who live in these neighbourhoods will not tolerate poor quality schooling for their children. Disadvantaged schools in inner city neighbourhoods push out families. Poor public schools destabilize communities and have a very negative effect on individual access and achievement. Schools are not just instruction and textbooks, but, like neighbourhoods, represent a series of reinforcing social networks that contribute to success or failure (Orfield 1998). Poor inner-city or low-valued suburban schools are characterized as one of the trends moving toward failure, with features that reinforce antisocial behaviour, drifting, teenage pregnancy and dropping out. The well-funded suburban schools generally have more resources and a far lower percentage of their students face a lack of stable housing; insufficient food and health care; lead paint risks; and, a lack of visible job prospects to help motivate them to study and to graduate (ibid.). Parents who are poorly educated are unable to help their children with school work, further education or job choices, which make it difficult for both the parents and their children, to be part of the school and neighbourhood community. 3.7. Creative Class Due to economic restructuring, one of the keys to economic growth lies in the ability to attract the creative class and to translate that into creative economic outcomes in the form of new ideas, new high-tech businesses and regional growth (Florida 2000, 2002, Gertler 2001). Correspondingly, neighbourhoods with less creativity potential are more likely to experience decline processes. In the new economy, regional advantage comes to places that can quickly mobilize the best people, resources, and capabilities required to turn innovations into new business ideas and commercial products. Leading regions establish competitive advantage through their capabilities… For these reasons, the nexus of competitive advantage shifts to those regions that can generate, retain and attract the best talent. This is particularly so since knowledge workers are extremely mobile and the distribution of talent is highly skewed (Florida 2000, p. 8). The Creativity Index was constructed to measure underlying creative capabilities of cities and regions. The index includes four components: Talent index, Bohemian index, Mosaic index, and Tech-pole index: Talent index: the proportion of the population over 18 years of age with a bachelor’s degree or higher. Bohemian index: employment in artistic and creative occupations. It is a location quotient that compares the region’s share of the nation’s bohemians to the region’s share of the nation’s population. Mosaic index: the proportion of the total population that is foreign-born. Tech-pole index: local employment in technology-intensive manufacturing and service sectors is calculated using high-technology employment data. The index compares a region’s share of national employment in high-technology industries to the region’s overall share of national employment. 31 Causes of Decline Cities or regions that have a high creativity index have a high proportion of people that are well educated with a high level of technical skills suitable for today’s information, research and development, financial and technology jobs. They also have a diversity of lifestyles and ethnic and racial groups that add interest and diversity to the urban milieu, including attractive arts and entertainment functions and activities. 3.8. Unintended Policy Effects The decline of the inner city can result from failed public policy. Examples of policies that have weakened inner city neighbourhoods include the development of freeways through inner city neighbourhoods to facilitate the flow of suburban commuters or subsidization of suburban home ownership through tax differentials that attract people from the inner city and older suburban areas robbing them of middle and higher income residents (CMHC 2001). Land use and zoning policies can, and have, added to inner city decline. In many metropolitan areas, suburbs in the "favoured quarter" have exclusionary zoning policies. These zoning regulations effectively ensure that only the wealthy can afford to live in those communities. The most common example is mandatory large lot zoning, such as the requirement that all single family homes must be on lots of, perhaps, 15,000 square feet or larger. Another example is the prohibition of, or severe restrictions on, the location of multifamily housing in a community. The effect of these types of zoning regulations is to limit housing options to those who can afford a single-family home on a large lot (Orfield 1998). In this way public policy has systematically favoured suburban development at the expense of inner city strength and stability. Similarly, zoning regulations and design guidelines which result in a development pattern that requires one to have a car, or a family to have a second car, in order to conduct daily business, has the effect of creating an economic barrier to that community for some people. Zoning practices that segregate housing from retail and employment centres require commuting (ibid.). If zoning and design guidelines dictate large lots on many cul-de-sacs, crescents and bays it may be inefficient to provide adequate public transit with such low-densities on street patterns that are difficult to service. Without adequate public transit, households that cannot afford a car would find it difficult to live in such areas. In addition to burdening the inner city with marginal and even destructive uses, exclusionary zoning may pose barriers for inner-city economic development. The concentration in inner cities of establishments such as sex shops, massage parlours, and pawnshops discourages the development of other economic activities, and entrenches the transiency of these areas (CMHC 2001). High quality standards for new housing and renovation projects contribute to the growing obsolescence of older housing stock. The standards include minimum size requirements for housing units, requirements for use of specific materials and construction methods, minimum lot size and building space requirements, and new fire 32 Causes of Decline code and safety standards. Any renovation requires that these standards be met, thus driving up the cost of housing beyond that which low-income households can pay (ibid.). Wilson (1999) notes that the passage of the recent welfare reform bill in the United States, which did not include a program of job creation, could have very negative social consequences in the inner city. Unless something is done to enhance the employment opportunities of inner-city welfare recipients who reach the time limit for the receipt of welfare, if the economy slows down they will flood a pool that is already filled with low-skilled jobless workers. Miller (2001) presents another example of unintended policy effect. He contends that during the 1970s it became evident that the banking system was taking advantage of low-income inner-city residents. In an effort to stimulate inner-city loans by banks, Congress passed the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) in 1977. Under the terms of this act, banks were directed to make extra efforts to solicit loans in older and lower income neighbourhoods, so that residents of these areas would be able to participate in the economic redevelopment of these inner-city areas. However, although the CRA was intended to promote lending in low-income areas, its overall effect has been to actually reduce rather than increase lending in America's inner cities and to discourage banks from locating there (ibid.). One of many examples of the law's impact on branch-banking decisions can be found in the New York City area, where 14 percent of Brooklyn's bank branches closed between 1980 and 1994; most of those closures came in the lower income areas of the borough. And in low income Bedford-Stuyvesant, there are only three bank branches to serve 129,000 people. In upscale Manhattan, meanwhile, banks are amply represented not merely by their branches, but also by automated teller machines (ATMs) that at times seem to populate almost every street corner (ibid.). Interestingly, new policies sometimes emerge in dialectical opposition to preceding policy sets (often of previous governments of different political persuasion) and useful aspects of previous policy approaches are eliminated along with those parts that are ineffective. As Carley (1990) notes, this failure of policy integration prevents policy makers from grasping what has been called the wicked nature of urban problems, where the problem is exceedingly complex, and therefore beyond the boundaries of available knowledge and comprehension. The problem is compounded by the fact that government departments that make policy are subdivided into discrete specializations (housing, transport, employment), while the life experience of people in cities in poverty is holistic (ibid.). 4. Threshold Indicators 4.1. Definition Threshold indicators may be useful as planning tools, alerting community groups and local planners in time to take steps to ensure these thresholds are not reached. This section of the literature review intends to identify thresholds beyond which decline 33 Causes of Decline reaches a “point of no return” – a point at which the neighbourhood begins a spiral of inevitable decline in the quality of life it offers. According to Galster and Krall (2003), beginning in the 1970s, investigators of neighbourhood change began using regression analysis as the basis for empirically testing theories and building predictive models. These predictive modelling efforts specify how exogenous variables affect neighbourhood outcome indicators and estimate parameters using linear multiple regression. Different models have been introduced, each addressing changes of a specific neighbourhood indicator, such as population density, income or social class, home ownership rates, female headship rates, and racial composition changes. Galster, Quercia and Cortes (2000) explored the threshold effects of different aspects of the neighbourhood environment and found identifiable thresholds for neighbourhood change. Threshold effects were defined as: …threshold effects are a particular sort of causal relationship in which the magnitude of the causal influence changes dramatically past some critical point. Expressed graphically, a threshold effect involves an extremely non-linear relationship between independent (X) and dependent (Y) variables past some value of X (Galster et al. 2000, p.703). 4.2. The United States Experience 4.2.1. Poverty, Unemployment, Female Headship, and School Dropout Rates The most common threshold effect on neighbourhood decline found in the literature was a poverty rate of at least forty percent of the population living in households below the fixed poverty line. Both Wilson (1987, 1996) and Jargowsky (1997) concluded that a forty percent cut-off reflected the point at which area conditions became noticeably more difficult. Poverty tracts above this level tend to be clustered together in inner city neighbourhoods, most often as part of sprawling ghettos, housing overwhelmingly ethnic minority populations. Turner and Hayes (1997) note that neighbourhoods with poverty rates below thirty percent share many of the problems faced by high-poverty neighbourhoods, but at significantly lower levels. When poverty rates exceed thirty percent, neighbourhoods have great difficulty sustaining the economic and civic institutions essential for a healthy community. Poor education, joblessness, teen parenthood, discrimination, and crime all reinforce one another in these high poverty neighbourhoods, creating a vicious cycle of distress. Galster et al. (2000) investigated threshold-like effects of four aspects of neighbourhood environment: poverty rate, adult unemployment rate, female headship rate for families with children, and secondary school dropout rate. The relationship between the value of numerous neighbourhood indicators in 1980 and subsequent changes in each of the four noted dimensions of neighbourhood quality from 1980 to 1990 was evaluated to test for threshold-like processes. The authors used the following indicators of neighbourhood quality of life for examining threshold-like effects: 34 Causes of Decline Percentage of persons below the poverty level. Percentage of households that have children (under 19) and are headed by a woman. Percentage of persons ages 16 to 19 neither enrolled in school nor graduated from high school. Percentage of persons over age 16 not employed (i.e., either unemployed or not in the labour force). Percentage of persons who moved into their dwelling since 1975 (a measure of community transience and instability). Percentage of workers not employed in professional or managerial jobs (a measure of lower occupational status and potential for income growth) Percentage of occupied dwelling units with no car available (a measure of constrained accessibility to jobs and other vital destinations). Vacancy rate for year-round housing units (a measure of weakened incentives for owners to maintain their properties or, in the extreme, abandonment). Percentage of dwellings specified as renter occupied (a measure of expected lower home upkeep, attachment to the neighbourhood, and wealth). Table 5. The Threshold-like Effects (adapted from Galster et al. 2000, p.724.) Processes Key Threshold Value(s) Sign of Effect None None < 12.1% female headship 12.1–52.7% female headship 52.7–70.7% female headship 70.7% female headship negative positive negative negative < 6.9% poverty rate 6.9–18.8% poverty rate 18.8–36.8% poverty rate 36.8–53.3% poverty rate > 53.3% poverty rate negative positive less positive negative positive 83% nonprofessional employment positive Nonprofessional/nonmanagerial employment Nonemployment rate 74.2% nonprofessional employment positive Nonprofessional/nonmanagerial employment Poverty rate 83% nonprofessional employment positive Renter-occupied units Female-headed households with children < 32% renter-occupied units 32 to 85.5% renter-occupied units >85.5% renter-occupied units positive negative positive Endodynamic Processes High school dropout rate Nonemployment rate Female-headed households with children Poverty rate Exodynamic Processes Nonprofessional/nonmanagerial employment Female-headed households with children 35 Causes of Decline Processes Key Threshold Value(s) Sign of Effect Renter-occupied units Non-employment rate < 60% renter-occupied units 60 to 85.5% renter-occupied units >85.5% renter-occupied units positive negative positive Renter-occupied units Poverty rate <85.5% renter-occupied units >85.5% renter-occupied units positive positive Findings of the study are the following (see Table 5 above). First, with regard to factors correlated with greater changes in themselves once they reach certain values (endodynamic relationships), no self-generating process appears to drive neighbourhoods that exceed some threshold to ever-higher incidences of overall non-employment, secondary school dropout rates, and the female headship rate for families with children. There is a distinct threshold effect when neighbourhoods exceed a poverty rate of about 54 percent. For neighbourhoods above that threshold, there is a rapid and escalating growth in poverty over time (ibid.). Second, with regard to factors correlated with greater changes in neighbourhood quality of life indicators (exodynamic relationships), the authors find two patterns. The percentage of workers not employed in professional or managerial jobs in a neighbourhood is found to be a strong predictor of threshold-like changes in three of the indicators: female headship, unemployment, and poverty rates. The significant threshold occurs when the percentage of non-professional employment reaches from 77 to 83 percent (ibid.). The degree of renter occupancy is also a good predictor of threshold-like changes in the same three indicators. In census tracts having more than 85.5 percent of their units renter occupied, all three indicators rise two to four percentage points after this threshold is exceeded. Higher rental rates are associated with larger subsequent increases in neighbourhood poverty rates. By contrast, the pattern involving changes in the other two indicators shows consistency with the conventional wisdom only at lower ranges of rental rates. At these low ranges, the relationship is both direct and disadvantageous. However, the relationship reverses itself at about sixty percent rental for overall non-employment and at about 32 percent for female headship. In these intermediate ranges, higher rental occupancy in 1980 is not associated with disadvantageous changes in neighbourhood quality of life over the ensuing decade. The study also tested additional predictor variables, including percentage of persons who moved into their dwelling since 1975, percentage of dwelling units with no car available, and residential vacancy rate, but did not find any threshold effects for them (ibid.). The authors suggest that understanding of threshold effects can inform decisions about cases in which neighbourhood interventions have the greatest chance for success. The article proposes a general rule for maximizing the impact of intervention: allocate scarce public policy resources to neighbourhoods where the reduction in the given social problem indicator will be greatest (ibid.). 36 Causes of Decline The study An Economic Efficiency Analysis of Deconcentrating Poverty Populations (Galster 2002) attempted to aid in assessing the social efficiency of alternative spatial distributions of low-income populations. It determined how the percentage of poor residents in a neighbourhood affects all residents’ incomes and problem behaviours. Galster refers to findings of Krivo and Peterson (1996) who employed FBI crime data for both violent and property crimes and matched them with 1990 census tract poverty rates3 for the Columbus Ohio, metropolitan area. There is no significant difference between high-and extreme-poverty neighbourhoods, but both have at least twenty percent higher property crime rates than low-poverty neighbourhoods, suggesting a threshold around the twenty percent neighbourhood poverty rate. In the case of violent crime, there is a regular step-function across the three neighbourhood poverty categories. Further Krivo and Peterson determine that there is a constant slope between neighbourhood poverty rate and violent crime over the low-and high-poverty ranges, but no further association once neighbourhood poverty exceeds forty percent (Galster 2002, p.320). The study suggests that both income and behavioural problems are related to neighbourhood poverty rates. Net social benefits will be larger if neighbourhoods with greater than roughly fifteen percent poverty rates are replaced with (an appropriately larger number) of neighbourhoods having less than fifteen percent poverty rates. However, net social benefits will be smaller if neighbourhoods with greater than about forty percent poverty rates are replaced with (an appropriately larger number) of neighbourhoods having between about fifteen and forty percent poverty rates. In policy terms, unless very low-poverty neighbourhoods can be opened up for occupation by the poor, de-concentration efforts should halt, because merely transferring the poor from high- to moderate-poverty neighbourhoods is likely to be socially inefficient (ibid. p.322). In their research publication, The Fortunes of Poor Neighborhoods, Galster et al. (2003) analyzed the factors correlated with 1980-1990 increases and decreases in poverty rates4 across poor neighbourhoods (twenty percent or higher), and examined whether factors vary by predominant racial/ethnic composition. Galster and co-authors point out that only one study has explored empirically what has occurred longitudinally in already poor neighbourhoods. Fogarty (1977) examined predicting patterns of neighbourhood relative income change from 1960 to 1970 in ninety census tracts within Pittsburgh that had median incomes below the citywide median. He included 1960 variables measuring tract income profiles, demographic characteristics, housing stock features, and urban renewal indicators as discriminators of whether a tract would demonstrate relative income increase or decrease during the decade. Fogarty found that no single discriminant function adequately 3 Census tract were classified as low-poverty (less than 20%), high-poverty (20 –39%), and extreme-poverty (40% and higher) rates (Krivo and Peterson 1996). 4 The authors define neighborhood poverty rate as the number of persons in poverty divided by the total population of the tract (Galster et al. 2003). 37 Causes of Decline predicted outcomes for all below-median income tracts, so he further stratified the sample into four relative median income categories: 40-59, 60-79, 80-89, and 90-100 percent of the city-wide median. Some consistent result patterns emerged: Greater income inequality increased the probability of decline in all but the highest relative income category of areas. Percentages of elderly population and black population were directly related to relative income decline in the 60-89 percent categories. The percentage of blighted properties was directly related to decline in all but the 90-100 percent category. Residential urban renewal programs increased the probability of income increases in all neighbourhood categories of sixty percent or more, whereas non-residential urban renewal programs had the opposite impact. Other patterns were less consistent: Median income within a relative income category of neighbourhoods was directly related to the probability of income declines in the 80-100 percent of median income category, but illustrated the opposite relationship in the 40-79 percent categories. The rental housing percentage variable predicted rising relative incomes in the 80-100 percent category, but falling incomes in the 60-79 percent category. 4.2.2. Housing and Homeownership Characteristics Galster et al. (2003) examine how socio-economic, demographic, and housing/home ownership profiles in poor areas might be predictive of their longitudinal fortunes and explore variations among poor neighbourhoods with different racial/ethnic profiles5. Some of the research findings on Likelihood of Poverty Increase (ibid. pp.11-12) include: A greater percentage of renter-occupied units in 1980 was associated with increasing likelihood of rising poverty. Higher neighbourhood vacancy rates also predicted poverty increases. Surprisingly, poor neighbourhoods comprised of older (pre-1940 vintage) dwellings were less likely to experience poverty increases than those comprised of some newer dwellings. In poor Hispanic neighbourhoods, higher housing vacancy rates, higher percentages of minorities, and fewer high-status households are stronger 5 The study grouped all census on the basis of their 1980 racial/ethnic composition (ibid. p.6): Black neighbourhoods - 50 percent or more non-Hispanic black population. Hispanic neighbourhoods - 50 percent or more Hispanic population. White neighbourhoods - 90 percent or more non-Hispanic white population 38 Causes of Decline predictors of increasing poverty than in either white or black poor neighbourhoods. In all strata, higher percentages of renters predict increasing poverty, but the power to do so is greatest in white poor neighbourhoods, least in black poor neighbourhoods. Pre-1940 vintage poor black neighbourhoods are less likely to experience increasing poverty than some newer ones; the opposite is true for poor white neighbourhoods. Local housing market characteristics predicted poverty decreases in roughly opposite ways than they predicted increases. Poverty decline was more likely in older housing of poor neighbourhoods and those having greater percentages of owner-occupied dwellings (ibid.). As for other neighbourhood housing characteristics, poor black neighbourhoods with more housing built from 1950 to 1969 were less likely to experience poverty decreases, but the opposite was the case for poor Hispanic neighbourhoods with more housing built during the 1960-1969 period. The findings illustrated the benefits of targeting housing interventions. Higher rates of homeownership are likely to be an obstacle to poverty growth in most poor neighbourhoods, but the relationship is non-linear and variant across racial/ethnic strata. The non-linearity suggests, for instance, that increasing the homeownership rate in the average poor neighbourhood from eighty to ninety percent will reduce the chances of poverty increase there over twice that of boosting it from forty to fifty percent. Moreover, the impacts will be much more effective in poor white neighbourhoods than in poor minority ones, regardless of the initial level of homeownership (ibid.). 4.3. The Canadian Experience In Canadian context, instead of the forty percent threshold employed by Jargowsky, a standard of twice the national family low-income rate was used by Hatfield (1997) to identify high poverty census tracts. In 1990, using the 1986 base Low Income Cut Offs compiled by Statistics Canada, the national family low-income rate was 13.2 percent. Therefore the threshold used in his analysis was 26.4 percent in 1990. The five indicators chosen by Hatfield to identify distressed neighbourhoods in Canada and the threshold levels for each were as follows: 1. A high individual poverty rate in the census tract – above 27.66 percent; 2. A high proportion of total household income in the tract coming from transfer payments from government – above 17.36 percent; 3. A low proportion of the 15-24 population in the tract attending school fulltime – below 43 percent; 4. A low percentage of the male population 15 and over employed for pay fulltime (49 or more weeks in the previous year) – below 35.7 percent; and, 5. A high percentage of families with children at home headed by lone parents – above 31.45 percent. 39 Causes of Decline Using these thresholds, 106 (2.7%) of the 3914 census tracts in Canada met all five criteria of distress. There were also sixteen tracts which did not meet the low-income criteria, but which met all four of the other criteria of social and economic distress. Both concentrated poverty and distressed neighbourhoods in Canada were highly concentrated in 1991 in Montréal, Québec City and Winnipeg (38, 10, and 12 percent respectively). These three centres accounted for nearly half of Canada’s distressed and near-distressed urban neighbourhoods. Substantial proportions of the overall populations of these CMAs live in distressed and near-distressed neighbourhoods. In Québec City almost one in ten (9.8%) do. In Montréal the share rises to 11.8 percent and in Winnipeg to 12.3 percent of the metropolitan population (ibid.). 5. Conclusions Many large old cities in North America, Australia and Europe have experienced population decline and increases in inner-city unemployment and poverty since the mid1960s, which have been attributed to such factors as de-industrialization and the “cycle of poverty”. The processes leading to the inner-city decline and its characteristics are common to many countries. These include poverty and segregation; vacant and abandoned property; disinvestment and economic decline; changing land uses; and public education decline. Deprived areas can slide into a cycle of decline, making it more and more difficult for people who live there to take advantage of opportunities. As neighbourhoods become less desirable, those who can move out do. Based on a comprehensive literature review addressing inner-city decline, major theories that have been used to explain urban decline were identified. These include: 1. The Ecological School - the concentric zone, the sectoral, the multi-nuclei models, social area analysis, filtering, the life-cycle, the bid rent and the border theories, the vacancy chain hypothesis, the cycles of disadvantage, the broken windows and urban underclass theories, the pull and obsolescence hypotheses and environmental determinism. 2. The Subcultural School. 3. Political Economists - the urban growth machine thesis, the urban structural change, the spatial mismatch, the exploitation hypotheses and the fiscal crisis theory. 4. The Social Capital Model. The literature review provides evidence of the absence of a consistent trend in support of any of the hypotheses. This can lead to the conclusion that, given the wide variation between inner cities in their age, size, and economic structure, no one single hypothesis can explain changes in decline levels throughout the urban system. All the theories of neighbourhood decline are partly right, partly wrong, and generally over-simplified. As Carley (1990) pointed out, one reason theories go in and out of fashion is probably that there is no one correct answer to the urban dilemma; we must therefore continually pick and choose among options which appear to work. For this reason, in considering the potential for area-based neighbourhood renewal, it is important 40 Causes of Decline to understand the advantages and constraints of areal approaches as compared with other ways to tackle urban renewal. The analysis of these theories can provide a useful network for better understanding which revitalization initiatives would aid declining neighbourhoods. Based on their review of urban decline theories Temkin and Rohe (1996) contend that physical, social, and economic factors can all have significant impacts on neighbourhood quality. That is, in their framework, investments in housing construction, homeownership initiatives, and investments in new establishments can all potentially serve as policy instruments for enhancing neighbourhood quality. Numerous causes triggering decline in inner cities were identified through the literature review. Poverty, racial conflict, ageing of the population, suburban sprawl, the spatial distribution of affordable housing, decline of inner-city schools, the creativity factor, and unintended policy effects were discussed in more detail. In a similar vein, it is possible to conclude that urban decline does not have a readily identifiable starting point or single isolated cause. Instead, decline is a complex, self-reinforcing phenomenon in which symptoms of decline themselves become causes. Once underway, decline tends to be evolutionary and accretive. The literature review also looked at threshold indicators beyond which neighbourhood reaches a point of inevitable decline in the quality of life it offers. Different threshold indicators have been used to measure neighbourhood change, such as poverty, unemployment, school dropout, home ownership rates, female headship rates, racial composition, and others. In order to develop a more balanced understanding of neighbourhood change, it is necessary to acknowledge the complexity of urban life, economic conditions and social relations, to recognize forces from both within and outside of neighbourhoods, and to analyze change at multiple geographic scales, taking into account both micro and macro dynamics. List of References Alonso, W. (1960) “A Theory of the Urban Land Market”, Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association 6 (1960): 149-158. Alonso, W. (1964) Location and Land Use. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA. Bourne, L. S. (1982) The Inner City in Modern Metropolitan Systems / edited by Charles M. Christian and Robert A. Harper. Columbus, Ohio: Charles Merrill Pub. Bradford, N. (2002) Why Cities Matter: Policy Research Perspectives for Canada. CPRN Discussion Paper No. F/23. Canadian Policy Research Networks Inc., Ottawa. Broadway, M. J. (1995) “The Canadian Inner City 1971-1991: Regeneration and Decline”. Canadian Journal of Urban Research 4 (1): 1-19. Burgess, E. W. (1925) “The Growth of the City” in R. E. Park, E. W. Burgess, R. D. McKenzie, and L. Wirth, editors. The City. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 41 Causes of Decline Carley, M. (1990) Housing and Neighbourhood Renewal: Britain's New Urban Challenge. Policy Studies Institute. Report number 710. <http://www.psi.org.uk/publications/MISC/housingnr.htm> Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy (2000) Moving Beyond Sprawl: The Challenge for Metropolitan Atlanta. The Brookings Institution. <http://www.brook.edu/es/urban/atlanta/toc.htm> CMHC (2001) Disinvestment and Decline of Urban Neighbourhoods. Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation, Ottawa. Ding, C. and Knaap, G. -J. (2002) Property Values in Inner City Neighborhoods: The Effects of Homeownership, Housing Investment, and Economic Development. The National Center for Smart Growth <www.smartgrowth.umd.edu/research/ neighborhoodstability-816.pdf> Downs, A. (1999) “Some Realities about Sprawl and Urban Decline”. Housing Policy Debate 10 (4): 955-974. Driedger, L. (1991) The Urban Factor: Sociology of Canadian Cities. Toronto: Oxford University Press. Ellen, I.G. and Turner, M.A. (1997) “Does Neighborhood Quality Matter? Assessing Recent Evidence”, Housing Policy Debate 8 (4): 833-866. Fainstein, S. and Campbell, S., editors (2002) Readings in Urban Theory. Second Edition. Oxford, U.K., Malden: Blackwell Publishers. Florida, R. (2000) Competing in the Age of Talent: Quality of Place and The New Economy. A Report prepared for the R. K. Mellon Foundation, Heinz Endowments, and Sustainable Pittsburgh. Florida, R. (2002) The Rise of the Creative Class: And How It’s Transforming Work, Leisure, Community and Everyday Life. Basic Books, 1st edition. Fogarty, Michael S. (1977) “Predicting neighborhood decline within a large central city: an application of discriminant analysis”, Environment and Planning A (9): 579-584. Franke, T. and Löhr, R. -P. (2001) “Neighbourhood Management - A Key Instrument in Integrative Urban District Development”. Paper presented at the conference Area-based initiatives in contemporary urban policy, Danish Building and Urban Research and European Urban Research Association, Copenhagen <http://www.by-og-byg.dk/eura/workshops/papers/workshop3/franke.htm> Galster, G. C. (1977) “A Bid-Rent Analysis Of Housing Market Discrimination”. American Economic Review 67 (2): 144-155. 42 Causes of Decline Galster, G. (2002) “An Economic Efficiency Analysis of Deconcentrating Poverty Populations”. Journal of Housing Economics 11: 303 –329. Galster, G. C. and Hill, E. W. (1992) “Place, Power and Polarization”. In The Metropolis in Black and White, edited by George Galster and Edward W. Hill. New Brunswick, NJ: Center for Urban Policy Research. Galster, G. C. and Krall J. M. (2003) Exploring Endogenous Neighborhood Dynamics. Paper for presentation at ACSP/AESOP Conference Leuven, Belgium. Galster, G. C., Quercia, R. G. and Cortes A. (2000) “Identifying Neighborhood Thresholds: An Empirical Exploration”. Housing Policy Debate 11 (2): 701-732. Galster, G. C., Quercia, R. G., Cortes, A., and Malega, R. (2003) The Fortunes of Poor Neighborhoods <http://www.culma.wayne.edu/pubs/galster/Fortunes_Poor_Neighds_UAR_2-03.pdf> Gertler, M.S. (2001) “Urban Economy and Society in Canada: Flows of People, Capital and Ideas”. Isuma: The Canadian Journal of Policy Research 2 (3): 119-130. Glennerster, H., Lupton, R., Noden, P., and Power, A. (1999) Poverty, Social Exclusion and Neighbourhood: Studying the area bases of social exclusion. CASE paper 22, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of Economics <sticerd.lse.ac.uk/dps/case/cp/CASEpaper22.pdf > Gregory, R. G. and Hunter, B. (2003). The Growth of Income and Employment Inequality in Australian Cities. Canadian International Labour Network Working Papers. <http://labour.ciln.mcmaster.ca/papers/cilnwp03.pdf> Harris, C. and Ullman, E. (1945). “The Nature of Cities”, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 242: 7-17. Hatfield, M. (1997) Concentrations of Poverty and Distressed Neighbourhoods in Canada. W-97-1E, Applied Research Branch, Strategic Policy, Human Resources Development Canada, Ottawa. Hoyt, H. (1933) One Hundred Years of Land Values in Chicago. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hoyt, H. (1939) The Structure of Growth of Residential Neighborhoods in American Cities. Federal Housing Administration, Washington D.C. Jargowsky, P. (1996) “Beyond the Street Corner: The Hidden Diversity of High-Poverty Neighborhoods”. Urban Geography 17 (7). Jargowsky, P. (1997) Poverty and Place: Ghettos, Barrios, and the American City. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. 43 Causes of Decline Jonas, A. and Wilson, D., editors (1999) The Urban Growth Machine: Critical Perspectives Two Decades Later. SUNY Press. Kasarda, J. D. (1990) “Structural Factors Affecting the Location and Timing of Urban ‘Underclass’ Growth”. Urban Geography 11: 234-264 Krivo, L.J. and Peterson, R.D. (1996) “Extremely disadvantaged neighborhoods and urban crime”. Social Forces 75 (2): 619 –650. Ley, D. and Smith, H. (1997) Is There An Immigrant Underclass in Canadian Cities? Vancouver Centre of Excellence: Research on Immigration and Integration in the Metropolis, Working Paper Series #97-08, 1-59. Logan, J.R. and Molotch, H.L. (1987) Urban fortunes: The political economy of place. Berkeley: University of California Press. Lucy, W. H. and Phillips, D. L. (2000) Confronting Suburban Decline: Strategic Planning for Metropolitan Renewal. Island Press. Maré, D. C., Mawson, P. and Timmins, J. Deprivation in New Zealand: Regional Patterns and Changes. Treasury Working Paper 01/09. The Terrace, Wellington, New Zealand. Metzger, J. T. (2000) “Planned Abandonment: Life-Cycle Theory and Urban Policy”. Housing Policy Debate 11 (1): 7-40. Miller, Roger LeRoy (2001) The Case of the Disappearing Banks. East Coast Economic Case Study #5. East Coast Economic Case Studies to accompany Miller, Economics Today, 2001-2002 Edition <http://occawlonline.pearsoned.com/bookbind/pubbooks/miller2001_awl/medialib/downl oad/east/east05.html> Orfield, M. (1998) Portland Metropolitics: A Regional Agenda for Community and Stability. A Report to the Coalition for a Livable Future <http://www.clfuture.org/orfreport/orfintro.html> Park, R. E., Burgess, E. W., McKenzie, R. D., and Wirth, L., editors (1925) The City. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Pitkin, B. (2001) Theories of Neighborhood Change: Implications for Community Development Policy and Practice. UCLA Advanced Policy Institute. Ricketts, E. R. and Sawhill, I. V. (1988) “Defining and Measuring the Underclass”. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 7 (2): 316-325 in Hatfield, M. (1997) Concentrations of Poverty and Distressed Neighbourhoods in Canada. W-97-1E, Applied Research Branch, Strategic Policy, Human Resources Development Canada, Ottawa. Robson, B. (1988) Those Inner Cities. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 44 Causes of Decline Shevsky, E. and Bell, W. (1955) Social Area Analysis: Theory, Illustrative Application and Computational Procedures. Stanford, Ca.: Stanford University Press. Smith, W. (1963) “Forecasting Neighborhood Change”. Land Economics 39: 292-97 in Pitkin, B. (2001) Theories of Neighborhood Change: Implications for Community Development Policy and Practice. UCLA Advanced Policy Institute. Temkin, K. and Rohe, W. M. (1996) “Neighborhood Change and Urban Policy”. Journal of Planning Education and Research 15 (3): 159-70. Temkin, K. and Rohe, W. M. (1998) “Social Capital and Neighborhood Stability: An Empirical Investigation”. Housing Policy Debate 9 (1): 61-88. Turner, M. A. and Hayes, C. (1997) Poor People and Poor Neighborhoods in the Washington Metropolitan Area. <http://www.urban.org/Template.cfm?NavMenuID=24&template=/TaggedContent/View Publication.cfm&PublicationID=6565> Wheeler, L. A. (1990) A Review of the Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis: Its Impact on the Current Plight of Central City in the United States. Occasional paper no. 137. Metropolitan Studies Program, The Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University. Williams, Colin, C. and Jan Windebank (2001) “Bottom Up Initiatives” in Revitalizing Deprived Urban Neighbourhoods: An Assisted Self Help Approach. Ashgate Publishers: Aldershot Wilson, J. Q. and Kelling, G. L. (1982) “The Police and Neighborhood Safety: Broken Windows”. Atlantic Monthly 249 (3): 29–38. Wilson, W. J. (1987) The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, the Underclass and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Wilson, W. J. (1996) When Work Disappears: The World of the New Urban Poor. New York: Knopf. Wilson, W. J. (1999) “When Work Disappears: New Implications for Race and Urban Poverty in the Global Economy”, Ethnic & Racial Studies 22 (3): 479-499. Wilson, D. and J. Wouters (2003) ”Spatiality and Growth Discourse: The Restructuring Of America’s Rust Belt Cities,” Journal of Urban Affairs 25 (2): 123-139. 45