2 Urbanizationand Economic Development George S. Tolley oncerns about urbanizationand economicdevelop_ ment go hand in hand, for a number of reasons. Beyondthe question of whether urbanizationis a cause or a consequenceof development,it is the backdropfor developmentin almost all nations. Rapidurbanization posescomplexmanagementproblemsin housing, transport, land use, the environment,energy,publicservices, and finance.These problemsare responsiblein part for interest in whether overurbanizationhas occurred and whether more active policiesare neededto control and direct urbanization. To deal adequatelywith urbanization issues,an understanding is neededofwhy the process takes place and what determines its rate, its geographic pattern, and the characteristics of people in cities. That there is a close relation between urbanization and economic developmentis evident from experience in most countries that haveundergone development.It alsoseemsclear that urbanizationis not a primarycause of economic development. In a very long view of history the role of cities in promotingeconomicdevelopment-through beingcenters of the learning and interactions that lead to innovation-would be a concern. In recent history, as communications have been revolutionized,economic development has come more to consist in applying ideas, no matter where they originate. It seems reasonable that some, and perhaps most, urbanizationis the result ofeconomicdevelopmentprocesses. But accepting a general line of causality from economicdevelopmentto urbanizationdoesnot answer the question of how the causalityworks. Economicdevelopmentmakesit possibleforpeopleto produce more. Why should this possibilitylead to urbanization?Can our understanding of the links between development and urbanization be carried to the point of quantification?What are the main implicationsof a better understanding of urbanization? In seeking answersto these questions in this chapter it is recognizedthat the explanationof urbanization is largelyan explanationof economicactivity.Citieswould not grow unless there were productivethings for people to do in them. In the past hundred years enormousgrowth of cities occurred in the Western world as peopletook the fruits of developmentin the form of products, other than food and fiber, that could be producedmore economicallyin cities than in the countryside. Rapid urbanization in developingcountries today is in some part a result of a similar wish to take the fruits of developmentin the form of goods and servicessuited to urban production. But more than in the past, urbanizationappearsto be relatedto internationalspecializationthat is freedfrom great dependenceon domesticdemand.Peopleare producing goods in the cities of the developingworld and trading them in international marketsfor all manner of other goods,includingfood.Thelinks betweenthe composition of domestic consumption and urbanization have been greatly weakened.Actually,the links were never exclusive,and theyhavebecomeprogressivelyless so throughout the worldwith the increasingimportance of international trade to all economies. Domestic and international demands for urban and nonurban goods, as just discussed, are the basis for demand influenceson urbanization.The abilityto pro- Note:KennethMirandaprovidedvaluablehelp in the preparationof this chapter. 15 16 GeorgeS. Tolley duce more urban and nonurban goods acts to increase abundance and is a supply consideration. Population growth results in growth of human inputs and is likewise a supply consideration. Many of the puzzles of urbanization can be understoodby analyzinghow these demandand supplyinfluencesinteract.Thedemandand supply influencesprovideheadingsunderwhich urbanization is analyzed in this chapter. A traditional model of urbanization, appropriate to closedeconomies,is consideredfirst. Relationsbetween urban and nonurban productivity,incomeelasticitiesof demand, and population growth as determinants of urbanization are analyzed.Then urbanization is considered in a more general setting, with international trade. Attempts are made to distinguish between firstorder and second-order effects for countries that are price takers in world markets. One of the conclusions from the resulting model, which is applicableto most countries, is that greater urban productivityleads to more urbanization rather than (as in the traditional model) less. Symmetrically,and again contrary to the traditional model, greater nonurban productivityleads to less urbanization. The model is applied to sixty-sixdevelopingeconomies, leading to explanationsof the degreeof urbanization in each economy in terms of growth in urban productivity, nonurban productivity, and population. The use of the frameworkdevelopedin this chapter to further deepen understanding of urbanization in individual countries is discussed,and some importantpolicy implicationsare noted. incomeand the relativeprices ofthe two typesof goods. These factors are in turn influenced by supply conditions. The total resources of an economyare devotedto either urban or nonurban activities. The amounts of output of the two types of activitiesdependon how the availableresources are split betweenthem and on production considerations that determine how much of each typeof output can be obtainedfrom a givenamount of resources. Overtime the total number of personsworking in the economy may grow, and for both urban and nonurban activitiesthe amount of output that can be obtainedfor a given amount of inputs may increase. Given the increases in the number of persons, in the total stock of capital in the economy, and in productivities,the responses to the demand and supply changes that occur during economicgrowth will determine changesin the allocation of resources between urban and nonurban activities. The view that urbanization accompanieseconomic development implies that the demand and supply changes are such that increasing urbanization in fact results. Whyis this, and is it necessarilyto be expected? The explanationof urbanization has been best explored for the high-incomeWestern countries which have experienceddramatic declinesin the proportion of people working in agriculture and in this sense have become the most fully urbanized. The receivedexplanation of this result centers on one element on the demandside and one on the supply side. Income Elasticities of Demand Demand and Supply Factors A first step towardan understanding of urbanization is to consider the underlying demandand supplyconditions that determine how the resources of an economy are divided between urban and nonurban activities. A first approximationis to associate nonurban activities with agriculture and urban activitieswith industry and other nonagricultural pursuits. The distinction ignores nonagricultural production by farmhouseholdsand industry in rural areas, and it begs the question of exactly how urban is defined-that is, whether smalltowns are urban or rural and where the dividing line between urban and nonurban phenomenalies.Althoughthe distinction is not perfect, the discussionhere proceedson the assumption that some degree of approximationis inevitableand that nonurban situations in most parts of the world are overwhelminglyagricultural. Demand conditionsdeterminehow peoplesplit their income betweenurban and nonurban products. Important factors in the allocation of income are the level of The element on the demandside is income elasticity of demand. Because of the low income elasticityof demand for agricultural products-say, 0.10 to 0.20people are viewedas choosing to spend an increasing proportion of income on urban products as per capita income rises. The low income elasticityof demandfor agricultural products has thus been cited as one of the principal reasonswhya societydevotesmore and more of its resources to nonagricultural pursuits and thus becomes more highly urbanized. Since people must spend all their income on either urban or nonurban commodities(where commoditiesare comprehensively defined to include both consumption goods and the capital goods on which savingsare spent), the income elasticityof demand for agricultural (nonurban) commoditiescan be translated into an income elasticityfor urban commodities.If all incomeelasticitiesare unity, a 1 percent increase in income leads to a 1 percent increase in expenditures on everycommodity. If the incomeelasticityfor some commoditiesis less than unity, expenditureson them will rise bylessthan 1 percentand Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment the income left over will enable expenditureson other commoditiesto rise by more than 1 percent.Thus,ifthe income elasticity for nonurban products is less than unity, the income elasticityfor urban productswill be greater than unity. The balance of income elasticitiesabove and below unity dependson the relativeamounts ofexpenditureon each kind of commodity.Awell-knownconditionis that the expenditure-weightedsum of income elasticities overall commoditiesis equalto unity. For example,if20 percent of expendituresare for nonurban commodities and 80 percent for urban commodities,and if the income elasticityof demand for agricultural products is 0.10, then the income elasticityfor urban products is 1.225, implyinga 1.225percent increasein expenditures on urban products for every 1 percent increase in income. To obtain this result, note that the weighted income elasticitycondition is w11¶111 + WaT-a= 1, where the ws are the urban and nonurban expenditureweights and %1 and q, are the income elasticities. The solution of the income elasticityfor urban products, %, is (1 - waTja)IWu, or, with the numbers in the example, (1 - 0.2 *0.1)/0.8, or 1.225. The exampleis fora high-incomecountry; a different result may be obtainedfor a low-incomecountry. It is generallythought that the income elasticitydemandfor agricultural productsgoes downas income rises. Thus, for lower-incomecountries a higher agricultural income elasticity implies a lower income elasticity for urban commoditiesand hence, other things beingequal, a lowerrate ofurbanization.Acountry couldstill experience urbanization, but the lower income elasticityfor urban commoditiesmight contribute to a lowerrate of urbanization in the early stages of development. In addition to differencesin income elasticities (the -qs),another differencebetween high-income and lowincome countries-and one that operates in the opposite direction-is the fractionof expendituredevotedto urban and nonurban commodities(the ws). If the fraction spent on nonurban commoditiesis high, the weight on the income elasticityfor nonurban commoditieswill alsobe high. At an earlystage of development,when per capita income is low, a large fractionof incomeis likely to be spent on agricultural commodities. The income elasticity of demand for agricultural commoditieswill not be as far belowunity as in a high-incomecountry and, because its weight is greater, it will tend to make the incomeelasticityforurban commoditiesonlyslightly aboveunity. As developmentproceeds,the gradual declinein the income elasticityfor agricultural commoditieswill act to increasethe incomeelasticityfor urbancommodities, while the decline in the agriculturalweight will act to decrease it. Whether the income elasticity for urban 17 commoditiesrises or falls during developmentdepends on which effect predominates. It is conceivablethat the income elasticityfor urban commoditiesis low during the early stagesof development, rises to a peakduringa middleperiod,and fallsat the later stages. If so, there willbe a tendencyforthe rate ofurbanizationto start out low,rise to a peak, andfall to a low rate. The first column of table 2-1 showsvarious valuesof the incomeelasticityofnonurban commodities and the second column shows accompanyingpercentages of expenditureson those commoditiesthat might be observed.The third column shows the income elasticity of demand for urban commodities that results from these combinations,as derivedfrom the formula for -9, above.The entries in the table progressfrom the top row,which correspondsto conditionsthat might be encountered in the initial stages of development,to intermediate situations (the middle of the table), to advanced development(the last row). In the first row the income elasticityof demand for agricultural products is at its high value, unity. The income elasticityof demandfor urban products is then alsounity, no matter what the expenditurefractionsare. The income elasticityeffectwould not lead to any relative urbanization, for it would leavethe urban proportion of the population unchanged. In the second set of entries the income elasticityof demandfor agricultural commoditieshas fallento 0.8. Some possiblevalues of the expenditureshare accompanyingthis elasticityare shown. If the share of expenditureon agriculturalcommoditiesremains high (80 percent),the income elasticity for urban commoditiesrisesto 1.8; it does not riseas much ifthe expenditureshares are less. In the next set of entries the incomeelasticityfor agriculturalproducts is 0.5. If the expenditureshare has fallenby this time to 50 percent, the incomeelasticityof demandfor urban commodities will be 1.5, with higher and lowervalues for different expenditureshares. The last row corresponds Table 2-1. Determinantsof IncomeElasticity of Demand for Urban Commodities Income elasticity of demand,nonurban commodities Income spent on nonurban commodities (percent) Income elasticityof demand for urban commodities 1.0 1.0 0-100 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.5 0.5 80 50 20 1.8 1.2 1.05 50 1.5 20 1.125 01 20 1.225 18 GeorgeS. Tolley to the exampleoriginallygivenfor a high-incomecountry, with an incomeelasticityforurban commoditiesof 1.225. Table2-1 suggeststhat the income elasticityforurban commoditieswill first rise and then fall during development. If the share of expenditureon agriculturalcommodities falls only slowly, the income elasticity for urban commoditiesrises longer and further than if the share of expenditureson agriculture falls rapidly. In additionto demandconditionswithin the country, the proportion ofthe populationwhichis urbanizedwill be affected by changes in the degree of international specializationthat occur duringdevelopment.Acountry may developprimarilyby increasingits output of manufactured goods for export to the rest of the world. If agricultural output does not increase enough to meet domestic demand, the exports of manufactured goods will be used in part to pay for increasing imports of agricultural commodities.As a result, the increase in production of urban commoditieswill be larger than if there were no changes in the degree of international specialization,and a smaller fraction of the increased demand for agriculturalcommoditieswill be met from production inside the economy.The income elasticity for agricultural commoditiesmust be redefinedto pertain only to the percentage increase in domestic agricultural production associatedwith a 1 percent rise in income, and increasesin output of urban commodities will be larger than implied by domestic elasticities. Changes in the degree of international specialization may thus accelerate the rate of urbanization during development. Changes in international specializationappear to be the rule and not the exception during development. Theyhavebeenparticularlypronouncedin such dramatic growth experiencesas the "Pacificgrowth miracles" in which Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, and Taiwan all experiencedrapid developmentsimultaneouslywith increasesin output of nonagriculturalgoodsfor export.In these economies and in others with similar, although less extreme, growth patterns, concern has arisen over the loss of agricultural self-sufficiencyas imports of agriculturalproductsrisealongwith the risingoutput of the economy. A more positive way of looking at the decline in agricultural self-sufficiencyis to view it as a manifestationof gainsfrom internationalspecialization. It is more economicalto produce manufactured goods and exchange them for agricultural products than to forgo the additional manufactured output and try to produce agricultural products that can be produced more efficientlyelsewhere. Although generalizationsare hazardous, historically economic development has been almost universally accompaniedby increasingspecializationof production. Indeed, the very possibilityof economic development has often been basedon such specialization.Increasing international specializationis part ofa wider processof specializationand providesa reason for increasing urbanization that is related to economicdevelopment. Increasingspecializationcan occur in agriculturalas wellas in urban production. It is conceivablethat some countriescould becomeless rather than more urbanized during development, although no prominent example comesto mind. A largepart of the internationallytraded portion of agricultural production comes from highincome countries, which are already highly urbanized. Growthof domesticdemandand comparativeadvantage in nonagricultural production are more important in explainingurbanization than is specializationin international agricultural trade. Su pply Factors Whenattention turns from the demandto the supply side, concern shifts from changes in output to changes in the numbers of people used to producethe output. If human inputs were equally substitutable for physical capital in urban and in nonurban production activities, and if the rates of growth of factor productivityin the two typesof activitieswere the same, changes in output and changes in numbers of people would go together exactly, and the demand considerations already discussed would sufficeto explainthe rate of urbanization during development.But this is not the case.Conditions vary widely, and output per person in production of urban commoditiesmay rise more or less rapidlythan for nonurban commodities. Traditionalexplanationshave emphasizedrapid technologicalchange in agriculture, which leads to more rapid growth of output per agricultural worker as the major supply consideration that acts in conjunction with low income elasticityof demandto eject resources from agriculture. Several considerations other than technological change, however, affect output per worker, as will now be discussed. Land scarcity is overrated as a factor that could decreaseoutput per worker in agriculture. If output did go down, the rate of urbanization would be retarded as more workers were kept in agriculture to produce a given agricultural output. This outcome could occur if growing population pressed seriously against scarce land supplies,but the evidenceevenforthe prime example of a country that might be in these straits-Chinais unclear.Newlandhas been cominginto productionin some parts of the world, notably in Latin America. Improvement of the quality of land through investment Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment retards declines in output per worker. International specializationhas worked against agriculture in many countries and has easedpressure on land supply. Agriculturalresearch has effectsoppositeto those of scarce land supply.An increase in output per worker in agriculture permitsa givendemandto be metwith fewer agriculturalworkers,releasespeopleforurban pursuits, and increases the rate of urbanization.Even if the increase in productivityas a result ofagriculturalresearch leads to income growth, workers will be released to urban areas if the income elasticityof demand for the productswhose output is increasedis lessthan unity, as seems likely. It is also true that the Green Revolution and other innovations resulting from agricultural research have sometimes been more saving of land and related physical inputs than of workers. The effect of these innovationshas in any casebeen extremelyvaried among and within countries, so that it is more than usuallydifficult to generalizeabout it. Asdevelopmentproceedsthere isa tendencyformore of the inputs used in agricultureto be producedin urban areas. This phenomenonis part of the increasing specializationthat has alreadybeenmentionedand appears to be speeded up by innovations resulting from agricultural research. Gasoline,feed concentrates,and fertilizers and other nutrients are among the inputs produced in urban areas that replace inputs formerly produced on farms.In addition,home gardenplots and home food processingdecline. Successfuleconomicdevelopmentis characterizedby rising returns to human inputs, resulting in part from substitution of capital for labor. These changes may affect urban and nonurban production differently.Urbanizationwill be favoredif the substitution of capital for labor is higher in nonurban than in urban production-another of the circumstancesthat maydifferfrom one country to another. A large source of the substitutions is replacementof labor-intensivehuman or animal sources ofpowerby machinepower,and possibilitiesfor substitutions abound in nonurban as wellas urban production. (The mechanizationof cotton growing in the United States had wholesaleeffects on rural-to-urban migration and profoundly affected American cities.) Urbanproduction,which uses readilytransferabletechniquesfrom other countries,mayoffergreater possibilities for substitutions, at least in manufacturingindustries. But urban production is more intensive than nonurban production in services,wherecapital appears to be less substitutable for labor. One of the effects of economic developmentis the gradual elimination of so-calledtraditional production in both urban and nonurban areas. Urbanizationwillbe speededif there is more of this traditionalproductionto 19 be eliminated in nonurban than in urban areas. Here, again, countries are not alike. Family and home businessesabound in many cities, as do small unviable farming operationsin many parts of the world. (Much campesinoagriculture is of this type.) The important characteristicof traditional productionfor the purposes of this discussionis that, in spiteof all of its adjustments to relative prices and other changes during development, it is outcompetedby other forms of production. During economicdevelopmentpeopleare releasedfrom the declining traditional forms of production to other activities. If they are releasedfrom traditional employment in urban areas and go into other employmentin urban areas, there is no effect on urbanization,but if they are releasedfrom traditional employmentin agricultural areas where there are no expandingemployment opportunities,they willseek employmentin urban areas, and urbanization will increase. Because of the low amount producedper person in traditional production, a reduction in traditional employmentleads to increasedoutput per person.Whether output per person rises more in urban or in nonurban areas depends on the rate of reduction in traditional production in the two types of areas and on its relative importance in the areas. Changes in the quality of human inputs through education and other forms of human capital formation deserve mention in relation to urbanization.Urbanization and human capital formation both appear to be responsesto factorsthat lead to economicdevelopment, rather than urbanization being a primary cause of human capitalformationor viceversa.Likephysicalcapital formation,human capitalformationresults in increases in output per person and allowsa given demandto be fulfilledby fewer people.Giventhe demands for urban and for nonurban commodities,a higher rate ofincrease in human capitalper person in nonurban than in urban productionwill be conduciveto a high rate of urbanization, since the demand for nonurban commoditiescan be fulfilledby fewerpeople.The increasein educational levelsand the growthof skilledand professionalcategories of employmentin cities are sometimesthought to be necessary conditionsfor development.Yet farmers alsobecomebetter educated.Nonurbanproductionmay use a loweramount of human capitalper person at the early stages of development,and the level may remain lowerthrough a great part of the developmentprocess even though human capital per person in nonurban production is continually rising and may indeed be rising at a faster rate than in urban production.The faster rise in human capital per person in nonurban than in urban production leads to the hypothesisthat increases in nonurban human capital could contribute to a high 20 GeorgeS. Tolley rate of urbanization. This effect,however,may be secondary to the considerationthat both urbanizationand human capital formation are basically results rather than causes of economicdevelopment. Population The demand and supply considerationsdiscussedso far pertain to the relativerate of urbanization,or urbanization per capita, and would be sufficient to explain urban growthin a countrywith stable population.Growing total populationprovidesa kicker to both urban and nonurban population growth. The rapid population growthrates in someparts of the world meanthat much urbanizationcomes simplyfrom the fact that there are more people in the country. The TraditionalModel of Urbanization The discussionhas consideredthe role of the income elasticitiesof demand in determining urbanization,the factorsthat affectoutput per person in each sector, and the role of total populationgrowth. The followingformula bringsthose factorstogetherinto an expressionfor understanding their combined influenceon the rate of urbanization. (2-1) ( / )r1TT - )V + N. N11(lu"laN 1 /N0 ) + 1 Since the urban populationN,, equalsthe proportion urban n,, times total populationN (or, N,, = n 1 N), the percentage change in the urban populationN,, is the percentage change in proportion urban h41 plus the percentage changein total populationN(or,&N= flu + N), which is the basis of equation 2-1. The variable on the left-hand side, N1 , is the annual percentage rate of growth of the urban population.The first term on the right-hand side is the percentage rate of change in the proportion of the populationwhich is urban. It includes all the considerationsdiscussedearlier exceptthe effect oftotal populationgrowthof the country,whichis given by the second term on the right-hand side, N. Note that the ratio of the percentage increases in output per capita of urban and nonurban commodities will be in the ratio of their income elasticities.(Recall that the incomeelasticitiesare redefinedto take account of internationaltrade effects.)This firstconditioncan be writteny,/ya = iu/ %, wherej11 is the percentagerate of growth of urban output per capita (4u = Y11/N, or urban output dividedby the country'stotal population) and r, is the trade-adjustedincomeelasticityof demand for urban commodities. Similar definitionsapply to Ya and 9, where the subscript a stands for nonurban commodities. Considerations that affect output per person are brought in by noting that the percentage increase in output per capita for any commodity is equal to the percentage change in output per person engaged in production of the commodity plus the percentage changein the proportion ofpeoplein the nation engaged in that production. The secondand third conditionsare thus ,u = Tu,+ hu for urban commoditiesandy 0 = T0 + h, for nonurban commodities,where T is percentage change in output per person engagedin productionand n is percentage change in the proportion of peopleengaged in production. The second and third conditions followfrom differentiationof the identity that output equalsnumber of workerstimes output per worker.The fourth condition is that any change in the urban proportion of the population must be accompanied by an equal and opposite change in the nonurban proportion. In percentage terms the fourth condition is k1 = - (NaIN,1 )ia, whereN0 and N11 are the numbers of persons in nonurban and urban areas. The four conditions that have been given determine the four variablesj11 , Ya,nu, andha0 . The firstterm on the right-hand side of the above expressionfor the rate of growth of urban populationis the solution of the set of four conditions for izh,the percentagechange in the proportionof the populationwhich is urban. As can be seen from equation 2-1, the numerator of the term givingthe percentagechangein the proportion urban is equal to the negative of the rate of growth of output per person in production of urban commodities (that is, an increasein urban productivity,acting alone, leads to a decrease in urban population because the demand for urban commoditiescan be met by fewer people) plus the ratio of urban to nonurban income elasticitiesmultipliedby the rate of growth of nonurban output per person (growthin nonurban output per person releasespersonsfor urban activities,and the magnitude of the effect depends on the income elasticities). The denominator-one plus the product of the ratio of income elasticitiesand the ratio of the numbers of people in urban and in nonurban areas-arises becauseof the interactions of the various effects. The secondterm in equation2-1 isN, the percentage rate of growth of total population of the country. Its presence indicatesthat when changes in the proportion of the populationthat is urban are taken into account, the urban populationvaries in direct proportion to the number of people in the country. From the formulait is clear that ratesof urbanization may differwith conditionsin particular countries.Asan example consider a country, still at an early stage of development,in which per capitaincome is rising somewhat rapidly.If the growth is orientedtoward growth of manufacturingproductsthat are exportedto world mar- Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment kets. the ratio of the increasein urban and in nonurban output, % I' , willbe rather high-say, 4. Supposethat one-third of the population is in urban areas and twothirds is in rural areas, sothat the valueforNu/N, is 0.5. Output per worker in urban areas is assumedto be rising at2 percent ayear (Tu = 0.02).Asa result of progressin a commercializedpart of agriculture and the declineof subsistence agriculture, output per worker in agriculture is alsoassumedto rise at the rate of 2 percent a year (Ta = 0.02). It is assumed that the total populationof the country is growingat 1.5percentayear(N = 0.015). Thevaluesare substitutedinto the formulaforthe yearly percentage growth in the urban population. 4 0.02 - 0.02 (2-2) N = 4 0.5 + I + 0.015 0.035. That is, the annual growth rate forthe urban population is 3.5 percent. Examplesof much more rapid or of slowerurbanization can be constructedbyvarying the values.The purposeof this section,however,has not beento explainthe rate of urbanizationfor any one country but to begin to suggestthe nature ofthe underlyingchangesin demand and supply that determine urbanization. A More General Explanation The discussion points to generalizationsabout why worldwideurbanizationis occurring.One reasonis that incomes are rising in many places, albeit in varying degrees. The higher income elasticity of demand for urban than for nonurban commoditiesis a fundamental reasonwhy urbanizationcan be expectedto accompany economicdevelopmentthroughout the world. Anotherreasonforworld urbanizationis more closely related to the nature of the economicdevelopmentthat is occurring. For much of the world economicdevelopment entailsa transfer oftechniquesof production,and by and large the techniques are more transferablefor urban than foragriculturalcommodities.Techniquesof agriculturalproductionare much more tied to localland and climate conditions. Efforts are being made to develop and adapt agricultural techniques to suit the unique conditions ofeach area of each country, but the pace,at best, is slow.Moreover,agriculture,as an inherent user of location-specificresources, is subject to intrinisic comparative advantages. Increasing specializationof agricultural production among major regions of the world may be in store. Urbanproduction, on the other hand, is not nearlyas location-bound. Factories, machines, and electronics parts tend to be physicallysimilar the worldover in their requirements for productiveinputs. It is not surprising 21 that developingcountries are increasinglygetting out of the agriculturalbusiness and into urban-basedproduction. Although the model of the preceding section allows for the effects of trade in the specificationof income elasticities, it is not fully consistent with the general reasonsfor rising urban populationconnectedwith specializationin productionnoted above.In equation2-1 a rise in agriculturalproductivitywill increaseurbanization because a given demand for agriculturalproducts can be satisfiedby fewer people and the excesspeople move to the cities. In like fashion,a rise in urban productivityacts to decr:ase urbanization,since fewerpeople are neededto satisfythe demandfor urban products. The amounts of labor required for production in both sectors change according to a life of their own, and amounts of output are not affected by productivity changes. Yet one might think that if a sector became more efficient, it would increase its production,not decrease it. An increasein efficiencylowersthe price at which a given quantity can be produced.If the price elasticityof demand is greater than zero,a loweringof the pricewill increase the amount that can be sold. A production response is to be expected. Indeed,ifthe responsesto changesin productiontake the form ofadjustments in foreignexportsand imports, prices are effectivelyset in world markets where de-mands are highlyelasticandwherein manycasesprices can be taken as given.Even within an economy,a more adequate view of the differencesbetween urban and rural production will recognizethat there is not a strict dichotomy in the types of goods produced.Aside from local or nontraded goodsin each sector,there are goods that may be produced in either sector and that can be traded betweenthe two sectors.There maybe little farmn output in urban areas (although chickens and garden plots can be significantin cities), but factoryproduction and home production of urban-type goods abound in rural areas,and trade betweensectors in processedfoods and other commoditiesis commonplace.For most ofthe world it maybe that most consumptionin either rural or urban areas is of goods producedwithin each area and that trade in marketed surpluses of rural and urban goods is confined to a small part of output, much of which can actuallybe produced in either sector. These considerationsof the waytrade occurs suggest that it maybe more reasonableto take pricesfacingrural and urban areas as given rather than to take relative quantity growth as given, as in the model presented above. If, as a first approximation,prices are taken as given,productivitychangeswill havethe oppositeeffect from that impliedby the model.Arise in productivityin urban areas enhancescities' abilityto competein inter- 22 GeorgeS. Tolley national markets and to compete with production in rural areas and thus leads to an increasein urban production, not a decrease.An analogousresult is obtained in nonurban areas, with the implication that rising nonurban productivitywill retard urbanization.The results are consistentwith the hypothesisthat urbanization results from changing advantagesin production. Giventhat a rise in productivityleadsto an expansion rather than a contraction of sector output, the question becomeshow great the expansionwillbe. Since relative quantitiesof output change are endogenousrather than exogenous, a careful distinction is needed between changes in average labor productivityand changes in marginal labor productivityas affectedby diminishing returns to employment in a sector. If there were no diminishingreturns as employmentincreasedin a sector, the assumption of given output prices (suggested here as a first approximation)would implythat, except by accident, one sector would have a higher marginal productivityof labor than the other. Migrationwould then lead to all the employmentbeing in one sector or the other-one sector would go to zero and the other would have all the employment. To avoid this unrealisticsolution the assumptionof given prices might be dropped, leading to a solution governedby changing prices of urban goods in relation to those of nonurban goods.But the ideathat urbanization is primarilyexplainedby massivechangesin prices of urban goodsin relation to those ofnonurban goodsin particular, by increases in relative prices of urban goods-is not appealing.This type of change does not appear to be a pervasiveworld phenomenon. Endogenous relativeprices can be introduced,but it would be bestto do so onlyafter a situationof givenrelativeprices has been more fullyexplored. Another way to avoidthe unrealisticsolution of having all employmentend up in one sector or the other would be to base a solution on impedimentsto labor migration. Then a rise in, say, urban comparedwith nonurban labor productivitywould increasethe attractivenessof urban employment.Imperfectlabor mobility wouldlead to a rising gapin real incomesbetweenurban and rural sectors that might be reduced only gradually over time. Oneproblemwith this solution is that it does not avoid the outcomethat all employmentends up in one sector; it only delaysthat outcome.Eventually,over generations,ifnot earlier,peopleallmigrate to the cities in responseto relativedifferencesin earningsopportunities. The only reason for not doing so would be nonpecuniary attachments to rural life. Basing an explanation of urbanization on permanent. nonpecuniary attachments to a wayof life is at least as unappealingas basing it on changing relative output prices of the sectors. If one has to choosebetween no labor mobilityand a degree of mobility that leads to rough equalizationof opportunitiesfor real earningsbetweensectors, the latter appearsfar more defensible.One is likelyto findthat, historically,real eamings of comparablelabor in urban and rural areashavechangedbyabout the same amount, and the degree of net and gross migration observed betweenurban and rural areas is so great as to belie the notion that responsesdo not occur. The single most important distinguishing feature in the relations between the urban and rural parts of an economymaybe that they are connected by migration. If one is not to base an explanationof urbanizationon a growingdisparity between real eamings of comparablelabor in urban and in rural areas, it is reasonableto supposethat there is sufficientlabor mobilityto roughlyequalizethe urban and rural changes in marginal productivitythat occur during economic development. The implications of lesser degrees of mobility could be considered,but this can be done more easilyand with more insightafter the first approximationis explored. In distinctionto the variableT that was used aboveto refer to average labor productivity, let A denote the influence of nonlabor inputs on the amount of output (taken to be synonymouswith income produced).For nonurban production,the availabilityof land maypartly determineA.Port facilitiesand other natural limitations could play a similar role in urban production. For both urban and nonurban production, privatecapitaland the amounts of various types of infrastructure influenceA. With laborN measuredin terms of numbersof peopleor hours, A is influenced by the productive quality per person, which in turn is determined in part by human capital investment. For both urban and nonurban production, perhapsthe greatestinfluenceonA is technical knowledgeused in production, which depends on encouragementof or impedimentsto international transfer of technology, entrepreneurship, incentive structures, and other policyand institutionalconsiderations. To obtain a formulation consistent with growth source analysis,take time derivativesof the production relation Y = AN6 and express as yearly percentage changes. Then growth in output will equalthe percentage growth in nonlabor influences,A, plus the product of elasticityof output with respect to labor, e,and the percentage change in labor. For urban production, (2-3) y +e aU and for nonurban production, (2-4) A, + N. The elasticityof output, e, is almost certainly between zero and one and is closer to one than to zero. If it were one or greater, the implicationwould be that-other inputs being held constant-output could be increased Urbanization and EconomicDevelopment 23 in equal or greater proportion to increases in labor. Under the assumptionof fixedproportionsthe elasticity would be zero. That assumption, however,ignores the myriadof possibilitiesfor drawingon a givenamount of nonlabor inputs to producevarying physicalquantities and qualities of outputs in modern factoryproduction, officework, retailing, personal services,and traditional above, E = wnIpy, can be rearrangedas an expression for the wage in a sector, w = epyIn. With the use of rates of change for the two sectors, production as the amount of labor is varied. The relation (2-6) Wa = Pa + Ya - Na assumingthat e is a stable parameter(e = 0). ThePs in these conditionsrefer to prices of output produced;the relevant deflatorthat determineslabor supplyresponse is an index of prices of goods consumed. The level of prices maydiffergreatly betweenurban and rural areas. If prices move proportionatelyover time and relative real earnings in urban and rural areas remain roughly the same, the rate of growth ofwagesin the two sectors will be similar, which yieldsthe condition Wu, = Wa. The right-handsides of equations2-5 and 2-6 can then be set equal to each other. If the approximationis retained that changesin prices of urban-producedgoodsrelativeto those of rural goods will not in the first instancebe usedas an explanationof the rate of urbanization,1% = Pa. Then the condition obtainedfrom setting the right-hand sidesof equations 2-5 and 2-6 equal to each other is between average labor productivityT in the preceding section and the influence of nonlabor inputs A in this section can be seen by combiningthe conditionsT = YIL and Y= AL' to obtain T = ALE- 1. If e is closeto one and if nonlabor influencesA are more predominantas causes of change in averagelabor productivitythan the elasticityeffectof changes in labor inputsLE-1, then T and A will move in a similar fashion. To proceed to the rest of the model in this section, suppose that labor is paid a wagew that is equalto its marginal product m multipliedby priceoutput p (or, m = wlp). The elasticityof output (the marginalproduct m multipliedbythe amount of laborn dividedbyoutput y) is seen to be equalto wagepaymentswn dividedbythe value of output py. This impliesthat e in equations2-3 and 2-4 equalsthe shareof product paidto labor,wn Ipy. The order of magnitude of e as labor's share can in principlebe observedrather readily.Althoughthe elasticity of output may be different in urban and in nonur- ban production, in this example it is taken to be the same. Not to do so would imply that major relianceis placedon differencesin factor shares in explainingurbanization. The rate of urbanization may indeed be affectedby urban-rural differencesin elasticityof output as well as by changes in elasticitiesin particular countries. There are no compellingstudiesthat indicatesystematicdifferences and changes in factor shares, and the shares do seem in fact to be fairlystable. The formulaforelasticity of output followedhere thereforeseemsappropriatefor an overviewof major factors that explainrate of urbanization. Givenobservedvalues of e, equations2-3 and2-4 can be used in connection with measurementsof income growth YandpopulationgrowthNto obtainestimatesof the growth of nonlaborinfluences,A.Wheneither equation 2-3 or equation2-4 is solvedforA,Ais foundto be Y minus eN. The estimate of growth of nonlaborsources of income in a sector is the observedincomegrowthless that part of income growth attributableto labor, which in turn is equalto labor'selasticityof output multiplied by the population growth of the sector. An essential feature of the model is that labor will adjust to keep the relativeearnings of urban and rural employment in line. To incorporate this feature, the condition pertaining to the elasticityof output derived (2-5) and Wu = Pu + Yu - - (2-7) Nu = - Na. This conditionhas the strong empiricalimplicationthatthe excessof the rate of income growth over the rate of employmentgrowth will be the same in urban and in nonurban areas. Put anotherway,averagelabor productivity will change by the same proportion in both sectors. Income produced in the two sectors may change by greatly differentamounts-that is, Yu,and Ya,may be very different. The differentialchanges in income produced are a result of differencesin growth of nonlabor sources of income,which lead to correspondingdifferences in growth of demand for labor. For example,if nonlabor sources of incomegrowth increasemore rapidly in urban than in rural areas, the demand for labor will increase more in urban than in rural areas. The increasein nonlabor sources of incomeand the associated increasein labor inputs willraise incomeby 1, and employment by some lesser amount, N . Meanwhile, because of the slower growth of nonlabor income sources in rural production, Ykwill be smaller than Yk and NQwill be correspondinglysmaller than N&(owing to a lessergrowth in demandfor labor in rural areas).If factor shares and relative wages and prices are not to change, the rise in ratio of incometo employmentmust be the same in the two sectors. How well does the condition stated in equation 2-7, that averagelabor productivitywill change bythe same 24 GeorgeS. Tolley proportion in urban and rural employment,fitthe facts? For sixty-six low- and middle-income economies for which the requisite income and populationfigures are availableto study growthrates for 1960-80,the mean of the excessof the proportionatechange in averageurban labor productivity over average rural productivity is - 0.0001.The standard error of this mean is 0.0029.In these comparisonsreal nonagriculturaland agricultural incomes are used as surrogates for urban and rural incomes. It is assumed that employment is roughly proportional to population, so that urban and rural populations can be used as surrogates for employment. Alternatively, still with nonagricultural and agricultural incomes as surrogates for urban and rural incomes, the labor force in agriculture can be used as a surrogatefor rural employmentand the nonagricultural labor force as a surrogate for urban employment.Or, more simply,the comparisonmay be viewedas an application of the model to agriculturalversus nonagricultural employmentrather than to urban versus rural employment.If agricultural and nonagricultural labor forces are used, rather than rural and urban populations, the mean of the excess of the proportionate change in average nonagricultural labor productivity over that of averageagricultural productivityis 0.0024 and the standard error is 0.0029. To further test the extent to which equation 2-7 is satisfied, if the error attributable to the fact that observedchanges in averageproductivitydo not exactly fulfill the equation is small, most of the observed changes in output and employmentwill be explainedby the model.The smallsizeof the error in relation to total income or employmentchange is an indication of the extent to which the hypothesisof equal proportionate changes ih average labor productivityis fulfilled. An error-of-fitmeasure, calculatedfor eacheconomy, is the proportionate annual change in average labor productivityas a fractionof the mean of annual proportionate urban and rural populationgrowth.The median of the error-of-fitmeasuresover all sixty-sixeconomies is 0.030. Two-thirds of the measures fall between - 0.735 and 0.826. When nonagricultural and agricultural labor forcesare used insteadof urban and rural populations, the median error-of-fit measure for the sixty-sixeconomiesis 0.067. Two-thirdsof these measures fall between - 0.981 and 0.828. The fact that most of the error-of-fit measures are substantially less than 1 indicates that most of the observedvariation in output and employmentis associated with growth of nonlabor income sources and the hypothesizedproportionate changes in labor and that relativelylittle change is left to be explainedbyerrors or departuresfrom the hypothesesof the model. The existence of nonzero error of fit may be partly a result of errors or differencesin the wayvariablesare calculated from availabledata. The uncertainty of output and employment figures is well known, and the reasons for differingchanges in measured employmentand output connectedwith changingmarket orientation ofproduction during developmenthave often been discussed.In general,more production maypassthrough the marketplaceas economicdevelopmentproceedsover a twentyyear period,but becauseof lagsin data collection,statistics may capture these changes only imperfectly. Nonzeroerror of fit may alsooccur becauseassumptions of the model that are justifiedas first approximation maynot be exactlyfulfilled.Butthe smallsize ofthe errors suggests that the principal factors are indeed capturedbythe model. In viewofall the possiblereasons for existenceof error, it is fair to say that the data fit the model well. It was specifiedthat growth in output can be represented as the sum of labor and nonlabor effectsin each sector in equations 2-3 and 2-4. Condition 2-7 (for changes in employmentrelativeto output in eachsector as migration occurs in response to changes in demand) was then derived.The model is completedby using the condition discussed above-that the total amount of labor used in the economy is the sum of urban and nonurban labor, or N = N11 + N,. The equation is differentiatedwith respect to time and dividedby the original valuesof the variables.The annual proportionate rate of growth of the total populationis expressedas the product of the urban share of populationand annual proportionate rate of growth of the urban population, plus the product of the nonurban share and the annual proportionate rate of growth of the nonurban population; that is, 2-8' N FN FN ( u a aThe four-equationmodel given by formulas2-3, 2-4, 2-7, and 2-8 determines the four rates of growth that pertain to outpyt and employmentin the two sectors, that is, Y, Ya,N, and NA. To solvefor the variable of interest-urban populationgrowth,Nu-equations2-3 and 2-4 are substituted into equation 2-7 to eliminate the Ys.The result is a relation betweenN1u and N1 that depends on the rates of growth of nonlabor sources of incomein the two sectors.Therelation can bewrittenNa = N11 + (A,, - A,,) / (1 - E), indicating that urban and rural populations move proportionatelyexcept as they are influencedby differentialchanges in growth of nonlabor sources of income, which havea multiplier effect of 1 / (1 - e) because under the model enough labor must be hired to drive the return to labor down to the same level in each sector. The result for Na is inserted into condition 2-8 for total employmentand the equation is solvedfor Nk: Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment (F. (2-9) N11 + 0 1 -Ael F. _ - ela - ThesolutionofthemodelforN 11 givenbyequation2-9 therateofgrowthof providesthe basisfordecomposing the urbanpopulationintothreefactors.Thefirstis total populationgrowthofthenation,N, whichhasa proportionate effecton urbanpopulationgrowth.Thesecondis an urban productivityfactor that stems from growth of nonlabor sources of urban production. The positive effectof increasesin nonlabor sourcesof urban production is enhanced by the multiplier 1 / (1 - e) that is connectedwith keepingearnings growththe same in the two sectors, and the magnitude of the effect is also proportionalto the fractionof the populationin agriculture. Agivenchangein the absolutelevelof employment as labor is reallocatedwill have a greater proportionate effect on urban population the smaller is the existing fractionof the populationthat is urban (which is to say, the larger the fraction that is nonurban). The third factor into which urban population growth is decomposed is a rural productivityfactor which stems from growthof nonlaborsourcesof rural income.It is exactly analogousto the urban productivityfactor,but it actson urban populationgrowth with a negativesign, since in this model a rise in rural productivityincreases rural population. Application the Sample to Appicafton to the Sample Measuresof the rate of population growth N to be appliedto equation2-9 are readilyavailable.Thefraction of the population that is not urban, Fa, is availablefor many countries but may be subject to more error than total population.Systematicmeasuresof labor'selasticity of output F that are comparableamong sectors and nations are apparently not available,but impressions about general orders of magnitude can be obtained. Althoughthe growth in nonlaborsourcesof income(the As)cannot be directlyobserved,first-cutmeasurements can be obtainedwith the use of equations 2-3 and 2-4. That is, when either equation is solvedforA, the contribution of growth in nonlabor sources of income to observedincome growthis equalto the observedincome growth Y minus the product of elasticityof output of labor F and the growth rate of labor N. (That is, the nonlabor source of income growth is total income growth minus the contribution of labor to income growth.) The calculationsjust describedgiveonly first-cutor, at most, suggestive measurements of the As because they ignore the stipulation of the model that average labor productivityrises at the same rate of growth in both sectors. The measures are dependent on the esti- 25 matesof growthof urbanand ruralincome,whichmay be subject to great measurement errors and possible in definition.Tominimizethe effectsof inconsistencies measurementproblems,the procedureusedhere is to averagethe changesin incomein the two sectorsand thus obtainincomemeasuresthat conformto the productivitycondition.Specifically, the averageexcessof the rate of growthof income in eachsector overthe rate of populationgrowth in each sectoryieldsan estimate of the common risein averagelabor productivityin the two sectors. This estimate made on the basisofthe observed averagefor the two sectors can be added to population growth in each sector to obtain the measuresof income growth in the sectors that would prevail if the model fitted the real situation precisely.After this attempt to purge the income measurementsof error and to eliminate the effectsthose errors would spuriouslyintroduce into estimates of the factors that affect urbanization, estimates of the As may be obtained as before by subtracting the product of labor elasticityof output and the amount of labor from the incomevaluesthat conformto the averagelabor productivitycondition. Table2-2 presentsthe results obtainedwhenthe model is appliedto sixty-sixlow- and middle-incomeeconomies, using urban populationstatisticsfrom the World Bankand an estimateof labor'sshare Fof 0.7. Column1, the annual proportionategrowth of urban populationin each economyfrom 1960to 1980,is the variable to be explained. Column 2 is the average fraction of the populationthat is urban for 1960-80. This fractionwas calculatedto conformto equation2-8, whichrelatesthe rates of urban and rural populationgrowthto the rate of growth of the total population. The fraction of the populationthat is rural, F,, is 1 - F,,. Arrangementof equation2-8 as an expressionforF givesas the fraction of the populationthat is urban F, = (N - Na) I (Nu 1 Na), the ratio between the excessof total population growthover nonurban populationgrowthand the excess of urban over nonurban populationgrowth. This measure is quite closeto the simple averageof the 1960and 1980 values for the fraction of the population that is urban, and in all cases it lies betweenthose values.The methodjust describedfor calculatingF 1 1 in conformance with equation 2-8, along with the method described above for calculating the growth of nonlabor income sourcesA to conformto equations2-3 and 2-4, ensures an internallyconsistent system of accounting in which the factorsthat explainurban populationgrowth exactly add up to urban population growth. Although other procedures for defining variables might have given about the same results, the proceduresused here have the advantageofeliminatingidiosyncraciesin definition as a perceivedreasonfor differencesin rate of urbanization. The analyticfactorsthat explainurban population 26 GeorgeS. Tolley Table 2-2. UrbanPopulation Change,Sixty-six Economies, 1960-80 Economy Annual proportionate change in urban population, Nu (1) Anmualpro- Annual proportionate portionate Urban growth in growth in share urban nonnonurban of populalabor nonlabor tion, 1980, sources of sources of Fu income, Au income, A,, (2) (3) (4) Componentsof change in urban population Annualpro- Urbanproportionate ductivity changein factory total popuF,A&I lation,N (1 - e) (5) (6) Nonurban productivity factor, Error of fit, -FaAal (Au - A,)! (I- E) '/2 (u +X N) (7) (8) Bangladesh Ethiopia Mali Somalia Chad Burma BurkinaFaso India 0.066 0.070 0.054 0.052 0.067 0.039 0.045 0.032 0.076 0.099 0.151 0.231 0.118 0.228 0.068 0.199 0.006 0.016 0.016 -0.025 -0.010 0.019 -0.001 0.019 - 0.007 0.001 0.005 - 0.036 -0.026 0.012 -0.010 0.015 0.027 0.024 0.024 0.024 0.020 0.022 0.016 0.022 0.017 0.048 0.045 -0.065 -0.030 0.048 -0.002 0.051 0.022 -0.002 -0.015 0.093 0.077 -0.030 0.032 -0.041 - 0.413 -0.171 0.196 1.527 -1.101 - 1.193 0.828 0.567 Malawi Rwanda 0.070 0.062 0.062 0.029 0.028 0.018 0.016 0.007 0.029 0.027 0.089 0.059 - 0.049 - 0.024 - 0.249 - 0.096 Sri Lanka Guinea Zaire Niger Benin Pakistan Tanzania Central AfricanRepublic Haiti Mauritania Lesotho Uganda Sudan Togo 0.041 0.061 0.060 0.070 0.044 0.041 0.072 0.051 0.055 0.128 0.067 0.223 0.141 0.242 0.091 0.119 0.249 0.080 0.315 0.247 0.102 0.033 0.019 0.013 - 0.006 -0.001 0.007 0.030 0.023 0.007 0.004 0.009 0.039 0.012 0.002 -0.021 - 0.014 0.001 0.025 0.009 -0.005 -0.012 - 0.025 0.025 0.021 0.029 0.023 0.031 0.027 0.029 0.028 0.022 0.016 0.026 0.021 0.050 0.038 - 0.016 -0.003 0.021 0.074 0.070 0.017 0.009 0.026 0.126 -0.030 -0.006 0.053 0.042 -0.004 -0.062 - 0.026 0.012 0.030 0.076 - 0.080 -0.315 -0.190 -0.176 -0.554 0.633 0.442 0.004 - 0.747 - 1.060 - 0.313 0.969 0.077 0.080 0.006 - 0.008 0.034 0.018 0.026 - 0.724 0.070 0.053 0.166 0.132 0.003 0.034 - 0.013 0.025 0.024 0.026 0.009 0.098 0.037 - 0.071 -0.027 0.671 Kenya 0.070 0.101 0.017 0.005 0.035 0.051 - 0.016 - 0.246 Senegal Indonesia Egypt Ghana Honduras 0.029 0.035 0.031 0.049 0.054 0.240 0.174 0.415 0.292 0.292 0.010 0.037 0.037 -0.001 0.017 0.008 0.031 0.033 -0.011 0.007 0.025 0.101 0.073 -0.002 0.040 - 0.021 -0.087 -0.065 0.025 - 0.017 - 0.538 0.826 1.046 -0.735 -0OA73 - 1.449 0.025 0.020 0.022 0.026 0.032 Zambia 0.054 0.301 0.019 0.008 0.029 0.045 - 0.020 Thailand 0.033 0.135 0.046 0.045 0.029 0.133 -0.129 Bolivia 0.042 0.284 0.025 0.018 0.026 0.059 - 0.043 - 0.030 Philippines Congo Nigeria El Salvador Morocco Peru Cote d'lvoire Nicaragua Colombia Paraguay DominicanRepublic Guatemala SyrianArab Republic Malaysia Jamaica Korea,Republicof 0.038 0.028 0.047 0.036 0.044 0.047 0.080 0.043 0.045 0.031 0.055 0.037 0.047 0.036 0.034 0.056 0.330 0.350 0.163 0.395 0.348 0.567 0.278 0.470 0.593 0.375 0.402 0.360 0.434 0.270 0.419 0.410 0.032 0.004 0.024 0.022 0.021 0.027 0.032 0.041 0.040 0.034 0.032 0.035 0.048 0.042 0.015 0.064 0.028 0.001 0.016 0.020 0.013 0.014 0.018 0.034 0.026 0.032 0.019 0.031 0.040 0.039 0.005 0.047 0.029 0.023 0.025 0.033 0.027 0.028 0.045 0.031 0.026 0.027 0.029 0.028 0.032 0.028 0.015 0.022 0.071 0.008 0.066 0.043 0.045 0.039 0.077 0.073 0.054 0.071 0.064 0.075 0.091 0.103 0.029 0.125 - 0.062 - 0.002 - 0.045 -0.040 - 0.028 -0.020 -0.042 - 0.060 -0.035 - 0.067 - 0.037 - 0.066 -0.076 - 0.095 - 0.010 -0.092 0.009 1.138 1.500 0.495 0.260 -0.149 0.009 -0.494 - 1.148 0.077 0.044 - 0.057 -0.384 0.652 -1.283 0.334 1.101 Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment 27 Table 2-2 (continued) Economy Annual proportionate change in urban population, N,, (1) Annual pro- Annualproportionate portionate Urban growth in growth in share urban non- nonurban of populalabor nonlabor tion, 1980, sources of sourcesof F,, income,A. incomne, A. (2) (3) (4) Componentsof change in urban population Annualpro- Urbanproportionate ductivity change in factor, total popuFaA]u lation,N (1 - e) Nonurban productivity factor, Error of fit, - FaAal (Au- a,)/ (1 - e) 1N2 W +a) (5) (6) 0.025 0.030 0.075 0.004 -0.053 0.031 0.301 - 0.195 0.033 0.030 0.024 0.019 0.030 0.028 0.008 0.014 0.003 0.010 0.039 0.060 0.061 0.022 0.067 0.062 0.009 0.021 0.070 0.091 -0.025 -0.046 -0.046 -0.014 -0.059 - 0.045 -0.007 -0.016 -0.055 - 0.071 0.122 0.012 1.408 -2.719 0.276 0.260 -5.082 -0.914 5.940 0.430 - 1.436 (7) Turkey Algeria 0.047 0.065 0.383 0.452 0.036 0.002 0.026 - 0.017 Mexico Panama Taiwan Chile CostaRica Brazil Uruguay Argentina Portugal Yugoslavia 0.046 0.044 0.038 0.028 0.038 0.046 0.010 0.019 0.018 0.030 0.592 0.475 0.680 0.749 0.400 0.556 0.821 0.782 0.269 0.348 0.029 0.034 0.057 0.027 0.033 0.042 0.016 0.029 0.029 0.042 0.018 0.026 0.044 0.016 0.039 0.030 0.011 0.022 0.023 0.033 Venezuela 0.044 0.756 0.042 0.029 0.034 0.035 - 0.024 HongKong 0.023 0.895 0.044 0.042 Greece 0.024 0.526 0.054 0.042 Spain 0.024 0.658 0.048 0.037 Israel 0.039 0.836 0.050 0.037 Note:Economies arelistedin increasing orderof1978percapitaincome. 0.023 0.015 -0.015 0.006 0.085 -0.066 0.011 0.055 -0.042 0.031 0.027 - 0.020 growthin fact add up exactlyto measuredurban population growth. Columns 3 and 4 present measures of the average annual rate of growth of the sourcesof nonlabor urban and nonurban income A, with the use of the purged income values, as describedabove. The key columns are 5, 6, and 7. They show the decomposition of the annual proportionate urban population growth given in column 1 into the three terms in equation 2-9. Thus, column 5 is the annual proportionate overall population growth of the economy, which makes a direct and equal contribution to urban population growth. Column 6 is the urban productivityfactor,whichgivesthe effectofnonlaborurban income source growth on the rate of urban population growth.Column 6 is column 3 multipliedby the nonurban fractionof the population(calculablefrom the table as 1 minus the urban fraction in column 2) and divided bythe share of incomethat accruesto factorsof production other than labor, 1 - e (in this case, 1 - 0.7, or 0.3). Column 7, the nonurban productivityfactor, is calculatedfrom column4 in the sameway as the urban productivityfactor is calculatedfrom column 3, except that the sign is changed, since nonurban productivity acts in the oppositedirectionfromurban productivityas an influence on the rate of urbanization. (8) 2.877 -0.601 0.894 - 0.642 Column 8 presents the error-of-fitmeasure for each economy.As discussedearlier, that measure is the differencebetweenurban and nonurbanaverageproductivity change (basedon observedincome) dividedby the averageemploymentchange in the two sectors. A positive sign indicatesa greater urban than nonurban average increasein labor productivity,using observedmeasures of income;a negativesign indicatesthe reverse.A value of less than one in absolute terms indicates that relativelymore of the employmentchanges are associated with the factorsexplainedby the model than with failureto satisfyexactlythe proportionateproductivity condition.The effectof the error is smallerthe closeris the value to zero. Column 5, proportionate total population growth, shows, as expected, that total population growth accounts for a rate of urbanizationthat is generallyon the order of 2 percent a year (0.020,as a decimalfraction, as expressedin the table). It rangesup to 3 percent in some casesand for certain economies,such as Yugoslavia, is very low. The direct effects of population growththus cannot account for the high ratesof urbanization-up to 7 percent-which are found in the table. Populationgrowth could alsocause pressure on limited agriculturallandsuppliesand forcegrowingnumbersof peopleto seek work in urban areas.This effectwould be 28 GeorgeS. Tolley manifested in a resource scarcity situation in which suppliesof nonlaborresources were more expansiblein urban than in rural areas. If nonlaborresourceswere as scarce in urban as in rural areas, in the sense of having an elasticity of supply that is zero or equally small, nonlabor inputs would tend to increaseby similar relative amounts in both rural and urban areas and there would be little impetusto urbanization.In a situation in which limited supplies of land providedthe major impetus to urbanization,one would expectto see limited increasesin nonlaborsourcesof income growthin rural areas, coupledwith larger increases in labor inputs in urban areas as the supply of urban sites with associated infrastructure and other urban facilities expanded to accommodatepeopledisplacedfrom agriculture. These endogenous increases in urban nonlabor inputs would be greater than the increases in agricultural nonlabor inputs, but if the only important impetus to urbanization were displacement of agricultural labor, the increases in urban nonlabor inputs still might not be great, since in this depictionof the world more vigorous positive impetuses to economic developmentare lacking. One might suppose that economieswith less than 1 percent a year growth in agricultural nonlabor inputs may have a land scarcitysituation. In table 2-2 twentyfiveof the sixty-sixeconomieshave growth of nonlabor sourcesof nonurban income ofless than 1 percent a year (or, as a decimalfraction,0.010)as indicatedin column 4. Of these, ten experiencednegativerates of change in nonlabor sources of income,which indicatesretrogression and other specialfactorsnot explainedby the usual land scarcitysituation. Note that land scarcity doesnot implynegative growth of nonlabor sources of income but rather no growth or a very small increase. The economieswith low and negative growth for nonlabor sources of nonurban income tend to be among those with the lowest incomes, as indicated by their early appearancein the table. (Economiesare ranked by 1978 per capita income.)It is also true that these economies generally have high urbanization rates. In the five lowest-incomeeconomies (Bangladesh,Ethiopia, Mali, Somalia,and Chad)rates of changefor nonlaborsources of rural income are negative or less than 1 percent a year. Each had a rate of growth of urban populationof over 5 percent a year (0.050, as a decimal). Of the twenty-fiveeconomieswith low or negative growth of nonlaborsourcesof rural income,only three-Senegal, CongoandJamaica-had an urbanpopulationgrowthof less than 4 percent a year. Bycontrast, in only twentyof the forty-one economies where growth of nonlabor sourcesof rural incomewasgreater than 1 percentwere annual rates of urban population growth more than 4 percent. The apparent tendencyfor high rates of urbanization to be associatedwith low rates of growth of nonlabor rural income sources does not prove that land scarcity has been a highly important reason for rapid urbanization. Amore likelyexplanationof the findingmaybe the general sluggishness of agriculture in the twenty-five economiesand a general failure to advanceknowledge or introduce new techniques-in short, a failureof nonland conventional and nonconventional inputs to increase, even though land supply may havebeen elastic. Lackof inputsother than landmayhaveactedto depress the marginal productivity of labor and hence the demand forlabor in rural areas. Ifso, it is a lackof effective economic developmentin agriculture and not a lack of land.that helpedto fosterhigh urbanizationratesamong the countries that experiencedlow rates of growth of nonlabor rural income sources. The interpretation of eventsin terms ofa more general economic developmentperspectivethat goes beyond preoccupation with the role of agricultural land is strengthened by consideringadditionalresults in table 2-2. One of the striking relations in the table is the positiveassociationbetween growth rates of urban and rural nonlaborsourcesof income,as revealedbylooking down columns 3 and 4. The two series have a simple correlation coefficient(R2) of 0.964. Tworeasons may be noted for the positiveassociation.First, the nonlabor incomesourcesincludecapital,which is mobilebetween sectors. Increasesin the capitalstockof an economywill tend to be allocatedamong sectors so as to equalizethe marginal returns to capital and impart changes in the same direction to nonlabor income sources in the different sectors. Second,and perhapsmore important, the nonlaborincomesourcesreflectmore generaleconomic developmentchanges, in addition to conventionalinputs, that act to increasethe productivityof the conventional inputs. There is some tendencyfor the effectsof economicdevelopmentchanges to be pervasive;for example, the influenceof research, infrastructure, incentivestructures, and institutionstends to be felt throughout an economy.Just as there is a tendencyto equalize returns to conventionalinputs among sectors, there is some tendencyto equalize returns to deeper economic developmentefforts, even though the latter tendency maybe less perfect.The fact that the economiesin table 2-2 which have low rates of growth of nonlabor rural income sourcesalso tend to havelow rates of growthof nonlabor urban income sources suggests that general economic developmentdifferences,and not primarily agriculturalland, are at work in explainingthose economies' high rates of urbanization. An ancillaryfindingin table 2-2 is that the growthin nonlabor sources of income tends to rise with the per capitaincome ofthe economy(whichis to say, it risesas one looks down the table). The simple R2 betweenthe income rank of an economy(asindicatedby its order in Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment the table)andthe urban nonlaborincomesourcegrowth rate in column3 is 0.658.The simpleR2 betweenincome rank and the rural nonlabor incomesource growthrate in column 4 is 0.642. The findingreflectsthe tendency among these economiesfor the more affluent among them to gain in relation to the less affluent. To return to factors that affect the rate of urbanization, it is noteworthythat when columns3 and 4 oftable 2-2 are compared,for every one of the sixty-sixeconomies the growth rate of urban nonlabor income sources is greater than that for rural nonlabor income sources.This findingis consistentwith the hypothesis noted earlier, that the techniques of urban production are easier to transfer among economiesthan those of agricultural production. Since an excessof urban over rural nonlabor income source growth acts to foster urbanizationin this model,the rate of urban population growth is greater than the rate of overall population growth for every one of the sixty-sixeconomies. A final considerationin interpreting table 2-2 is the role of the fraction of the populationwhich is urban. If this fraction is small, any differentialchange between urban and rural nonlabor income source growth has a magnifiedeffecton urban population.The reasonis that a given absolute change has a greater percentage effect on a smallnumber than on a largenumber. Thiseffectis reflectedin equation 2-9, in which the coefficientFa / (1 - e) multiplies the growth rate of nonlabor income source to arrive at the urban and rural productivity factors.Thus,economieswith large nonurban fractions in their populations tend to have greater urbanization rates. Since these economies generally have low per capita incomes, they are the ones that have predominantly experiencedthe highest urbanizationrates. Progressing down the table to increasinglyhigherincome economies, one finds that the difference between urban and rural nonlabor income sourcegrowth stays about the same or becomes larger, but the contributions of the urban and rural productivityfactors decreasebecauseof the decliningvalueof the multiplier Fa I (1 - E). SinceFa = 1 - Fu, the multiplierwill be greater than one if the fractionof the populationthat is urban is greater than the share of incomethat accruesto labor. The condition would be fulfilled for all but a handful of the economies,regardlessof the value of e, but the multiplier falls more and more toward one toward the bottom of the table. The rates of growth of urban population decline until they are not much greater than the rate of overallpopulationgrowth.This is shownin equation2-9, which givesan analyticexplanation for the descriptivefindingof the associationbetween the fraction that is urban and the growth rate of urban population. The analysispresented here of factors that affecturbanization was carried out for three other cases: a 29 population analysis in which labor share, E, is 0.5 instead of 0.7;and two labor forceanalysesthat use nonagricultural labor force as a surrogate for urban labor force,with e at 0.7 in one caseand 0.5 in the other. The results were essentiallysimilar to those presentedhere. The existence of many variations from the general patterns that havebeen discussedindicatesthat conditions in individual economies-playa part in urbanization. India and Burmaare among the economieswhich stand out particularlyas exceptionsto some of the patterns in table 2-2. Both rank low in per capita income and havehigh nonurban proportionsof population,yet unlike most other economieswith these characteristics theyhaverelativelylowurbanizationrates. Growthrates of urban and rural nonlabor incomesources are largely offsettingin these two countries. The size of the Indian economymight influencethe result, but this consideration would not apply to Burma. India and Burma are only two examplesthat indicate the usefulnessof more analyticwork for understanding patterns of urbanization.For any one of the economies, more detailedanalysiscould be undertaken, with more refined identificationof the factorsthat affecturbanization as an object. Further comparativeanalytic work to contrast and understand differences among regions and different types of economiesis recommendedto strengthen the knowledgebasefor predictionandpolicyconcernedwith economicdevelopment.Further workshould giveattention to differencesin industrialstructure and to considerations that affect trade. Greater detail on types of goods could be included, as could allowancefor price effects, age composition, education, dependency,and other considerationsbearingon workparticipation.The assumption that the number of workers in urban areas goes hand in hand with the population of these areas would be modified. Conclusion This chapter suggests that the degree to which a country succeeds in fosteringgrowth of urban productivity is likelyto be the major determinant of its urbanization. Populationgrowthwill continue to be a source of both urban and nonurban growth.Countriesthat lag in growth of agricultural productivitywill experience added urbanization pressures. As important as these general findingsis the usefulness of the frameworkof this chapter as a basis for quantifyingthe experienceof individualcountries.Prediction and planning are enhanced, and the economic factors that influencethe effectivenessof policiesconcerned with urbanization can be better understood. 30 GeorgeS. Tolley Bibliography Developmentand CulturalChange,vol. 3, no. 1 (October), pp. 4-5. Armstrong,Harvey,and Jim Taylor.1978.RegionalEconomic Policy and Its Analysis. Deddington,Oxford,U.K.: Philip Allan. Arriaga,Edward.1970. "ANewApproachto the Measurement of Urbanization."Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 18, no. 2 (January), pp. 206-18. Berry,BrianJ. L. 1961."CitySizeDistributionsand Economic Development." Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 9, no. 4, pt. 1 (July),pp. 573-88. Bourne,L. S., and J. W.Simmons,eds. 1978.Systems of Cities: Readings on Structure, Growth, and Policy. New York: OxfordUniversityPress. Breese, Gerald. 1966. Urbanization in Newly Developing Countries.EnglewoodCliffs,N.J.:Prentice-Hall. Chapin, Stuart F., Jr. 1971. "Selected Theories of Urban GrowthandStructure." In L. S.Bourne,ed.,InternalStructure of the City:Readingson Spaceand Environment. New York:OxfordUniversityPress. Colosio,Donaldo.1979.UrbanizationandEconomicDevelopment in Mexico. WorkingPaper79-19.Laxenburg,Austria: International Institute for AppliedSystemsAnalysis. Currie, L. 1975. "The Interrelation of Urban and National EconomicPlanning." UrbanStudies, vol. 12, no. 1 (February), pp. 37-46. Davis,Kingsley.1965."The Urbanizationof the Human Population." ScientificAmerican, vol. 213 (September),pp. 28, 40. - 1971."The Roleof Urbanizationin the Development Process." In RaananWeitz, ed., Urbanizationand the Developing Countries.Report on the Sixth Rehovot Conference. Praeger Special Studies in International Economics and Development.NewYork: Praeger. Felstehausen,H. 1971."PlanningProblemsin ImprovingColombianRoads and Highways."Land Economics, vol. 47, no. 1 (February),pp. 1-13. Friedmann,J., and C. Weaver.1979.Territoryand Function. Universityof CalifomiaPress. Hansen,NilesM. 1969."RegionalDevelopmentand the Rural Poor."JournalofHuman Resources,vol.4, no. 2 (Spring), pp. 205-14. Hansen, NilesM., ed. 1976. PublicPolicy and RegionalEconomicDevelopment.TheExperienceofNine WesternCountries. Cambridge,Mass.:Ballinger. Harberger, C. 1970. "Economic Policy Problems in Latin America:A Review."Journal of PoliticalEconomy,vol. 78, no. 4, pt. 2 (January-August),pp. 1007-16. Henderson,J. V. 1980. "AFrameworkfor International Comparisons of Systemsof Cities."Urban and RegionalReport 80-3, World Bank, Washington,D.C. Processed. Holleb, D. B. 1976. "Mao's Legacyfor RevolutionaryUrban Development."WorkingPaper.Universityof Chicago,Center for Urban Studies. December. Hoselitz, Bert. 1954. "Introduction; The Role of Cities in EconomicDevelopmentand CulturalChange."Economic . 1957. "Urbanizationand EconomicGrowthin Asia." Economic Developmentand CulturalChange,vol. 6, no. 1 (October),pp. 42-54. Kelley,Allen C., and JeffreyG. Williamson,1979.Modeling UrbanizationandEconomic Growth.WorkingPaper79-81, Laxenburg,Austria:International Institute for AppliedSystems Analysis.September. Lasvwn,J. R. 1973. "Urbanization and Development-The Temporal Interaction BetweenGeographicaland Sectoral Cluster." UrbanStudies, vol. 10, no. 2 (June), pp. 163-88. Linn,J. F. 1979."AutomotiveTaxationin the CitiesofDeveloping Countries." Nagarlok(January). Lipton,Michael.1977.WhyPoorPeopleStay Poor:UrbanBias in World Development. Cambridge,Mass.: Harvard University Press. Miller, J. C. 1979. "RegionalDevelopment:A Reviewof the State of the Art." AID20523. Agencyfor InternationalDevelopment, Washington,D.C.Processed. Mills,Edwin. 1971. "CitySizesin DevelopingEconomies."In RaananWeitz,ed., Urbanizationand the DevelopingCountries. Report on the Sixth Rehovot Conference. Praeger Special Studies in International Economicsand Development. NewYork:Praeger. . 1972.'WelfareAspectsof NationalPolicytowardCity _ Sizes."UrbanStudies, vol. 9, no. 1 (February),pp. 117-24. Pascal, AnthonyH. 1971. "Urban Growth and Development: Discussion."American Economic Review, vol. 61, no. 2 (May),pp. 357-59. Renaud, Bertrand. 1981. National UrbanizationPoliciesin DevelopingCountries.NewYork:OxfordUniversityPress. Reynolds,L. G. 1975."Chinaas a Less DevelopedEconomy." AmericanEconomicReview,vol. 65, no. 3 (June),pp. 41828. Richardson,Harry W. 1977. City Size and National Spatial Strategiesin DevelopingCountries.WorldBankStaffWorking Paper 252. Washington,D.C. Rondinelly,DennisA., and Kenneth Ruddle.1978.Urbanization and RuralDevelopment:A SpatialPolicyfor Equitable Growth.NewYork:Praeger. Tolley, GeorgeS. 1974. "The WelfareEconomicsof CityBigness."Journalof UrbanEconomics,vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 32445. Tolley,G. S., and G.D. Gwyer.1967. "Intemational Trade in Agricultural Products in Relation to EconomicDevelopment." In Herman M. Southworthand BruceF. Johnston, eds., Agricultural Development and Economic Growth. NewYork:CornellUniversityPress. Pp. 403-47. Tolley,G. S., and G. K. Kripalani. 1974. "Stagesof Development and Urbanization."In A. A.Brown,J. A. Licori,and E. Neuberger,eds., Urbanand SocialEconomicsin Market and Planned Economies. NewYork:Praeger. Tolley,G.S., and S. Smidt. 1964."Agricultureand the Secular Positionofthe U.S.Economy."Econometrica,vol. 32, no.4 (October),pp. 554-75. Urbanizationand EconomicDevelopment Tolley,G. S., and Barton Smith. 1975."SocialCostsand the Rural-UrbanBalance."In Earl 0. Headyand LarryR. Whiting, eds., Externalities in the Transformationof Agriculture: Distributionof Benefitsand Costsfrom Development. Ames, Iowa:Iowa State UniversityPress. Tolley,GeorgeS., PhilipE. Graves,and John L. Gardner,eds. 1979. Urban Growth Policy in a Market Economy. New York:AcademicPress. Tolley,G. S., R. J. Krumm, and P. Graves."Designof Incen- 31 tives for Spatial Intervention for DevelopingCountries." WorkingPaper. Chicago:Universityof Chicago. Townroe,Peter M. 1979.EmploymentDecentralizationPolicy Instruments for Large Cities in LessDevelopedCountries. Vol. 10, pt. 2, in D. R. Diamondand J. McLoughlin, eds., Progressin Planning. Elmsford,N.Y.:Pergamon. Wheaton, W. C., and H. Shishido. 1979. "UrbanConcentration, AgglomerationEconomies,and the Levelof Economic Development."Working Paper. Cambridge,Mass.:MIT.