Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107 – 127 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Family ownership and productivity: the role of owner-management Erling Barth, Trygve Gulbrandsen, Pål Schøne * Institute for Social Research, Pb. 3233 Elisenberg, 0208 Oslo, Norway Received 28 January 2003; accepted 13 February 2004 Available online 16 April 2004 Abstract This article analyses the relationship between family ownership and productivity, with special focus on the role of owner-management. The results show that family-owned firms are less productive than non-family-owned firms. This productivity gap is, however, explained by differences in management regime. Family-owned firms managed by a person hired outside the owner family are equally productive as non-family-owned firms, while family-owned firms managed by a person from the owner family are significantly less productive. This finding is sustained after controlling for endogeneity of management regime. D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: G32; G34 Keywords: Ownership structure; Management; Productivity 1. Introduction During the last two decades, ownership of firms has received increased attention among scholars as well as in the general public debate. Several researchers and observers have claimed that ownership matters and that the economic behaviour of enterprises is influenced by how property rights are allocated and by who their owners are (Blair, 1995; Schleifer and Vishny, 1997). But the issue is not settled. A summary of studies of the effect of ownership structure on firm performance is given by Demsetz and Villalonga (2001). This summary shows that empirical studies of the relation between ownership structure and performance have yielded conflicting results. * Corresponding author. Tel.: +47-23086182; fax: +47-23086101. E-mail address: psc@socialresearch.no (P. Schøne). 0929-1199/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2004.02.001 108 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 In this paper, we analyse how family ownership affects the performance of enterprises. In line with Palia and Lichtenberg (1999), we use total factor productivity (TFP) as our measure of corporate performance. We believe productivity is a more reliable measure of performance than financial measures, as for instance operating profits, because the accounting profit rates of an enterprise may be manipulated.1 In addition, as only a small percentage of our firms are listed, performance measures based on market prices are not possible. It is not necessarily the mode of ownership in itself that may affect the economic performance of a firm. Recent literature (Hart, 2001) has focused on the allocation of decision rights. Accordingly, we go on to investigate the importance of owner-management versus professional management. In many family businesses, the owner or a member of the owner family chooses to run the firm him/herself. On the one hand, ownermanagement provides a solution to the inherent agency problem involved in operating the business. On the other, it has been claimed that this combination of the roles of owner and top manager may have unfavourable consequences for the efficient operation of a firm. In order to examine the validity of this claim, we compare family businesses managed by a member of the owner family and family businesses where a professional manager is at the helm. In the empirical analyses presented below, we will distinguish accordingly between three types of firms: (i) family firms run by a member of the family, a mode of governance we choose to term ‘‘owner-management’’; (ii) family businesses where a professional manager is in charge of the day-to-day running of the firm; and (iii) non-family firms, which presumably are also run by a professional manager. We first compare the productivity of family-owned firms to the productivity of nonfamily firms. This analysis provides us with an estimated productivity gap between these two modes of ownership. We then control for management regime. Comparing the productivity gap between family- and non-family-owned firms, with and without this control, allows us to assess the extent to which this productivity gap is due to differences in the allocation of decision rights rather than to the difference in ownership structure per se. Furthermore, we obtain an estimate of the productivity gap between professionally and owner-managed family firms. Demsetz (1983) and Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) argue that ownership structure should be thought of as an endogenous outcome. In a study of management succession in family-controlled firms, Smith and Amoako-Adu (1999) found that the appointment of non-family successors tended to follow periods of poor operating performance, indicating that the management function is endogenous. Drawing on a recent theoretical analysis of family firms by Burkart et al. (2002), we develop a simple empirical choice model to account for the endogeneity of management regime. We extend their model by allowing for private benefits of day-to-day control and use years in family ownership, year of establishment, and preferences for family control as instruments for the choice between hiring a professional manager or leaving management to the heir. 1 Of course, measures of productivity also come with errors. Our argument is only that this type of measure is less exposed to manipulation errors than most financial measures. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 109 The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we briefly discuss theoretical issues and some previous empirical evidence. Section 3 presents the data and empirical strategy. We argue that one contribution from our study comes from the data. In contrast to many other studies in this field, we have access to a data set containing information for a representative sample of family firms. Section 4 provides the first analysis of the productivity gap between family- and non-family-owned firms. Section 5 gives the analysis of management regime. Conclusions are given in Section 6. 2. Theory and previous empirical studies Previous literature has argued both in favour of and against the claim that concentrated family ownership as well as owner-management may have beneficial economic consequences. Theoretically, there are reasons to expect that firms where ownership is concentrated in the hands of a family will be more efficient than other firms. Firstly, concentrated ownership gives the owners a particular incentive to monitor the managers, thus reducing agency costs connected to hired management (Schleifer and Vishny, 1997). Concentrated ownership may as well ease the task of monitoring. Anderson et al. (2003) argue that founding families, representing a form of undiversified ownership, may mitigate the risk-shifting problem between shareholders and bondholders (Jensen and Meckling, 1976) as the founding families are more interested in firm survival than are other types of shareholders. Consequently, family firms may face a lower cost of debt financing. Furthermore, the relations within a family are largely characterized by altruism, loyalty, and trust. Pollack (1985) and Coleman (1990) have emphasized that in a family business, these qualities may promote flexibility in operations, ease decision-making and reduce shirking, all of which may have favourable effects upon the productivity of the firm. There are also reasons to believe that family-owned firms may be less efficient than non-family firms. Concentration of ownership implies a limited diversification of financial risk and a higher cost of capital due to higher risk premium (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985). This situation may induce family owners to be cautious when making new investments and reluctant to raise loans or to admit new investors (Agrawal and Nagarjan, 1990; Gallo and Vilaseca, 1996). This caution may limit the introduction of productivity-enhancing new technology. Inadequate investment in R&D and new technology has also been attributed to an alleged preference on the part of family owners for a continuous and stable cash flow in order to finance a privileged lifestyle (Chandler, 1990). This illustrates that concentrated ownership gives an owner opportunity to reap private benefits, which may be incompatible with the efficient operation of the firm. Pollack (1985) has maintained that the same qualities that promote mutual trust among owners may make them excessively tolerant towards lax efforts by family members working in the firm. As to the distinction between owner-management and professional management, owner-management aligns the interests of owners and managers, thus providing a solution to the agency problems connected with monitoring and motivating professional managers (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama and Jensen, 1983). 110 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 Owner-management may also have negative effects. In an owner-managed family business, the top manager is taken from a much more restricted pool of talent than when the manager is recruited from the general market for managers. According to Coleman (1990) and Burkart et al. (2002), this situation generally leads to a lower quality among owner– managers than among professional managers and may be detrimental to the productivity of the firms. In owner-managed family businesses, the middle managers know that they have few hopes of achieving top management positions in the firm. Limited career prospects may function as a disincentive to these middle managers with reduced efforts as a result. Owner – managers have a strong preference for control. Often, this preference may entail an inefficient concentration of decision-making authority in the hands of the ownermanager (Goffee and Scase, 1985; Hofer and Charan, 1984). Their control orientation may also prevent them from adopting new and productivity-enhancing management principles and personnel policies (Gulbrandsen, in press). Empirical studies comparing the performance of family-owned, owner-managed, and non-family-owned firms are rather sparse. Gorriz and Fumas (1996) have studied familyowned firms in Spain. They used both productivity and profitability as measures of firm performance. They found that on an average, family firms have higher productivity than non-family-owned firms, but they did not find any difference in profitability. In a study by McConaughy et al. (1998), founding family-controlled firms turned out to be more efficient and valuable than firms without founding family control. Anderson and Reeb (2003) find that family firms perform better than non-family firms, both as to return-on-assets, return on equity, and as measured by Tobin’s Q. Moreover, in family firms where a family member serves as chief executive officer (CEO), performance is better than in family firms with an outside CEO. Wall (1998) has analysed the impact of family ownership on productivity among private firms in Western New York. He found that family firms are less productive than non-family firms after controlling for industry, labour input, and firm age. The productive gap was estimated to be approximately 18%. Lauterbach and Vaninsky (1999) examined the extent to which performance in Israeli firms was influenced by type of ownership and by how the management function was organized. They distinguished between family firms, firms controlled by a partnership of individuals, firms controlled by a group of firms, and firms where blockholders had less than 50% of the votes. Across these modes of ownership, they then distinguished between firms managed by a representative of the owners and firms being led by a professional top manager. Their analyses demonstrate, firstly, that family businesses are less efficient than firms with another form of ownership. Secondly, firms managed by their owners perform worse than those run by a professional manager. Perez-Gonzalez (2001) has analysed the impact of inherited control on firm’s performance. He found that firms where control is inherited undergo a large decline in return-on-assets and market-to-book ratios compared to firms that promote a chief executive officer who is not related to the owner family. In a Canadian study (Morck et al., 1998), heir-controlled firms showed low industry-adjusted financial performance relative to other firms of same ages and sizes. Controlling for endogenous ownership, Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) found no statistically significant relationship between ownership structure and firm performance. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 111 3. Data, variables, and empirical strategy We use an establishment level survey conducted in 1996 among firms associated with the Confederation of Norwegian Business and Industry (NHO).2 The sample of establishments is representative for NHO firms with more than 10 employees, a net total of 438 firms. These firms were all operative in 1996 and they have non-missing values in all the included variables. Our information on ownership (whether the firm is family-owned or not) is based on response to the following question: ‘‘Are at least 33% of the shares in the firm, owned by one person or by one family?’’ If the respondent answers ‘yes’, the firm is classified as family-owned. Owner-management is measured by response to the following question: ‘‘Does the manager come from the owner family?’’ This question identifies two kinds of family-owned firms: family-owned firm run by a manager from the family (answer ‘yes’ to the latter question), and family-owned firms run by a professional (from outside the family) manager (answer ‘no’ to the latter question). The reference type of firm is nonfamily-owned firms. In the empirical analyses, we estimate standard Cobb –Douglas production functions, allowing for productivity differences between different ownership structures: Y ¼ AecFAM La K b where Y is value added, L is labour, and K is capital. Furthermore, a and b are the corresponding elasticities.3 Value added is measured by the difference between sales of the firm and the value of purchase of intermediary goods used in the production. Labour input is measured by the number of employees. Capital is measured by the sum of equity plus debt.4 As control variables, we include information on industry and stock exchange affiliation. Industry is measured by three broad categories: manufacturing, service, and crafts.5 Stock exchange affiliation is measured by a dummy variable, taking the value 1 if the firm is listed on the stock exchange and 0 otherwise. 2 Statistics from 1997 show that approximately 70% of all private Norwegian establishments with more than 10 employees were associated with an employer’s organisation. 3 In studies of producer behaviour, there is a well-known potential endogeneity problem related to the input variables, labour and capital. The input variables are chosen by the producer in some optimal or behavioural fashion and cannot therefore treated as predetermined exogenous variables. There is a vast literature on different approaches to overcome these problems (see, for instance, Griliches and Mairesse, 1995; Arellano and Bover, 1995; Blundell and Bound, 1999). Common to most of the proposed remedies is that they require panel data, which unfortunately are not available for this study. Therefore, if there are unobservable firm-specific characteristics correlated with labour and capital and if these unobservables are also correlated with the output variable, our estimated coefficients for labour and capital will be biased. However, our estimated coefficients fall within reasonable ranges. Perhaps more importantly, as reported below, our results are quite robust to variation in the coefficients for labour and capital. 4 The book value of debt and equity is vulnerable to manipulation and different types of adaptation to accounting and tax rules. Alternative proxies like replacements or market values were not available. 5 Crafts include construction, engineering, building, and installation. 112 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 Table 1 Summary statistics for included variables Family firms Mean values Log value added Log number of employees Log capital Listed firm Manager from the owner family Industry Manufacturing Crafts Services N Non-family firms Standard deviation 9.389 3.375 9.252 0.020 0.763 0.953 0.802 1.247 0.133 0.463 0.345 0.259 0.295 0.476 0.439 0.490 220 Median Mean values Standard deviation 9.113 3.178 9.139 10.064 3.873 10.027 0.069 1.277 1.074 1.607 0.254 0.486 0.096 0.417 0.501 0.295 0.494 218 Median 9.900 3.689 9.856 Family firms and non-family owned firms. Median, means values and standard deviations. Listed firm is a dummy variable taking the value 1 if listed on the stock exchange and 0 otherwise. To measure the importance of ownership, we include a binary variable (FAM), taking the value 1 if the firm is family owned and 0 if otherwise. Taking logs of the production function, we get: ln Y = ln A + cFAM + a ln L + b ln K, where (after controlling for other observable variables) c measures whether family-owned firms are more or less productive than non-family-owned firms. To analyse the importance of management, we include a dichotomous variable showing whether the firm is led by a member of the owner family. We get ln Y = ln A + dFAMMAN + gFAM + a ln L + b ln K, where d measures whether family firms managed by a member of the owner family (FAMMAN) are more or less productive than non-family-owned firms. So far, we have not addressed the problems related to endogeneity of management. If modes of management are chosen in an optimising form, results from standard ordinary least squares (OLS) will be biased. This problem and our suggestion on how to solve it are dealt with in Section 5. 4. Results Table 1 presents some summary statistics for family-owned and non-family-owned firms. Approximately 50% of the firms in our sample are family owned.6 The familyowned firms have lower value added, fewer employees, and less capital. Regarding industry location, approximately 35% of the family-owned firms are located in manufacturing industry. Compared to non-family-owned firms, family-owned firms are overrep- 6 Furthermore, (but not shown in the table), among the family-owned firms, 75% do not have any external owners (100% family owned). E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 113 resented in the craft industry. Furthermore, we see that family firms are less represented among firms established after 1980 and they are listed on the stock exchange to a lesser extent. Among the family-owned firms, 168 firms (76%) employ a manager from the owner family, while 52 firms (24%) use an external manager. Table 2 presents results from the multivariate analysis. We present four models. Model 1 includes variables for family ownership, number of employees, and industry. Model 2 adds information on whether the manager comes from the owner family. This enables us to analyse the effect of management on productivity. Model 3 adds measures of capital services. By adding capital services, we get a picture of how sensitive the relationship between family ownership and productivity is to differences in the level of capital. From Table 1, we know that family-owned firms have less capital than non-family-owned firms. Finally, Model 4 adds information on whether the firm is listed on the stock exchange. The results in Model 1 show that on an average, family-owned firms are less productive than non-family-owned firms. The difference is estimated to be 0.102 or approximately 10%. Model 2 controls for the importance of owner-management. Family-owned firms with a manager from the owner family are less productive than Table 2 The relationship between family ownership and productivity under different model specifications Intercept Family-owned firm Manager from the owner family (FAMMAN) Log number of employees Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 5.764*** (0.102) 0.102*** (0.046) 1.041*** (0.024) 5.808*** (0.1037) 0.056 (0.070) 0.215*** (0.073) 1.035*** (0.024) 3.825*** (0.1217) 0.056 (0.070) 0.155*** (0.052) 0.617*** (0.027) 0.370*** (0.018) 3.834*** (0.120) 0.060 (0.049) 0.153*** (0.052) 0.614*** (0.026) 0.374*** (0.018) 0.169** (0.076) 0.365*** (0.066) 0.220*** (0.063) 0.848 438 0.343*** (0.066) 0.196*** (0.063) 0.851 438 0.097** (0.048) 0.100** (0.063) 0.925 438 0.096** (0.048) 0.099** (0.045) 0.926 438 Log capital Listed firm Industry (ref: Crafts) Manufacturing Services R2 adj. N Estimates of production functions including indicators of family ownership (Model 1), family management (Model 2), capital stock (Model 3) and whether the firm is listed on the stock exchange (Model 4). Estimated coefficients and standard errors of coefficients in parentheses. Ordinary least squares. Dependent variable: log value added. Listed firm is a dummy variable taking the value 1 if listed on the stock exchange and 0 otherwise. The reference alternative for industry is craft. Level of significance: ***1%; **5%. 114 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 non-family-owned firms.7 These results suggest that difference in management regime is the driving force behind the productivity gap of Model 1. Adding capital in Model 3 reduces the negative effect of family management, reflecting that family managed firms are less capital intensive. The productivity gap is estimated to 0.155 or about 14% compared to non-family-owned firms. Finally, Model 4 reveals that listed firms are more productive compared to non-listed firms. The family management relationship is not altered by the inclusion of this variable. The results indicate that firms with family management are about 14% less productive than nonfamily-owned firms. The lesson from Table 2 is that neither differences in labour input, capital services nor listing on the stock exchange is sufficient to explain productivity differences between family and non-family-owned firms. The ‘culprit’ is the management function. Ownermanagement is significantly less productive compared to external management. The productivity difference is about 14%. An interpretation is that search for the best qualified manager from a large pool of applicants characterized by open competition is more likely to ensure a good firm – manager match and high productivity. 4.1. Alternative specifications and robustness checks In Table 3, we report results from some alternative specifications. We present some results based on regression analyses using all firms (columns 2 and 3) as well as results based on the sample of family-owned firms only. The focus is on the coefficient of the ‘‘manager from own family’’ indicator. For the different specifications, the table only presents the regression coefficients for the two variables ‘‘Manager from owner family’’ and ‘‘Family owned’’. First, we present two models where we impose the restriction of constant returns to scale with respect to capital and labour. The first model is obtained by dividing value added by our measure of capital. Assuming constant returns to scale we have Y/K = A(L/ K)a, which is then estimated in logs allowing A to vary with industry, listed firms, and family control variables. We report the coefficients of the family control variables only. We find a negative and significant coefficient for the ‘‘manager from owner family’’ indicator ( 0.150), again indicating a productivity gap of about 14%. In the second specification, we address the issue of potential endogeneity of inputs by using the following estimator for the elasticity of production with respect to labour inputs: a = WL/Y, averaged across firms. This estimator is taken from the first-order condition of profit-maximising firms with constant returns to scale. In accordance with the assumption of constant returns to scale, we proceed by estimating the elasticity of production with respect to capital by (1 a). Next, we calculate the log of total factor productivity by 7 A White test for heteroskedasticity is performed. No evidence of heteroskedasticity is found. Robustness tests reveal that we cannot reject unit elasticity of scale. The conclusions with respect to ownership and the management regime remain unchanged. The coefficients for capital and labour are not significantly different between family- and non-family firms. We have experimented with different input elasticities. For instance, reducing the elasticity of production with respect to capital to 0.15 only strengthened our results by increasing the difference between family- and professionally managed firms from 0.168 to 0.216. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 115 Table 3 Productivity effects under alternative specifications Alternative specifications All firms Family-owned firms Number of Manager from observations owner family 0.062 (0.050) 0.163*** (0.050) 0.134** (0.053) 0.064 (0.051) 0.134** (0.053) 0.129 (0.085) 0.186** (0.082) 0.109 (0.087) 0.058 (0.053) 0.033 (0.051) 0.104* (0.058) 0.101** (0.047) 0.053 (0.045) 0.134*** (0.048) 369/200 69/20 0.114** (0.053) 0.303* (0.167) 0.018 (0.052) 0.202 (0.133) 0.126** (0.051) 0.347 (0.240) 93/27 345/193 0.319** (0.122) 0.127** (0.057) 0.078 (0.095) 0.063 (0.057) 0.293* (0.159) 0.134** (0.055) 182/76 178/87 78/57 419/216 0.143* (0.081) 0.177** (0.083) 0.034 (0.092) 0.149*** (0.053) 438/220 0.174 (0.188) 0.216 (0.182) 0.140 (0.197) 438/220 0.193* (0.106) 0.213** (0.102) 0.187* (0.111) Alternative forms of labour input Number of employees 436/220 replaced by payroll costs Hourly wage added to 436/220 number of employees Return on capitala Dependent variable: value added divided by total capital Dependent variable: return divided by total capital Manager from owner family 0.150*** (0.052) Dependent variable: ln (value 438/220 added per unit of capital) Dependent variable: 438/220 total factor productivity Dependent variable: ln (Sales) 438/220 Sub-samples Number of employees Less than 100 employees 100 employees or more Capital 50 million NKr or more Less than 50 million NKr Industry Manufacturing Services Crafts Non-listed firms Family owned 0.004 0.109 0.019 0.053 (0.076) (0.078) (0.099) (0.051) 0.154* (0.089) 0.181** (0.079) 0.042 (0.097) 0.170*** (0.052) Some results from production functions including indicators of family ownership and family management estimated under alternative specifications. Dependent variable: log value added. The table reports estimated coefficients of the variables ‘‘Manager from owner family’’ and ‘‘Family owned’’. Standard errors of coefficients are in parentheses. All firms and family owned firms. The set of explanatory variables used in the specifications are the same as the one used in Table 2 (model 4). Estimated coefficients and standard errors. Level of significance: ***1%; **5%; *10%. a Return on capital is regressed on industry, listed firms, and family control variables only. ln( Y) a ln L (1 a)ln K, which we then regress on industry, listed firms and family control variables. Again, we find a significant negative effect of owner-management ( 0.134 or about 12.5%). These results show that applying the constant returns to scale assumption and using another plausible estimator of a does not change our results in any interesting way. 116 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 In the third specification, we investigate a model where we use log sales as the dependent variable instead of log value added. Qualitatively, we do not find large differences to the model using log value added, that is, we find a negative coefficient for the variable ‘‘manager from owner family’’ in both data sets. The coefficients are not significantly different from zero. However, as the value of intermediate goods is an obvious omitted variable in this regression, we definitely prefer the analysis presented in Table 2. Labour input may be of different quality, for instance, as a result of different levels of human capital of the workers. If this is systematically related to family control, our results may be biased. We present two tests to check for this potential problem. Assuming that the wage rate equals marginal productivity, we may use total payroll (WL) as a measure of labour input (in a specification otherwise identical to that of Table 2). This is done in the first specification. We find a negative, but not significant coefficient of 0.058 in the regression on all firms. In the regression on family firms only, we find a negative and significant coefficient of 0.104. In the next specification, we allow for differential effects of the wage rate (labour quality) and the number of workers employed by adding the log of the wage rate to the standard equation of Table 2. We then find a significant negative effect of family management in both analyses. Examination of the models reveals that the restriction imposed on the first model is not valid and that the results from the model with differential effects of the wage rate and the number of employees should be the preferred. We still tend to trust the model presented earlier (in Table 2) more for the following reason: if wages are in some way related to firms’ productivity through some bargaining mechanism, for example, they will be correlated with the error term in the production function and thus introduce a bias to the estimators of the equation. It is comforting, therefore, to note that our results do not rely on the exclusion of measures of labour quality and remain strong and significant also after controlling for human capital and other quality differences. One might be concerned that our sample is too broad and that our results arise from some underlying heterogeneity rather than from differences in management regime. To check for this, we split the sample into sub-samples along several dimensions. The first split is according to employment level. We find a strong and significant effect among small firms (smaller than 100 employees) in line with what we found in the full sample. For large firms (100+), we find an even stronger effect, in the order of 0.303, indicating a gap of more than 25%. For the group of family firms, we have only 20 firms with more than 100 employees and fail to find a statistically significant effect. Given the sub-sample size, this is not of particular concern and the point estimate of 0.347 is not significantly different from 0.126 either. In the next specification, we split the book value of total capital. The point estimates are again larger (negatively) in the larger firms than the smaller firms and the effects are statistically significant from zero in all specifications. Again, we fail to find statistically significant differences between the two sub-samples. The split, according to industry, yields more interesting results. In manufacturing and services, the management effect is significant. However, within the crafts industry, neither ownership nor management matters significantly for productivity. This means that had we removed the crafts observations from the sample in Table 2, we would have obtained even stronger effects of the management variables. We suspect that within the crafts industry, E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 117 which is dominated by small firms, several of which probably resemble self-employment, management is not such an important skill as they are in the two other industries. As a further robustness check, we have removed the listed firms and estimated the model for the non-listed firms only. The results remain large and significant. Lastly, we have made three experiments related to the return to total capital. In this exercise, we use two measures of earnings: one is sales minus intermediate goods (value added) and the other is sales minus intermediate goods minus total wage bill, i.e., a measure of operating profits. Both were then divided by the book value of total capital. These two variables are regressed on industry, listed firms, and family control variables. We find a negative relationship between return on capital, measured in terms of value added per unit of capital, and family management, but which is statistically insignificant. A similar, and significant, relationship at the 10% level is found between operating profits per unit of capital and family management ( 0.193 or about 17.5%). A third experiment, not reported in the table, is conducted using operating profits per unit of equity. This latter relation displays no significant relationship to any of the variables and is not reported. In our opinion, a production function approach represents the most appropriate test of the hypothesis that professional managers are better. This is particularly true since the measure of total capital, i.e., the book value of debt and equity, is vulnerable to manipulation and different types of adaptation to accounting and tax rules (e.g., rules on capital depreciation), which may well differ between ownership and management structure. This source of error is more serious in the analyses of returns to capital than in the production function approach, particularly as the estimates obtained for total factor productivity appear highly robust to changes in the estimated coefficients for capital and labour. However, our results also show that returns in terms of operating profits per unit of total capital are lower for family managed firms than for professionally managed firms. We now turn to an analysis of questions related to endogeneity of management regime. 5. A simple model of ownership and control In order to address the issue related to endogeneity of management, we need to model the choice between owner-management and professional management. We use a simplified and slightly modified version of the model developed by Burkart et al. (2002). They model both the founder’s choice between professional and ownermanagement, and a subsequent choice of the proportion of shares to float on the stock exchange. This unified framework allows them to combine the twin conflict between the manager and the owners, and that between the family and other minority shareholders. In our analysis here, we limit the discussion to the choice between owner-management and professional management, assuming, for the sake of simplicity, that the family maintains full ownership of the stocks. A key assumption in Burkart et al. (2002) is that owner-management is inferior to professional management. This assumption is tested below. We model this assumption 118 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 in the following way: consider a family-owned firm described by the following value added VF ¼ A ð1Þ V M ¼ Aed ð2Þ where superscript F denotes family managed firms and superscript M denotes professionally managed firms. Furthermore, d z 0 is a measure of the professional’s advantage. The owner’s utility under the two regimes is given by: U F ¼ Aec ð3Þ U M ¼ Aed ð1 p wÞ k ð1 pÞ2 2 ð4Þ where c reflects the family’s preference for controlling the firm. We will return to a discussion of c below. A positive c means that the owners have preferences for controlling the firm, while a negative c could be a result of the working effort involved in managing. The utility level in case of a professional manager is slightly more complicated. In addition to the value added of a professionally run firm, the term involves three costs: w is the wage rate paid to the manager, p is a private benefit extraction of the professional manager, and k[(1 p)2/2] are monitoring costs involved in keeping p down. Consider first the choice of monitoring level by a family firm with professional management. Firm profits are given by: P = Aed(1 p w) k[(1 p)2/2]. Maximising profits with respect to p gives: ð1 pÞ ¼ Aed k pVp̄ ð5Þ where p̄ is an upper level of the private benefit extraction possible for the manager (technologically or institutionally determined). Next, the wage w is given by the professional manager’s outside option c: Aed ðp þ wÞzc ð6Þ If VMp̄ is greater than c, the owner chooses to monitor the manager. As monitoring is costly, the family will choose to set w = 0, and let the manager obtain his benefits through p.8 Inserting w = 0 and Eq. (5) into Eq. (4) gives: UM ¼ ðAed Þ2 ; 2k ð7Þ 8 Whether the manager is able to obtain a rent or not in this firm depends on the size of value added and monitoring costs, relative to the outside option, c. See Burkart et al. (2002) for a more elaborate discussion. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 119 which is to be compared to the family’s utility under owner-management (Eq. (3)). We obtain the following qualitative results. Choose professional management: – in the more productive firms (the intuitive reason is that the monitoring costs are smaller per value added); – the higher is the professional manager’s advantage; – the smaller are the monitoring costs; – the smaller are the preferences for family control. In addition, as discussed below in the framework of the empirical model, there may be important patterns in the stochastic elements of the value added of the two regimes. We now have a model framework that enables us to empirically model the choice between family ownership and professional ownership. What we want to analyse is the following empirical relationship: m M ¼ a þ d þ uM m F ¼ a þ uF ð8Þ where a is logs of A and u represents stochastic error terms with standard properties. However, we observe the professional management regime only when the owners find this profitable. Comparing (the logs of) Eqs. (3) and (7) gives us the following model. Choose professional management when: a þ 2d ln2 lnk czu ¼ uc þ uF 2uM ð9Þ c We have introduced u to allow for stochastic variations in preferences for family control. As our data is constructed under the selection equation (Eq. (9)), the expected value of the observed value added in each group is given by (see, e.g., Maddala, 1990, p. 260): EðmM Þ ¼ a þ d rMu EðmF Þ ¼ a þ rFu / þ e1 U / þ e2 1U ð10Þ where riu = Cov(ui,u) = Cov(ui,uc + uF 2uM), and / and U are the density and cumulative density functions of the standard normal. The error terms in Eq. (10) imply that OLS on Eq. (8) produce biased results. To see this clearly, we may calculate the expected value added of the establishment as: / / ð1 DÞrMu ð11Þ EðmÞ ¼ ða þ dÞ dD þ DrFu 1U U An indicator of a family-run establishment is given by D = 1, while D = 0 for professionally run establishments. From Eq. (11), we find that by omitting the selection terms, the OLS estimation of d may be considerably biased. In order to discuss the nature of the bias consider the following simple example. 120 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 Let uM = uF = uA; which means that there is a stochastic productivity factor uA, which is identical regardless of management regime. Let also uc = 0, so that the common productivity shifter is the only stochastic element of the model. In this case, riu = rA2 for i = F, M, and consequently: EðmÞ ¼ ða þ dÞ dD r2A D / / ð1 DÞ 1U U ¼ ða þ dÞ dD r2A k ð12Þ Note that k is increasing in D and thus larger for family-owned establishments. Thus, failure to account for the selection term produces a positive bias for the professionally run establishment and a negative bias for the family run establishment and consequently an upward bias in the coefficient d. The intuition behind this result is simple. Because monitoring costs are increasing in the share of A, that may be kept by the owner (1 p), rather than in the absolute value of the profit, the optimal monitoring level is higher for more productive establishments and owners gain more from professional management of productive establishments. When comparing across management regimes, we are consequently comparing across establishments with different expected productivity levels. Inserting a weighted Heckman’s lambda, as suggested by Eq. (12) then produces the necessary correction to obtain unbiased estimates of d. Consider next the introduction of a stochastic element in family preferences, uc. Now rMu = rFu = rAu = rAc rA2. We obtain: EðmÞ ¼ ða þ dÞ dD þ ðrAc r2A Þk ð13Þ The coefficient attached to the weighted Heckman’s lambda is thus rAc rA2. If the correlation between the productivity term and family preferences for running the business is negative, the selection term still produces an upward bias in the OLS estimator of d. However, if the correlation is positive and large enough relative to the variance in productivity, the selection term produces a negative bias. This case may occur if families enjoy running well performing firms more than running inefficient firms. If the firm performs well, the family prefers to keep control, but if the enterprise turns out to be negative, they resort to outside management for help. Obviously, different correlations between the productivity terms of the two regimes may also induce similar results. If, for instance, managers are relatively more efficient than the family in handling troubled times, a negative bias occurs. Note also that an absolute bankruptcy level may also produce a similar bias as the productivity distribution is truncated at a higher level for family-owned firms (who, by assumption is d units to the left of the productivity distribution of professionally run firms). In all of these cases, we are more likely to find professional managers in the poorer establishments, while the family keeps on running the efficient ones. In the empirical section below, a standard selection model of the type presented here is estimated. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 121 Another way of writing the expected value added is: / / EðmÞ ¼ U a þ d rMu þ ð1 UÞ a þ rFu U 1U ¼ ða þ dÞ dð1 UÞ þ ðrMu rFu Þ/ ð14Þ One modelling strategy is thus to estimate the log of value added including both / and U in the model. This is a standard switching model. The coefficient for (1 U) (the probability of being run by the family) gives us and estimate of d and the coefficient for / gives us an estimate of (rMurFu) = rMcrFc + 2rM2 + rF23rFM. We also run this switching model below. 5.1. Issues of identification The switching model described above is identified by functional form, but also from the fact that the switching regression includes variables that are not in the value-added regression. Therefore, we do not rely solely on identification by functional form. The two variables that enter the switching regression are the monitoring costs as well as the family’s preferences for managing the firms themselves. The variables we use to represent monitoring costs are firm size, whether the firm is listed on the stock exchange, and industry. These variables should also be included in the value added regressions and cannot be used for identification purposes. Nevertheless, we have in our data variables that could reasonably represent (c) the family’s preference for control. We have information on the number of years the firm has been in the family’s ownership. Conditional upon the number years since the firm was established, the number of years in family’s ownership could be a good proxy for variables affecting the family’s preference for control. We also have a direct question to the manager on the perceived importance of family control: ‘‘How important is it to sustain control of the family firm?’’ We utilized this as an indicator of the family’s preference for control. We present both a two-stage least squares (2SLS) approach as well as the Heckman procedure presented above, and the switching regression in the next section. First, however, we take a closer look the first-stage results: What determines the choice of management regime? 5.2. Family manager or professional manager? In this section, we report from the first-stage regressions of the switching model. What determines the choice of family versus professional manager? We limit the analysis to family-owned firms, i.e., to the 220 firms that report that at least 33% of the shares in the firm are owned by one person or one family. The dependent variable is a dummy variable, taking the value 1 if the firm uses a manager from the owner family and 0 otherwise. 122 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 Table 4 Estimates of the probabilities of choosing owner-management Model 1 Probit coefficients Intercept Log capital Log number of employees Listed firm 2.458*** (0.910) 0.269* (0.141) 0.075 (0.196) 0.629 (0.687) Industry (ref: Crafts) Manufacturing 0.544* (0.319) Services 0.566* (0.306) Importance of 0.397 control (0.242) Established (ref. after 1990) Pre-1900 0.364 (0.721) 1900 – 1919 1.576** (0.709) 1920 – 1939 0.406 (0.712) 1940 – 1959 0.231 (0.653) 1960 – 1979 0.091 (0.649) 1980 – 1989 0.572 (0.608) Marginal probabilities 0.063 0.018 0.148 0.128 0.133 0.094 0.086 0.372 0.096 0.055 0.021 0.135 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 LPM (OLS) Instruments only Without instruments 1.059*** (0.229) 0.054 (0.034) 0.002 (0.050) 0.229 (0.207) 0.519*** (0.110) 1.441*** (0.223) 0.058* (0.035) 0.015 (0.053) 0.272 (0.213) 0.109 (0.074) 0.124* (0.069) 0.077 (0.057) 0.081 (0.057) 0.114 (0.119) 0.448** (0.189) 0.119 (0.184) 0.108 (0.175) 0.061 (0.175) 0.177 (0.168) 0.265 (0.186) 0.614*** (0.183) 0.276 (0.181) 0.233 (0.172) 0.142 (0.172) 0.254 (0.167) How many years in family’s ownership ( ref. less than 6 years) 6 – 9 years 1.637*** 0.386 0.479*** (0.599) (0.146) 10 – 19 years 1.147** 0.271 0.377*** (0.528) (0.135) 20 – 49 years 1.221** 0.288 0.399*** (0.531) (0.133) 50+ years 1.958*** 0.462 0.531*** (0.583) (0.137) Log likelihood 93.052 R2 adj. 0.179 N 220 220 0.119 (0.077) 0.122* (0.072) 0.538*** (0.147) 0.441*** (0.134) 0.457*** (0.131) 0.618*** (0.137) 0.148 220 0.050 220 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 123 In Table 4, Model 1 displays a probit analysis of the probability of choosing a family manager. As the probit model is a nonlinear regression model, the parameters cannot be interpreted as marginal effects on the probability of choosing a family manager. To receive a measure on the marginal effects on the probability, we must multiply the estimated parameter with /; the standard normal density, evaluated at the mean of the sample. Measures of the marginal effects are presented at the right hand side of the probit coefficients. The specification in Model 1 is used to calculate the / and U. Model 2 reports results from a simple linear probability model (LPM) that is used in the 2SLS specification. The two last models are reported to give an account of the explanatory power of the instruments used in the first-stage regression. These models are also estimated by LPM models. From the probit equation (Model 1), we find that owner-management is significantly less likely in firms with more capital. A doubling of the capital stock decreases the probability of owner-management by 6.3 percentage points, as judged by the marginal effect in Model 1. This result is in accordance with our theoretical model. In the theoretical model, it is more profitable for professionals to manage the more productive firms mainly because the optimal level of monitoring is higher in these firms. The point estimate for listed firms is negative, possibly indicating that professional managers are easier to monitor in listed firms, but as the coefficient is insignificant, we cannot rely too heavily on this result. Model 1 shows that a young firm is more likely to be managed by the owner. Conditioned on the firm’s age, however, a recently acquired firm is less likely to be family managed. One reason for the positive relationship between owner-management and number of years in family ownership is that some of the family firms were established earlier and subsequently taken over by the present owners. Several of these acquired firms were probably managed by professional managers at the time of acquirement. However, after the first 5 years, the relationship between owner-management and years in family ownership is quite stable. Model 2 contains results from the LPM model. The LPM coefficients can be interpreted as marginal effects on the probability. We see that estimated coefficients in Model 2 are fairly comparable to the predicted marginal effects from the probit estimation in Model 1. In Model 3, we find that the variables reflecting the age of the firm, years in family ownership and preferences for family control explains about 15% of the variation in management regime, when entered alone. Comparing Models 4 and 2, we also find that the instruments add about 10 percentage points to the explained variation, when added to the full model. Even though these numbers suffer from the weakness of the linear Notes to Table 4: Family-owned firms only. The table reports results from a probit model (Model 1) and three linear probability models (Models 2 – 4). Estimated coefficients and standard errors of coefficients in parentheses. Dependent variable: dummy variable for owner-management. Level of significance: ***1%; **5%; *10%. 124 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 probability model, they clearly indicate that we have a set of instruments that contributes significantly in explaining the choice between family and professional management. 5.3. Family ownership and productivity In this section, we test the basic assumption that managers from the family are less productive than professional managers. We estimate four models on the sample of familyowned firms only. The results are presented in Table 5. Model 1 is the OLS specification. In this specification, we find that family managed firms are about 16% less productive than firms managed by a manager outside of the family. Model 2 is the weighted Heckman model as presented in Eq. (12). Model 3 is the switching model as presented in Eq. (14), and Model 4 is the 2SLS specification. In Model 2, the family manager disadvantage increases after controlling for endogeneity. This result indicates that there is a positive selection into family management; i.e., Table 5 The relationship between family management and productivity Model 1 (OLS) Intercept Manager from the owner family Log number of employees Listed firm Log capital Model 2 (weighted Model 3 Model 4 (2SLS) Heckman model) (Switching model) 4.166*** (0.183) 4.242*** (0.237) 4.333*** (0.255) 4.294*** (0.243) 0.169*** (0.051) 0.222* (0.115) 0.292** (0.134) 0.257*** (0.122) 0.641*** (0.040) 0.639*** (0.040) 0.634*** (0.041) 0.639*** (0.041) 0.244 (0.161) 0.338*** (0.027) 0.229 (0.164) 0.335*** (0.028) 0.279* (0.167) 0.341*** (0.027) 0.220 (0.165) 0.333*** (0.028) 0.047 (0.060) 0.092 (0.057) 0.037 (0.072) 0.077 (0.062) 0.128** (0.059) 0.043 (0.060) 0.088 (0.057) Industry (ref: Crafts) Manufacturing 0.052 (0.058) Services 0.099 (0.055) Heckman’s k / Hausman test coefficient (standard error) Basmann test for overidentifying restrictions, P-value R2 adj. 0.893 N 220 0.448* (0.248) 0.141 (0.132) 0.413 0.892 220 0.890 220 0.891 220 Production functions estimated on the sample of family-owned firms only. All regressions include an indicator of family management (‘‘Manager from the owner family’’). Models 2 – 4 include different types of control for the endogeneity of family management; a weighted Heckman model, a switching regression model and a two-stage least square model (2SLS). Estimated coefficients and standard errors of coefficients in parentheses. Dependent variable: log value added. Level of significance: ***1%; **5%; *10%. Instruments in the first-stage regression include a survey question of the importance of control of the firm, the establishment date of the firm and the length of time with family involvement in the firm. See Table 4 for the firststage regressions. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 125 that the family prefers to keep control of the good firms. However, as the coefficient for the Heckman’s lambda is not significant, we should express some caution in interpreting the results. In the next model, we present the results from the switching model. The effect is now estimated to be 0.292, indicating a productivity gap of about 25%. We do not obtain a significant coefficient at the 5% level for the selection term (/). This suggests we cannot reject the OLS model to the advantage of the switching model. In Model 4, where we instrument manager type by standard 2SLS, the Hausman test fails to support a significant selection bias. However, in the 2SLS specification, we obtain an even larger negative effect of owner-management on productivity. To test for overidentifying restrictions, we report results from a standard Basmann test (Basmann, 1960) as well. The Basmann test performs satisfactorily, indicating that the instruments should not be included in the productivity equation. 6. Conclusion We compare the performance of family-owned versus non-family-owned firms. The measure of performance is productivity. The results show that family-owned firms are less productive than non-family-owned firms. The difference in productivity is estimated to be approximately 10%. This productivity gap is explained by differences in management regimes. Family-owned firms managed by a manager from outside the owner family are equally productive as non-family-owned firms. However, familyowned firms managed by a person from the owner family, are found to be significantly less productive than non-family-owned firms. We estimate this productivity gap to be about 14%. When we compare within the sample of family-owned firms only, the difference between firms that are managed by a member of the family and those operated by managers from outside the family is estimated to be 15 –16%. When we try to correct for the endogeneity of management type, we obtain even larger negative effects. From the discussion above, this indicates that there is positive (negative) selection into family (professional) management. One reason could be that professional managers are called for in difficult times, or similarly, that in good times or in good firms family owners enjoy keeping control. As the selection terms are not significant in any of our second-step specifications, we cannot put much weight on this particular result. What remains is a strong and significant negative (positive) effect of family (professional) management on productivity. The productivity gap may be due to skill differences between professional and family managers. After all, professional managers are chosen from a larger pool of talent. But, it might also be the case that family managers choose to run the firm in less productive manners. Owner – managers may retain the position as top manager because they enjoy being in charge and manage their lifework, the family firm, in their own way. At first sight, our results seem to be at odds with the recent results reported in Anderson and Reeb (2003), who report that family firms perform better than non-family firms. However, they find a concave relationship between family ownership and performance. After about 30% ownership, further family ownership has a negative effect on performance and after about 60%, family firms perform worse than non-family-owned firms. In 126 E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 our sample, most of the family-owned firms have family ownership shares of more than 50%. In fact, 74% of the family-owned firms have no other owners, that is, they are 100% owned by the owner family. Thus, our results are consistent with the findings of Anderson and Reeb. But they also conclude that hired CEOs perform worse than managers from the family. The difference shown in our results may be because our performance measure differs, as we analyse productivity while they study the effect on returns-on-assets and Tobin’s Q. Further, our analysis suggests a positive selection into family management. Even if this effect is not statistically significant in our sample, such a selection may be present in a sample of large listed firms. In summary, we do not find support for the hypothesis that concentrated ownership per se affects productivity. It does, however, matter who runs the firm. When choosing between owner-management and professional management, the owner may have to make a trade-off between skills and incentives. Owner-management ensures right incentives. Nevertheless, it seems that professional managers hired in the market are more efficient in operating the firm. Acknowledgements The authors thank Hege Torp, Tone Ognedal, an anonymous referee and the Editor for valuable comments. The paper has been presented at the research seminar at the Frisch Centre for Economic Research, and at the 2nd European Conference on Corporate Governance, Brussels 27 – 29 November 2002. We thank seminar and conference participants for fruitful discussions. The work is financed by the Norwegian Research Council, grant # 136779. The financial support is gratefully acknowledged. References Agrawal, A., Nagarjan, N.J., 1990. Corporate structure, agency costs, and ownership control: the case of allequity firms. Journal of Finance 45, 1325 – 1331. Anderson, R.C., Reeb, D.M., 2003. Founding family ownership and performance. Evidence from the S&P 500. Journal of Finance 58, 1301 – 1327. Anderson, R.C., Mansi, S.A., Reeb, D.M., 2003. Founding family ownership and the agency costs of debt. Journal of Financial Economics 68, 263 – 285. Arellano, M., Bover, O., 1995. Another look at the instrument-variable estimation of error component models. Journal of Econometrics 68, 29 – 52. Basmann, R., 1960. On finite sample distributions of generalized classical linear identifiability test statistics. Journal of the American Statistical Association 55, 650 – 659. Blair, M.M., 1995. Ownership and Control. Rethinking Governance for the Twenty-First Century. The Brooking Institution, Washington, DC. Blundell, R., Bound, S., 1999. GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS), working paper no. W99/4. Burkart, M., Panunzi, F., Shleifer, A., 2002. Family firms. Working paper 8776. National Bureau of Economic Research. Cambridge, MA, USA. Chandler, A.D., 1990. Scale and Scope. The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Harvard/Belknap, Cambridge, MA. Coleman, J.S., 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. The Belknap Press of Harvard Univ. Press, Cambridge, MA. E. Barth et al. / Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 107–127 127 Demsetz, H., 1983. The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm. Journal of Law & Economics 26, 375 – 390. Demsetz, H., Lehn, K., 1985. The structure of corporate ownership: causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy 93, 1155 – 1177. Demsetz, H., Villalonga, B., 2001. Ownership structure and corporate performance. Journal of Corporate Finance 7, 209 – 233. Fama, E.F., Jensen, M.C., 1983. Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law & Economics XXVI, 301 – 325. Gallo, M.A., Vilaseca, A., 1996. Finance in family business. Family Business Review 9, 387 – 401. Griliches, Z., Mairesse, J., 1995. Production functions: the search for identification. In: Strøm, S. (Ed.), The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium. Cambridge Univ. Press, New York, USA, pp. 169 – 203. Goffee, R., Scase, R., 1985. Proprietorial control in family firms: some functions of quasi-organic management systems. Journal of Management 22, 53 – 68. Gorriz, C.G., Fumas, V.S., 1996. Ownership structure and firm performance: some empirical evidence from Spain. Managerial and Decision Economics 17, 575 – 586. Gulbrandsen, T., 2004. Flexibility in Norwegian family-owned enterprises. Family Business Review (in press). Hart, O., 2001. Financial contracting. Journal of Economic Literature 39, 1079 – 1100. Hofer, C.W., Charan, R., 1984. The transition to professional management: mission impossible? In: Aronoff, C.E., Ward, J.L. (Eds.), Family Business Sourcebook. Omnigraphics, Detroit. Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305 – 360. Lauterbach, B., Vaninsky, A., 1999. Ownership structure and firm performance: evidence from Israel. Journal of Management and Governance 3, 189 – 201. Maddala, G.S., 1990. Limited dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Econometric Society Monographs. Cambridge Univ. Press, New York, USA. McConaughy, D.L., Walker, M.C., Henderson, G.V., Mishra, C.S., 1998. Founding family controlled firms: efficiency and value. Review of Financial Economics 7, 1 – 19. Morck, R., Stangeland, D., Young, B., 1998. Inherited wealth, corporate control, and economic growth, The Canadian disease? NBER Working paper 6814. National Bureau of Economic Research. Cambridge, MA, USA. Palia, D., Lichtenberg, F., 1999. Managerial ownership and firm performance: a reexamination using productivity measurement. Journal of Corporate Finance 5, 323 – 339. Perez-Gonzalez, F., 2001. Does inherited control hurt firms performance? PhD dissertation, Harvard University. Pollack, R.A., 1985. A transaction cost approach to families and households. Journal of Economic Literature 23, 581 – 608. Schleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance 52, 737 – 783. Smith, B.F., Amoako-Adu, B., 1999. Management succession and financial performance of family controlled firms. Journal of Corporate Finance 5, 341 – 368. Wall, R.A., 1998. An empirical investigation of the production function of the family firm. Journal of Small Business Management 6, 24 – 32.