Corporate Tax Compliance: The Role of Internal and External Preparers Kenneth Klassen University of Waterloo kklassen@uwaterloo.ca Petro Lisowsky University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign lisowsky@illinois.edu Devan Mescall University of Saskatchewan mescall@edwards.usask.ca Abstract: Using a survey of tax executives and proprietary data on who signs the corporate tax return, we investigate tax reporting strategies to understand how firms are managing this challenging task, and what effect tax preparers have on corporate tax positions. Specifically, we investigate whether tax preparer type—whether internal, external auditor, or external non-auditor—is related to tax aggressiveness. Using IRS data on who signs a firm’s tax return, we find that (1) internal and external non-auditor preparers exhibit greater tax aggressiveness than external auditor preparers; and (2) publicly disclosed tax fees paid to a firm’s auditor do not provide infomration sufficient to replicate this result. In our survey, tax executives report that their firms outsource only 30% of their compliance and planning work, and seldom utilize their auditor exclusively for such work. Applying conventions in tax fee research to infer preparer type, we estimate that tax fees incorrectly classify between 20 and 62 percent of firms into tax preparer types that do not match those reported on a firm’s tax return. Our findings are important given that the paucity of archival research on tax preparers and the importance of tax advisors to the tax-related decisions made by companies in the U.S. economy. Keywords: paid preparer, tax expert, audit expert, FIN 48, tax reserve, tax aggressiveness ______________________________________________________________________________ We obtain confidential tax return data from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Large Business & International Division’s (LB&I); these data are not publicly available. Because tax return data are confidential and protected by data non-disclosure agreements under the Internal Revenue Code, all statistics are presented in the aggregate; no statistics with fewer than three observations are disclosed. Any opinions are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the IRS. The authors thank Stephen Powers for excellent research assistance. 1. Introduction The current corporate tax environment is characterized by a high degree of uncertainty. Uncertainty in the tax law can create opportunities for planning, but can also create challenges in compliance. To evaluate the compliance responsibilities and implications surrounding business transactions, companies employ internal tax specialists and/or hire external advisory firms. The effect of the tax advisor in compliance decisions of corporations is very important, but has not been subject to much archival empirical research due to the lack of available data. This paper begins to overcome that shortcoming by using proprietary data on who signs the corporate tax return and survey responses of 170 tax executives to examine the effect of the tax service provider on the compliance of tax positions claimed by corporations. An extensive literature has examined the relation between auditors providing tax services and the effect on the audit process.1 There continues to be a debate over whether auditors providing tax services impairs independence, creates knowledge spillover, or both. For example, Davis, et al. (1993) find no evidence of a knowledge spillover, while 43% of CFOs surveyed by Cripe and McAllister (2009) identify knowledge spillover as their primary reason for integrating their choice of auditor and tax preparer. Frankel, et al. (2002) show the provision of non-audit services generally is positively associated with earnings management, but Ashbaugh, et al. (2003), Chung and Kallapur (2003), and Larcker and Richardson (2004) refute this relation. Kinney, et al. (2004) show that the provision of tax non-audit services in particular reduces restatements. Francis and Ke (2006) show that the equity market uses non-audit service fees to assess audit quality (negatively), but Pittman and Fortin (2008) show that increasing tax nonaudit services lowers cost of debt financing. Despite this lack of resolution, a majority of studies 1 For example, see Davis et al. (1993); DeFond et al. (2002); Abbott et al. (2003); Kinney et al. (2004); Francis and Ke (2006); Pittman and Fortin (2008); Lim and Tan (2008); and Zamar et al. (2011). 1 in the accounting literature continue to look at the decision to choose the auditor as the firm’s tax service provider through the lens of the audit and auditor-related consequences. The literature remains mostly silent on the role of the tax preparer and its effect on tax-related decisions. Two notable exception are Neuman, et al. (2011) and McGuire et al. (2011). Neuman et al. explore the not-for-profit sector where the identity of the tax preparer is disclosed in publicly available tax returns.2 In testing the effect of paid preparer type on donations (their measure of credibility), they find that external preparers are positively associated with donations. They interpret this evidence to suggest that the public views self-prepared returns as less credible. Although they infer that their results generalize to the for-profit sector, direct evidence on the role of tax preparer type in a corporate setting remains elusive. Our objective is to fill this void. In particular, our research questions ask whether tax preparer type is associated with tax aggressiveness; and how accurately public data on tax fees paid to a firm’s auditor capture the actual tax return preparer type. McGuire et al. (2011) use auditor fee data, as descibed more fully below, to show that firms who obtain any tax services from their auditors, that are also local industry tax experts, are more aggressive in their tax reporting. Our research is a complement to McGuire et al. because we ask whether using the company’s auditor to be primarily responsible for tax compliance in particular affects tax-related decisions. Secondly, we focus on a measure of tax decision making (uncertain tax benefits) that is generally regarded as more extreme than those analyzed by McGuire et al. (measures based on effective tax rates and permanent tax-book differences) because, guided by the theoretical model of Phillips and Sansing (1998) the advisor should matter most where the tax positions are particularly uncertain. 2 In particular, IRS Form 990 is required for tax-exempt entities and is available for public examination. 2 To answer these questions, we use confidential data from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) on who signs the tax return for 1,533 firm years during 2008 and 2009. The tax return data allow us to focus on whether the compliance activities of the firm are primarily administered by the internal tax department, the firm’s financial statement auditor, or an external non-auditor preparer. Until now, researchers have only been able to observe the dichotomous choice of a corporation using or not using its auditor for tax services (e.g., Lassila, et al. 2011); and even so, it remains unclear whether the services pertain to tax compliance or planning. To set the context for this analysis, we survey 170 tax executives from the Tax Executives Institute (TEI) who disclose their use of external firms for compliance work. Our survey reveals that 20% of the respondents do not use any external firm for compliance work, 16% use their auditors only, 52% use another type of consultant (either an accounting firm that is not their auditor, or another type of provider), and 12% use both their auditor and other providers. The survey also reveals that external providers perform only 30% of compliance work, and external providers are used for a similar percentage of tax planning work. Finally, companies who do not outsource their tax compliance work, and to a somewhat lesser extent those who use accounting firms that are not their auditor, are generally larger firms. With this background, we employ the theoretical model of Phillips and Sansing (1998) to form predictions around the relation between the type of tax preparer and the observed aggressiveness of the company’s tax-related decisions. As described in Section 3, we predict that internally-prepared tax returns and returns prepared by external firms that are not the companies’ auditors, will be more aggressive, on average, because theory suggests that companies who do not hire an external preparer tend to have a high tolerance for reassessment and are willing to 3 claim aggressive tax positions.3 Phillips and Sansing (1998) also predict that, in equilibrium, companies’ aggressiveness will be increasing in their preparer’s expertise and we assume that hiring another firm raises the average quality of the tax preparer. Using the FIN 48 tax reserves as our proxy for tax aggressiveness, and linking them to the tax preparer identity from the tax returns, our empirical tests support these hypotheses. In particular, we find that external auditor-prepared tax returns are the least aggressive compared to returns prepared by internal tax departments or other external preparers. Including proxies for both internally prepared returns and non-auditor prepared returns in our models, their coefficients are similar, and both types of companies have tax returns that are more aggressive than auditor-prepared tax returns. In a final analysis, we examine how accurate using publicly available data on tax fees paid to a firm’s auditors are with respect to inferring tax preparer type from the tax return. We do so to assess whether the window available to investors and researchers in financial reports on tax compliance is useful. We find that more than 80% of companies in our sample publicly disclose tax fees paid to their auditor, but only 20% of tax returns are in fact prepared by the auditor. Using a variety of proxies generated from the tax fee data to infer preparer type, we attempt to replicate our main results using tax returns, but are unable to do so. We estimate that tax fees incorrectly classify between 20 and 62 percent of firms into tax preparer types that do not match those reported on a firm’s tax return. This finding suggests that tax fee data has limited value in correctly identifying the tax return preparer, and thus the tax compliance advisor of the company. Given the paucity of archival research on tax preparers generally, our research makes a significant contribution to understanding their important role in the U.S. tax system. Specifically, 3 We acknowledge that the choice of preparer is likely endogenous and account for this possibility in our empirical tests. 4 our research is the first to document the identity of tax return preparers for a large sample of U.S. companies, reports its links to tax aggressiveness, and evaluate how tax fees mostly do not accurately capture tax compliance activity that is observed directly from the tax return. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes our setting of tax preparers by reporting results of our survey of tax executives at TEI. Sections 3 and 4 develop hypotheses and describe the research design. Section 5 reports the results of tests using large-sample tax return data. Section 6 explores the accuracy of public fee data in the context of testing our research questions. Section 7 concludes. 2. Institutional Setting 2.1 SURVEY OF TAX EXECUTIVES ON TAX COMPLIANCE To gain an understanding of the general use of external tax advisors in a corporate compliance environment, we surveyed a sample of the Tax Executives Institute (TEI) membership on this topic. The survey was conducted online between October and December, 2010, and members were contacted directly by TEI in two emails. Both the original email and the second follow-up email were sent to tax executives at 2,700 multinational firms. We received responses from 218 tax executives resulting in a response rate of 8.1%.4 The response rate is comparable to previous surveys of senior executives, including the 8.8% response rate in Graham and Harvey (2001) and 9% in Slemrod and Venkatesch (2002), although it is lower than the exceptional 26.6% rate in Hanlon, et al. (2010).5 4 Of the respondents, 40% identified themselves as their firm’s Tax Director, 39% identified themselves as VP Tax or CTO, 19% as Tax Manager, and 2% as CFO. 5 To allow the researchers to ask the questions of interest and to insure the responding members of TEI felt comfortable responding, it was agreed that all questions would be optional and members should feel free to skip any questions. As a result, the response rate varies across questions. 5 Pursuant to our agreement with TEI, participation in the survey was optional. Therefore, we evaluate whether our inferences suffer from non-response bias. The survey was conducted by sending out the request for participation by TEI leadership to its members, and followed up by a second request 42 days later. This approach allows us to test for evidence of a non-response bias on the overall survey using Wallace and Mellor’s (1988) method (see also, for example, Graham and Harvey, 2001). Our results show no statistical difference in the characteristics of the early versus late respondent firms in terms of size, industry, or geography, suggesting the effect of any non-response bias is likely minimal. We also compare our respondents to the overall population of TEI member firms. In Table 1, we compare the size and industry of our sample to the 2005 survey that TEI required its total membership to answer. Our sample of surveyed firms is generally comparable to slightly larger in revenue, total assets, and tax budget. For example, we find 17% and 4% of our sample are in the largest two revenue categories of $10-$50 billion and greater than $50 billion, respectively, while the 2005 population had 11% and 2%, respectively. This may suggest our responses come from larger firms than the overall TEI membership. [Insert Table 1 about here] The respondents to our survey and the TEI membership have a similar industry composition with the exception of a higher concentration of manufacturing firms; i.e., 49% compared to 36% in the 2005 survey, and 11% in industries not identified in the 2005 survey. Although we could not identify any obvious bias stemming from this difference in industry composition or the somewhat larger respondents, we cannot rule out a bias of unknown severity that may affect our inferences. Nevertheless, the survey data provide additional context against which we can evaluate the different types of tax preparers used by U.S. corporations. 6 Summary statistics of survey questions are presented in Table 2. One question asked respondents to identify who they use to provide assistance with tax compliance. Possible responses include the company’s auditor, other accounting firms, and/or non-accounting firms such as lawyers, consultants, etc. Respondents indicated that they use one, two, or all three of these alternative providers. Of the seven possible combinations listed, the exclusive use of one accounting firm other than the company’s auditor was the most common response at 41%. Twenty percent do not outsource any compliance work. Interestingly, only 16% of the respondents outsourced their compliance work exclusively to their auditor. Seventeen percent indicate that they use more than one type of outside firm to perform compliance work. [Insert Table 2 about here] The next column of statistics summarizes the amount of compliance work that is outsourced. Overall, only approximately 30% of compliance work is outsourced. However, when only the company’s auditor or another accounting firm is used, approximately 40% of compliance work is outsourced. On the other hand, only 22% of compliance work is outsourced when only a non-accounting firm is used. Using more than one type of provider does not dramatically increase the proportion of work outsourced. Column 5 lists the percentage of planning work that is outsourced. Comparison of columns 4 and 5 reveals that on average, the same proportion of work is outsourced, 30%, but in almost all categories, the average amount of planning work outsourced is smaller (for example, for auditor only, 40% of the compliance work is outsourced, but only 31% of planning work is outsourced). The only group for which planning work is a higher percentage is when only a non-accounting firm is used for compliance work. Overall, these statistics suggest that much of the typical companies’ tax work is done in-house, and that if 7 anything, planning work is even more commonly done in house too. This provides some validation that firms with internal tax departments are well-resourced, indicating an ability to pursue advantageous tax positions. The last two columns of Table 1 provide some summary statistics on respondent size in terms of the number of internal tax personnel employed and total assets. On average, the firms who do not outsource any compliance, i.e., “in-house,” are on average the largest in asset size, while the group that does not use its auditors (both non-auditor accounting firms and nonaccounting firms) for compliance work has the largest internal tax personnel. Firms using only a non-auditor accounting firm are, on average, large, and also have sizable tax departments. Those firms that use only a non-accounting firm are the smallest, on average, but have a large number of internal tax personnel, suggesting that firms generally use internal personnel, then supplement with specialists (such as lawyers) as necessary. Those who use only their auditor are both small in size and have the fewest internal tax personnel (though on a size-adjusted basis these firms may also have sizable tax departments). Overall, our analysis reveals that survey respondent-firms generally do not outsource the majority of either their compliance or planning work. It also shows that while many firms choose a single type of firm for compliance, there is a noteworthy percentage that uses more than one type. Firms using only their auditor tend to be small while firms using only a non-audit accounting firm or not outsourcing at all tend to be large in terms of asset size and tax personnel. Other than those who do not outsource any compliance, other categories generally outsource a smaller proportion of their planning than the proportion of their compliance work. In the next section, we describe tax return information on the party primarily responsible for the tax compliance work of the corporation, which we later employ in our empirical tests. 8 2.2 SIGNATURE INFORMATION ON THE TAX RETURN To our knowledge, there is no archival research on the importance of a specific type of tax preparer in a corporate setting.6 Studies such as Christian, et al. (1993), Hite and McGill (1992), and Long and Caudhill (1987) investigate various aspects of the decision by individual taxpayers to use paid tax preparers, and Neuman, et al. (2011) examine tax preparer use in the non-profit sector. Although some factors identified in the individual tax preparer literature, such as time, cost, and complexity (Christian et al. 1993) may impact corporate decisions to seek external tax advisors as well, the tax compliance environment for corporations is certainly different from individuals and non-profits along other dimensions. For example, differences in audit probabilities, agency and reputational costs, resource availability, and profit-motive, all create a unique environment in which corporations evaluate and implement tax compliance activities. The main challenge facing external observers who assess corporate tax compliance is observing its qualitative input. For example, one cannot observe the set of transactions available to the corporation; design details of the transactions; or the labor, time, and management talent required to implement the transactions. To overcome this shortcoming, interested parties are forced to utilize noisy observable outputs to infer unobservable inputs. For example, disclosures in securities documents of fees paid to corporate auditors for tax services are sometimes used as proxies for tax planning activities (e.g., Cook, et al. 2008). However, it is unclear whether tax fees (a) in fact represent compliance-related activities at all; (b) accurately reflect the auditor’s relative role and importance in the context of all the corporation’s tax compliance activities, and (c) appropriately describe how much the corporation also uses its internal tax department or other 6 We discuss related theoretical research in Section 3. 9 external non-auditor parties to prepare and report the tax return to the tax authorities. Unfortunately, these issues only become more opaque when tax fees paid to auditors are not disclosed at all. One avenue toward obtaining a clearer picture of a corporation’s tax compliance activities is by observing the identity of the party that signs the tax return. Although this information is not publicly available for corporations, it is for the first time made available to one of the authors on a limited, confidential basis for purposes of this study. Importantly, by using tax returns, the signature’s observability is not conditional on the corporation using its auditor for tax services. Also, the tax return preparer’s identity provides a more direct signal of compliance work than do tax fees.7 Most notably, Internal Revenue Code (IRC) Section 6694 outlines penalties related to external preparers signing tax returns containing unreasonable positions that result in an understatement of tax liability.8 The related penalty regime for non-compliance requires the preparer to pay the greater of $1,000 or half of the income derived (or expected to be derived) with respect to preparing the tax return (§6694(a)(1)). Clearly this latter penalty, coupled with related litigation and reputational costs, can be significant for large external paid preparers, such as those in our sample. The effect of the penalty regime is that an external preparer will not sign the tax return unless it is confident it has obtained enough information to properly defend the underlying tax positions and advocate for the client in the event of a dispute with the tax authority. Therefore, if the external advisor does not sign the tax return, it is either because it did not provide any tax work at all, or it only provided limited, focused compliance work on a 7 We thank a tax partner at a large accounting firm for extensive input on this subject. We also conduct various tests on whether tax fees are informative for tax compliance. We report those results in Section 6. 8 An unreasonable position is one that (a) the tax preparer knew or reasonably should have known of the position; (b) there was not a reasonable belief that the position would more likely than not be sustained on its merits; and (c) the position was not disclosed or there was no reasonable basis for the position (§6694 (a)(2)). 10 particular transaction (e.g., calculated the foreign tax credit only). A narrow scope of work does not require the external advisor to sign the tax return. In fact, the advisor will prefer not to sign the return in this situation because it has not adequately evaluated the merits underlying the rest of the tax return and thus does not want to incur additional risks by claiming material responsibility over that tax return. If there is no other external party claiming responsibility over the tax return compliance work, then the tax return is only signed by the corporation, typically the senior tax officer (e.g., the Tax Director or Vice President of Tax). However, if the corporation would like the external party to sign the tax return, the §6694 penalty regime provides strong incentives for the external party to require a much larger scope of work (and thus more fees) to gather adequate documentation and support underlying the entire tax return. If an external party reasons that through the additional work, its compliance-related requirements are met, it signs the tax return (in the “Paid Preparer” section) alongside the corporation’s tax officer.9 In fact, if the work by the external advisor is substantial, the external party is required to sign the tax return; conditional on the work performed, the signature itself is not an election.10 In all, the strict regulatory regime underlying §6694, which exposes an external preparer to substantial risk if sufficient support is not gathered in preparing the return, provides strong institutional incentives that ensure the signature information on the tax return represents the party most substantially associated with the corporation’s tax compliance work. In the next section, we develop hypotheses regarding the links between tax preparer type and aggressive tax transactions. 9 Although technically the corporation must always sign the tax return, the absence (presence) of a paid preparer signature implies that the compliance work is predominantly executed internally (externally). We use this fact in our research design. 10 The tax partner at a large accounting firm stated to one of the authors that if a client wants his firm to sign the tax return, his firm has to be “comfortable that it has substantially impacted the development of the return. If we are signing the return, we have to feel in good conscience that the return is properly prepared. We will not sign a return that we have not substantially worked on, and similarly, if we have substantially worked on the return, we cannot duck the responsibility by not signing the tax return.” 11 3. Hypothesis Development 3.1 USING AN EXTERNAL TAX RETURN PREPARER The effect of a company’s tax preparer on its tax positions is an important, but understudied area of corporate decision making. Recently, Neuman et al. (2011) explore the not-forprofit sector where the identity of the tax preparer is publicly disclosed. In tests relating paid preparer type and donations (their measure of credibility), they find that external preparers are positively associated with donations. They interpret this evidence to suggest that the public views self-prepared returns as less credible. McGuire et al. (2011) explore the role of expertise in tax aggressiveness. They find a positive relation between tax aggressiveness and the use of expert tax providers, where expertise is based on the proportion of all tax fees paid to auditors in the industry-city of the client.11 In particular, firms paying tax-related fees to an auditor who is also a tax expert have lower effective tax rates (ETR) and higher book-tax differences, and marginally lower cash ETR and marginally higher discretionary permanent book-tax differences, consistent with such firms being more tax aggressive. To guide our predictions as to when firms choose among preparing their tax return internally or engaging their auditor or another external provider, we explore the theoretical model of Phillips and Sansing (1998) (hereafter PS). PS analyze the effects of external tax preparers in the tax compliance of a firm. The focus of their study is on the effects of requiring a fixed fee for compliance work, rather than a contingent fee based on the filing position. PS conclude that a fixed fee contract, relative to a contingent fee contract, raises the expected cost of tax return preparation, and leads to more taxpayers filing a favorable (aggressive) tax position, 11 Reichelt and Wang (2010) suggest expertise can also be measured at a national level. 12 increasing under-compliance overall. They also note that the use of a higher quality preparer will lead to greater observed tax aggressiveness. While not discussed in their paper, the PS model can also provide predictions for the relation between using an external preparer and the aggressiveness of firms’ tax positions. In their model, taxpayers are endowed with an exogenous, unobservable aversion to enduring a tax audit adjustment (that is, an aversion to having a tax position reversed on audit). They use the parameter λ to denote this characteristic. Thus, firms can be sorted along this dimension, with lower values of λ denoting firms that are inherently less sensitive to audit adjustments and more willing to be tax aggressive (i.e., tax aggressive taxpayers use favorable tax positions when the outcome of a tax audit is uncertain, ex ante). Use of an external tax preparer reduces uncertainty over the legitimacy of uncertain tax positions. In a first-best solution (subscripted ‘FB’), where the taxpayer does not need to motivate the tax preparer to work, taxpayers with λ below a critical value, λ FB, report the favorable position (more aggressive) when the preparer remains uncertain, whereas those above the critical value report the unfavorable position (more conservative) when uncertainty remains.12 With the need to motivate the preparer to investigate the appropriate treatment and to report as desired by the taxpayer, the critical value, λ FF, is higher than λ FB (with ‘FF’ denoting the use of a fixed fee contract for the external advisor). Thus, more taxpayers report aggressively because more taxpayers have λ values less than the critical value. One can also allow the possibility for internally prepared tax returns. In this case, it can be shown that the point of divide between reporting aggressively versus conservatively is equal 12 In Phillips and Sansing (1998), taxpayers above the critical value (who are labeled conservative) only report the favorable tax position if the tax preparer’s research reveals that the favorable position will withstand audit. If the audit outcome is uncertain, they will report the unfavorable position. Taxpayers below the threshold (who are labeled aggressive) will report the favorable position if the outcome is uncertain and will only report the unfavorable position if the preparer’s research shows the position will not withstand an audit. 13 to the first-best critical value. Thus, with no external preparers, taxpayers with λ < λ FB will not choose to use an external preparer, and always report the favorable (aggressive) position.13 In the intermediary case, where λ FB < λ < λ FF, the taxpayer will never report the favorable position without the use of an external preparer. However, with an external preparer, the taxpayer will report the favorable position unless the knowledgeable external professional discovers that the favorable position will be overturned on audit. With the availability of an external preparer, taxpayers below λ FB will trade off the greater certainty that the knowledgeable external preparer provides with the fees charged by such a preparer. Depending on the parameters of the setting, there will be a critical value, λ* , below which an external preparer is not hired, and above which an external preparer is used. Thus, in cases with (1) low values of λ , (2) lower audit probabilities or (3) lower tax benefit to the favorable position, it is value maximizing to self-prepare because the expected benefit arising from the higher probability of certainty does not exceed the fees paid to the preparer.14 In the conservative case, λ FF < λ , the taxpayer will also never report the favorable position without hiring a professional, but will report the favorable position when the external preparer is certain that the favorable position is correct. Thus, when λ* < λ , the taxpayer’s wealth is improved by hiring an external preparer because the expected benefit of reporting the favorable position some of the time exceeds the cost of the preparer. From this extension of the Phillips and Sansing (1998) model, the only situation in which the taxpayer will internally prepare is when the taxpayer’s sensitivity to reassessment is low (i.e., 13 We assume here that the taxpayer, in the absence of a paid preparer, has no tax knowledge on the issue at hand; however, the analysis holds for internal tax staff that is less knowledgeable than the external preparer. If the internal staff has some ability to discern the legitimacy of the position, the company will choose the favorable position except in the rare cases the internal analysis shows that the position will not withstand audit. 14 Anecdotal discussions with tax directors at two large publicly traded companies confirm this analysis. One reason their companies do not employ external preparers is because their transactions are complex enough that the cost of educating and managing a team of external preparers is not worth the potential benefit that the team might provide a better understanding of the merits of the company’s positions, i.e., the effect on the company’s tax uncertainties. 14 when λ < λ* ). In that case, the taxpayer always reports the favorable (aggressive) position. However, when hiring the external preparer is optimal for a particular taxpayer, the taxpayer either reports the favorable position or the unfavorable position depending on the findings of the professional’s research and the taxpayer’s underlying tolerance parameter (i.e., depending if λ* < λ < λ FF or if λ FF < λ ). Thus there is less aggressive reporting with an external preparer, on average. This leads us to our first hypothesis: H1: Tax returns filed without the assistance of an external preparer will be more aggressive than tax returns filed with the assistance of an external preparer, on average. Hypothesis H1 arises from the model of Phillips and Sansing (1998) using the assumption that the choice to hire an external preparer is endogenous to the model. However, it remains possible that the firm decides to hire a preparer for other reasons, and this decision is independent of the firm’s parameter λ .15 Whatever the other dimensions involved in the choice to self-prepare or to use an external preparer, it continues to be reasonable to assume that the external preparer is of higher quality than the internal staff (to justify the fees). If the decision to hire an external preparer is independent of λ and the external preparer is of higher quality than the internal staff, then consistent with the analysis in Phillips and Sansing (1998), the use of a higher-quality external provider would raise the threshold value of λ needed to claim aggressive tax positions. In this setting, conditional on hiring an external preparer, the taxpayer will, on average, be aggressive more often with an external preparer, contrary to hypothesis H1. 15 Firms that internally prepare tax returns might include those that are less sophisticated and resource constrained, such that they will not have the capability or talent to develop and execute aggressive tax planning strategies, resulting in less aggressive reporting overall, than for firms that engage an external preparer. 15 3.2 ROLE OF NON-AUDITOR PROVIDERS As described in the introduction, the use of auditors as tax advisors has been the subject of much research. This research suggests that firms choose to use, or not use, their auditor as a tax preparer for a variety of reasons (see, for example, Omer et al., 2006, and Lassila et al., 2010). Cripe and McAllister (2009) survey 42 CFOs about their decisions to use their auditor as a tax preparer. When asked for their primary reason why a firm would choose their auditor as their tax preparer, the most common response, at 48%, was lower cost. Alternatively, when firms who used a non-auditor external preparer were asked about the effect of this choice on fees, 31% identified that they pay higher fees by foregoing their auditor as tax preparer. So if, on average, and using a non-auditor for tax compliance is more costly, then to make this choice rational, the benefits of the external non-auditor preparer must exceed the incremental cost. One of the benefits will be that the external non-auditor preparer will be of higher quality, on average. Respondents to the Cripe and McAllister (2009) study identified non-auditor tax expertise as the second most popular reason for choosing to acquire their audit and tax preparer services from separate providers.16 Even if this is not the main reason to choose another preparer, when choosing among the alternative firms, we assume that the highest quality preparer is most likely to be chosen. Thus, given that an external, high quality preparer is chosen, on average, the non-auditor external preparer will be of higher quality than the auditor.17 16 Auditor independence was the most popular response which is not surprising as the survey was conducted in early 2007 shortly after new PCAOB rules on auditor provided tax services were introduced. 17 For example, assume that there are four preparers possible, denoted A, B, C, and D in order of quality for a given industry, location, etc. For each taxpayer, one is the auditor. If the taxpayer does not use the auditor, we assume it always chooses the highest quality preparer among the remaining three choices. In this case, only audit clients of A will choose a non-auditor preparer that is of lower quality (that is, B). However, clients of all other firms will choose A, a higher quality tax preparer than their auditor. Given the relatively even distribution of companies among the major audit firms, on average, the non-auditor preparer will be of higher quality than the auditor. 16 If we consider non-auditor preparers to generally have greater ability, the threshold between what Phillips and Sansing (1998) refer to as “aggressive taxpayers” versus those labeled “conservative taxpayers” is increasing in the ability of the tax preparer. In their model, the higher quality preparers allow marginal taxpayers to report aggressively because reducing the likelihood that the filing position is uncertain allows more taxpayers to overcome the trade-off between receiving the expected benefits of the favorable (aggressive) reporting position and suffering the expected cost of being overturned on audit. As discussed above, McGuire et al. (2011) study the importance of expertise on tax aggressiveness. Their empirical work is consistent with a positive relation between using an expert for tax work and the aggressiveness of the tax position. McGuire et al. (2011) follow extant research by classifying accounting firms as tax experts if the reported tax fees paid to that firm (for audit clients) are “high” in the metropolitan area, where “high” is defined as greater than 30% of reported audit and non-audit fees. One shortcoming of this measure is that only fees paid to auditors are considered because these are the only fees that are publicly disclosed. Because we can directly observe the compliance work through the tax return signatures, we can further refine this literature by classifying a tax preparer as an expert if the external preparer is not the auditor, as suggested by Cripe and McAllister (2009). Thus, we extend our analysis by further delineating the external tax preparers into auditors and non-auditors, while still estimating the effects of internally preparing the tax returns. Thus, assuming non-auditors are experts on average, the predictions of Phillips and Sansing (1998) lead to the hypothesis below: H2: Tax returns filed with the assistance of an external preparer who is not the firm’s auditor will, on average, be more aggressive than tax returns filed with the assistance of the firm’s auditor. 17 4. Method 4.1 RESEARCH DESIGN We design our empirical tests to examine whether tax returns filed without an external preparer or with a non-auditor external preparer will be more aggressive than tax returns filed with the assistance of an external preparer. We alternately estimate regressions of the logged FIN 48 tax reserve ending balance (Log_UTB_EB) on INTERNAL_PREP, OTHER_PREP, and control variables for firm i at time t as follows:18 β0 + β1 INTERNAL_PREPit + β2 OTHER_PREPit + β3 LOG_ASSETSit + β4 PRETAX_ROAit Log_UTB_EBit = + β5 FOR_INCOMEit + β6 NOLit + β7 R&Dit + β8 LEVERAGEit + β9 YR2008it + (1) 16 ∑ βkIndit + eit k =9 We define the model variables in the Appendix. We use Log_UTB_EB as our proxy for tax aggressiveness because Lisowsky, Robinson, and Schmidt (2011) find that it is a reliable proxy for corporate tax aggressiveness, namely tax shelters disclosed as reportable transactions (obtained from the tax return). A key reason underlying their finding is that both tax shelters and the FIN 48 tax reserve (UTB) contain information on tax benefits at the extreme end of the tax avoidance continuum, regardless if the transactions conform or do not conform between financial and tax reporting. Supporting this notion, they find that the UTB is the only key variable from the tax avoidance literature that contains information on tax shelter use because the other measures focus on a set (or even subset) of non-conforming transactions only. In particular, Lisowsky, et al. (2011) compare the 18 Since our sample period is short (2008-2009), we follow Petersen (2009) and cluster the standard errors by firm and include a 2008 time indicator variable in all of our regressions. All regressions also include industry fixed effects at the one-digit SIC code level. We winsorize continuous variables at the 1st and 99th percentiles to mitigate the effect of outliers. We employ both OLS and Tobit to ensure that the 154 firms with zero values in the dependent variable do not alter our inferences. 18 explanatory power of the logged UTB to the GAAP effective tax rate (Rego 2003), cash effective tax rate (Dyreng, et al. 2008), total book-tax differences (Mills 1998), permanent book-tax differences, and discretionary permanent book-tax differences (Frank, et al. 2009), and find that the non-UTB measures—either alone or together, and with or without the UTB—are not associated with tax shelter use. Lisowsky, et al. (2011) also demonstrate that the information on tax aggressiveness contained in the UTB is not eliminated due to reporting discretion arising from non-tax factors, such as financial reporting preferences (Hanlon and Heitzman 2010), corporate governance mechanisms (Desai and Dharmapala 2006), independent auditor certification process (Gleason and Mills 2011), capital market incentives to manage earnings (Gupta, et al. 2011), and tax director compensation (Armstrong, et al. 2011). They conclude that the tax reserve itself, even if subject to managerial discretion about reporting aggressiveness or conservatism, is a reliable proxy for the aggressiveness of the underlying tax position claimed on the firm’s tax return. Therefore, following advice in Hanlon and Heitzman (2010) to carefully select the tax aggressiveness proxy to suit the particular research question and empirical evidence in Lisowsky, et al. (2011), we employ the ending balance UTB to examine the relation between preparer type and tax aggressiveness. The favorable positions modeled in Phillips and Sansing (1998) are those with material benefit and uncertainty, and we therefore view UTB as the closest approximation of this construct. Our first independent variable of interest is INTERNAL_PREP, equal to one if the firm does not use an external tax preparer. Because hypothesis H1 seeks to examine the relative aggressiveness of internal preparers over external ones, we specify INTERNAL_PREP as our test 19 variable. If tax returns filed without an external preparer are more aggressive than those filed with the assistance of the auditor, β1 will have a positive sign.19 We are also interested in the relation between tax aggressiveness and other external preparers, as specified in hypothesis H2. We include OTHER_PREP to examine the relation between using an external preparer that is not the firm’s auditor, rather than the firm’s auditor, to explain tax aggressiveness. To do so, we specify OTHER_PREP as equal to one if the external tax preparer is not the firm’s auditor, zero otherwise. We expect the coefficient on OTHER_PREP, β2, will have a positive sign. We draw on prior literature regarding investments in tax planning (Mills, et al. 1998), auditor-provided tax services (McGuire, et al. 2011), and tax reserves (Lisowsky, et al. 2011) to select our control variables. They include firm size (LOG_ASSETS), profitability (PRETAX_ROA), foreign income (FOR_INCOME), existence of net operating losses (NOL), research and development activities (R&D), and debt burden (LEVERAGE). We expect positive coefficients on all the control variables. In the hypothesis development, the choice to use an external preparer and the tax positions taken by the taxpayer were both related to characteristics of the firm. Further, the choice to use the auditor, versus other options (internally prepare or use another tax provider) may relate to firm characteristics that also affect the aggressiveness of the firm’s tax positions. Thus, to estimate equation (1), we explicitly model the endogeneity of this multiple-alternative preparer choice. To do so, we employ a treatment-effects model (see, for example, Greene, 19 Hypothesis H1 is motivated by internal versus external preparers, but to jointly test H1 and H2, we use the auditprepared firm-years as the base group in both tests. In untabulated regressions without OTHER_PREP, the coefficient on INTERNAL_PREP is approximately 60% as large but continues to be statistically significant at the 5% level. 20 2008), as extended by Deb and Trivedi (2006) to a multinomial treatment. To summarize their work, the firm has an indirect utility, EV*, associated with the jth choice of preparer: EVij* = zi′ α j + δ j1 li1 + δ j2 li2 + ηij EVi0* is assumed to be zero for the base choice, j = 0, and zi are exogenous covariates with parameters α. EV* includes latent factors lik which incorporate unobserved characteristics common to firm i’s preparer choice and the outcome, yi (observed tax aggressiveness). η is an i.i.d. error term. If dij are binary variables representing the observed choice of preparer of firm i, then di = [di1, di2], with the probability of the choice represented as ( ) ( Pr di zi ,l i = g zi′ α1 + δ11 l11 + δ12 l12 , zi′ α 2 + δ 21 l21 + δ 22 l22 ) g is a multinomial probability function. Finally, the outcome equation for firm i, formulated in linear form, is yi = x i′ β + γ 1 di1 + γ 2 di2 + λ1 li1 + λ2 li2 + ε i This model can be estimated, as described in Deb and Trivedi (2006), using maximum simulated likelihood estimation.20 To implement this model in our setting, we identify the choices as 0 if the preparer is the auditor (the base alternative), di = [1, 0] if the firm does not use an external preparer (i.e., INTERNAL_PREP = 1), and di = [0, 1] if the preparer is an external preparer other than the auditor (i.e., OTHER_PREP = 1). In addition to the exogenous variables from equation (1), namely firm characteristics (size, profitability, foreign income, NOL, R&D, and leverage), year, and one-digit SIC industry code, we include NON_TAX_FEE as an additional variable in the choice equation. NON_TAX_FEE is the fees paid to the auditor for services other than audit and 20 Stata uses this estimation approach in its mtreatreg procedure. 21 tax, deflated by the total non-tax fees paid to the auditor. NON_TAX_FEE is a measure of the willingness of the firm to use the auditor for non-audit services and has been used in, for example, Omer et al. (2011) in a similar choice equation. We anticipate that the coefficient on NON_TAX_FEE will be negative for both selection equations because greater reluctance to use the auditor for other services will lead to higher likelihood of internally preparing or using another external preparer (i.e., not using the auditor for tax services).21 4.2 SAMPLE SELECTION We obtain data from four sources: (1) FIN 48 tax reserve (UTB) data from the IRS Large Business & International Division (LB&I);22 (2) tax return preparer identity from IRS-LB&I; (3) financial statement data from Compustat; and (4) auditor identity, audit fee, and tax fee data from Audit Analytics. We determine the sample used for our analysis in several steps. First, we obtain the intersection of LB&I and Compustat data during 2008-2009, consisting of 10,881 firm-years.23 Second, we obtain IRS data on tax preparer identity from the face of the U.S. corporate income tax return, Form 1120, for a restricted set of 805 calendar year-end firms in the S&P 1500 as of the end of 2008.24 We are able to identify the tax preparer by name and tax identification number (PTIN) in the “Paid Preparer” signature area; if preparer information is 21 We confirm that this variable does not have a statistically significant coefficient when also included in the main regression (equation (1)). We also included a variety of other variables in the first stage, including other aggressiveness measures such as Cash ETR; other firm attributes such as the corporate governance G-Score, stock exchange listing, and IRS audit probability; and auditor characteristics such as Big 4, each Big 4 firm individually, and audit fees. The coefficient on none of these variables were statistically significant, either when included alone or together. For parsimony, we only include NON_TAX_FEE in tabulated tests. 22 The UTB ending balance is also available to empirical researchers from a public data source (i.e., Compustat mnemonic TXTUBEND) or can be retrieved from financial statement footnotes. As in Lisowsky, et al. (2011), we use LB&I data because they undergo several layers of review, and are believed to be highly accurate. Confirming this point, Lisowsky, et al. (2011) report that the correlation between the authors’ hand-collected UTB ending balances and the amounts collected by LB&I (Compustat) is 0.96 (0.86). 23 Specifically, we obtain 5,539 (5,342) firm-years when intersecting LB&I and Compustat data for 2008 (2009). 24 Access to Form 1120 data is more restricted than access to the UTB data because the former is confidential while the latter can be obtained from other sources. Therefore, IRS non-disclosure agreements allowed us to only merge 805 (785) calendar year end S&P 1500 firms (excluding REITS) in 2008 (2009). 22 missing, we assign the firm’s tax return as being internally prepared.25 We then merge the LB&I FIN 48/Form 1120 data with Compustat and Audit Analytics over the same years, yielding a final test sample of 1,533 firm-years with non-missing observations for all of our multivariate analyses. 5. Main Results 5.1 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS Table 3 Panel A presents descriptive statistics for the tax preparers in our sample. In our sample of 1,533 firm-years, 690 (45 percent) of the tax returns are externally prepared, of which 545 (145) are prepared by Big 4 (non-Big 4) accounting firms. The remaining 843 (55 percent) are internally prepared. The proportions of externally and internally prepared returns are consistent from 2008 to 2009, and reflect our survey results that most tax compliance work is done in-house. Also consistent with the survey results is how large our sample firms are that internally prepare their tax returns, with mean (median) assets of $24.8 ($5.9) billion, compared to firms with externally prepared tax returns, either by Big 4 firms (mean [median] assets are $8.9 [$1.8] billion) or non-Big 4 firms (mean [median] assets are $5.3 [$1.1] billion). The descriptive statistics suggest that firms internally preparing their tax returns are well-resourced, and likely sophisticated enough to not exhibit demand for outside tax preparer expertise, even if it is a Big 4 preparer. [Insert Table 3 about here] 25 The IRS employee within LB&I supplying the tax preparer data confirmed that missing preparer information on the Form 1120 is consistent with internally prepared tax returns rather than the external tax preparer omitting its information for whatever reason. This fact reflects that a corporate officer must always sign the tax return, whether an external preparer is used or not. Therefore, the internal preparation of the tax return is determined by the absence of a paid preparer signature. See Section 2.2 for further details. 23 In Table 3 Panel B, we report the count of internally and externally prepared tax returns by outside auditor (note that each firm in our sample is publicly traded and requires a financial statement audit). The diagonal values (bolded) in this Panel highlight where the auditor is also the tax preparer. For example, of the 415 company financial statements that Firm A audits during our sample period, 275 self-prepare their tax returns, 71 hire Firm A to also prepare the tax return (i.e., auditor-provided tax service), and the remaining 69 firms hire an external tax preparer that is not Firm A.26 Examining the data from a different perspective, Firm A is the tax preparer for 128 firmyears in our sample, meaning that they prepare tax returns for 57 non-audit firm-years (128 minus 71), of which 17 are audited by Firm B, 25 by Firm C, 10 by Firm D, and 4 by Firm F. The Panel suggests that auditor-provided tax services highlighted as the bolded diagonal values are the most common combination for externally prepared tax returns, at least for Big 4 users. However, the greatest incidence of firms prepares their returns internally without the help of an external auditor or non-auditor. In summary, Panel B reports that 312 firm-year tax returns are prepared externally by the firm’s auditors (i.e., the sum of the bolded diagonal values); 378 firm-year tax returns are prepared by an external preparer that is not the auditor (i.e., the sum of the non-bolded, offdiagonal values, not including internally prepared); and 843 firm-year tax returns are prepared internally, of which 829 use Big 4 firms as their auditor and 14 use non-Big 4 firms as their auditors. These results are interesting in that we observe that auditor-provided tax services are by far the minority of prepared tax returns. 26 Due to confidentiality agreements, we are unable to name the paid preparer, so we use the more generic terms “Firm A,” “Firm B,” and so forth to denote the external preparers (who may or may not also be the corporation’s auditor). We are also unable to disclose counts that are less than three; we denote these values as “ND” in the tables. Although it would be interesting to examine the time-series trends in tax preparer use, especially before and after the passage of Sarbanes-Oxley (SOX), unfortunately our data are limited to analyzing cross-sectional relations only. 24 In Table 3 Panel C, we also report the industry composition for the three types of preparers. In each industry, the internally prepared return is the most common. In five (three) of the disclosed eight industries, the next most common combination is for the external preparer to not be the auditor (to be the auditor). Again, the majority of firms do not employ their auditors to provide tax services. Table 4 Panel A reports descriptive statistics for our dependent variable, control variables, and other audit and tax fee-related data. The mean (median) raw UTB ending balance is $97.98 ($16.35) million, or 1.1% (0.60%) of total assets. The mean (median) total assets for our sample is $17.4 ($3.4) billion, which is consistent with our sample composition of large, publicly traded firms. On average, the firms are profitable (mean [median] Pretax ROA of 4.7% [6.2%]), but with foreign operations in only a limited number of firms (mean [median] scaled Foreign Income of 1.7% [0%]). A large share of firms—45%—report net operation loss carryforwards, indicative of the economic crisis during the sample period. R&D activities are, as typically the case, also concentrated in a limited number of firms (mean [median] R&D of 2.4% [0%]), and debt levels show mean (median) values of 19.6% (17.3%) of total assets. [Insert Table 4 about here] With respect to tax fee data disclosed by firms who engage their auditor for tax work, 80.6% of firms in our sample report positive tax fees paid to their auditors. Combined with our tax return preparer information, it appears that many firms do not have their tax return prepared by their auditor, although a vast majority of firms hire their auditor for some type of tax work, perhaps limited consulting as consistent by our survey results. Tax fees account for a mean (median) of $532,000 ($117,000), or 8.4% (4.8%) of total fees paid to auditors. 25 Table 4 Panel B reports related values, where pertinent, for the preparer groupings we examine in our study. Most notably, the raw and logged UTB ending balances are significantly higher for the internal tax department than for either of the external (is or is not auditor) groups, while the scaled values for the internal tax department and external non-auditor preparer are higher than the external auditor preparer. Finally, the correlation table in Panel C reports a significantly positive (negative) association between the UTB ending balance and the internally (externally) prepared tax returns, providing initial support for hypothesis H1. We also find significantly positive correlations between the UTB and OTHER_PREP suggesting support for hypothesis H2. 5.2 MULTIVARIATE RESULTS: HYPOTHESIS H1 AND H2 Table 5 presents the results of estimating Equation (1). We find significant results supporting hypothesis H1 that tax returns filed without the assistance of an external preparer are more aggressive than tax returns filed with the help of an external preparer, on average. In particular, the coefficient on INTERNAL_PREP is positive and significant in all specifications. In this setting, the OLS provides the most conservative estimates, in terms of the smallest coefficients and the lowest t-values. The estimate for the coefficient on INTERNAL_PREP using OLS is 0.29. This suggests that, relative to tax returns prepared by auditors, tax returns that are internally prepared have uncertain tax benefits that are 29% higher. Second, the coefficient estimate on INTERNAL_PREP using a Tobit estimation approach, which explicitly models the truncation of the UTB balance at zero, is 0.35. Third, when the estimates explicitly control for the endogeneity of the firm’s selection process using a multinomial treatment effect specification, the coefficient on INTERNAL_PREP is 0.67. Overall, these tests provide evidence 26 that not using an external preparer, relative to use the auditor as the tax preparer, is associated with an increase in UTB balance from between 29% and 67%. [Insert Table 5 about here] Table 5 concurrently presents the results of estimating whether an external non-auditor preparer, rather than the auditor, is related to greater tax aggressiveness. We find evidence supportive of H2 that tax returns filed with the assistance of a non-auditor external preparer will, on average, be more aggressive than tax returns filed with the assistance of other external preparers. Using both OLS and Tobit specifications, our tests yield significant and positive coefficients on OTHER_PREP, suggesting that outside, non-auditor preparer-experts are related to tax aggressiveness. The coefficient estimates on OTHER_PREP are smaller than those on INTERNAL_PREP, and range from 0.22 using OLS to 0.55 using the multinomial treatment effects model.27 The control variables, where significant, are in the expected directions; firm size (LOG_ASSETS), the share of foreign income (FOR_INCOME), existence of net operating losses (NOL), and research and development activities (R&D) are all increasing in the tax reserve, while profitability and leverage are not significantly related to the FIN 48 tax reserve. In the selection models, the non-tax fee ratio has a negative coefficient, statistically significant at the 10% level using a two-tailed test. This result confirms that firms less willing to use their auditor for services other than tax and audit are more likely to choose a non-auditor alternative preparer, either internally prepare or use another firm. Size and foreign income are also positive related to internal preparation, while R&D is negatively related. None of the equation (1) control variables are related to the choice to use a a tax preparer other than the audit firm for tax preparation. 27 A test of differences between the coefficients on INTERNAL_PREP and OTHER_PREP reveals they are not significantly different (significance levels range from 21% to 51% using two-tailed tests). 27 The results on INTERNAL_PREP and OTHER_PREP are the first that provide empirical evidence supportive of differences in tax aggressiveness across preparer type. Until now, researchers have been unable to definitively observe the preparer type to examine whether tax returns filed with the help of external preparers are more or less aggressive that those that are internally prepared. By using tax return data on preparer type, we are, for example, able to provide clear support that, as our survey results also suggest, internally prepared tax returns are indicative of tax departments that are linked to more aggressive tax positions. 6. Comparing Tax Return Data to 10-K Inferences on Tax Preparer Type Because tax preparer type is only observable from confidential tax returns, we examine the extent to which publicly available information can aid interested parties in inferring preparer type reported on the tax return. Specifically, we examine whether disclosures of auditor-provided tax service fee data in financial statements can provide a window onto tax preparers, and thus, tax compliance activities of the corporation. Since the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, firms are required to disclose in their financial statements audit and non-audit fees paid to their auditor. Although firms must disclose tax fees paid to their auditors, they are not required to disclose fees paid to non-auditors, or for that matter, whether the tax return is prepared in-house and what resources are used to do so. Because of this limitation, outside researchers can only observe the dichotomous outcome of whether the firm’s auditor does or does not receive a fee for tax services. This information is then used to analyze the propensity to engage, retain, or dismiss the auditor as the tax service provider (e.g., Lassila, et al. 2010; Omer, et al. 2006; and McGuire, et al. 2011). Of course, information on whether the provider for tax services other than the auditor is either a non-auditor or the internal 28 tax department—and whether “services” have to do with compliance or planning—have until now been unobservable in a corporate setting.28 Because we can observe the identity of the tax preparer, we design an archival experiment that compares how the accuracy of preparer type classification using tax fees versus tax returns might affect our established inferences about tax aggressiveness. To begin, we re-specify Equation (1) by creating one variable, NONAUD_PREP_TR, that combines the INTERNAL_PREP and OTHER_PREP firms into one proxy for non-audit tax service provider that we can observe directly from tax returns. This re-specification of the preparer variable of interest exactly mirrors the dichotomous specification using the tax fee data as to whether the firm uses (or does not use) the auditor as the tax service provider. As in all of our previous specifications, we leave the auditor tax service provider as the reference category and continue to employ the same firm characteristics, year, and industry control variables. Table 8 Panel A reports our replication of previous results using the modified Equation (1). As expected, we continue to obtain a significantly positive sign on NON_AUD_PREP_TR, indicating that tax service providers that are not the auditor (i.e., either external non-auditors or internal tax departments) are linked to greater tax aggressiveness. These results in Panel A based on tax return classification of preparer type serve as our benchmark case. Using a similar approach when specifying our variable of interest, we then designate the variable NON_AUD_PREP_10K as capturing whether the auditor does not provide tax services to the client; this variable equals one if tax fees disclosed in the financial statements are equal to zero; 0 otherwise. As reported in Panel B as “Case 1,” we re-estimate our modified Equation (1), 28 As noted above, Neuman, et al. (2011) are able to observe the choice of non-auditor tax service provider for notfor-profit organizations because the IRS Form 990 is publicly available. However, data access limitations to corporate tax returns preclude them from evaluating the for-profit sector as we do here. 29 but find no significant relation between this financial statement-based variable and tax aggressiveness. [Insert Table 8 about here] Because using a non-zero tax fee might unnecessarily designate firms that use their auditor very little for tax services as similar to those that use their auditors for large amounts of tax services, we designate several cut-off values on the size of the ratio of tax fees to total fees paid to the auditor (or “tax fee ratio”). Specifically, we designate a new variable in “Case 2” of Panel B as NON_AUDIT_PREP_10K_1% equal to one if the firm discloses a tax fee ratio of less than or equal to 1%, zero otherwise. We re-estimate the modified Equation (1) and again obtain no significant results. In successive specifications, we continue to increase the tax fee ratio cut-off at less than or equal to 5%, 10%, 25%, and 50% when defining our non-auditor preparer variables of interest. In every case, the results are either not significant (10% and 50% designations) or significantly negative (5% and 25% designations). These results are in stark contrast to those obtained from using tax preparer data directly observable from tax returns. We repeat these specifications at levels less than or equal to 2%, 3%, 4%, 15%, 20%, 30%, 35%, 40%, 45%, and 55%, but to no avail (untabulated). Not once do the results using the presence or magnitude of the tax fee yield inferences that are consistent with our original results using tax preparer designations directly from the tax return. In Table 8 Panel C, we report error rates inherent in using public tax fee data in our sample to classify the preparer type as either non-auditor (Non_Aud_Prep) or auditor (Aud_Prep). Recall that our data report that 1,221 firm-years do not use their auditor to prepare the tax return, while 312 do. Using these figures as benchmarks, we report for each tax fee ratio 30 cut-off the number and percent of firms that are correctly and incorrectly classified by preparer type. For example, using NON_AUD_PREP_10K_1% derived from the tax fee data classifies 428 firm-years as having a non-auditor preparer, while 1,105 firm-years are classified as having an auditor preparer. Of the 428, 412 indeed have a non-auditor tax preparer as reported on the tax return. Of the 1,105, only 296 indeed have an auditor-preparer as reported on the tax return. These figures illustrate that of the 1,533 total firm-year observations in our sample, only 708 (46.2%) are correctly classified into the two auditor and non-auditor preparer groups. In particular, using the tax fees, sixteen firm-years are incorrectly classified as using nonauditor preparers, since per the tax return, they are in fact using auditor preparers; and an astonishing 809 firm-years are classified as having an auditor preparer, when in fact they use non-auditor preparers as confirmed by the tax return. These figures illustrate that of the 1,533 firm-year observations, 825 (53.8%) are incorrectly classified. To be sure, the classification accuracy improves as the cut-off values increase (because increasing sample sizes ensnare enough correct tax preparer types). However, the fee data continue to incorrectly classify between 20 and 62 percent of firm-year observations. Overall, our archival experiment implies that using tax fee data to classify the tax preparer as the auditor (or not the auditor) is not only materially inaccurate, it is inaccurate enough to yield starkly different inferences from tests that are otherwise designed exactly the same way. As a corollary, we demonstrate that using tax return data is materially beneficial in our setting when drawing stable conclusions about links between preparer type, expertise, and tax aggressiveness. Admittedly, the original aim of this exercise was to provide guidance to researchers when using tax fees to help them infer tax preparer type, and thus compliance activities of the firm. However, the implication that tax fees are not informative of tax 31 compliance activities, namely the preparation of the tax return, suggests that researchers must remain cautious when drawing inferences on the type of services supplied by tax providers when tax fee data are used as the basis for such an analysis. 7. Conclusion Our study examines companuies’ choices regarding advisors for their tax compliance work and how these decisions relate to companies’ tax positions. We survey 170 tax executives from the Tax Executives Institute (TEI) to determine firms’ strategies for tax compliance. The survey reveals that 20% of companies do not use any external firm for compliance work, 16% use their auditors only, 52% use another type of consultant (either an accounting firm that is not their auditor, or another type of provider), and 12% use both their auditor and other providers. The survey also reveals that external providers perform only 30% of compliance work, and external providers are used for a similar percentage of planning work. We then test whether the choice of tax preparer type—whether internal, external auditor, or external non-auditor—is related to the aggressiveness of positions claimed on a firm’s tax return, as suggested by theory in Phillips and Sansing (1998). Using confidential data obtained from the IRS on who signs a firm’s tax return, we find a positive and significant relation between tax aggressiveness and not using an external tax preparer or using an external non-auditor preparer, compared to using an auditor preparer. Finally, we find that tax fees paid to a firm’s auditors as publicly disclosed in a firm’s securities filings are unable to reliably measure the tax compliance and preparation activities of the firm, namely the identity of the tax preparer. In particular, we estimate that the tax fee data incorrectly classify between 20 and 62 percent of firms into tax preparer types that do not match those reported on a firm’s tax return. This finding 32 should caution other researchers when attempting to use the tax fee data to infer the tax compliance attributes of firms. Our findings are important given the paucity of archival research on tax preparers generally. We make a significant contribution to the literature by better understanding this important part of the U.S. tax system and companies’ decision making. Specifically, we are the first to document the identity, distribution, and attributes of tax return preparers for a large sample of U.S. companies. This analysis helps us evaluate the compliance responsibilities and implications surrounding business transactions, and examine the extent to which companies employ internal tax specialists and/or hire external advisory firms. We are also the first study to provide empirical archival evidence in support of theoretical predictions in Phillips and Sansing (1998) concerning the relation between tax preparers and tax aggressiveness. Documenting the effect of the tax preparer in corporate tax compliance decisions with respect to tax aggressiveness is of interest to tax authorities, tax service providers, corporate tax executives, and tax researchers, as the archival literature remains largely silent on the role of the corporate tax preparer and its effect on compliance. 33 APPENDIX Variable Definitions Variable Dependent Variable Log_UTB_EB Definition = The natural log of (1 + UTB), where UTB = Ending balance (in $millions) of the FIN 48 unrecognized tax benefit (UTB). Source: IRS-LB&I. Tax Preparer and Expert Measures INTERNAL_PREP = 1 if the firm’s Form 1120 tax return is not signed by an external preparer; 0 otherwise. Source: IRS-LB&I. OTHER_PREP = 1 if the firm’s Form 1120 tax return is signed by an external preparer that is not the firm’s external auditor; 0 otherwise. Source: IRSLB&I, Audit Analytics. Control Variables LOG_ASSETS PRETAX_ROA FOR_INCOME NOL R&D LEVERAGE NON-TAX FEE RATIO = The natural log of Total Assets (AT). Source: Compustat. = The ratio of Pretax Income (PI) / Total Assets (AT). Source: Compustat. = The ratio of Foreign Pretax Income (PIFO) / Total Assets (AT). Source: Compustat. = Indicator variable equal to one if Tax Loss Carry Forward (TLCF) is non-zero; 0 otherwise. Source: Compustat. = The ratio of R&D Expense (XRD) / Total Assets (AT). Source: Compustat. = The ratio of Long-Term Debt (DLTT) / Total Assets (AT). Source: Compustat. = The ratio of fees paid to the auditor for services other than tax or audit, divided by fees paid to the auditor for services other than tax. Source: Audit Analytics. 34 REFERENCES ABBOTT, L., S. PARKER, G. PETERS, AND K. RAGHUNANDAN. “An Empirical Investigation of Audit Fees, Nonaudit Fees, and Audit Committees.” Contemporary Accounting Research 20 (2) (2003): 215-34. ARMSTRONG, C., J. BLOUIN, AND D. LARCKER. “The Incentives for Tax Planning.” Journal of Accounting and Economics (2011): forthcoming. ASHBAUGH, H., R. LAFOND, AND B. MAYHEW. “Do Non-Audit Services Compromise Auditor Independence? Further Evidence.” The Accounting Review 78 (3) (2003): 611-39. CHRISTIAN, C., S. GUPTA, AND S. LIN. “Determinants of Tax Preparer Usage: Evidence from Panel Data.” National Tax Journal 46 (1993): 487-503. CHUNG, H., AND KALLAPUR, S. “Client Importance, Nonaudit Services, and Abnormal Accruals.” The Accounting Review 78 (2003): 931-55. COOK, K., G. RYAN HUSTON, AND T. OMER.”Earnings Management through Effective Tax Rates: The Effects of Tax-Planning Investment and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002.” Contemporary Accounting Research 25 (2): 447-71. CRIPE, B., AND B. MCALLISTER. “Determinants of Audit/Tax Separation Decisions.” American Journal of Business 24 (2009): 47-56. DAVIS, L., D. RICCHIUTE, AND G. TROMPETER. “Audit Effort, Audit Fees, and the Provision of Nonaudit Services to Audit Clients.” The Accounting Review 68 (1) (1993): 135-50. DEB, P., AND P.K. TRIVEDI, “Specification and Simulated Likelihood Estimation of a Nonnormal Treatment Outcome Model with Selection: Application to Health Care Utilization,” Econometrics Journal 9 (2) (2006): 307-331. DEFOND, M., K. RAGHUNANDAN, AND K. SUBRAMANYAM. “Do Non-Audit Service Fees Impair Auditor Independence? Evidence from Going Concern Audit Opinions.” Journal of Accounting Research 40 (4) (2002): 1247-74. DESAI, M., AND D. DHARMAPALA. “Corporate Tax Avoidance and High-Powered Incentives.” Journal of Financial Economics 79 (2006): 145-79. DYRENG, S., M. HANLON, AND E. MAYDEW. “Long-Run Corporate Tax Avoidance.” The Accounting Review 83 (2008): 61-82. FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD (FASB). Statement of Financial Accounting Standards (SFAS) No. 109, Accounting for Income Taxes. Norwalk, CT (1992). 35 FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD (FASB). Financial Interpretation No. 48 (FIN 48), Accounting for Uncertainty in Income Taxes—an Interpretation of FASB Statement No. 109. Norwalk, CT (2006). FRANCIS, J., AND B. KE. “Disclosure of Fees Paid to Auditors and the Market Valuation of Earnings Surprises.” Review of Accounting Studies 11 (2006): 495-523. FRANK, M. M., L. LYNCH, AND S. REGO. “Tax Reporting Aggressiveness and Its Relation to Aggressive Financial Reporting.” The Accounting Review 84 (2009): 467-96. FRANKEL, R., M. JOHNSON, AND K. NELSON. “The Relation between Auditors’ Fees for Nonaudit Services and Earnings Management.” The Accounting Review 77 (Supplement) (2002): 71105. GLEASON, C., AND L. MILLS. “Do Auditor-Provided Tax Services Improve the Estimate of Tax Reserves?” Contemporary Accounting Research, forthcoming 2011. GRAHAM, J., M. HANLON, AND T. SHEVLIN. “Inside the Corporate Tax Department: Insights on Corporate Decision Making and Tax Aggressiveness.” Working paper, 2011. GRAHAM, J., AND C. HARVEY. “The Theory and Practice of Corporate Finance: Evidence from the Field.” Journal of Financial Economics 60 (2001): 187-243. GUPTA, S., R. LAUX, AND D. LYNCH. “Do Firms Use Tax Cushion Reversals to Meet Earnings Targets?” Working paper, 2011. HANLON, M., AND S. HEITZMAN. “A Review of Tax Research.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (2010): 127-178. HITE, P. AND G. MCGILL. “An Examination of Taxpayer Preference for Aggressive Tax Advice.” National Tax Journal 45 (4) (1992): 389-403. KINNEY, W., JR., Z.-V. PALMROSE, AND S. SCHOLZ. “Auditor Independence, Non-Audit Services, and Restatements: Was the U.S. Government Right?” Journal of Accounting Research 42 (June) (2004): 561–88. LARCKER, D., AND S. RICHARDSON. “Fees Paid to Audit Firms, Accrual Choices, and Corporate Governance.” Journal of Accounting Research 42 (3) (2004): 625-58. LASSILA, D., T. OMER, M. SHELLEY, AND L. SMITH. “Do Complexity, Governance, and Auditor Independence Influence Whether Firms Retain Their Auditors for Tax Services?” Journal of the American Taxation Association 32 (Spring) (2010): 1–23. LIM, C-Y., AND H-T. TAN. “Non-audit Service Fees and Audit Quality: The Impact of Auditor Specialization.” Journal of Accounting Research 46 (1) (2008): 199-246. 36 LISOWSKY, P., L. ROBINSON, AND A. SCHMIDT. “Do Publicly Disclosed Tax Reserves Tell Us About Privately Disclosed Tax Shelter Activity?” Working paper, 2011. LONG, J., AND S. CAUDHILL. “The Usage and Benefit of Paid Tax Return Preparation.” National Tax Journal 40 (1987): 35-46. MAYDEW, E. AND D.SHACKELFORD. “The Changing Role of Auditors in Corporate Tax Planning.” In Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century, edited by Auerbach, A., J. Hines, and J. Slemrod. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. (2007): 307-34. MCGUIRE, S., T. OMER, AND D. WANG. “Tax Avoidance: Does Tax-Specific Industry Expertise Make a Difference?” The Accounting Review (2011): forthcoming. MILLS, L. “Book-Tax Differences and Internal Revenue Service Adjustments.” Journal of Accounting Research 36 (1998): 343-56. MILLS, L., M. ERICKSON, AND E. MAYDEW. “Investments in Tax Planning.” Journal of the American Taxation Association 20 (1) (1998): 1-20. MILLS, L., L. ROBINSON, AND R. SANSING. “FIN 48 and Tax Compliance.” The Accounting Review 85 (5) (2010): 1721-42. NEUMAN, S., T. OMER, AND A. THOMPSON. “Competition for Non-Audit Services among Professional Services Firms: Determinants and Consequences of Tax Service Provider Choice in the Not-for-Profit Sector.” Working Paper, 2011. OMER, T., J. BEDARD, AND D. FALSETTA. “Auditor-Provided Tax Services: The Effects of a Changing Regulatory Environment.” The Accounting Review 81 (October) (2006): 10951117. PETERSEN, M. “Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets: Comparing Approaches.” Review of Financial Studies 22 (2009): 435-80. PHILLIPS, J., AND R. SANSING. “Contingent Fees and Tax Compliance.” The Accounting Review 73 (1) (1998): 1-18. PITTMAN, J., AND S. FORTIN. “Auditor Choice and the Cost of Debt Capital for Newly Public Firms.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 37 (2004): 113-36. REICHELT, K., AND D. WANG. “National and Office-Specific Measures of Auditor Industry Expertise and Effects on Audit Quality.” Journal of Accounting Research 48 (3) (2010): 64786. SLEMROD, J., AND V. VENKATESCH. “The Income Tax Compliance Cost of Large and Midsize Businesses.” A Report to the IRS LMSB Division (2002). 37 WALLACE, R. AND C. MELLOR. “Nonresponse Bias in Mail Accounting Surveys: A Pedagogical Note.” British Accounting Review 20 (1988): 131-39. ZAMAN, M., M. HUDAI, AND R. HANIFFA. “Corporate Governance Quality, Audit Fees and NonAudit Services Fees.” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 58 (2011): 165-197. 38 TABLE 1 Descriptive Statistics for Survey Respondents and Comparison to TEI Membership Population TEI Survey Total Assets membership respondents <$10M 1% 1% $10M-$500M 24% 22% $500M-$1 Billion 17% 15% $1 Billion- $5 Billion 32% 29% $5 Billion-$50 Billion 21% 26% $50 Billion-$500 Billion 4% 5% > $500 Billion 1% 2% 100% 100% TEI Survey Total Revenues membership respondents < $500 Million 24% 25% $500 Million - $1 Billion 17% 10% $1 Billion - $5 Billion 37% 34% $5 Billion - $10 Billion 10% 10% $10 Billion - $50 Billion 11% 17% Greater than $50 Billion 2% 4% 100% 100% Tax Budgets < $250,000 $250,000-$500,000 $500,000- $1 Million $1 Million - $5 Million >$5 Million TEI Survey Industry membership respondents Mining and resources 6% 2% Utilities 4% 0% Construction 1% 1% Manufacturing 36% 49% Wholesale and retail 11% 8% Transportation 3% 2% Information and telecomm 5% 8% Financial and Insurance 10% 6% Real estate 2% 1% Professional services & Education 6% 6% Health 6% 2% Media and Entertainment 3% 1% Food and Accommodation 7% 3% Other 0% 7% None of the above 0% 4% 100% 100% TEI Survey membership respondents 15% 10% 21% 18% 26% 16% 32% 40% 5% 16% 100% 100% These data are drawn from the Tax Executives Institute’s (TEI) mandatory survey of its membership in 2005 and from our Tax Survey conducted in 2010. TABLE 2 Survey Statistics of Compliance Outsourcing Compliance Work Outsourced To: N Not outsourced 34 Average Average Average Percentage Percentage Number of Of Compliance Of Planning Work Internal Tax Total Assets Percentage Work Outsourced Outsourced Personnel ($ Billion) 20% 0% 16% 13 37.9 Auditor only 27 16% 40% 31% 5 2.2 Non-auditor accounting firm only 70 41% 39% 35% 14 29.5 Non-accounting firm only 9 5% 22% 37% 18 1.8 Auditor and non-auditor accounting firm 11 6% 27% 24% 16 7.4 Auditor and non-accounting firm 3 2% 52% 17% 9 2.8 Non-auditor accounting firm and non-accounting firm 11 6% 40% 38% 21 15.2 All three types 5 3% 37% 28% 12 7.5 100% 30% 30% 13 22.2 Totals 170 These data are drawn from our Tax Survey. Respondents are classified according to their responses to the question "If your tax compliance is outsourced, to whom is it outsourced?" Tabulations in columns 4, 5, and 7 are based on the mid-point of categorical responses given in 11 categories; and column 6 are based on the mid-point of categorical responses given in 5 categories. The highest, open-ended category is not considered. Column 4 is based on responses to the question, "What percentage of overall tax compliance work (both transfer pricing and non-transfer pricing) is outsourced?" Column 5 is based on responses to the question, "What percentage of overall tax planning work (both transfer pricing and non-transfer pricing work) is outsourced?" Column 6 is based on responses to the question, "How many full time tax personnel are employed company wide?" Column 7 is based on responses to the question, "My company's asset size as of the most recent annual fiscal period is." While only 120 responses to this last question were received, the distribution across classifications is almost identical to that shown in column 2 (for example, 25 of 120 response, or 21%, are in category 1-not outsourced; 18 of 120 responses, or 15%, are in category 2-auditor only; etc.). TABLE 3 Descriptive Statistics on Firms by Tax Return Preparer Type and Year Panel A. Distribution of Sample and Assets by Tax Return Preparer and Year Big 4 Firm A Firm B Firm C Firm D Total Big 4 Non-Big 4 Firm E Firm F Other Total Non-Big 4 2008 mean median Assets Assets n % of Total 69 73 89 51 282 8.6% 8,366 9.1% 8,462 11.1% 10,663 6.3% 5,811 35.1% 8,654 0.9% 2.0% 7.1% 10.0% 7 16 57 80 2009 mean median Assets Assets n % of Total 1,754 2,018 1,417 1,439 1,670 59 63 90 51 263 8.1% 15,106 8.6% 5,712 12.3% 9,581 7.0% 6,703 36.1% 9,336 2,958 3,527 3,832 3,695 1,420 629 1,679 1,138 7 11 47 65 n 2,662 1,920 1,661 1,636 1,955 128 136 179 102 545 2,544 4,031 8,808 7,325 631 833 1,857 1,352 14 27 104 145 55.0% 25,680 6,143 843 1.0% 1.5% 6.4% 8.9% Internal Tax Dept. 442 55.0% 24,158 5,544 401 TOTAL 804 100.0% 16,684 3,215 729 100.0% 18,147 Total By Preparer % of mean median Total Assets Assets 8.3% 11,473 8.9% 7,188 11.7% 10,119 6.7% 6,257 35.6% 8,983 0.9% 1.8% 6.8% 9.5% 2,751 3,732 6,081 5,322 1,067 702 1,761 1,146 55.0% 24,882 5,884 3,601 1,533 100.0% 17,379 3,380 Asset values are in $Millions. Panel B. Count of Sample Firms by Tax Return Preparer Type and Auditor Auditor Firm Tax Preparer A B C D E F Other TOTAL Firm A 71 17 25 10 ND 4 ND 128 Firm B 21 54 27 19 ND ND 10 136 Firm C 19 17 103 32 4 ND ND 179 Firm D 10 11 16 56 ND 6 ND 102 Firm E 0 0 5 0 7 ND ND 14 Firm F 5 3 7 7 ND 5 ND 27 Other 14 23 24 18 6 3 16 104 Internal 275 190 211 153 4 7 3 843 TOTAL 415 315 418 295 25 30 35 1,533 Bolded numbers on the Diagonal represent that the outside Tax Preparer is also the Auditor ND = Not disclosed to do small sample sizes. Summary External Tax Preparer: Is the Auditor Is Not the Auditor Total External Internal Preparer Uses: Big 4 Auditor Non-Big 4 Auditor Total Internal Total Sample Totals 312 378 690 829 14 843 1,533 2,346 1,988 1,585 1,506 1,834 TABLE 3 (continued) Panel C. Distribution of Sample Firms by Tax Return Preparer Type and Industry Preparer Type Internal Preparer External Preparer is Auditor External Preparer is not Auditor Total SIC0 ND ND ND SIC1 58 11 25 SIC2 166 31 48 SIC3 217 74 104 SIC4 136 40 38 SIC5 37 29 30 SIC6 122 76 68 SIC7 61 34 50 SIC8 39 16 14 SIC9 ND ND ND ND 94 245 395 214 96 266 145 69 ND ND Total 9 Total 836 311 377 9 1,533 ND Total 9 Total 836 311 69 35 101 52 26 377 40 73 73 35 117 9 1,533 Panel D. Distribution of Sample Firms by Tax Return Preparer Type, Firm, and Industry Preparer Type Internal Preparer External Preparer is Auditor Firm A Firm B Firm C Firm D Non-Big4 External Preparer is not Auditor Firm A Firm B Firm C Firm D Non-Big4 Total SIC0 ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND SIC1 58 11 5 ND ND ND ND 25 ND ND 7 7 5 SIC2 166 31 6 10 9 3 3 48 6 7 15 12 8 SIC3 217 74 20 ND 33 11 ND 104 ND 31 21 ND 31 SIC4 136 40 11 ND 13 10 ND 38 7 12 ND ND 15 SIC5 37 29 ND ND 15 6 4 30 6 ND 10 ND 8 SIC6 122 76 18 6 18 18 16 68 6 14 11 9 28 SIC7 61 34 4 15 8 4 3 50 10 9 9 7 15 SIC8 39 16 5 4 5 ND ND 14 5 ND ND ND 7 SIC9 ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND ND 94 245 395 214 96 266 145 69 ND ND = Not disclosed to do small sample sizes. SIC 0 = Agriculture SIC 1 = Construction SIC 2 = Chemicals SIC 3 = Manufacturing SIC 4 = Transportation SIC 5 = Retail SIC 6 = Financial SIC 7 = Business Services SIC 8 = Health SIC 9 = Diversified/Other TABLE 4 Descriptive Statistics for Regression Variables Panel A. Summary Statistics Variable Dependent Variable UTB Ending Balance ($M) UTB EB / Total Assets Log_UTB_EB n Median Full Sample Mean 1,533 1,533 1,533 16.347 0.006 2.853 97.982 0.011 2.912 199.177 0.017 1.953 Control Variables Total Assets ($M) LOG_ASSETS PRETAX_ROA FOR_INCOME NOL R&D LEVERAGE 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 3,379.889 8.126 0.062 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.173 17,379.490 8.217 0.047 0.017 0.450 0.024 0.196 44,622.450 1.725 0.143 0.042 0.498 0.055 0.170 Tax Fee Data Tax Non-Audit Fees > 0 (0/1) Tax Non-Audit Fees / Total Assets Tax Fee Ratio (Tax Fees / Total Fees) Tax Non Audit Fees ($M) Log(1+Tax Fees) 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 1.000 0.0000 0.048 0.117 0.111 0.806 0.0001 0.084 0.532 0.298 0.396 0.0002 0.096 1.129 0.431 1,533 0.050 0.082 0.098 1,533 1,533 1,533 1,533 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 0.450 0.204 0.247 0.550 0.498 0.403 0.431 0.498 Non-Tax Fee Ratio (Non-Audit Fees - Tax Fees)/(Total Fees - Tax Fees) Categories Preparer Type External Preparer is Auditor (AUD_PREP) is not Auditor (OTHER_PREP) Internal Preparer (INTERNAL_PREP) STD Notes: UTB EB is the total value (ending balance) of uncertain tax benefits recorded by the IRS Large Business & International Division. LOG_ASSETS is the natural logarithm of total assets. PRETAX_ROA is pretax income deflated by total assets. FOR_INCOME is the ratio of the company's disclosure of foreign pretax income, deflated by total assets. NOL is an indicator variable if the firm has a loss carryforward. R&D is research and development expenses, deflated by total assets. LEVERAGE is the ratio of long-term debt to total assets. Tax Non-Audit Fees and Total Fees are the fees disclosed by the company that are paid to the auditor for tax services and all services, respectively. AUD_PREP is an indicator variable that takes on the value 1 if the tax return is signed by the company's audit firm; NONAUD_PREP is an indicator variable that takes on the value 1 if the tax return is signed by a preparer who is not the firm's auditor; and INTERNAL_PREP is an indicator variable that takes on the value 1 if the firm's tax return is not signed by an external preparer. AUD_PREP, OTHER_PREP and INTERNAL_PREP are mutually exclusive and jointly exhaustive. TABLE 4 (continued) Panel B. Summary Statistics by Tax Preparer and Expert Type Variable Dependent Variable UTB Ending Balance ($M) UTB EB / Total Assets Log_UTB_EB Control Variables Total Assets ($M) LOG_ASSETS PRETAX_ROA FOR_INCOME NOL R&D LEVERAGE External Tax Preparer: Not the Auditor Auditor (AUD_PREP = 1) (OTHER_PREP = 1) n Median Mean STD n Median Mean STD Internal Tax Department (INTERNAL_PREP = 1) n Median Mean STD 312 5.79 46.86 127.66 378 6.65 46.77 134.40 843 37.30 312 0.00 0.01 0.02 378 0.01 0.01 0.02 843 0.01 0.01 0.01 312 1.19 2.10 1.79 378 2.03 2.23 1.70 843 3.65 3.52 1.91 312 312 312 312 312 312 312 1,956 7.58 0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.13 9,472 28,610 7.71 1.58 0.04 0.15 0.01 0.03 0.45 0.50 0.02 0.06 0.17 0.17 378 378 378 378 378 378 378 1,339 7.20 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.11 7,175 18,697 7.42 1.61 0.02 0.19 0.01 0.04 0.49 0.50 0.04 0.07 0.16 0.18 843 843 843 843 843 843 843 5,884 8.68 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.21 5. 6. Panel C. Correlation Table 1. 1. Log_UTB_EB -0.21 2. AUD_PREP -0.20 3. OTHER_PREP 4. INTERNAL_PREP 0.34 5. LOG_ASSETS 0.63 6. PRETAX_ROA 0.06 7. FOR_INCOME 0.28 8. NOL 0.07 9. R&D 0.04 10. LEVERAGE 0.18 2. -0.29 -0.56 -0.15 -0.01 -0.09 0.00 0.00 -0.08 3. -0.63 -0.26 -0.13 -0.11 0.05 0.13 -0.12 4. 0.35 0.12 0.11 0.16 0.14 -0.04 -0.19 -0.12 -0.21 0.16 0.18 7. 0.38 -0.07 0.09 -0.13 0.11 -0.02 -0.09 8. 9. 0.13 0.09 -0.16 This Panel reports Pearson correlation coefficients. Correlations in excess of 0.04, in absolute value, are generally statistically significant at a 5% level. 139.87 232.75 24,882 55,116 8.76 1.63 0.06 0.11 0.02 0.04 0.43 0.50 0.02 0.04 0.22 0.16 TABLE 5 Multivariate Regression Results on the Link between Tax Aggressiveness and Tax Preparer Type Multinomial Self-Selection Model Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Variable Sign OLS Coefficient (t-statistic) INERNAL_PREP + 0.287 ** (2.49) OTHER_PREP + 0.216 * (1.70) LOG_ASSETS + 0.917 *** (27.82) PRETAX_ROA + -0.463 (-1.39) FOR_INCOME + 3.476 *** (2.72) NOL + 0.276 *** (3.23) R&D + 2.501 ** (2.13) LEVERAGE + 0.084 (0.25) NON-TAX FEE RATIO Constant Year Control Industry Controls λ_INTERNAL_PREP + -4.986 *** (-10.55) YES YES Tobit Coefficient (t-statistic) 0.353 *** (2.73) 0.274 * (1.89) 0.963 *** (27.13) -0.536 (-1.49) 3.481 ** (2.55) 0.301 *** (3.25) 2.542 * (1.93) 0.113 (0.32) Stage 1 INTERNAL_ OTHER_ PREP PREP Coefficient Coefficient (z-statistic) (z-statistic) -5.448 *** (-10.72) YES YES 0.663 *** (7.99) -0.335 (-0.43) 5.147 * (1.77) -0.257 (-1.11) -5.055 * (-1.69) 0.800 (1.14) -1.635 * (-1.69) -2.581 * (-1.68) YES YES 1,533 843 -0.129 (-1.32) -0.881 (-1.13) -0.182 (-0.06) 0.083 (0.34) 2.512 (1.02) -0.078 (-0.10) -2.067 * (-1.88) 0.734 (0.45) YES YES λ_OTHER_PREP Observations Adjusted R2 Model F-Stat Model Chi-Square Pseudo-R2 Log Pseudo-Likelihood Tests between Coefficients: INTERNAL_PREP vs. EXT_ISNT_AUD 1,533 60.1% 84.92 *** 378 Stage 2 Coefficient (z-statistic) 0.667 *** (4.31) 0.550 ** (2.21) 0.897 *** (22.11) -0.414 (-1.25) 3.265 ** (2.55) 0.279 *** (3.26) 2.598 ** (2.26) 0.054 (0.16) -5.150 *** (-10.20) YES YES -0.432 *** (-3.34) -0.359 (-1.47) 1,533 78.81 *** 1,845.67 *** β1 = β2 F = 0.43 p=0.514 20.5% -2,534.04 β1 = β2 F = 0.43 p=0.513 -3,838.08 β1 = β2 2 χ = 1.54 p=0.21 All models use robust standard errors clustered by firm. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1 and 99 percentile levels. *, **, and *** denote significance at the p < 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels (all two-tailed), respectively. See Appendix for full variable definitions. TABLE 6 Sensitivity Test Summary Results: Classifying Type of Preparer from Tax Returns vs. from Financial Statement Disclosures of Tax Fee Data Panel A. Benchmark Case - Using Tax Returns to Classify Preparer as (Internal or External) Non-Auditor Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Variable Sign OLS Coefficient (t-statistic) NONAUD_PREP_ TAXRET + 0.259 ** (2.41) All Controls YES Observations 1,533 Adjusted R2 60.1% Model F-Stat 90.14 *** Pseudo-R2 Log Pseudo-Likelihood Tobit Coefficient (t-statistic) 0.323 *** (2.64) YES 1,533 83.57 *** 20.5% -2,534.41 Panel B. Using Tax Fee Data to Classify Preparer as (Internal or External) Non-Auditor Case 1: Non-Auditor Preparer as Zero Tax Fees Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Variable Sign OLS Tobit Coefficient Coefficient (t-statistic) (t-statistic) NONAUD_PREP_ 10K + -0.012 -0.025 (-0.11) (-0.21) All Controls YES YES Observations 1,533 1,533 Adjusted R2 59.8% Model F-Stat 89.74 *** 83.03 *** Pseudo-R2 20.3% Log Pseudo-Likelihood -2,540.91 Case 2: Non-Auditor Preparer as <1% Tax/Total Fee Ratio Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Variable Sign OLS Tobit Coefficient Coefficient (t-statistic) (t-statistic) NONAUD_PREP_ 10K_1% + -0.059 -0.060 (-0.61) (-0.56) All Controls YES YES Observations 1,533 1,533 Adjusted R2 59.8% Model F-Stat 90.11 *** 83.25 *** Pseudo-R2 20.3% Log Pseudo-Likelihood -2,540.67 Case 3: Non-Auditor Preparer as <5% Tax/Total Fee Ratio Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Variable Sign OLS Tobit Coefficient Coefficient (t-statistic) (t-statistic) NONAUD_PREP_ 10K_5% + -0.141 * -0.144 (-1.69) (-1.53) All Controls YES YES Observations 1,533 1,533 Adjusted R2 59.9% Model F-Stat 91.12 *** 84.12 *** Pseudo-R2 20.3% Log Pseudo-Likelihood -2,538.93 Case 4: Non-Auditor Preparer as <10% Tax/Total Fee Ratio Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Variable Sign OLS Tobit Coefficient Coefficient (t-statistic) (t-statistic) NONAUD_PREP_ 10K_10% + -0.127 -0.133 (-1.52) (-1.46) All Controls YES YES Observations 1,533 1,533 Adjusted R2 59.9% Model F-Stat 92.80 *** 85.25 *** Pseudo-R2 20.3% Log Pseudo-Likelihood -2,539.49 TABLE 6 Panel B (continued) Case 5: Non-Auditor Preparer as <25% Tax/Total Fee Ratio Case 6: Non-Auditor Preparer as <50% Tax/Total Fee Ratio Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Dependent Variable: Log_UTB_EB Pred. Pred. Variable Sign Variable Sign OLS Tobit OLS Tobit Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient (t-statistic) (t-statistic) (t-statistic) (t-statistic) NONAUD_PREP_ NONAUD_PREP_ 10K_25% + -0.301 ** -0.351 *** 10K_50% + 0.858 1.171 (-2.42) (-2.63) (1.39) (1.39) All Controls YES YES All Controls YES YES Observations 1,533 1,533 Observations 1,533 1,533 Adjusted R2 59.9% Adjusted R2 59.8% Model F-Stat 91.67 *** 84.78 *** Model F-Stat 90.06 *** 83.13 *** Pseudo-R2 20.4% Pseudo-R2 20.3% Log Pseudo-Likelihood -2,537.37 Log Pseudo-Likelihood -2,539.96 All models use robust standard errors clustered by firm. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1 and 99 percentile levels. *, **, and *** denote significance at the p < 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels (all two-tailed), respectively. TABLE 6 (continued) Panel C. Analysis of Accuracy in Classifying Preparer Type from Financial Statement Disclosures of Tax # incorrectly classified Is not NONAUD_ Is NONAUD_ # correctly classified # as PREP but PREP but NONAUD # as AUD_ NONAUD AUD_ 10-K implies 10-K implies _PREP PREP _PREP PREP Total it is it is not Tax Return NON_AUD_PREP_TAXRET 1,221 312 1,221 312 1,533 0 0 10-K NON_AUD_PREP_10K NON_AUD_PREP_10K_1% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_2% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_3% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_4% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_5% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_10% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_15% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_20% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_25% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_30% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_35% NON_AUD_PREP_10K_40% 298 428 538 640 718 777 1,055 1,203 1,320 1,417 1,471 1,496 1,514 1,235 1,105 995 893 815 756 478 330 213 116 62 37 19 288 412 510 601 668 717 933 1,025 1,104 1,159 1,190 1,206 1,216 302 296 284 273 262 252 190 134 96 54 31 22 14 590 708 794 874 930 969 1,123 1,159 1,200 1,213 1,221 1,228 1,230 10 16 28 39 50 60 122 178 216 258 281 290 298 933 809 711 620 553 504 288 196 117 62 31 15 5 Total % Sample Incorrectly Classified 0 0.0% 943 825 739 659 603 564 410 374 333 320 312 305 303 61.5% 53.8% 48.2% 43.0% 39.3% 36.8% 26.7% 24.4% 21.7% 20.9% 20.4% 19.9% 19.8% NONAUD_PREP_TAXRET = 1 if tax return does not report the firm's auditor as its tax preparer; 0 otherwise. NONAUD_PREP_10K = 1 if firm does not report in its 10-K any tax fees paid to its auditor; 0 otherwise. NONAUD_PREP_10K_1% (_2%, _3% …) = 1 if firm reports in its 10-K any tax fees paid to its auditor less than or equal to 1% (2%, 3%..., respectively) of total fees paid to the auditor; 0 otherwise.