making the case for free enterprise Weight Watchers for Whitehall By Dominic Raab, MP for Esher & Walton with a foreword by Andrew Sentance, Senior Economic Advisor at PwC 3 Contents Foreword4 Executive Summary 6 The Case for Streamlining Whitehall 8 Measuring State Spending 13 Streamlining Whitehall’s Bloated Bureaucracy 15 Controlling Public Sector Pay 20 About the Free Enterprise Group 21 4 Foreword The UK – like many other countries in the western world – is struggling to contain high levels of public spending and borrowing. Using the OECD’s definitions, the UK government spent 49% of GDP in 2012 – nearly half of total national product. We have the third highest public spending to GDP ratio among the G7 economies (behind France and Italy) and our government spends over 6% of GDP more than the average for the OECD economies (42.6%). In the 2010 Budget, the coalition government was optimistic that a combination of economic growth, tax rises and spending restraint would bring the deficit down to a sustainable level over the lifetime of this Parliament. However, instead of falling to below £40bn by 2014/15, as expected in 2010, the OBR now project that public borrowing will be £108bn in the last year of this Parliament – around 6% of GDP. A strong rebound in economic growth and/or further tax-raising do not offer a way out. Most western economies have seen a slowdown in economic growth associated with the post-financial crisis “new normal” world. And in an increasingly globalised world economy, raising taxes is not a solution either. Higher taxes on the income of companies and individuals will undermine competitiveness, and encourage economic activity to relocate. Imposing more taxes on households and consumers will intensify the squeeze they are already feeling as a result of rising energy and food prices. That leaves government with only one option: reducing the burden of public expenditure. But how might this be achieved, in a world where demographic trends and public expectations are pushing in the opposite direction? There is no single obvious and easy solution. The public sector in a mature western economy like the UK is a large and complex legacy business, which has been accumulating and developing its activities since the beginning of the 20th century. Privatisation and stronger financial discipline enabled the government to reassert control over public spending in the 1980s and 1990s. But new radical ideas will be needed to rethink and reshape government to meet the challenges of the 21st century. 5 One potential area for reform and efficiency improvement is in the way government is structured. Businesses frequently restructure their operations to reduce administrative overhead and complexity. As well as raising efficiency and cutting costs, a slimmer more effective organisational structure can act as an enabler for other business improvements. A similar approach is needed within government – to reduce the overlap between departmental responsibilities, speed up decision-taking and to support the efficient and effective delivery of public services. This paper makes an important contribution to the current public spending debate. It sets out an agenda for reshaping government – creating a slimmer, more effective structure, better suited to the current needs of the UK economy and society. As well as reducing administrative cost, a more efficient and leaner government machine should be an enabler for other reforms in the delivery of public services and welfare support, as well as simplifying the interface with the private sector. Private enterprise is the key engine of growth in the UK and other western economies. By slimming down and restructuring government, the private sector can be given more room to grow and create a more sustainable recovery for the UK economy. Dr Andrew Sentance is the Senior Economic Adviser at PwC. He was a member of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England from 2006 to 2011. 6 Executive Summary The sprawling bureaucracy and cost of Whitehall should be scaled back, to make the UK government more efficient, and find £10billion worth of annual savings to help cut the deficit faster and reduce business taxes to promote growth. This should be done by: 1.Increasing transparency over domestic public spending and facilitating international comparison, by adopting the OECD measure of government spending in place of the narrower OBR definition. 2.Reducing the total number of separate government departments from 20 to 11, and saving £8billion per year. 3.Rigorously implementing the 1% cap on pay rises in the public sector, through measures to prevent its circumvention, saving an estimated £2billion per year. 7 8 The Case for Streamlining Whitehall In the context of the coalition’s efforts to reduce the UK budget deficit, and the forthcoming public spending review, the case for streamlining government is primarily built on the need to cut costs and spending that have to be paid for through borrowing or taxation. The International Monetary Fund recently confirmed that: ‘Reducing the large structural fiscal deficit over the medium term is essential’.1 The need to cut the deficit, maintain market confidence and re-balance the economy was further recently endorsed, as ‘necessary’ and ‘appropriate’, by the chief economist at the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Pier Carlo Padoan.2 With gross UK government debt at 94% of Gross Domestic Product (GDP), the Treasury is embarked on a further spending review, to identify further savings in order to implement the Chancellor’s deficit reduction plan. It is reported that the Treasury is still searching for around £9billion worth of cuts in annual public sector spending.3 In addition, with quarterly economic growth at 0.3%, further reductions to public expenditure would help pay for cuts to business taxes to give the economy a supply-side fillip. As crucial as these immediate economic concerns are, they are not the sole reason for reviewing the functions and departments of state during the spending review. In addition, there is a crowding out effect from high levels of public spending, because it takes up the space that would otherwise be filled by private sector activity, and as a result of the opportunity cost of the tax revenue raised to fund it. This is resource that otherwise could be used to innovate and invest. It has been shown that a 10% reduction in tax as a proportion of GDP can lead to an increase in growth of up to 1%.4 1 IMF 2013 Article IV Consultation, Concluding Statement of Mission, May 22, 2013. 2 Widely reported, 30 May 2013. 3 Widely reported, including Reuters, 28 May 2013. 4 Philip Booth (ed.), Sharper Axe, Lower Taxes: Big Steps to a Smaller State, IEA, 2011, p.42. 9 Another key consideration is the impact on efficiency. There remain widespread concerns about whether the structures of governments are delivering good outcomes or not. During the decade after Labour took office, productivity in the private sector went up by 2.3% each year on average, while public sector productivity declined by 0.3% each year.5 Higher levels of spending have not improved, and should not be confused with, public sector productivity. There is also an important point to be made about democratic accountability. There have been recent reports of government departments trying to reclassify spending into other departmental budgets to get around budgetary ring-fences. This risks blurring the functions of government, and obscuring government budgets. More generally, the expanding and sprawling functions of the state have eroded the ability of Ministers to exercise ministerial responsibility over their departments. Finally, although difficult to quantify, high levels of government intervention and spending can play into the hands of vested interests. For example, training subsidies are most easily accessed by large companies that are able to restructure courses to meet bureaucratic qualifying criteria. Likewise, complex regulation gives an advantage to incumbent companies with teams of compliance offices, and makes it harder for new start-up businesses or smaller companies to compete. This report addresses three discrete aspects of Whitehall spending, with a view to streamlining the costs, bureaucracy and functions of various government departments. First, in the interests of transparency, it considers the appropriate measure of UK government spending. Second, it analyses 5 ale Bassett, Thomas Cawston, Andrew Haldenby, Lucy Parsons, Public Sector D Productivity, Reform, 2010, p.4. 10 certain government departments that could be abolished or merged. Third, it looks at the savings to be made from controlling the scope for circumventing centrally-imposed limits on public sector pay. The report does not purport to be an exhaustive consideration of all government waste or functions. Rather, it is an attempt to propose a modest number of practical steps to help streamline government bureaucracy, and place Whitehall spending on a more sustainable basis, without harming frontline services. Together, these policy measures would save over £10billion per year. Those savings could be used to pay down the deficit further and faster, and cut business taxes to deliver a supply-side fillip to the UK economy. A Brief History of Whitehall Expansion Britain’s public sector is complex. According to the latest Whole of Government Accounts, there are around 1,500 ministerial departments, regulators, QUANGOs, public corporations, executive agencies, academies, foundations and devolved administrations.6 In practice, British Cabinets have historically been limited to twenty or so Ministers, and thus around twenty main Ministerial Departments. These Departments in turn oversee the rest of the public sector. While the essential functions of the public sector – security, welfare and taxes – have been constant for centuries, governments have continually altered how they allocate space at the Cabinet table. The modern civil service dates from the time of the Northcote-Trevelyan report in 1853. Influenced by the Chinese Imperial bureaucracy, Britain moved away from patronage to a more meritocratic system. By this point, many of today’s departments were already in place. The Treasury traces its ancestry back to medieval times, while the modern division into Home and Foreign Office dates from 1782. 6 HM Treasury, Whole of Government Accounts: year ended 31 March 2011, October 2012 11 The original structure of the Cabinet was based around the needs of Empire. Campbell-Bannerman’s cabinet of 1905-1915, for example, contained separate Secretaries of State for Foreign Affairs, the Colonies, War, India, and the Admiralty. The first significant reorganisation came during the First World War. The Haldane report of 1918 argued that there was ‘much overlapping and consequent obscurity and confusion in the functions of the Departments of executive Government.’7 It argued that it would be best for the Cabinet to be kept ‘small in number – preferably ten, or at most, twelve’. Haldane believed that there were two means of organising department: either by function (health, education, defence) or by the clientele they served (children, pensioners, the unemployed). He argued that the former was preferable and proposed as a sample list: Finance; Defence and External Affairs; Research and Information; Production (including Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries), Transport and Commerce; Employment; Supplies; Education; Health; and Justice. By 1919, new departments had been created to deal with Labour, Pensions, Science and Industrial Research, Health, and Transport. The bureaucratic expansion continued, and by 1951 there were 29 departments. The Government was pruned back in the 1960s. Under Harold Wilson, the War Office, Admiralty, Ministry of Aviation and Air Ministry were consolidated into a new Ministry of Defence in 1964. Two years later, the Departments for Colonies, Dominion Affairs and Commonwealth Relations were merged into a new Department for Commonwealth Affairs, which by 1968 had merged into the larger Foreign Office. The shift away from imperial government represented just one aspect of Government re-structuring. The low point of seventeen departments in 1971 was soon added to as Governments created new departments, often to appease political rivals or to bring salience to some issue of the day. 7 Ministry of Reconstruction, Report of the Machinery of Government Committee, 1918, p.4. 12 The other reorganisations by Wilson, for example, proved less durable. An attempt to split the Treasury into two with a new Department for Economic Affairs lasted barely five years. The Department for Overseas Development lasted just six years until 1970, although it was resurrected for a year in 1974, and then returned once more as the Department for International Development in 1997. A frequent concern has been that departments organised by function are susceptible to ‘departmentalism’. Fixated on their own concerns, they may ignore the needs of joined-up government. To counter this, governments have experimented with new institutions above and across departments: cabinet subcommittees, super ministries or simply greater coordinating power at the centre. When this fails to work, governments have tried to create greater synergy by changing how departments are bundled together. Nearly every government seems to have had a different opinion on how best to group education, universities, skills, employment, research and science. Similarly, the links between environment, energy, transport, planning and local government policy have led to regular change. Despite little evidence that this constant creation of new and reconfigured departments increases efficiency, the process shows little sign of abating. Since 1979, British Governments have created 25 new departments, of which only twelve now exist. By comparison, in the United States, where it is much harder to make such changes, only two new departments have been created. Both still exist.8 8 National Audit Office, Reorganising Central Government, March 2010, p. 10. 13 Measuring State Spending As with any credible diet, it is important to measure consumption accurately. So too, government’s consumption of taxpayer’s money needs to be clearly and consistently recorded. However, there is a discrepancy between the current UK measure of state spending, used by the independent Office of Budget Responsibility (OBR), and that used by the OECD. The main difference is that the OBR takes into account various streams of government income - from leisure centre fees to hospital parking charges and deducts it from its figure for total expenditure. Whilst that is a legitimate methodological approach, it has two downsides. First, netting off income streams serves to mask the overall level of actual UK government spending. There are good accounting reasons for keeping spending and income separate, especially for those seeking to control the overall level of actual expenditure. Second, it obscures international comparison. An OECD review of 40 countries showed Britain to be the ninth biggest spender in 2009 on the OECD measure, whereas it would have been around the OECD average if the OBR measure were used. The table below illustrates the UK’s international ranking between 2000 and 2009 on the OECD measure. Between 2001/2 and 2012/13, the OBR measure has been between 2% and 5.4% lower than the OECD measure as a proportion of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). This can also have a distorting effect on the evaluation public policy. For example, at the 2013 budget, the Treasury’s Red Book estimated that public spending would be cut to 44% of GDP by the next election, which would appear implausible on the OECD measure. The OBR and Treasury should adopt the OECD measure of government spending for greater transparency - both as a domestic measure, and for purposes of international comparison. General government expenditures as a percentage of GDP (2000, 2007 and 2009) Source: Government at a Glance, OECD 2011. 14 15 Streamlining Whitehall’s Bloated Bureaucracy The UK has 20 separate central government departments.9 This is high by international standards. By contrast, the US has fifteen federal departments, Japan has twelve, Germany fourteen, while even high-spending Sweden has eight fewer ministries than Britain. As well as inflating the cost of government bureaucracy, the proliferation of government departments encourages mandarins to build up fiefdoms and hampers a joined-up approach to policy-making in cross-cutting areas. There are signs that the Treasury is currently considering reducing the number of Whitehall departments, in particular by abolishing the Department for Culture, Media and Sport (DCMS).10 This report urges the government to go further. By abolishing or merging a range of Whitehall departments, offices and agencies, the number of separate central departments could be reduced from 20 to 11, policy integrated more closely in a range of important areas, and £8billion saved each year. These savings can be achieved by cutting bureaucracy and waste, and through the efficiencies gained by consolidating separate departments, without touching frontline public services. There is a wealth of comparable experience in the private sector. For example, research on the effects of mergers and acquisitions suggests that labour cost savings of around a fifth can be made through efficiencies gained.11 Whilst the consolidation of public sector operations and functions presents a different context, it is reasonable to expect at least the same level of scope for savings. 9 his excludes the Office of the Leader of the House of Commons and the Office of the T Leader of the House of Lords (which are part of the Cabinet Office), UK Export Finance (which is part of the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills), and the Office of the Advocate General for Scotland (which, although constitutionally separate, shares offices and its accounts with the Scotland Office). 10 As reported, New Statesman, ‘Is Osborne about to abolish the culture department?’, 30 May 2013. 11 artin Conyon, Sourafel Girma, Steve Thompson and Peter Wright, The Impact of Mergers M and Acquisitions on Company Employment in the United Kingdom, Centre for Research on Globalisation and Labour Markets, University of Nottingham, 2002. 16 In particular, based on the respective Departmental Business Plans, Annual Reports and the Treasury’s forecasts for spending in 2014/15, the following general estimate has been made of potential savings relative to each respective department:12 —The DCMS should be abolished. The department brings together a range of largely unrelated functions, and does not require a separate free-standing bureaucracy of its own. Certain areas of spending including broadband, Ofcom, sport and certain aspects of heritage - should be retained and hived off to other departments (including the Treasury, the Department for Education, a new Department for Transport and Communications, and the new Department of Devolved Affairs, see below). By hiving off essential functions, reducing DCMS’s Departmental Expenditure Limit by 50%, and eliminating its administration costs, at least £0.7billion of savings per year could be made. —The Government Equalities Office (GEO) should be abolished. This agency (currently part of DCMS) is superfluous, and a source of unnecessary and burdensome regulation. Whilst this measure would only save £47million per year in departmental spending, wider savings would accrue in the public and private sectors by removing a source of onerous and counter-productive red-tape. Any vital residual functions could be discharged by the Equalities and Human Rights Commission or the Home Office. —The Department for Business, Innovation and Skills (BIS) should be abolished. Key areas of economic program spending should be hived off to the Treasury, and responsibility for skills and further education returned to their natural home at the Department for Education. While it would be worth reviewing each element of program spending individually for further savings, eliminating BIS’s administration costs, saving 50% 12 he estimates are based on Departmental Business Plans and Annual Reports, HM T Treasury forecasts and Civil Service Statistics. The estimate is based on the figures available for 2014/15. A line-by-line analysis would be required to specify the savings with greater precision. 17 from its capital spending, and ending further taxpayer subsidisation of the Green Investment Bank, would save £2billion per year. Furthermore, whilst the integration of economic policy in a single department would be valuable, the strategic priority of strengthening UK competitiveness also needs to be disseminated and coordinated more effectively across Whitehall. This could be achieved by establishing a cross-departmental Competitiveness Council, chaired by the Prime Minister, with overarching responsibility for delivering improvements in competitiveness, as well as introducing an economic competitiveness duty for each public sector department and agency.13 —Return the Department for International Development (DfID) to the Foreign and Commonwealth Office (FCO). DfiD conducts a shadow foreign policy driven by aid considerations, often inconsistently with wider FCO objectives (for example, in the area of conflict resolution). Returning its functions to the FCO would ensure a more integrated foreign policy strategy in key areas. By saving the administration and capital costs of having a separate department dispensing aid, £2billion per year could be saved without touching programme spending. —Merge the Home Office (HO) and Ministry of Justice (MoJ). With the creation of the MoJ in 2007, the HO’s functions were split between two departments. Given the cross-cutting nature of criminal justice policy, and wider issues that require a joined-up approach (for example, the deportation of foreign criminals), this division of functions was always questionable. In addition, by creating two departments, their combined spending has risen by £5billion per year in real terms since the division of functions.14 By just halving their combined administration and capital costs, merging the departments back together would realise savings of £1billion per year. 13 or further detail on the proposal for a competitiveness duty in the public sector, see George F Freeman and Kwasi Kwarteng, The Innovation Economy, Free Enterprise Group, 2013. 14 stimate based on expenditure data from: HM Treasury, Public Expenditure Statistical E Analyses 2007, April 2007, p.21, and HM Treasury, Statistical Bulletin: Public Spending Statistics, April 2013, p. 14. 18 — Merge the Department for Energy and Climate Change (DECC) and the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (DEFRA). The division of environmental responsibilities between two departments has led to duplicated spending. For example, DEFRA is spending over £200million per year on climate change. The split has also impaired the formulation of coherent environmental policy, for example, by separating key areas such as environmental resilience and adaptation from energy and carbon reduction policy. By merging the two departments into a Department for Energy and the Environment, it would be possible to reduce the combined budget by 20%, saving around £1.3 billion per year. —Merge the Scotland Office, Wales Office and Northern Ireland Office with the Department for Communities and Local Government (DCLG), creating a new Department for Devolved Affairs. There is no need for three separate departments for the devolved administrations, and they could easily be merged with DCLG to deliver combined administration and capital savings of around £10 million per year. —Merge Her Majesty’s Customs and Revenue (HMRC) and the Department for Work and Pensions (DWP), to create a Taxation and Payments Agency under the Treasury. Both HMRC and DWP provide an interface in the UK for transfers of money between the public sector and households. DWP has 20 million clients and HMRC deals with 30 million individual taxpayers throughout the country. There are potentially large efficiency gains to be achieved by bringing together the administrative and payment infrastructure of these two organisations, including providing the public with a single online gateway to deal with payments to and from government. In addition, by pooling resources, HMRC and DWP can more easily provide an integrated approach to tax and benefits and achieve higher compliance. HMRC and DWP could be merged under the umbrella of the Treasury, saving at least £1billion just by halving their combined administration and capital spending. The streamlined departmental structure is illustrated in the table below. In addition to improving the coordination of public policy, it could yield aggregate savings of over £8billion per year, principally by cutting excess bureaucracy. 19 20 Controlling Public Sector Pay Until 2010, the UK’s public sector remained relatively immunised from much of the fallout from the largest and deepest recession since the war, which started in 2008 and saw a 6% contraction in the economy. As a result of that recession, many in the private sector went out of business, lost their jobs or took pay cuts. In contrast, public sector wages have risen systematically over the last decade. Median annual full-time public sector employees now earn over £4,000 per year more than their private sector counterparts.15 In the last year, whilst private sector pay remained frozen, public sector pay rose by 1.4% despite a notional freeze imposed by the Treasury. Not only is this questionable on grounds of fairness, the 1.4% increase represents an estimated £2.4billion in extra public spending each year.16 The government has imposed a 1% cap on public sector pay increases from 2013/14 to 2015/16. It is only an average cap, leaving further scope for it to be circumvented. The 1% cap should be enforced consistently as a ceiling, applying to individual employees and the total public sector wage bill, with steps taken to ensure it cannot be circumvented in the same ways as the earlier public sector pay freeze. In particular, there is a widespread problem in the public sector with automatic pay and promotion as well as promotion around pay limits. The government should take measures to rigorously and consistently apply the 1% public sector cap on pay increases, for example, by ending ‘automatic’ salary increases or promotion (based on period of tenure in post rather than performance), and preventing the creation of additional senior posts as a means of side- 15 ONS, Labour Market Statistics, May 2013, Table: EARN01. 16 here was a 1.4% increase in public sector pay for Q1 2013 compared to Q1 2012, applied T to the most recent data available for total public sector pay which was £171 billion in 2011/12. ONS, Labour Market Statistics, May 2013, Table: EARN01; HM Treasury, Public Expenditure Statistical Analysis 2012, July 2012, p. 77. 21 stepping pay limits. Given the experience of implementing the pay freeze, properly enforcing such controls can be expected to result in savings of at least £2billion per year. 22 About the Free Enterprise Group Objectives ­­ Encourage a competitive and free economic environment — ­­—Raise the global economic standing of the United Kingdom ­­— Challenge monopolies and oligopolies ­­—Free individuals to create, innovate and take risks ­­ Supporters Harriett Baldwin MP Nick de Bois MP Karen Bradley MP Robert Buckland MP Aidan Burley MP Alun Cairns MP Therese Coffey MP Charlie Elphicke MP George Eustice MP George Freeman MP Mark Garnier MP John Glen MP Ben Gummer MP Sam Gyimah MP Matthew Hancock MP Richard Harrington MP Chris Heaton-Harris MP Margot James MP Sajid Javid MP Chris Kelly MP Kwasi Kwarteng MP Andrea Leadsom MP Brandon Lewis MP Anne-Marie Morris MP Brooks Newmark MP Jesse Norman MP Guy Opperman MP Priti Patel MP Christopher Pincher MP Mark Pritchard MP Dominic Raab MP David Ruffley MP David Rutley MP Laura Sandys MP Chris Skidmore MP Julian Smith MP Rory Stewart MP Elizabeth Truss MP Andrew Tyrie MP Mike Weatherley MP Nadhim Zahawi MP www.freeenterprise.org.uk Contact: Dominic Raab MP on 0207 219 3000 or dominic.raab.mp@parliament.uk Kwasi Kwarteng MP on 0207 219 3000 or kwasi.kwarteng.mp@parliament.uk DISCLAIMER: All supporters subscribe to the aims of the group. However, articles written under the auspices of the group reflect the author’s own views and not necessarily those of all group members.