CQUniversity Division of Higher Education School of Business and Law LAWS11062 Contract Law B Topic 5 Illegality Term 2, 2014 Anthony Marinac © CQUniversity 2014 1 Table of Contents 1.0 Introduction ...................................................................................... 3 1.1 Objectives ......................................................................................... 4 1.2 Prescribed Reading .......................................................................... 5 1.3 Key Terms ........................................................................................ 6 2.0 Contracts opposed by Common Law ................................................ 6 2.1 Contracts illegal at common law on the grounds of public policy ... 7 2.2 Review questions ........................................................................... 14 2.3 Contracts void at common law ...................................................... 16 2.4 Review questions ........................................................................... 21 3.0 Contracts Prohibited by Statute ...................................................... 22 3.1 Express Statutory Prohibition ....................................................... 22 3.2 Implied Statutory Prohibition .......................................................24 3.3 Review questions ...........................................................................26 4.0 Consequences for Illegal and Void Contracts ................................. 27 5.0 Review ............................................................................................ 28 6.0 Tutorial Problems ...........................................................................29 7.0 Debrief............................................................................................ 30 2 Topic 5: Illegality 1.0 Introduction Right back at the very start of Contracts A, I introduced you to the concept of classical contract theory. The idea of classical contract theory was that any two parties could create a private law which would be binding upon themselves; a further concept underpinning this theory was the idea of freedom of contract; that parties should be free to make those binding private laws in just about whatever fashion they wish. But how far should we push this? Ultimately, don’t you feel that the law of the land ought to dominate over the private laws of contract? To take the most obvious example, how would you feel about two parties forming a contract where Party A pays Party B a sum of money to rape or murder a third party? This week, we look at those circumstances in which the law (both statute and common law) either prohibits contracts altogether, or simply makes them unenforceable. In cases of the first type, you might potentially be punished simply for engaging in the contract; in cases of the second type, the law will simply not assist parties who are engaged in activities contrary to the law itself. 3 8852817 1.1 Objectives After studying Topic 5 you should be able to demonstrate knowledge of: The key reasons contracts are forbidden by the common law: o Contracts to commit a crime, a tort or a fraud; o Contracts to promote sexual immorality; o Contracts prejudicial to the administration of justice; o Contracts promoting corruption in public life; o Contracts prejudicial to national interests; The range of contracts not forbidden by the common law, but which the common law will refuse to enforce; Contracts ousting the jurisdiction of the courts; Contracts prejudicial to the status of marriage; 4 Contracts for the restraint of trade; The ways in which statutes may affect the enforceability of contracts, either by an express or an implied prohibition; and The circumstances in which a party to an illegal or unenforceable contract might nevertheless be able to obtain relief. 1.2 Prescribed Reading Lindy Willmott, Sharon Christensen, Des Butler and Bill Dixon, Contract Law (Australia Oxford University Press, 4th ed, 2013) Ch. 18; Ashton v Pratt (No.2) [2012] NSWSC 3 Attwood v Lamont [1920] 3 KB 571 Campbells Cash and Carry Pty Ltd v Fostif Pty Ltd (2006) 229 CLR 386 Cope v Rowlands (1836) 2 M & W 149 Dobbs v National Bank of Australia Ltd (1935) 53 CLR 643 Everet v Williams (1725), unrep. Exch, 30 October 1725 Hirsch v Zinc Corporation Ltd (1917) 24 CLR 34 Nelson v Nelson (1995) 184 CLR 538 Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns and Ammunition Co Ltd [1894] AC 535 Parkinson v College of Ambulance Ltd [1925] 2 KB 1 Pearce v Brooks (1866) LR 1 Exch 213 Pham v Doan (2005) 63 NSWLR 5 Public Service Employees Credit Union Co-operative Limited v Campion (1984) 56 ACTR 39 Re Mahmoud and Ispahani [1921] 2 KB 716 Scott v Scott (1904) 25 ALT 174 Yango Pastoral Co v First Chicago Australia Ltd (1978) 139 CLR 410 1.3 Key Terms Administration of justice: A general term to describe the broad range of activities required in order to operate a justice system – may encompass everything from policing functions through to court processes, and the operation of prisons. Champerty: A tort where an external party funds legal proceedings on the understanding that they will then obtain some benefit (usually a financial benefit) from the winnings at the end. Maintenance: A tort involving the payment by one person of the legal fees of another person, where they have no real interest in supporting the legal action. Meretricious: Based upon pretence, deception, or insincerity; particularly applied to prostitutes, given their role of undertaking relationships on a meretricious basis. Restraint of trade: A contract which limits the freedom of one party to undertake specific trading or commercial activities within a specific market (usually defined geographically). 2.0 Contracts opposed by Common Law 6 Over the centuries, the common law has identified a range of types of contracts which it will not enforce because those contracts are contrary to public policy (i.e. they are contrary to the court’s understanding of the common good). As we will see below, these categories are not closed (and it may even be unhelpful to see them as categories at all) but they do provide a mechanism to understand the types of contracts which the court will not enforce. 2.1 Contracts illegal at common law on the grounds of public policy Where contracts are illegal, the very existence of the contract is contrary to the law. If the contract is merely void, the law will tolerate its existence but will not assist either party to enforce the contract. In these illegal cases, the very contract is considered to be unlawful. Let’s look at a range of these: 2.1.1 Contracts to commit a crime, a tort or a fraud OK, we’ve all watched The Sopranos, right? Or Mr & Mrs Smith? I suspect your life must have been sadly lacking in entertainment if you had never come across the concept of a contract killing. And yet the idea of one of the parties to such a contract suing in the event that something went wrong seems patently ludicrous! And yet that is just what happened in a case known to history as The Highwayman’s Case, or more properly Everet v Williams. This was a case filed in Chancery (that is, the court of equity) in 1725. At that time, not all judgments were recorded in writing, and sadly this was not one which made the grade. However contemporary news circulars recorded the case and knowledge about it has been passed down. In essence, Everet and Williams were robbers who had a joint enterprise to rob travellers, sell 7 the goods onwards and split the proceeds evenly. For quite a time this joint enterprise went well. The men eluded capture and plundered quite handsomely, until Everet began to feel that he was not getting his fair share of the loot. So what do you think you did? He sued in equity! Naturally he did not openly say that he was a highwayman; he tried to style himself as skilled in secondhand goods. The courts saw through it all immediately, and not only did the court refuse to enforce the contract, but both highwayman were immediately arrested. They were both later hanged. Wikimedia commons In all seriousness, it is not too likely that too many highwaymen will be suing in the 21st century. However, less ludicrous forms of the legal agreement do still take place. For instance, it does not seem all that unlikely that a truck driver might come under pressure from a trucking company, in the course of executing his or her employment contract, to carry an overweight load, to drive too fast, or to avoid work-rest requirements. Neither does it seem at all unlikely that business partners might jointly conspire in a contract with the effect of avoiding taxation. Even 8 within my own experience, long ago as an undergraduate it was made clear to me that in my part-time employment as a pizza delivery driver I would be expected to exceed the speed limit in order to get those yummy, yummy pizzas to hungry parties on time. 2.1.2 Contracts to promote sexual immorality Until quite recently, one might have been forgiven for thinking that the rule prohibiting contracts which promote sexual immorality was simply an anachronistic thing of the past. The classic case is Pearce v Brooks (1866) LR 1 Exch 213, in which a carriage was let to a prostitute in the knowledge that she would use the carriage in pursuit of her business. The court found that the owner of the carriage could not sue for outstanding hiring costs. The rationale for this rule, of course, was that the court did not wish to assist conduct which was seen as sexually immoral. It is also matter of notoriety that during the 20th century sexuality underwent a transformation. In the age of 50 Shades of Grey, is it really still possible to say that there is such a widespread concept of sexual immorality that the law should intervene? Until 2012, I would have said no. However in 2012, along came the famous case of Ashton v Pratt (No.2) [2012] NSWSC 3. Some of you may remember this case from the time, as it caused something of a media stir. Ms Ashton was a prostitute and brothel madam who alleges that she received a promise from Mr Pratt, a billionaire, that if she left the sex industry and made herself available as his mistress whenever and wherever he wished, he would install her in luxurious accommodation, pay her a very generous annual allowance, and establish seven-digit trust funds for any children. Ms Ashton states that she left the sex industry on this basis. 9 Mr Pratt then died, and as you can imagine his wife was less than enthusiastic about continuing to support Ms Ashton. Ms Ashton sued to enforce the agreement. The Judge acknowledged that there had been a substantial change in sexual morality, but found that the particular type of relationship enjoyed by Mr Pratt and Ms Ashton was still contrary to public morality, because the sex was entirely meretricious – that is, unlike other circumstances where clients are said to fall in love with a prostitute, there was no pretence in this case of any affectionate relationship between the two; the relationship was rather an ongoing sexual transaction. His Honour said: The arrangements between Ms Ashton and Mr Pratt involved none of the saving graces which enabled a different result to be reached in the cases to which I have referred. Those arrangements were not made to facilitate continuation of an existing cohabitation, but to establish the "mistress relationship". The evidence does not reveal a relationship, or consideration, beyond "meretricious sexual services". In my view, on the current state of the authorities, the arrangements were contrary to public policy and illegal in the relevant sense. Had they otherwise constituted a contract, it would have been void as contrary to public policy. This is still quite difficult to understand. Ashton was a lawful, registered prostitute, and Pratt was an experienced businessman. As there was no emotional relationship, the question of undue influence does not seem to arise. Under those circumstances, it is difficult to see why two free and selfdetermining adults should not make a contract, even an extremely generous one, for meretricious sex. However it probably still makes sense to regard this case is being an exception, rather than the rule. In these days, it would be quite difficult to assert that there is a common public morality, let alone describing its actual content. So, while it 10 remains the case that contracts promoting sexual immorality are unlawful, sexual morality is now such that these contracts will be few and far between. 2.1.3 Contracts prejudicial to the administration of justice Prejudice to the administration of justice by, for instance, preventing a witness from giving evidence in court, is already a serious criminal offence, so contracts for these purposes would be made unlawful on that basis. There are, however, three additional circumstances in which a contract might interfere with the administration of justice. First, a person with knowledge of a crime might be “bought off” to prevent them from reporting the crime to the appropriate authorities. This was essentially what happened in Public Service Employees Credit Union Co-operative Limited v Campion (1984) 56 ACTR 39), where Campion offered a financial benefit to the Credit Union if the Credit Union did not report his son for misappropriating money. Second, the law has long forbidden what is known as “maintenance”, which is the payment by one person of the legal fees of another person, where they have no real interest in supporting the legal action. So, for instance, it would not be maintenance for a father to pay his daughter’s legal bills, but it would be maintenance for a complete stranger to do so (for instance, in order to keep the other side under the pressure of an impending legal dispute). Maintenance is now regarded as something of an “antique” tort, although it does come up from time to time. Finally, the law forbids what is known as champerty, which is where an external party funds legal proceedings on the 11 understanding that they will then obtain some benefit (usually a financial benefit) from the winnings at the end. Champerty was also long considered to be an antique tort, but it has enjoyed something of a resurgence in recent years. Consider, for instance, Campbells Cash and Carry Pty Ltd v Fostif Pty Ltd (2006) 229 CLR 386, which considered the position of a firm whose sole real business was to encourage tobacco retailers to participate in a class action for the recovery of overpaid taxes. 10037867 2.1.4 Contracts which promote corruption in public life. The classic case here is Parkinson v College of Ambulance Ltd [1925] 2 KB 1, in which Parkinson made a substantial donation to the college on the understanding that he would receive a knighthood in return. The donation was duly accepted, but no 12 knighthood was forthcoming. Parkinson was quite nonplussed at this, and decided that his best course of action was to sue for a refund of his donation. He was unsuccessful, primarily because the contract was held to the unlawful: had the court enforced such a contract, it would have been tantamount to a situation in which public positions could be bought and sold. For example with a more Australian flavour, consider the famous “Kirribilli Agreement” made in 1988 by then Prime Minister Bob Hawke and Treasurer Paul Keating. The effect of the agreement was that if Mr Hawke won the 1990 general election, he would step down during that term and allow Mr Keating to take the Prime Ministership. In return, Keating would not mount a leadership challenge in the meanwhile. After the 1990 election was won, Hawke showed no inclination to step down. He was eventually overthrown by Keating in late 1991. Had Keating chosen to try to enforce the Kirribilli Agreement, it would have been unenforceable due to its tendency to promote corruption in public life (by potentially allowing a Prime Minister to remain in his position even if he genuinely lacked the support of the parliament). 13 14337129 Parkinson was most upset when he didn’t get his knighthood … he had bought a sword and everything! 2.1.5 Contracts prejudicial to national interests Contracts which are prejudicial to Australia’s national interests may not be enforced by Australian courts. The most obvious example of such contracts might be contracts dealing with an enemy in time of war. An example here is Hirsch v Zinc Corporation Ltd (1917) 24 CLR 34, in which the High Court was called upon to unravel the mess created by an ongoing contract to sell zinc and silver to a German, resident in Germany (which was then of course an enemy nation). The question before the court was whether Hirsch was liable to pay for the zinc received before the outbreak of the war, or whether the entire contract was now void. There was no question, however, that the contract ceased in its effect once the war commenced. 2.2 Review questions 14 Question 1 Which of the following principles of sexual morality has been upheld by an Australian court in recent years, as the basis for forbidding a contract? a) that adults should remain chaste until they are married or in a de facto relationship; b) that adults who are in a relationship should only engage in sexual conduct with their partner; c) that an ongoing sexual relationship should not be based upon money alone; and d) that couples should clarify their sexual health status before engaging in unprotected sex. Answer: (c) Question 2 Which of the following contracts would not be excluded by the common law? a) A contract for the sale of stolen goods, where both parties knew the goods were stolen; b) A contract between Party A and Party B whereby Party A was to blackmail Party C in return for a share of the proceeds of Party C’s recent lottery win; c) A contract to import forbidden sports supplements into Australia; d) A contract intended to create a tax-effective loss for one of the parties to the contract. 15 Answer: (d) Question 3 Which of the following would not be considered prejudicial to the administration of justice? a) A contract whereby a witness agreed not to report a crime or come forward with information, in return for a cash payment; b) A contract whereby a party agreed to pay the expenses incurred by a witness in attending court; c) A contract whereby a banker undertakes to pay the legal expenses of a person, in return for a 40% share of any damages; d) A contract whereby a person funds litigation against his worst enemy, with the intention of running up that enemy’s costs. Answer: (b) 2.3 Contracts void at common law Next we move to contracts which are not forbidden outright by the common law, but which the common law holds to be void and will not enforce. Again, there are a range of these. 2.3.1 Contracts which oust the jurisdiction of the courts The whole point of a contract is that it should be able to be enforced within the courts. Consequently, a provision in a contract which prevents one party or both parties from taking court action will be void. “It is not possible for a contract to create rights and at the same time to deny the other party in whom they invest the right to invoke the jurisdiction of the 16 courts to enforce them” (Dobbs v National Bank of Australia Ltd (1935) 53 CLR 643). Having said this, there is no problem with a contract containing a mechanism to resolve disputes between the contracting parties, or a provision requiring a party to undertake certain actions prior to commencing court action. However if a contract purports to prevent a party from being able to go to the court altogether, the provision will be invalid. What about honour clauses then? Don’t they seek to oust the jurisdiction of the courts? Well, in a sense they do, but they do so by making the agreement nonjusticiable: an honour clause says “this agreement is not a contract” whereas an ouster clause says “this agreement is a contract but you cannot sue anyway”. 2.3.2 Contracts prejudicial to the status of marriage Here is another moral provision which sounds positively antique. A range of types of contracts have been voided under this rule, including agreements not to live together after marrying (Scott v Scott (1904) 25 ALT 174), agreements by a married party to marry another party, agreements by an unmarried party not to marry at all, or only to marry a particular person (without there being an engagement, or a similar agreement by the other person), and even separation agreements, which were considered to be avoided because of their effect on the sanctity of marriage prior to their endorsement in family law legislation. Finally, and perhaps most interestingly, the role of a marriage broker is void under these laws. A person whose role is to seek out and arrange marriages will potentially be unable to sue for their fee. Personally, my view is that if there is a test case on this issue from this point forward, this rule may not hold up to modern scrutiny. 17 16426294 2.3.3 Contracts for restraint of trade A contract for the restraint of trade is a contract in which one party agrees not to compete in the same marketplace with another party. Such an agreement represents, in economic terms, a market failure and may lead to an abuse of market power, to the detriment of the public and the economy as a whole. However, contracts for the restraint of trade are not automatically a bad thing. Under some circumstances, they may be an appropriate action by a party to protect its legitimate interests, as opposed to simply seizing market power. If you think about it, even something like copyright law is really a restraint on trade, but it is regarded as quite legitimate. So, how do we tell the difference? 18 In essence, the court looks to two factors. First, it considers whether the restraint on trade is fair as between the parties to the contract. In other words, is the restraint just an unfair effect of one party having superior bargaining power? Second, it considers whether the restraint on trade is in the interests of the public. Generally speaking, a restraint of trade clause is likely to be valid in one of two circumstances. First, where a business is sold, the seller of the business might be restrained from opening another competing business close by (and therefore attracting away all of the good-will and custom which the purchased business might otherwise have expected). However, even in such circumstances, the restraint will need to be reasonable. In Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns and Ammunition Co Ltd [1894] AC 535, Nordenfelt sold his weapons and ammunition business to Maxim, and as part of the deal agreed not to manufacture guns or ammunition anywhere in the world for 25 years, and would not compete with Maxim “in any way”. The court found that the restraint of trade, in itself, was no problem. The sale price had fairly reflected this loss of liberty on Nordenfelt’s part. However the court found that a promise not to compete “in any way” was too broad, and refused to enforce that part of the contract. The court was still able to sever that part of the contract, and enforce the rest. 19 9911188 For those who are interested, the colour tips indicate the type of bullet: purple for incendiary, and red/orange for two different types of tracer rounds. Regardless of the colour, one of these will ruin your whole afternoon The second circumstance in which restraint of trade might well be valid is where an employee is restrained from leaving their employer, and setting up business in direct competition with that employer (and therefore competing with the same clients they had come to establish a reputation with while employed by the employer). Again, the key question is likely to be whether the restraint in trade is unfair. In the case Attwood v Lamont [1920] 3 KB 571, Lamont was employed in the tailoring department of a general outfitters. When he commenced, he signed a restraint of trade clause under which he promised not to undertake a wide range of activities (tailor, dressmaker, general draper, milliner, hatter, haberdasher, gentlemen's, ladies', or children's outfitter) within ten miles of the employer. He later did so, but the court determined that the restraint of trade clause was unreasonably broad, so it refused to enforce it. 20 2.4 Review questions Question 4 Which of the following would be void at common law? a) A contract requiring parties, in the event of a dispute, to engage in mediation prior to the commencement of any litigation; b) A contract requiring the parties to commence any legal action in Victoria, under Victorian law; c) A contract whereby the parties agree that neither party is entitled to sue the other; d) An agreement whereby the parties agree that neither party is entitled to sue the other, because the agreement is subject to an honour clause. Answer: (c) Question 5 Which of the following are considerations the court will take into account where restraint of trade is alleged? a) Whether a reasonable person would consider the clause to be a restraint of trade; b) Whether the restraint is in the public interest; c) Whether the restraint is subject to licencing regimes; d) Whether the restraint is fair as between the parties. Answer: (b) & (d) 21 3.0 Contracts Prohibited by Statute By now you are no doubt well and truly aware that from a legal perspective, we live in a statutory world. While contract law, more than most other areas of law, still relies on caselaw, contract has not been immune from the progressive predominance of statute law. Many statutes (by far too many to list separately here) either prohibit or restrict specific activities which might be done under a contract. In general, statute is likely to make a contract void in one of four ways. These were outlined in Yango Pastoral Co v First Chicago Australia Ltd (1978) 139 CLR 410: 1. The contract may be to do something which the statute forbids; 2. The contract may be one which the statute expressly or impliedly prohibits; 3. The contract, although lawful on its face may be in order to effect a purpose which the statute renders unlawful; 4. The contract, although lawful according to its own terms, may be performed in a manner which the statute prohibits. 3.1 Express Statutory Prohibition Perhaps the most important one to look out for is express statutory prohibition. In these circumstances, the statute effectively says ‘these contracts are illegal and may not be formed’. This usually involves words such as ‘shall not sell’, ‘shall not engage’ or ‘shall not deal’. If contracting parties make a contract to do something with the law says they must not, then obviously the law will not enforce the contract; and in addition, the contracting parties may be committing an offence. 22 For example, in Re Mahmoud and Ispahani [1921] 2 KB 716, an order made under the Defence of the Realm Regulations (UK) provided: “a person shall not…buy or sell or otherwise deal in …[linseed oil]...except under licence. The plaintiff, who had a seller’s licence, contracted to sell a quantity of linseed oil to the defendant in the mistaken belief that he had a buyer’s licence. The defendant later refused to accept delivery and the plaintiff sued him for damages for breach of contract. The plaintiff’s action failed. The order clearly prohibited the sale of linseed oil to an unlicensed purchaser and therefore expressly prohibited the contract in question. 8624970 23 More recently in New South Wales, in the case Pham v Doan (2005) 63 NSWLR, a pharmacist formed a business partnership contract with his brother-in-law. The problem was that the brother-in-law was not a pharmacist, and was therefore unable to be participating in this highly regulated industry. The partnership agreement was therefore illegal and void. 10016569 3.2 Implied Statutory Prohibition Implied statutory prohibition occurs when the statute does not expressly prohibit the contract itself, but it does prohibit certain conduct which comes within the contract. In such circumstances, it will usually be found that the parliament’s intention was not just to prohibit the conduct, but was also to prohibit any contract to undertake the conduct. In such cases, the contract is impliedly prohibited and will not be enforced. 24 This is very similar to the common law rule that a contract can be void for illegality. In Cope v Rowlands (1836) 2 M & W 149, a UK statute provided that brokers in the city of London had to be licenced or forfeit a fine of 25 pounds. The plaintiff, an unlicensed broker, performed work for the defendant and sued for his unpaid fee. The defendant argued that the contract was illegal and unenforceable because of the statute which really intended to prevent unlicensed broking contracts, and therefore impliedly made the contract illegal. It was held that the legislation was aimed at protecting the public by ensuring that only those who had passed through the licencing process could act as financial intermediaries. Consequently, broking contracts negotiated by unlicensed persons were impliedly prohibited and the fee was not recoverable. www.nyse.com However, sadly this principle is not as simple as it might seem. Under some circumstances, particularly when voiding the contract may have negative consequences for an innocent party, and whether statute simply provides a penalty for certain prohibited conduct, the court may choose to enforce the contract but also to enforce the penalty. This occurred in Yango Pastoral Co v First Chicago Australia Ltd (1978) 139 CLR 410, 25 where penalty was applied but the underlying mortgage contract was still held to be valid. 3.3 Review questions Question 6 Which of the following is not one of the ways in which a statute may make a contract void? a) If the contract is to do something which the statute forbids; b) If the contract is to do something lawful, in an unlawful way; c) If the contract is to do something the statute forbids by implication; d) If the contract is to do something which the statute regulates. Answer: (d) Question 7 If a statute states that certain building activities require the payment of a stamp duty, which of the following is true? a) A contract to undertake the building without paying the stamp duty will be incomplete; b) A contract to undertake the building without paying the stamp duty will be expressly prohibited; c) A contract to undertake the building without paying the stamp duty will be impliedly prohibited; 26 d) A contract to undertake the building without paying the stamp duty would be void on the grounds of public policy. Answer: (c) 4.0 Consequences for Illegal and Void Contracts As a general rule, the consequences for illegal and void contracts are fairly easy to understand. Simply put, they are completely void and neither party will be able to recover any money they have paid or any losses they have suffered through their involvement with the contract. However this rule is not absolute. There are four circumstances in which they party may be able to recover some form of relief. As you will see, all these circumstances operate where the party seeking a remedy was in some way innocent, or at least less culpable in relation to the illegality of the contract. The circumstances were set out in Nelson v Nelson (1995) 184 CLR 538, which in itself is a rather complicated real estate matter. McHugh J identified the circumstance in which a party might claim under an illegal contract: Where the claimant was ignorant or mistaken as to the factual circumstances which rendered the contract illegal; Where the statutory scheme that rendered the contract illegal was enacted for the benefit of a class to which the claimant is a member; Where the legal agreement was induced by the other party’s fraud oppression or undue influence; and Where the illegal purpose has not been carried into effect. In addition, the court has considered circumstances in which only one part of the contract is illegal. Under those 27 circumstances, it may be possible to sever the unlawful part of the contract and to give effect to the lawful part of the contract. This will be a question of fact for each case. A good example is the Nordenfelt case above. The promise not to compete with Maxim “in any way” was too broad, but the promise not to manufacture guns or ammunition was not considered too broad. There was no reason why the rest of the contract should not continue to operate, provided Maxim did not seek to enforce the provisions that Nordenfelt should not compete with them “in any way”. 5.0 Review One of the basic understandings we have carried with us throughout our study of Contracts is that in some cases, the law will come to the aid of a party who needs to enforce what would otherwise be a private obligation. Realistically, though, one would hardly expect the law to come to the aid of those seeking to enforce obligations which are profoundly opposed to the community’s general interests. This week we have considered circumstances in which the law will not enforce a contract, even when all of the other aspects of contract law are met. First, and perhaps most obviously, the courts will not enforce a contract which is illegal in nature. The common law forbids this; and in addition, the courts will not enforce contracts which are contrary to the express or implied requirements of statute. In addition, there are a range of other circumstances in which the courts will not enforce contracts on the grounds of what amounts to the public interest. The courts will not, for 28 instance, enforce contracts which oust the jurisdiction of the courts, because it is fundamental to the notion of law that parties in dispute should be able to approach the courts. Perhaps most important of these is the question of restraint of trade. Restraint of trade, in itself, is not prohibited. Under some circumstances, restraint of trade might be perfectly sensible. Who would hire staff if doing so meant the risk of those staff departing and taking one’s customers with them? However under other circumstances, restraint of trade may be unfair and unreasonable. The court therefore considers whether a restraint of trade clause is fair as between the parties, and also whether it is in the interests of the community. 6.0 Tutorial Problems Problem 4 Fruit trees are boring Please watch the short animated video at the following link, and then consider the questions below. I promise I tried to get the animation software to pronounce “Akubra” properly, but it couldn’t be done! https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=JWB66sVUTOM Is the contract between our client and the wholesaler forbidden outright, or is it just void? What, if any, obligations does our client have towards the wholesaler? 29 Consider the doctrine of mistake. Is it relevant to this dispute? Do you think either party was under a duty to inquire whether the rabbits were to be farmed in Queensland? Was the wholesaler entitled simply to assume the farmer would be farming lawfully? [30 Minutes] 7.0 Debrief After completing this topic you should recognize: That contracts to commit a criminal offence, a tort or a fraud are forbidden by the common law. That contracts promoting sexual immorality are forbidden, although the content of “sexual immorality” is highly contested. That contracts which prejudice our systems of governance – by interfering with the administration of justice, promoting corruption among public officials, or prejudicing the national interest – are all forbidden by the common law. That a contract purporting to oust the jurisdiction of the courts will be void; That, historically, contracts prejudicial to the status of marriage were void, although it is doubtful how a court would respond to this now; 30 That contracts for the restraint of trade may be permissible if the contract is fair as between the parties, and also in the community’s interests; That contracts will be void if they require conduct which breaches an express or implied prohibition contained in a statute (even where that prohibition does not amount to a criminal offence). That an innocent party to a contract forbidden by statute may nevertheless obtain relief if: o They were ignorant or mistaken about the fact that the contract was illegal; o The law which makes the contract illegal was enacted to protect them, not constrain them; o They were induced to enter into the contract by the other party’s fraud, oppression or undue influence; or o If the illegal purpose has not been carried into effect. 31