BORAL ENERGY HOLDINGS LIMITED ACN 004 132 423 Planning & Development Level 39, AMP Centre 50 Bridge Street Sydney NSW 2000 GPO Box 910 Sydney NSW 1041 Telephone 02 9220 6300 Facsimile 02 9235 1661 Writer’s Direct Dial: 9220 6438 31 March 1998 Mr Stephen Kelly Associate Director NECA Limited Level 7 14 Martin Place SYDNEY NSW 2000 By facsimile: (02) 9224 8943, Original by mail Dear Mr Kelly, Re: Transmission and Distribution Pricing Review Boral Energy Holdings Limited (Boral) is pleased to provide the National Electricity Code Administrator (NECA) with written comment in response to its Transmission and Distribution Pricing Review. Boral and its subsidiary companies are substantial participants in the Australian energy market. Through the Boral Building Products and Boral Construction Materials Groups we are a major consumer of energy in this country. The Boral Energy group is a significant electricity retailer and trader, a significant supplier and retailer of natural gas, and is one of the largest marketers of LPG in Australia. Boral has taken an active interest in the structure and incidence of transmission pricing, particularly as it relates to interconnectors. Boral has actively participated in discussions and correspondence with the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC), Transgrid, Powerlink and various interested parties over the derogation to the Code involving the Queensland – New South Wales Interconnect (QNI). Boral has also been an active participant in the consultation process between the Transitional Inter-Regional Committee (TIRC) and industry over the Riverlink proposal. Hence, Boral is particularly interested in those areas of the review which investigate the incidence of Transmission Use Of System (TUOS) charges and the locational signals offered by the manner in which they are charged. Page 2 The Scope of the Review The review is required by its Terms of Reference to consider inter alia: the locational signals resulting from the transmission and distribution pricing regimes, including the appropriate balance between cost reflective and postage stamp elements of charges and the incidence and treatment of cross-subsidies. The ACCC in its draft determination on the National Electricity Market Access Code has further called for the more onerous requirement to: “re-examine and justify the appropriate balance between cost reflective network pricing and postage stamp allocation of costs for TUOS charges;” (p.xvii) It is this dichotomy between Cost Reflective Network Pricing (CRNP) and postage stamp pricing and its effects on economic efficiency that are the primary focus of our comments. Locational Signals There is general acceptance that a move to full nodal pricing of Transmission systems in the NEM is unworkable at this point in time. Whenever full nodal pricing is not economically justifiable there must inevitably be a trade off between the degree of complexity of various zonal pricing models and the simplicity of postage stamp pricing. The dilemma is fundamentally one of the size of the zone. As the number of zones within a geographical area increases and the size of the zones decreases, the more cost reflective the pricing and the more accurate the locational signals become, however there is an inversely proportional increase in complexity and therefore costs. It is the role of the NECA review to determine the appropriate balance. Several market participants favour postage stamp pricing within state transmission systems, which they argue, are largely unconstrained meshed systems. However, unconstrained trade will remove price distortions within a market, it does not imply one delivered price. The argument for one postage stamp price should be based on simplicity, not lack of constraint. Unfortunately the simplicity serves to hide price signals to embedded generation and demand side management options. The lack of transmission pricing signals promotes the economically inefficient location of generators. Generators faced with one transmission zone will locate to minimise fuel transportation charges, regardless of the assets required to supply their power to the market, perhaps hundreds of kilometres distant. Zonal transmission pricing within regions is the only way to cost effectively produce the correct cost reflective price signals in the market. Given the desire to increase the similarities between the deregulated electricity and deregulated natural gas industries it is interesting to note that Victoria has adopted the zonal pricing of transmission systems for pricing the Natural Gas Transmission system in that state. The Energy Projects Division of the Victorian Department of Treasury and Finance has chosen to separate the 8 March, 2016 Page 3 system into 8 zones, with a further zone to cover the interconnector between Barnawatha in Victoria and Culcairn in New South Wales. Interconnectors The approach adopted in the Code is to regulate all existing interconnectors and if QNI and Riverlink are any indication it is also the intention for all future interconnectors to be regulated. The treatment of regulating interconnectors is to roll the interconnector into the asset base of the Network Service Provider (NSP), and therefore its revenue is regulated as a return of and on the capital investment apportioned to the interconnector. This treatment serves to remove locational signals and is an anathema to the CRNP principles espoused in the Code. The nature of interconnectors is that they are relatively straight forward links between A and B designed to transport product, in this case electricity, between the two centres. It is logical to treat this transportation link as a separate zone within a zonal transmission pricing model. This treatment conforms to CRNP principles and sends the appropriate pricing signals to the market. Any other treatment of interconnectors artificially promotes the economically inefficient location of generators and creates a bias in the market to favour interconnectors over new generation or demand side management alternatives. Inter-Regional Surplus The regulation of interconnectors leads to further distortions in the market when one looks at the Inter-Regional Surplus (IRS). The IRS is essentially the revenue that could be captured by an entrepreneurial interconnector for the transportation of product between regions of disparate price. It is obviously inappropriate for this surplus to be allocated to regulated interconnectors, as their revenue is funded through a return on the assets employed. Hence the appropriate allocation of the IRS is unclear. By treating all new interconnectors as unregulated and allowing them to develop hedging products between the markets these artificial market distortions could be avoided. This action would have the additional benefit of exposing the interconnector to the same level of risk as its competitors, generation alternatives and demand side management. Transition to Zonal Pricing The introduction of zonal transmission pricing will obviously alarm some businesses that have unwittingly located in economically inefficient areas, at least in terms of TUOS costs. Businesses may have made significant investment decisions under the expectation that the existing postage stamp pricing regime would continue. The need for some kind of transitional arrangements, particularly for those businesses are at the extremities of the network, should be acknowledged. However, the transitional arrangements must take the form of external subsidies, they should not be covered in the code, nor should they be funded 8 March, 2016 Page 4 by the market. Any subsidy must be treated in the same manner as Community Service Obligations and be funded by government. The benefits of electricity reform to the economy and the Competition Principles Agreement payments should adequately compensate. Conclusion Boral supports the introduction of cost reflective zonal transmission pricing to: increase the level of price signals in the market; allow the locational benefits of embedded generation to be assessed against transmission system augmentation; and encourage major electricity consumers to make investment decisions to locate in economically efficient locations. Further, all new interconnectors should be treated as unregulated interconnectors to avoid the market distortions which creates the IRS and expose the interconnector to comparable risk as its competitors. Yours sincerely JOHN HAYWARD General Manager, Planning and Development 8 March, 2016