Matthew Haigh ACCOUNTING’S ROLE IN PROVIDING FOR LIFE AFTER WORK Correspondence: Associate Professor Matthew Haigh, Department of Business Studies, Aarhus School of Business, Aarhus University, Fuglesangs Allé 4, Aarhus V, 8210 Denmark. Fax: +45 89 48 66 60. E-mail address: haighmatthew@yahoo.com.au. Prepared for the ILPC conference, Edinburgh, 2009. ABSTRACT Accounting standard setters have asserted and denied connections between the public interest and the reporting of employer-sponsored pension plans. Recognition of the public interest involves a real and apparent contribution to the idea of the public. For accounting standard setters, this rests on a capacity to contribute to the type of political economy to which the profession would claim its strongest commitment. Hence we see pensions reporting justified using assumptions about frictionless markets and, in particular, statements of the usefulness of reporting a marketised value. Other values are imbricated in private pension plans. Members project socialised economic expectations, liberal governmentalities inject a hopedfor release on the public purse, while investment consortia are on the lookout for unrecognised financial value. A shift of perspective made to include these concomitant values reveals an unwanted antagonism of representation according to fitness for trading. The model has been used to shape rather than to reflect realities. Sponsors have withdrawn their support from pension plans, which by promoting a transfer of the social security burden to the state, has detracted from an important ideal of the profession and its credibility in the business community. ACCOUNTING’S ROLE IN PROVIDING FOR LIFE AFTER WORK 1. INTRODUCTION As the calculative technology of accounting continues to gain in importance in so many spheres of social life, an understanding of the conditions and consequences of such a calculative technology is vital (Miller, 1994, p. 3). Accounting’s acquittance of the obligations it owes its ‘moral employers’ (Cooper, 2005, p. 596) hinges on a capacity to contribute to the type of liberalist political economy to which the profession claims its strongest commitment (Willmott, 1990). The techniques that standard setters have determined appropriate to measure and report employer-sponsored pension provision are those that would facilitate efficient capital markets. According to standard setters, this is the best way to serve the public interest. The reporting requirements have brought reductions of pension benefit levels, corollary outcome of which has been to transfer the welfare burden onto public systems. Such seemingly perverse outcome provides useful information on the location of the public interest in accounting requirement. The management of pensions arrangement is of some transnational political importance. Demographic changes have required actuarial adjustments to assumptions of the longevity of populations (Disney, 2000). Countries are urged to find ‘strong financial incentives to carry on working and existing [in which] subsidised pathways to early retirement have to be eliminated’ (OECD, 2006). Guarantees of social security using unregulated, private means of governance in which primary consideration is cost have proved difficult to maintain (Held, 2000). Eleven OECD countries operate mandatory employer-sponsored pensions as substitute for and supplementation of public pension provision[1]. These countries have adopted a position, to varying degrees, that the effective maintenance of private pensions requires structural adjustment to global capital (and occasionally labour) markets. Agents of states have turned to the actuarial and accountancy professions. ‘Adopt International Accounting Standards’ (Regulation 1606 of the European Parliament) and value relevance for potential investors in plan sponsors (Hann et al., 2007) have become catchwords before modernisation (EU Directives 43 and 51), integration (OECD, 2007a), single passport (The Pensions Regulator, 2007a), convergence (Lamfalussy, 2000a), smooth functioning (Lamfalussy, 2000b) and regularised monitoring (Thornton, 2007). By fiat, one type of pension plan, defined benefit arrangement, in which the sponsor promises a predetermined amount to its members, has been represented as expensive and risky for the sponsor. Sponsors have sought to replace the defined benefit with accumulation arrangements in which contributions invested directly, together with investment returns arising from the contributions, determine the amount of the post-employment benefits received. Accounting requirement for accumulation arrangement is much less extensive as relevant investment risks are transferred to plan members who, assumedly, have less need for reports of investment and actuarial assessments of their plans. At consideration in this paper is how the reporting treatment of employment-related pension plans in the US, UK and Australia might provide for the efficiency of capital markets (rather laudable goals and an objective of standard setters), articulate with national pensions policies and so serve as a vehicle for the accounting profession (both in the narrow sense of standard setting bodies and the wider sense of ‘accountants in practice’) to acquit its public interest obligations. 1 The paper uses both traditional and critical research paradigms. An objective common to the more traditional research conducted in capital markets, in pensions policy development and, to a lesser extent, in professional public interest obligations is ‘promotion of the rationalisation of society by being purposive, ... developing productive forces, [and] increasing technical mastery over nature’ (Benhabib, 1986, p. 230). In this tradition, value relevance of reporting of financial items becomes expressed in terms of, for example, ‘the association between financial statement measures and equity investors’ future cash flow expectations [… ] as proxied through stock prices’ (Hann et al., 2007, p. 329). (Conventional treatment in conventional capital markets research is to draw large samples of financial statements of quoted companies over a relatively short period.) Usefully, this tradition addresses those aspects of accounting treatment whose acceptability is not decided and points at the political nature of standard-setting processes. A critical theoretic approach is used to give credence to the structural conditions of pensions accounting treatment that in the usual case will escape consideration. Justification for a critical approach is found in much of the argument expressed in Willmott (1986, p. 556): However, at present, accountancy continues to be graced by a public image which, in stressing its technical, esoteric qualities, underplays the social and political formation of its practices and standards. ... The present paper ... reflect[s] the view that the organisation of the profession cannot be adequately understood independently of an appreciation of the political, economic and legal circumstances that have supported and constrained its development. A policy paradigm, in the framework expounded by the political scientist Peter Hall (1993), is constituted by an overarching set of ideas that specify how the problems facing policymakers are to be perceived, which goals might be attained, and what sorts of techniques can be used to reach these goals. Hall emphasises that all policy paradigms operate ideologically. An example is public pensions policy, where the ideological underpinnings of the idea of the public pension are found in the liberal welfare state, in which the policy goal might be to ‘alleviate the financial problems of the elderly’ part of the population no longer working, the policy instrument used ‘might be an old age pension’ and the instrument’s setting would concern the benefit level and its delivery (Hall, 1993, p. 278). Hall’s interpretation of policy development is used in a reading of Slavoj Žižek’s revival of dialectical materialism. Žižek (2006, pp. ix-x) seeks to ‘revive a practice of reading which confronts a classic text, author or notion with its own hidden presuppositions’ so as to reveal its ‘disavowed truth’. Using the contextual notion of parallax, which is defined in quantum mechanics as the apparent displacement of an object caused by a change in observational position, Žižek sees the dialectic as a way to comprehend conflicting perspectives whose existence necessarily binds them together. Parallax refers to a social (or political, or scientific ...) duality in which two perspectives that seem incommensurate reveal themselves, on analysis, to be composed of the same material. Thus there is no rapport between the two levels, no shared space—although they are closely connected, even identical in a way, they are, as it were, on the opposed sides of a Moebius strip. (Žižek, 2006, p. 4) Objective of analysis using the idea of parallax becomes identification of a ‘minimal difference [between rhetoric and reality] and which divides one and the same object from itself’ (Žižek, 2006, p. 18). Structural asymmetries are revealed by identification of 2 constitutive opposites. Parallaxes are shown between the public interest ideal—as encapsulated in accounting’s ‘conceptual framework’ and its supporting ideas of representational faithfulness and a true and fair view—with the social potential, depth of promise, and burden of the private pension. The text used is pronouncements about private pensions as appearing in legislation and issued by regulators, and contested between the accountancy, investment analysis and actuarial professions. National statistics of changes in private pension schemes are used to identify the social outcomes of such pronouncements. The paper proceeds in five sections. The next section justifies and outlines the method of data collection. A following section identifies the location of the public interest in the reporting requirements imposed on private pension plans. This is followed by a section which identifies and interprets the competition between the accountancy, investment analysis and actuarial professions for control of policy setting. A penultimate section discusses the real effects that accounting has brought to post-employment cessation benefits. A final section considers the problems that accounting standard setters face in the representation of social and economic realities, here problematizing accounting bodies’ constitutive allegiances and the wider implications this has for the contribution accounting practice might make to social security. 2. DATA COLLECTION The United States, United Kingdom and Australia were chosen for their mature, large and lightly regulated pension systems designed to supplement public pensions[2], the relatively high equity allocation in investment portfolios held by their private pension schemes, making them subject to many of the same policy-setting risks, and the pressure that ageing populations in these countries has brought on funding requirements (Disney, 2000). The exploration of the connections between pensions accounting and the professional public interest is based on a meta-analysis (Guthrie et al., 1991) of three different types of documents, the first of which comprised the scientific or academic literature. Here we examined roughly 120 reports, books, and papers issued by associations, think tanks, and academics and dealing with the topics of pensions governance and pensions accounting. The documents were located using online research databases (the main keywords being simply ‘pensions’, ‘accounting’, ‘employee benefits’, ‘actuarial’ and ‘fair valuation’) and the three predominant genres of informal scholarly communication on the internet, namely, mailing lists, scholarly homepages, and scholar-produced decentralised digital resources (Fry & Talja, 2007). Documents came from accounting, actuarial studies, corporate governance, demography, economics, finance, geography, legal studies, political science, public administration, and sociology. The second type of data comprised the pronouncements made and analyses provided by the many organizations involved in private pensions. The rhetoric of pronouncements and other evidences of history are important in an account of the linkages of social practices (Partner, 1977). Organizations sourced included the International Organization of Pension Supervisors, International Organization of Securities Commissions, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, the so-called Lamfalussy Level 3 networks[3], the UK Department for Work and Pensions and Financial Services Authority, as well as others. Lobby groups and professional associations were accessed and included the International Forum of Actuarial Associations, the OECD’s International Network of Pension Regulators and Supervisors and Private Pensions Working Party, and the UK’s Pensions Policy Institute, Age Concern England, Association of British Insurers, Confederation of British Industry, National Association of Pension Funds, Trades Union Congress, The Pensions Regulator, Pensions 3 Commission, and Institutional Shareholders Committee. Another data source used was media outlets such as Investment & Pensions Europe, and Pensions Funds Online. This second data set comprised just over 400 pages of website material, not including the reports or documents to which these organizations’ websites are linked. A third type of data comprised the commentaries and pronouncements of major accounting and actuarial bodies. Sources included the International Accounting Standards Board, European Financial Reporting Advisory Group, International Federation of Accountants, American Society of Certified Practicing Accountants, the Institutes of Chartered Accountants in England and Wales and in Australia, the UK’s Faculty and Institute of Actuaries, the Financial Reporting Councils of the UK and Australia, and the Australian Accounting Standards Board. Documents included proposals and exposure drafts of accounting standards and actuarial guidance notes, and articles published in professional journals and websites. This material amounted to just under 1,000 pages, not including the reports or documents to which these organizations’ websites are linked. 3. LOCATING THE PUBLIC INTEREST IN PENSIONS REPORTING REQUIREMENT The public interest as a normative theory is consistent with the notion of the common good as it was originally identified in the 17th century—to enhance the common good rather than private interests. This view is consistent with the concept of the common good bound in the welfarist state (George & Wilding, 1994). Therefore according to the normative perspective, a policy or action is in the public interest if it advances the collective welfare of the public (Oppenheim, 1975, p. 265). An abolitionist view of the public interest sees no interests in the public and only diverse groups each with their own particular set of interests and goals pursued in the absence of consideration to others (Cochran, 1974). In this view, the public interest is an orientation toward the maximisation of private interests within the constraints imposed by organised society (Dellaportas & Davenport, 2008). The ideas of retirement provision and the public interest in accounting pronouncement both reference the idea that the liberal welfarist state is the best conduit for economic and social welfare. The public interest, impartiality and integrity have been ranked with value to investors (Francis & Schipper, 1999), transparency of reporting to investors (Barth et al., 2008; Sapra, 2008) and provision of information useful in assessing the stewardship of managers (Barlev & Haddad, 2003). The relevant public in the actuarial measurement of pensions is held as ‘consulting clients, employers, lawyers, accountants, policymakers and regulators ... investors, policyholders, pension scheme members, employees and beneficiaries’ (Financial Reporting Council, 2009). Accounting’s public interest in private pensions appears more nebulous. Argument has appeared that the relevant public in pensions reporting includes investors and might extend to pensions scheme members (see, International Accounting Standards Board, 2006a; OECD, 2007b). To better specify the location of accounting’s public interest, it is helpful to sketch the institutional arrangements (Gallie, 2008) of private pension schemes. Figure 1 below gives the oversight arrangement in the US, UK and Australia. [insert point for Figure 1] The relative emphases placed on accounting’s core values of representational faithfulness, reliability, relevance and comparability can indicate the type of public interest being served (Willmott, 1990). The values underpinning pensions accounting have been caught up in the 4 concept of fair valuation. A trend toward recognition of fair-valued measurements for financial items begins from 1976 in the US, following the passing of federal legislation that governed the minimum funding requirements for an employer-sponsored pension scheme and the maintenance of the ratio of plan assets to accrued liabilities. Under accounting standards[4], an entity offering a pension scheme of a defined benefit type must calculate how much it will have to pay in future pensions, discount those payments to the present, deduct the market value of plan investments, and report the result as either a liability or asset in its statement of financial position. Fair value applied to an asset purchased by a pension fund means a current exit price—a price referring to that relevant to a hypothetical seller of an item reported or used in the valuation of an item reported in the statement of financial position (Financial Accounting Standards Board, 2007).[5] In line with the dividend-discounting valuation model which posits a connection between quoted prices and accounting numbers, accumulated benefits payable under a DB plan are discounted when the measurement date extends beyond the reporting date. The calculation uses the Projected Unit Credit Method, which uses prescribed mortality tables (as issued by national public actuaries) and discount rate, and takes into account other assumptions concerning final salaries, employee turnover and medical cost trends, possibility of future pension increases if benefits are indexed with general price changes, and any other variable that will influence the cost of the benefit. The result is the present value of the total DB obligation. A discounting requirement appeared after a Financial Accounting Standards Board-initiated review in 2005 of pensions reporting. That review pointed to two benefits of pensions reporting, namely, reporting transparency and measurement appropriateness. Some evidence then is provided of the public interest in pensions accounting being located with investors. Representation of DB arrangement as expensive and risky and of accumulation arrangement as the only other possible alternative is claimed to supply transparency to investors. The claim is made by connecting stewardship and an assumed link between equity prices and reported performance. [Because investors believe that] fair value is grounded in economic reality, [fair value] facilitates informed investment decisions, which ultimately strengthens our capital markets. (Financial Accounting Standards Board, 2008) The fairness in use of values ascribed to the capital markets derives from the parity of information as used by a willing buyer and willing seller (Bradbury, 2008). The claim of measurement appropriateness is supported by argument that as the sponsoring entity will bear the actuarial and investment risks associated with a DB plan (i.e., the risk of an unfunded plan), the entity should report that risk. The funded status is measured as the difference between the fair value of plan assets and the projected DB obligation. Funding requirements calculated under the Projected Unit Credit Method are expected to maintain the pension fund assets at such a level that, with future investment income but without any future contributions, the fund will be able to pay all accrued benefits until the last plan beneficiary dies (OECD, 2007b). Due to the method of calculation, the absolute value of the gain/expense under DB arrangement might be greater than produced under an accumulation scheme of similar size and asset composition, and less predictable[6]. It appears then that the public interest in pensions reporting encompasses two groups. Fair valuation is relevant because (a) it brings transparency and appropriateness to a potential investor in a firm and (b) supplies information on funding adequacy to a member of a pension plan.[7] 5 An assumption underlying the requirement of pensions reporting standards is that the value yielded is relevant to a hypothetical seller (e.g., Financial Accounting Standards Board, 2006b) (i.e., an investor considering its options). This is a different type of user from that which has been used to justify financial reporting for pensions. The Accounting Standards Board (2008, Ch. 11: 2.1) sees a need for pensions accounting stemming from assumed need of plan beneficiaries to assess the sponsor covenant. The UK actuarial standard setting bodies have commented in several places that a different amount to the amount yielded under financial reporting standards may be relevant for purposes of assessment of the strength of the sponsor covenant. Actuarial Guidance Note 36 Accounting for Retirement Benefits under Financial Reporting Standard 17 (Financial Reporting Council, 2006b) explains the differences to liability valuation produced under the two sets of requirements. The aim of a valuation is to crystallise an amount which can be applied to a transaction or recorded in a formal document, whereas the aim of planning is to arrive at a provisional amount for budgeting or target-setting purposes. (Board for Actuarial Standards, 2008) The planning amount, determined jointly by the plan’s consulting actuary and the sponsor, concerns funding assessments and as such is influential in the maintenance of the sponsor covenant. The assumptions appropriate to the accounting amount, namely, ‘for the purposes of a transaction’ (Board for Actuarial Standards, 2008, clause A.9), are not those that would promote maintenance of the sponsor covenant. Accounting standards setters have added to recognition uncertainty by announcing a series of changes to the bases of valuation. Discounting uses a stipulated rate which is chosen by reference to current conditions in the markets for used by an organization to source debt capital. SFAS 158 originally equated the discounting rate to the four-year weighted average yield on 30-year US Treasury bonds. FASB requirement has since reflected the treatment mandated by the IASB, which, following prescription in the UK’s FRS 17 Retirement Benefits, gives the discount rate as current yields on high-quality corporate bonds in cases where there is a large market in corporate bonds. (FRS 17 allows UK companies to value pensions liabilities use AA-rated corporate bond yields, which are generally higher than the British standards setter’s proposal in 2008 to use a lower rate such as that attaching to indexlinked UK government bonds). The Australian standards setter has changed the discounting rate stipulated on three occasions since 2004. To reiterate, accounting standard setters have claimed that the reporting requirements for DB schemes are designed to meet the needs of plan members[8] (e.g., The Institute of Chartered Accountants in Australia, 2006). The calculation of DB liabilities, which represents pension plans by how much they might fetch in an auction, suggests that accounting has prioritized the assumed purposes of potential investors over those of plan members. The history of pensions reporting and certain anomalies in pensions reporting requirement point at ‘an insistence on compromise, on negotiation, on piecemeal “democratic” reform, [which] has long been the privileged vehicle for the reproduction and reinforcement of the status quo’ (Žižek, 2006, p. 322). The current piecemeal reporting requirements belie standard setters’ claim of representational faithfulness[9]. In 2007 and 2008, widespread market instabilities were associated with increased volatilities in corporate bond yields and declines in the value of equity investments held by pension funds. Sponsors holding DB schemes in this period could use increases in corporate bond yields to offset asset losses in asset portfolios and include the result in corporate income. As instance, BT (British Telecom) reported a GBP600 6 million surplus after tax in its defined benefit schemes in the September quarter of 2008. The surplus was comprised of a decrease of quoted value of assets owned by BT’s plans (GBP2.9 billion), which was offset by the relatively (and unusually) high yield offered by the iBoxx fifteen-year index (7.25 percent) used to discount BT’s pension obligations. In the name of representational faithfulness, international financial reporting standards have allowed profound decreases in the values of assets purchased by schemes to be represented as reductions in payment obligations and realised gains.[10] A public interest constructed of a different public according to the item under measurement surely cannot describe accounting’s highest ideal. The Public Interest Oversight Board was formed by regulators in 2005 following concerns that the credibility of the accounting profession had been compromised by the financial scandals of the early 2000s[11].Fair valuation, apparently on the basis of its status as a measurement basis of various types of financial assets, has been connected to regulators’ concerns of capital market stability and hence to an international-styled public interest ‘inherent’ to audit practice and financial reporting, ‘a broad and evolving concept that requires continuous engagement with many entities in the international environment’ (Public Interest Oversight Board, 2008). Entities in the Board’s sights are those ‘that endorse and support its mission’ and ‘other international entities that have explicit public interest goals’ such as the Forum of Firms (a network of public accounting firms with transnational audit clients), International Association of Insurance Supervisors, Committee of European Securities Regulators, Financial Stability Forum (a network of financial regulatory authorities) and the International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO), from which PIOB’s inaugural Chairman and another member have been drawn. Such entities indicate accounting’s public interest is selective, and necessarily abolitionist. The reporting values claimed in support of the public interest objective are ‘transparency, proportionality and comparability’, taken to refer collectively to cross-border confidence of, impliedly, regulators and investors. Accountants are expected to use ‘increasingly principles-based standards’ so as to ‘promote the needs of the public’, namely, clients of accountancy services, in areas ‘where the actions of a profession can improve or harm the common wellbeing’. Standard setters have not deigned to identify common wellbeing. 4. A HISTORY OF PROFESSIONAL COMPETITION FOR FAIR VALUE The evolution of pensions reporting treatment has followed a different path from the original purpose of modern financial reporting to manage social relationships between providers and management of capital (Bryer, 1993). Accounting standard setting bodies have used and developed the initiatives and pronouncement of actuarial, investment analysis and other trade associations to promote fair valuation reporting and to promote itself. The emergence and development of professional accountancy bodies, as argued by Willmott (1986, pp. 556, 558), has relied on political processes ‘whose purpose is to define, organise, secure and advance the interests of their (most vocal and influential) members’ and in so doing provide ‘a basis for the domination of [associated] institutions, organisations and other occupations’. The ascendancy of fair valuation in financial reporting since 1990 has relied on relations between the professional accounting bodies and the institutions inscribing and instating the capital markets. IOSCO (2008a) sees the international accounting standards as a mechanism which will facilitate capital by providing consistency to financial reporting. IOSCO’s objective to reduce the ‘costs and complexity of international accounting standards’ has seen ‘adequate transparency’ equated to information on trading values[12]. Pronouncements 7 issued by the Accounting Standards Board (2008), The Faculty and Institute of Actuaries (2008), the European Financial Reporting Advisory Group (2008) and other quasi-regulators, some of which exhibit cross-memberships, have lent support to IOSCO in its mission to establish fair valuation as the single basis of financial reporting. Institutional momentum has also been garnered in the joint FASB/IASB (2008) project[13] on fair valuation. The FASB and IASB have sought ‘authoritative’ opinion from such as the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, the International Organisation of Pension Supervisors (formed by the OECD in 2004 and represented by supervisors of employer-sponsored pensions), and the Chartered Financial Analysts Institute. The latter, as illustration of the type of consensus opinion emitted, has issued statements that ‘fair value is the most relevant information for financial decision making’ (Chartered Financial Analysts Institute, 2007) and has recommended fair value assessment of defined pension plan assets according to ‘liquidity’ (of the sponsor). The OECD (2007b) has suggested that the UK Accounting Standards Board has hoped to boost its professional credibility by advocating an accepted actuarial funding method for accounting valuation. British accounting standard setting bodies have long sought involvement with the actuarial profession and the investments industry. Establishment of the Pension Research Accountants Group and the Pension Management Institute in 1976 led to several actuarial guidance notes for accountants. In 1988, a time in which the UK’s Accounting Standards Committee was grappling for professional legitimacy (Willmott, 1986), the Committee issued a pension accounting standard, Statement of Standard Practice 24 Accounting for pension costs. An early stage of professionalisation is establishment of legitimacy with other professions (McKinstry, 1997). SSAP 24 was introduced at a time when pension fund policy in the UK had been controlled by professional advisers, and chief among them the actuarial profession, for nearly forty years. Between 1970 and 1990, lack of transparency was considered an important aspect of the prevailing approach to actuaries’ pension fund risk management, an aspect which was reflected in the requirements of SSAP 24 (Avrahampour, 2008). The Accounting Standards Board, once established in 1990, moved to establish professional accounting values such the public interest, value relevance, information transparency and information reliability (see, Accounting Standards Board, 2000a). Although the UK accounting profession—at the minimum, the accounting standard setting bodies—had by 1990 directed itself outside the actuarial profession, it maintained close connections with the insurance and investments industries (see, Ernst & Young, 1996). The actuarial profession was also developing at this time, when as described in Klumpes (1999, p. 186), actuaries developed ‘realistic’ and ‘economic’ methods to report UK life insurance company profitability to shareholders. The models incorporated risk into measurement by the rate used in calculation of future expected outgoings and future expected premium income. (Actuaries have legal authority to value the profitability of life insurance companies and pension schemes in OECD countries.) Pension obligations and employees’ long service leave entitlements had become objects of an ASB objective to position accountancy services as an important profession in financial services. ASB issuance in 1999 of Exposure Draft FRED 20 Retirement Benefits associated these items with previous attempts at professional primacy such as the fair value accounting treatment of long-term insurance contracts (Horton & Macve, 1994). Fair valuation heralded in FRED 20 and subsequently mandated in FRS 17 Retirement Benefits (issued 2000) established the power of the Accounting Standards Board[14]. For the first time, the requirements of a mandated accounting standard were more stringent than actuarial practice. (FRS 17 has, for instance, mandated the Projected Unit Credit method of expense calculation, one of several available methods.) 8 This achievement allowed the Accounting Standards Board to demonstrate its independence from the actuarial profession. The British actuarial bodies responded to FRS 17 (rather than caused a response, as had been the norm) by issuing a separate Guidance Note (see, Financial Reporting Council, 2006a). In a battle for possession played out between the savoirs (Dezalay, 1995), it is the accountants, once preceded, who were being heard first. The Accounting Standards Board’s mooted changes to FRS 17 (see, Note 8) has kept the control of pensions valuation firmly in accountants’ hands, with the period for submissions being prolonged on more than one occasion. The accounting, investment analysis and actuarial professions’ often shared consultation processes, shared supervisory authority, and coincidence of pronouncements (e.g., International Forum of Actuarial Associations, 1997) lend support to an argument that professional competition (Fogarty & Grant, 1995) has shaped the accounting treatment for pensions. 5. REAL EFFECTS OF PENSIONS ACCOUNTING This section present evidence to support argument that the attention and commitment paid by accounting standard setting bodies to market value-based reporting has led to certain deleterious changes to employer-sponsored retirement provision. Taking the form of a scientific parallax, the model has shaped, rather than reflected, economic realities. A following final section reflects on the implications for accounting’s public interest obligations. There have been four recent changes to private pensions plans in the US, UK and Australia. Membership levels of schemes have declined. Sponsors have replaced DB arrangements with accumulation schemes. Benefits available in accumulation arrangements have been less generous than offered in DB schemes. Sponsors have transferred pension obligations from their financial statements. These changes are considered below in four sub sections. The material used focuses on the UK and the US. 5.1 CHANGES TO MEMBERSHIP LEVELS The current plan for national social security in the UK is drastically modified from that drawn up by William Beveridge in 1942. The UK supplements a basic state pension with mandatory employee contributions made through a National Insurance system. There is no mandate for a third tier of employer-sponsored pension arrangement. Coverage of employer-sponsored plans in 2006 was 43 percent of men and 37 percent of women working (Office for National Statistics, 2008). Membership levels in UK schemes have been in decline since the start of the current decade. Between 2000 and 2005, membership of all types of UK pensions schemes decreased by 33.1 percent. Between 2005 and 2007, the decrease was 18.4 percent, and in open-ended (meaning contributions are accepted) schemes, 41.6 percent. Between 2005 and 2006, ‘active’ membership (not retired and contributing) of all types of private sector schemes fell by 4.3 percent. Declines in scheme membership levels are marked in DB arrangement. Between 2000 and 2005, the proportion of active members in DB schemes that were closed to new members increased from around 10 percent to around 40 percent. Between 2005 and 2006, membership of DB schemes (75 percent of active members in private sector schemes) fell by 13.0 percent (The Pensions Regulator, 2007b). An extrapolation from a Pensions Regulator study of 1,300 private sector schemes and 200 public sector schemes suggests that between 2006 and 2007, the total number of schemes fell 9.0 percent, the number of open-ended schemes dropped 8.8 9 percent, and membership of private sector accumulation schemes slipped 10.0 percent to 900,000. In 2007, 60 percent of DB schemes were closed to new members or were in the process of closing down completely (Pensions Regulator, 2007a). 5.2 A SHIFT TO ACCUMULATION ARRANGEMENT Accounting requirements have been acknowledged by standards setters themselves and commentators as contributing to valuation uncertainty and problems of funding shortfalls in employer-sponsored pensions, particularly in regards to cost (Accounting Standards Board, 2008; Clark & Monk, 2007b). DB schemes tend to be more generous and encourage greater employee contributions accumulation schemes. In the UK, the average private sector employer (employee) contribution rates in 2005 were 16.0 percent (4.4 percent) of salary for DB schemes compared with 6.3 percent (2.7 percent) for accumulation schemes (Office for National Statistics, 2007). Most British DB schemes existing in 2004 were created before 1980 (between 59 and 71 percent) (Office for National Statistics, 2005). One in three open DB schemes existing in 2006 was set up in the period 1945-1969. This compares to five percent of open accumulation schemes set up in the same period. The relative proportions reverse with schemes set up after 2000 (Office for National Statistics, 2007). (Approximate figures have been used in these comparisons.) Figure 2 below gives the movements between UK DB and accumulation schemes in the period 2000-2007. [insert point for Figure 2] Between 2000 and 2004, the numbers of open DB schemes decreased by 36.3 percent (52.1 percent decrease in the private sector), while the number of accumulation schemes increased 13.2 percent (Government Actuary’s Department, 2006). The smaller decrease in 2005 of all open DB schemes includes a 66.2 percent decrease in private sector open DB schemes. The fewer accumulation schemes in 2005 (7.8 percent decrease) has been attributed to the closure in that year of schemes with fewer than 12 members. There have been two types of DB dismantlement. The first type concerns the dissolution and freeze of DB schemes. (A pension freeze means stopping future accruals for existing members and/or new employees.) A second type of dismantlement concerns the decision of a plan sponsor to offer its pension obligations for sale to uninterested buyers (in the sense of non-fiduciary interest). Munnell et al. (2006) list 17 US-listed companies which, not exhibiting signs of financial distress, closed their DB pension schemes over the period 2004-2006. The 400,000 affected employees were all offered substitute 401(k) plans. Replacement of DB schemes in the US by accumulation schemes and elimination of benefits in existing arrangements have been attributed to inter alia fair value accounting (Barlev & Haddad, 2003)[15]. Similar causes to declining numbers of DB schemes in the UK have been cited (Bridgen & Meyer, 2005). The following six large, politically visible companies in the US and Europe closed their DB schemes during the period 2005-2007. The sample was chosen judgementally on the basis of the financial health of each of the companies in the sample at the time of scheme closure. Sprint Nextel Corporation (nyse: s) announced in 2005 that from 2006 employees vested in its DB plans prior to its 2005 purchase of Nextel Communications Inc. would stop accruing benefits. Non-vested employees would receive benefits once satisfying qualification requirements. The plan would affect 39,000 of the pre-acquisition total of 82,900 employees. The announcements appeared to be related to plan solvency[16]. ALCOA (nyse: AA) announced, in 2006, plans for closure of its DB scheme for new employees from 2007. 10 Quoting ‘volatility’ and ‘expense’ (possibly code for the accounting requirements to use selling prices in calculation of DB plan expenses) ALCOA made a decision to supply new employees an accumulation 401(k) pension plan, offering a lower absolute level of employee benefits[17]. Similar plans were announced in 2006 by DuPont (nyse: DD), announcing that, beginning 2008, contribution rates to existing US workers’ pensions (estimated at 30,000, August 2006) would be reduced by two-thirds, disqualifying portions of salaries from attracting pension entitlements, closing all DB schemes to employees hired after December 2006, and removing co-contributions for health care and life assurance benefits. The plans were prompted by the solvency position of its DB schemes. At year end 2005, DuPont DB pension obligations were USD22.9 billion and associated assets were USD19.8 billion. The announced closure and contribution reduction were expected to improve earnings by approximately 3 cents per share in 2007 and 5 cents per share in 2008[18]. The consumer goods company Unilever NV (nyse: UN) announced plans in 2007 to close its DB scheme to new members, offering in its place a less generous ‘hybrid’ scheme[19]. The new scheme had a DB component, based on a career average, covering pensionable earnings up to a threshold of GBP35,000 per annum. Above this threshold there was an accumulation component. Employee members of the existing Unilever DB scheme were asked to increase their contribution to the fund. The Spanish-owned Ferrovial subsidiary British Airports Authority (London: BAAPY) announced in 2008 that it was closing its solvent staff DB scheme to be replaced by accumulation arrangement. Members of the replacement accumulation scheme were offered an employer contribution rate of fifteen percent, ill-health retirement and death-in-service benefits, and life assurance benefits for members’ partners. Actuarial advice obtained by BAA’s staff association suggested that the benefits promised under the accumulation scheme would not approximate the benefits foregone under the DB scheme[20]. British Airways (London: BAY) announced in 2006 that it wanted to significantly reduce its GBP2.1 billion pension fund deficit. The success of the deal depended on whether British Airways staff accepted a cut in future benefits and/or an increase in the scheme’s normal retirement age for pilots and cabin crew from 55 to 65 and from 60 to 65 for ground staff. Trustees’ subsequent acceptance of the offer was met with a rejection from employees.[21] 5.3 CHANGES TO BENEFIT LEVELS A third phenomenon is the reduction of benefits available in existing arrangements. Employer contribution rates in UK accumulation schemes between 2006 and 2007 were significantly lower (respectively, 56.5 percent and 64.2 percent) than in comparable DB schemes (Office for National Statistics , 2008). This suggests that cost considerations might be significant to sponsors. The average pension obligation reported on the FTSE Global 100 index as at 31 December, 2007 was GBP5.9 billion. The average excess of obligation over plan assets was GBP176.5 million (3.0 percent). The significance of these amounts can be assessed by noting that pension obligations represented 13 percent of the GBP4.58 trillion market capitalisation of the FTSE Global 100 index as at 31 December, 2007. The reported total pensions deficit in 2007 was 92.0 percent of the GBP19.1 billion of pension contributions (Lane, Clark & Peacock, 2008). The sensitivity of these amounts to changes in assumptions used in their calculations have been illustrated by Brigden et al. (2008), predicting, for example, significant increases to contributions payable to plans if the discount factor used were to be lowered from the rates required over the 2004-2007 period. 11 The UK Accounting Standards Board proposals to lower the discount factor used (see, Note 8) are supported by the UK Pensions Regulator, which has added a proposal to ‘standardise’ the various longevity assumptions (mortality rates) permitted in pensions accounting. According to commentators, if both set of proposals were implemented in the form proposed, they would increase the volatilities and absolute levels of reported pension liabilities. The Department for Work and Pensions has advised its critics (e.g., Bridgen et al., 2008; National Association of Pension Funds, 2008) to ‘put up or shut up’ (Thornton, 2007, p. 40).[22] Example of the types of benefits affected is provided by the British retailer Marks and Spencer Group plc (London: MKS). In January 2009, the retailer announced various reductions of benefits in its DB staff pension schemes, affecting at the time 21,000 members. Reductions included a ten percent reduction of its annual GBP300 million cash contributions to plans; partial disqualification of increases to salaries to pensionable salaries; acceleration of reductions of benefits for members retiring before pensionable age; and redirection of income earned by assets of the schemes to the company. Reasons cited for the announced measures included the company’s intention to reduce its reported pension liabilities, and uncertainties introduced by reporting requirements placed on private DB schemes.[23] 5.4 TRANSFER OF OBLIGATIONS A fourth phenomenon is the transfer of pension liabilities from sponsors’ financial statements. Tinker and Ghicas (1993) have suggested that compliance with SFAS 36 (since superseded by SFAS 87) may have led to overstatements of US pension surpluses due to underreporting of net pension liabilities. The requirement of SFAS 36, by underscoring ‘the amount that could be appropriated’ (Tinker & Ghicas, 1993, p. 361), possibly motivated takeovers of firms tin order o extract the plan surpluses and divert them from plan members. The attractiveness of a sale option for a plan sponsor comes with the financially uncompensated risk of holding a pension obligation in its statement of financial position. The aggregate position of DB schemes may vary considerably. In 2006, the value of aggregate deficits for UK DB schemes was estimated at GBP33.8 billion if calculated according to Section 179 of the Pensions Act 2004 and GBP88.6 billion under FRS 17 (The Pensions Regulator, 2007a). The reason for the difference, according to The Pension Regulator, is that under the Pensions Act, estimates of liabilities exclude any indexation of benefits accrued before April 1997, whereas FRS 17 includes indexation for the entire accrual period. It becomes in the interests of an investor to negotiate a transfer price at fair value such that benefits under a plan are reduced and a surplus extracted. Buyers of pension plans in the UK have included private equity consortia and investment banks [24, 25]. In retirement plans established under trust, the employer does not have direct liability for benefits but only an obligation to fund the trust to provide the benefits. In a sale agreement, plan members stand to lose if the sale agreement includes a shortfall clause whereby the seller underwrites any shortfall in the actual amount transferred by the trustees compared with the negotiated transfer amount. Other usual consequence affecting the beneficiaries of a transferred plan is a non-extensible cap to any annuities purchased under the plan. Both have been common in, following the issues of FRS 17 and IAS 19, the transfers of pension obligations made as part of an acquisition of a business and outright sales of pension obligations (Clark and Monk, 2007a). 12 6. ACCOUNTING-IN-PRAXIS Our aim has been to conceive the gaps and tensions between the social idea of the private pension scheme and the public interest obligation of the accounting profession as recognised in accounting pronouncement. The financial panics which preceded conceptualisation of retirement savings and health insurance schemes in the early twentieth century (Bridgen, 2000) were the rationale for the promotion of the actuarial and accounting professions (Willmott, 1986). Actuaries were seen to provide accuracy to a scheme’s funding requirements by appropriate measurement of payment obligations and assets used to fund those obligations (Keintz & Stickney, 1980), while accountants were seen to provide an objectively relevant level of transparency (McKernan, 2007). By providing adequate information about the firm, the capital markets would self-correct, financial crises could be avoided and distribution of wealth could proceed. Hence, transparency became representative of relevance, which became the value most intimately caught up in the ideal of the public interest. To date, recognition of the public interest in the accounting treatment of private pension schemes has been justified by reference to transparency, comparability, and relevance to capital markets and, more tenuously, to labour markets. We are reminded by Bourdieu (2001, p. 97) that organizations and individuals in organizations engage in economic exchanges to accrue various forms of capital: economic, cultural, and social. Cultural capital has been defined as ‘those expectations for action within a collectivity that affect the economic goals and goal-seeking behavior of its members, even if those expectations are not oriented toward the economic sphere’ (Portes & Sensenbrenner, 2001, p. 114). Contemporary meanings of social capital refer metaphorically to the building of a community through its spirit and its joint activities (Farr, 2004) and to the systematization of the effects of social relations (Bourdieu, 2001). ‘The very meaning of the exchange’ (Bourdieu, 2001, p. 106) between a plan’s sponsor, trustee and members is the stocks of connections and social relationships and the discharge of obligations of that involvement. The employer-sponsored pension plan is an arrangement designed to improve the quality of both work and social life (Gallie, 2006) in capitalist societies. The rise of pension schemes as the principal vehicle of institutional investment and (what might be seen as) the predominant form of appropriation of surplus-value has made labour a direct participant in the wild speculations of financial capital. A perspective of a form of social organization as an unsecured debt has inserted a concrete antagonism between lived experience, which refers to the store of meanings projected into members’ accumulated savings, and representation of that arrangement. A permanent gap is opened between ‘the phenomenal experience of reality’ and its scientific, as-if objective explanation (Žižek, 2006, p. 247). This is example of Žižek’s description of how representation on occasion instates for reality. Reporting transparency and comparability are ‘not directly properties which demonstrate ... priority over others, but indicators of such properties—the so-called “fitness indicators”’ (Žižek, 2006, p. 247, emphasis original). Setting such as representational faithfulness into a hierarchy governed by a public interest ideal is illusory. Of course, the enigma here is: how does this short circuit come about? How can the ... experience which was originally a mere by-product of goal-oriented activity ... turn into an aim in itself? (Žižek, 2006, p. 247, emphasis original) 13 It is not as if accounting standard setting bodies are unaware that their commitment to an ontology borne of financial economics might frustrate a public interest ideal. This might be confined to a professional (philosophical ) difficulty and a matter for reflection if not for the reliance of many OECD countries on private solutions as a mechanism of social security and, therein, opportunity for the standard setting bodies to make a (real) contribution to the public interest. Private pension schemes provide an example of where standard setters’ partiality to mirror economic reality reflects another partiality towards a particular, imagined conflux of social welfare and private interests. Fair valuation has been used to promote an active capital market and, to that extent, some success can be marked out. Unintended outcomes include an unsecured, volatile debt of the plan sponsor, in turn placing pressure on public funds for provision of retirement security. The truth of capital markets (symbolizing economic reality) has vacated other meaning from national social policies and cultural meanings of postretirement arrangement. Representation of the private pension by its trading value is at the abolitionist end (Hall, 1993) of public interest models. Accounting hardly has discretion to lay aside its normative public interest ideal. Recovery of accounting’s status as a helping profession (Danile & McCarthy, 2007) is linked to an ability to countenance the short-circuiting logic of appearance and essence (Žižek, 2006, p. 417). For a consulting actuary, proportionality means to ‘consider not only the potential cost from the perspective of those who incur the cost, but also the potential benefits when viewed from the perspective of the beneficiaries’ (Board for Actuarial Standards, 2008). Less even-handed is accounting’s prescription of a valuation base designed for a sceptical but otherwise uninterested investor. Reality and a promise of a better one are given together in a rationalized world (Eagleton, 1991, p. 184). A preparedness to maintain (by practising, commenting on and teaching) accounting’s conceptual framework and a set of financial reporting standards tailored to a set of private interests must recognise the performative contradiction. The public interest is not some sort of screen interposing between social realities and ourselves; nor is it a superstructure erected over pressing economic realities. If the profession is to discharge its public interest obligation, it must show its link to the technical principles it prescribes. Accounting’s governing principle comes into being as a politics of prescription (described in Žižek, 2006, pp. 321-325). Its limitation is precisely that the form of the public interest as ideal is not concrete enough, but a mere neutral container of some content—fair value, truth and fairness, and representational faithfulness—that eludes this form. [1] US, UK, Australia, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand, Belgium, Czech Republic, France, Germany and Japan. Assets in OECD private pension schemes at 2006 were valued at USD15.2 trillion, just under two-thirds of the total OECD funded pensions market. <http://webnet.oecd.org/wbos/index.aspx> Downloaded 7 July 2008. The terminology in this paper follows the OECD (2007a) pensions taxonomy. [2] The US, UK and Australia have relatively high ratios of pension fund assets-to-GDP (over 70 percent) and have not regulated funding requirements of private pension plans as 14 they have been in places such as the Netherlands, which places solvency buffers on pension funds’ equity and derivatives investment strategies and mandates the debt securities yield curve used to value pension obligations. [3] The Committees of European Securities Regulators, European Banking Supervisors and European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Supervisors have begun acting in a regulatory capacity. [4] Sixteen reporting standards and pronouncements prescribe pensions reporting in the US, UK and Australia. Fair valuation for benefits payable was introduced in 1985 by SFAS 87 Employers’ Accounting for Pensions; current US standards are SFAS 157 Fair Value Measurements and SFAS 158 Employers’ Accounting for Defined Benefit Pension and Other Postretirement Plans. The UK and Australia have issued, respectively, FRS 17 Retirement Benefits and AASB 119 Employee Benefits. The IASB has issued IAS 19 Employee Benefits and IAS 26 Accounting and Reporting by Retirement Benefit Plans. The Australian accounting standard AAS 25 Financial Reporting by Superannuation Plans, issued to apply to public sector agency reporting, provides an exception to use of fair valuation as a measurement basis for payment obligations. [5] Two FASB standards discuss fair value in relation to markets. SFAS 115, cl. 3a, justifies the use of fair value of equity securities only in cases where prices are readily available, giving a definition of fair value as a potential seller’s estimates of market prices based on the present value of estimated future cash flows. SFAS 125 supplies procedures for determining the fair value of assets in circumstances where quoted market prices are not available. The US has moved toward IAS 19, which in 2005 was amended to resemble the UK’s FRS 17 (Munnell et al., 2006). [6] Accounting for expenses in accumulation plans as set out in IAS 19, FRS 17, SFAS 158, and AASB 119 is straightforward because the entity’s expense for each period is determined by the undiscounted amounts to be contributed for that period as set out in agreement establishing the plan. Treatment of expenses in DB arrangement is more extensive. An initial increment produced using the Projected Unit Credit Method represents the undiscounted current obligation. The associated expense, known as the current service cost, is calculated by reference to the discounted value of the additional unit of benefit attributable to the current period of service of employees in the plan. To this amount is added any change in the fair values of pension assets and in the discounted value of accrued benefits, the latter known as interest cost, with an adjustment made for the expected return on plan assets, which is computed by multiplying the assumed long-term rate of investment return by the average fair value of assets during the year and, if positive, deducted from the other items. Additionally, changes to the levels of benefits promised to plan members, known as past service cost, are amortised to the statement of financial performance over the period from reporting date to expected redemption date. The effects of fluctuations in market values of plan assets, known as actuarial gains and losses, are not recognised in the statement of financial performance but 15 in a separate statement of total recognised gains and losses. Unrecognised actuarial gains and losses (within a prescribed bound) and unrecognised past service cost are recognised indirectly by adjustments made to the defined benefit obligation. [7] The UK, US and Australia are expected to act on IASB Interpretation IFRIC 14 IAS 19 The Limit on a Defined Benefit Asset, Minimum Funding Requirements and their Interaction (issued July 2007). IFRIC 14 establishes the salience of fair-valued assets for those DB pension scheme arrangements that require a minimum funding level from a sponsor (most of them). The condition set is this: when fair-valued plan assets exceed present-valued obligations, a surplus is created. In the usual case, such would be recognised as an asset. If a minimum funding requirement exists—customary in a DB scheme—an asset is not to be recognised, a liability is to be recognised by reducing any recognised DB asset (in the case of a surplus) or by increasing the DB liability, and note disclosure is required on the ’estimation uncertainty’. [8] The Accounting Standards Board (2008) has advocated several changes to FRS 17, including an extension of fair valuation measurement from final salary schemes to average salary and cash balance pension schemes; reporting of changes in pension assets and liabilities as they ‘happen’ rather than as projected; use of actual current requirement of estimated returns on assets in the calculation of the pension obligation; and replacement of the corporate bond rates currently used as to value pension obligations by a lower rate attaching to public bonds. [9] Four inconsistencies in pensions reporting requirement can be noted: (i) Allowance in IAS 19 of offset of the value of plan assets against payment obligations is inconsistent with a principle set out in IAS 1 Presentation of Financial Statements, cl. 32 and present in other treatment, e.g., IAS 18 Revenue and IAS 12 Income Taxes; (ii) Recognition of expected return from plan assets departs from the concept of accrual accounting—to recognise income when it is earned—as set out in the IASB Conceptual Framework document; (iii) The extent of discretion permitted for recognition of actuarial gains and losses contradicts requirement in IAS 8 Accounting Policies, Changes in Accounting Estimates and Errors: (iv) Pension reporting standards use principles of measurement faithfulness, matching expenses to income and assets to liabilities, and the reliability of using the historical dates of economic events. Justification for these principles could once be found in a doctrine of historical cost; resort to them in a fair valuation regime is more tenuous. Use of the matching principle in pensions reporting is selective, as requirement to value payment obligations independently of assets purchased in their satisfaction makes plain. [10] Considerable latitude exists between current service costs and accounting expenses. The discrepancy between the accounting expenses of and cash contributions made to DB plans attached to FTSE Global 100 companies in 2007 was GBP4.47 billion (Lane, Clark & Peacock, 2008). The yields offered by iBoxx (http://www.markit.com) cash corporate bonds in January 2009 were in the range of 6.5 percent to 13.3 percent. 16 [11] The Public Interest Oversight Board supports the work of the IASB through issuance of Statements of Membership Obligations. [12] IOSCO has factored in international accounting development since 1988, when statements of support were issued for IASC principles and the implementation of international accounting standards. Current levels of support are suggested by the entitling of ‘A.1. Enforcement of Accounting Standards’ in IOSCO’s 2008 work program, which gives that IOSCO ‘closely monitors the developments’ in IFRSs by provision of comments on proposed changes and ‘routine discussion’ of standard-setting work with representatives of the IASB (IOSCO, 2008b). [13] The Norwalk Agreement has established a formal working relationship between the FASB and the IASB. It has been suggested that the FASB is in a privileged position in terms of its influence on the IASB (De Lange & Howieson, 2006). [14] FRS 17 requirement reflects the original form of the FRED 20 proposal that the effects of fluctuations in market values of plan assets be excluded from operating results of the plansponsoring entity and be treated in the same way as revaluations of fixed assets, i.e., recognised in an ‘auxiliary’ performance statement, the statement of total recognised gains and losses. [15] Munnell et al. (2006) attribute the attractiveness of DC schemes in US companies to sponsors’ intentions to reduce overall cash outlays, as DC schemes typically require lower employer contribution levels relative to DB schemes; pressures of rising health care insurance outlays, as health care is commonly ‘bundled’ with retirement benefits in the US; possibility that schemes are considered as an unwanted cost impost to senior management; actuarial risks, and the attractiveness of income gains that can be recognised when an organization closes a scheme. [16] Eckert, B. Sprint Nextel freezes pension for half its workforce. Washington Business Journal (23 January 2006). <http://www.bizjournals.com/washington/stories/2006/01/23daily6.html> Downloaded 11 January 2008. [17] Maher, K., & Glader, P. (17 January 2006). ALCOA’s pension will be closed to new workers. Wall Street Journal. <http://www.online.wsj.com/article/sb113745049216447873.html?mod=us_business_whats_ news> Downloaded 11 January 2008. [18] Steve, J. (28 August 2006). DuPont cuts defined pension contributions. Reuters. <http://www.uwua1-2.org/09_08_record.pdf> Downloaded 11 January 2009. 17 [19] BBC News (1 March 2007). Unilever to shut pension <http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/6408297.htm> Downloaded 18 July 2008. scheme. [20] Stewart, N. (2008). London: Investments & Pensions Europe. <http://www.ipe.com/news/baa_staff_accept_final_salary_closure_28475.php> Downloaded 20 July 2008. [21] Frei, E. (2007). Brite Media. <http://www.financemarkets.co.uk/2007/02/13/disputeover-british-airways-pension-plan> Downloaded 20 July 2008. [22] Actuarial estimates have suggested that five-year differences in the life expectancies of working and non-working people in OECD countries would be sufficient to add ten percent to the total value of pension obligations. To give some context, estimated pension obligations on FTSE 100 companies were €250 billion in December 2008 (Lane, Clark & Peacock, 2008). Consulting actuaries use mortality tables as issued by national public actuaries. [23] Press Release: Marks and Spencer Group <http://corporate.marksandspencer.com/documents/results_presentations/2009/q3_ts> Downloaded 7 January 2009. plc [24] Investments & Pensions Europe. <http://www.ipe.com/news/db_schemes_continue_feeding_buyout_market_28582.php> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Examples of transfers of pension obligations in the US and the UK collected by the author have not been presented. [25] A UK commercial consultancy has reported the intentions of sponsors of some British DB schemes in 2008 to offer their pension obligations for sale. CREATE-research, London. Downloaded <http://www.create-research.co.uk/pdfs/dbanddcplans2008.pdf> 26 November 2008. 18 Accounting Standards Board (2000a). Statement of principles for financial reporting—the way ahead. London: Financial Reporting Council. Accounting Standards Board (2000b). Financial Reporting Standard 17 Retirement Benefits. London: Financial Reporting Council. Accounting Standards Board (2008). The financial reporting of pensions. Discussion paper. London: Financial Reporting Council. Alexander, K., Eatwell, J., Persaud, A., & Reoch, R. (2007). Financial supervision and crisis management in the EU. Strasbourg: Policy Department Economic and Scientific Policy, European Parliament. Allen, F., & Carletti, E. (2008). Mark-to-market accounting and liquidity pricing. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 45(2-3), 358-378. Australian Accounting Standards Board (1993). Accounting Standard AAS 25 Financial reporting by superannuation plans. Australian Accounting Standards Board (2004a). Accounting Standard AASB 119 Employee benefits (July 2004). Australian Accounting Standards Board (2004b). Accounting Standard AASB 119 Employee benefits (December 2004). Australian Accounting Standards Board (2005). Compiled Accounting Standard AASB 119 Employee benefits. Melbourne: Australian Accounting Standards Board. Australian Accounting Standards Board (2006). Compiled Accounting Standard AASB 119 Employee benefits. Melbourne: Australian Accounting Standards Board. Australian Accounting Standards Board (2007). Compiled Accounting Standard AASB 119 Employee benefits. Melbourne: Australian Accounting Standards Board. Avrahampour, Y. (2008). A recent history of UK pension provision. Pension Funds Online. <http://www.apinfo.co.uk/pfa/articles/Retrospective.htm> Downloaded 20 July 2008. Barlev, B., & Haddad, J. R. (2003). Fair value accounting and the management of the firm. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 14, 383-415. Barth, M. E., Beaver, W., & Landsman, W. (1992). The market value implications of net period pension cost components. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 15, 27-62. Barth, M. E., Hodder, L. D., & Stubben, S. R. (2008). Fair value accounting for liabilities and own credit risk. The Accounting Review, 83(3), 629-664. Benhabib, S. (1986). Critique, Norm and Utopia. A Study of the Foundations of Critical Theory. New York: Columbia University Press. Board for Actuarial Standards (2008). Conceptual Framework. London: Financial Reporting Council. Bourdieu, P. (2001). Forms of capital. In M. Granovetter, & R. Swedberg (eds.), The Sociology of Economic Life (2nd. ed.) (pp. 96-111). Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Bradbury, M. (2008). Discussion of Whittington (Fair Value and the International Accounting Standards Board/Financial Accounting Standards Board Conceptual Framework Project: An Alternative View). Abacus, 44(2), 169-180. Bridgen, P. (2000). The one nation idea and state welfare: the conservatives and pensions in the 1950s. Contemporary British History, 14(3), 83-104. Bridgen, P., & Meyer, T. (2005). When do benevolent capitalists change their mind? Explaining the retrenchment of defined-benefit pensions in Britain. Social Policy & Administration, 39(7), 764-785. Brigden, A., Clare, A., Driver, R., McKersie, M., & Selvaggi, M. (2008). Coping with uncertainty and the importance of the sponsor’s covenant. ABI Research Paper, 9. London: Association of British Insurers. <http://www.abi.org.uk/bookshop/researchreports/abi%20defined benefit%20paper%20ii_v11.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Bryer, R. (1993). The late nineteenth-century revolution in financial reporting: accounting for the rise of investor or managerial capitalism? Accounting, Organizations and Society, 18(7-8), 649-690. Chartered Financial Analysts Institute (2007). A comprehensive business reporting model: financial reporting for investors. Charlottesville ,VI. <http://www.cfainstitute.org/centre/topics/reporting/cbrm.html> Downloaded 20 July 2008. Chua, W. F., (1986). Radical developments in accounting thought. The Accounting Review, 14(4), 601-632. Clark, G. L., & Monk, A. H. B. (2007a). The ‘crisis’ in defined benefit corporate pension liabilities. Part II, current solutions and future prospects. Pensions, 12, 68-81. Clark, G. L., & Monk, A. H. B. (2007b). The ‘crisis’ in defined benefit corporate pension liabilities. Part I, scope of the problem. Pensions, 12, 43-54. Cochran, C. E. (1974). Political science and ‘the public interest’. The Journal of Politics, 36(2), 327-355. Committee of European Securities Regulators (2008). EU legislation. <http://www.cesreu.org/images/keydates_bt_detail.gif> Downloaded 20 July 2008. Cooper, C. (2005). Accounting for the public interest: public ineffectuals or public intellectuals? Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 18(5), 592-607. Danile, T. M., & McCarthy, I. N. (2007). Ethical implications of reporting fair value in financial statements. Review of Business, 27(4), 46-50. Dellaportas, S., & Davenport, L. (2008). Reflections on the public interest in accounting. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, In-press, doi:10.1016/j.cpa.2007.06.002. Department for Work and Pensions (2006). Security in retirement: towards a new pensions system. London. <http://www.dwp.gov.uk/pensionsreform/pdfs/white_paper_complete.pdf> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Dezalay, Y. (1995). ‘Turf battles’ or ‘class struggles’: the internationalization of the market for expertise in the ‘professional society’. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 20(5), 331-344. Disney, P. R. (2000). Declining public pensions in an era of demographic ageing: will private pensions fill the gap? European Economic Review, 44, 957-973. Eagleton, T. (1991). Ideology. London: Verso. European Financial Reporting Advisory Group (2008). The financial reporting of pensions. Brussels. Evandrou, M., & Falkingham, J. (2005). A secure retirement for all? Older people and New Labour. In J. Hills, & K. Stewart. A More Equal Society? New Labour, Poverty, Inequality and Exclusion (pp. 167-188). Bristol: Polity Press. Everett, J., Neu, D., & Rahaman, A. S. (2007). Accounting and the global fight against corruption. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32, 513-542. Ezzamel, M. (2008). Order and accounting as a performative ritual: evidence from ancient Egypt. Accounting, Organizations and Society, In-press, doi:10.1016/j.aos.2008.07.004. Faculty and Institute of Actuaries (2000a). IASC insurance issues paper. Edinburgh, London and Oxford. <http://www.actuaries.org.uk/__data/assets/pdf_file/0006/26439/gen_ins.pdf> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Faculty and Institute of Actuaries (2000b). Steering the UK response. Views on the IASC insurance issues paper. Edinburgh, London and Oxford. <http://www.actuaries.org.uk/__data/assets/pdf_file/0018/26442/pwright.pdf> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Faculty and Institute of Actuaries (2005). Sponsor covenant working party final report. Edinburgh, London and Oxford: Sponsor Covenant Working Party.<http://www.actuaries.org.uk/__data/assets/pdf_file/0005/33476/sponsorcovenant rep.pdf> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Faculty and Institute of Actuaries (2008). Edinburgh, London and Oxford. <http://www.actuaries.org.uk/pensions> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Falkingham, J., & Rake, K. (2003). Pension choices for the 21st. century: meeting the challenges of an ageing society. Social Policy Review, 15, 197-216. Farr, J. (2004). Social capital: a conceptual history. Political Theory, 32(1), 6–33. FASB/IASB (Financial Accounting Standards Board & International Accounting Standards Board) (2002). Memorandum of understanding: “The Norwalk Agreement”. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. FASB/IASB (Financial Accounting Standards Board & International Accounting Standards Board) (2008). Measurement bases for financial accounting – measurement on initial recognition. <http://www.fasb.org/project/CF_Milestone_I_Summary_Report.pdf> Downloaded 8 October 2008. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1980a), Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 2: Qualitative Characteristics of Accounting Information. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1980b), Statement of Accounting Standard No. 35: Accounting and Reporting by Defined Benefit Pension Plans. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1985). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 87: Employers’ Accounting for Pensions. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1990). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 106: Employers’ Accounting for Postretirement Benefits Other Than Pensions. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1991). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 107: Disclosure about Fair Value of Financial Instruments. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1993). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 115: Accounting for Certain Investments in Debt and Equity Securities. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (1996). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 125: Accounting for Transfers and Servicing of Financial assets and Extinguishments of Liabilities. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (2006a). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 158: Employers’ Accounting for Defined Benefit Pension and Other Postretirement Plans. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (2006b). Statement of Accounting Standard No. 157: Fair Value Measurements. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (2007). Summary of Statement No. 157. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. Financial Accounting Standards Board (2008). Some facts about fair value. Understanding the Issues, May Issue. Norwalk, CT: Financial Accounting Foundation. <http://www.fasb.org/pdf/ uti_fair_value_may_2008.pdf> Downloaded 20 July 2008. Financial Reporting Council (2006a). Combined code on corporate governance. London. Financial Reporting Council (2006b). Guidance Note 36 Accounting for Retirement Benefits under Financial Reporting Standard 17. London. Financial Reporting Council (2008a). Guidance Note 9 Funding Defined Benefits – Presentation of Actuarial Advice. London. Financial Reporting Council (2008b). Combined code on corporate governance. London. Financial Reporting Council (2009). Actuarial quality framework. London. Fogarty, T. J., & Grant, J. (1995). Impact of the actuarial profession on financial reporting. Accounting Horizons, September, 23-33. Francis, J., & Schipper, K. (1999). Have financial statements lost their relevance? Journal of Accounting Research 37(2), 319-352. Fry, J., & Talja, S. (2007). The intellectual and social organization of academic fields and the shaping of digital resources. Journal of Information Science, 33(2), 115-133. Gallie, D. (2008). Employment Regimes and the Quality of Work. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Geller, S. M. (2007). ERISA fiduciary responsibilities and registered investment advisors. CPA Journal. New York: New York State Society of CPAs. <http://www.nysscpa.org/cpajournal/2007/107/essentials/p56.htm> Downloaded 17 July 2008. George, V., & Wilding, P. (1994). Welfare and Ideology. London: HarvesterWheatsheaf. Government Actuary’s Department (2006). Occupational pension schemes 2005: 13th survey by the government actuary. Newport: Office for National Statistics. <http://www.statistics.gov.uk/downloads/theme_social/occ_pension/occupationalpensi onschemes2005.pdf> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Guthrie, J., Petty, R., & Johanson, U. (1991). Sunrise in the knowledge economy. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 14(4), 365–383. Hagerman (2007). More than a profit? Measuring the social and green outcomes of urban investments. WP 07-17, 1-46. Oxford: Oxford University Centre for the Environment. Hall, P. A. (1993). Policy paradigms, social learning and the state. The case of economic policymaking in Britain. Comparative Politics, 25(3), 275- 296. Hann, R.N., Heflin, F., & Subramanayam, K.R. (2007). Fair-value pension accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44, 328-358. Hebb, T., & Wójcik, D. (2005). Global standards and emerging markets: the institutionalinvestment value chain and the CalPERS investment strategy. Environment and Planning A, 37(11), 1955-1974. Held, D. (2000). Regulating globalisation? The reinvention of politics. International Sociology, 14(2), 394-408. Horton, J., & Macve, R. (1994). The development of life assurance accounting and regulation in the UK: reflections on recent proposals for accounting change. Accounting, Business and Financial History, 4(2), 295-320. Institute of Chartered Accountants in Australia (2006). Submission to Australian Parliament Select Committee inquiry into the structure and operation of the superannuation industry. Sydney. <http://www.aph.gov.au/senate/committee/corporations_ctte/completed_inquiries/2004 -07/superannuation/tor.pdf> Downloaded 28 July 2008. Institutional Shareholders Committee (2007). The responsibilities of institutional shareholders and agents—statement of principles. London. International Accounting Standards Board (2006a). Framework for the preparation and presentation of financial statements. London. International Accounting Standards Board (2006b). Fair value measurements. Discussion paper. London. International Accounting Standards Board (2008). Summaries of International Financial Reporting Accounting Standards: IAS 19 Employee Benefits. London. International Accounting Standards Committee (1987). IAS 26 Accounting and Reporting by Retirement Benefit Plans. London. International Accounting Standards Committee (1997). Discounting for liabilities. London. International Accounting Standards Committee Education Foundation (2006). Technical summary, IAS 19 Employee Benefits. London. International Forum of Actuarial Associations (1997). Comments on the International Accounting Standards Committee’s Exposure Draft E59 Provisions, Contingent Liabilities and Contingent Assets. <http://www.actuaries.org/library/submissions/iasci_e59e.cfm> Downloaded 28 July 2008. IOSCO (2008a). Statement on providing investors with appropriate and complete information on accounting frameworks used to prepare financial statements. Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions. Madrid. IOSCO (2008b). An overview of the work of the IOSCO technical committee. Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions. Madrid. Keintz, R. J., & Stickney, C. P. (1980). Immunization of pension funds and sensitivity to actuarial assumptions. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 47(2), 223-239. Lamfalussy (2000b). Summary of Chairman Alexandre Lamfalussy's remarks to the press. Brussels: European Commission. Lamfalussy (The Lamfalussy Report) (2000a). Initial report of the Committee of Wise Men on the regulation of European securities markets. Brussels: European Commission. Lane, Clark & Peacock (2008). European pensions briefing. <http://www.lcp.uk.com> Downloaded 19 December 2008. McKernan, J. (2007). Objectivity in accounting. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32(1-2), 155-180. McKinstry, S. (1997). Status building: some reflections on the architectural history of Chartered Accountants’ Hall, London, 1889-1893. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 22(8), 779-798. Meagher, F., & Gummow, G. (1986). Jacobs’ Law of Trusts in Australia (Fifth ed.). Sydney: Butterworths. Miller, P. (1994). Accounting as social and institutional practice: an introduction. In A. G. Hopwood, & P. Miller (eds.) (1994). Accounting as Social and Institutional Practice (pp. 1-39). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Munnell, A. H. (2006). The shift from defined benefit to defined contribution. In G. L. Clark, A. H. Munnell, & J. M. Orszag (eds.) (pp. 359-380), The Oxford Handbook of Pensions and Retirement Income. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Munnell, A. H., Sundén, A., & Lidstone, E. (2002). How important are private pensions? An issue in brief, 8. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College. Boston. <http://crr.bc.edu/images/stories/briefs/ib_8.pdf?phpmyadmin=43ac483c4de9t51d9eb4 1> Downloaded 16 September 2008. Myners, P. (2004). Myners principles for institutional investment decision-making: review of progress. Norwich: Her Majesty’s Treasury. National Association of Pension Funds (2008). NAPF Response to the ASB discussion paper: the financial reporting of pensions. London. OECD (2005). Guidelines for Pension Fund Governance. Paris. OECD (2006). Ageing and employment policies: live longer, work longer. Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs. Paris. OECD (2007a). Private Pensions: OECD Classification and Glossary. Paris. OECD (2007b). Funding rules and actuarial methods. In Protecting Pensions: Policy Analysis and Examples from OECD Countries (pp. 75-160). Paris. OECD (2008b). Survey of investment regulations of pension funds. July 2008. <http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/12/46/40804056.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Paris. OECD) (2008b). Recent developments in pension accounting. July 2008. <http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/60/54/40954137.pdf> Downloaded 3 July 2008. Paris. Office for National Statistics (2005). Pension trends 2005. Newport. <http://www.statistics.gov.uk/downloads/theme_compendia/pensiontrends/Pension_Tre nds_ch04.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Office for National Statistics (2007). Employer pension provision. Newport. <http://www.statistics.gov.uk/downloads/theme_compendia/pensiontrends/Pension_Tre nds_ch11.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Office for National Statistics (2008). Pension trends 2008. Newport. <http://www.statistics.gov.uk/downloads/theme_compendia/pensiontrends/Pension_Tre nds_ch07.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Oppenheim, F. E. (1975). Self-interest and public interest. Political Theory, 3(3), 259-276. Partner, N. F. (1977). Serious Entertainments: The Writing of History in Twelfth-Century England. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. Pensions Policy Institute (2007). The changing landscape for private sector defined benefit pension schemes. <http://www.pensionspolicyinstitute.org.uk/uploadeddocuments/ppi_landscape_for_def ined benefit_schemes_8_october_2007.pdf > Downloaded 17 July 2008. Portes, A., & Sensenbrenner, J. (2001). Embeddedness and immigration: notes on the social determinants of economic action. In M. Granovetter, & R. Swedberg (eds.), The Sociology of Economic Life (2nd. ed.) (pp. 112-135). Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Public Interest Oversight Board (2008). Third public report of the PIOB. International Federation of Accountants. Madrid. Rayman, R. A. (2007). Fair value accounting and the present value fallacy: the need for an alternative conceptual framework. The British Accounting Review, 39(3), 211-225. Renn, D. F. (ed.) (1998). Life, Death and Money: Actuaries and the Creation of Financial Security. Oxford: Blackwell. Sapra, H. (2008). Do accounting measurement regimes matter? A discussion of mark-tomarket accounting and liquidity pricing. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 45(23), 379-387. The Pensions Regulator (2007a). The purple book. Defined benefit pensions universe risk profile. Brighton. <http://www.thepensionsregulator.gov.uk/pdf/purplebook2007.pdf> Downloaded 17 Jul 2008. The Pensions Regulator (2007b). Abandonment of defined benefit pension schemes. Brighton. <http://www.thepensionsregulator.gov.uk/pdf/abandonment.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. The Pensions Regulator (2007c). Guidance for trustees. Brighton. <http://www.thepensionsregulator.gov.uk/trustees/guidance/index.aspx> Downloaded 17 July 2008. The Pensions Regulator (2008). Foundation indicative syllabus. Brighton. <http://www.thepensionsregulator.gov.uk/pdf/tkuindicativesyllabus.pdf> Downloaded 17 July 2008. Thornton, P. (2007). A review of pensions institutions. Norwich: Her Majesty’s Stationery Office. <http://www.dwp.gov.uk/pensionsreform/pdfs/institutionalreviewfinalreport180507.pdf > Downloaded 17 July 2008. Tinker, A., & Ghicas, D. (1993). Dishonored contracts: accounting and the expropriation of employee pension wealth. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 18(4), 361-380. Willmott, H. (1986). Organizing the profession: a theoretical and historical examination of the development of the major accountancy bodies in the U.K. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 11(6), 555-580. Willmott, H. C. (1990). Serving the public interest? A critical analysis of a professional claim. In D. Cooper, & T. Hopper (eds.), Critical Accounts (pp. 315-331). London: Macmillan. Žižek, S. (2006). The Parallax View. Massachusetts: The MIT Press. Figure 1: Regulatory and Supervisory Arrangement in the UK, US and Australia Regulator/Supervisor International OECD-issued standards on governance of private pensions Accountants Standards issued by IASB UK Standards issued by Financial Reporting Council, which supervises ICAEW and other member bodies US Australia Actuaries International Forum of Actuarial Associations provides input to the IASB work program The Pensions Regulator Faculty and Institute of administers Pensions Act Actuaries supervised by 2004, Pension Schemes Act Financial Reporting 1993 and Social Security Act Council 1986 under supervisory aegis Standards issued by of the Financial Services Board for Actuarial Authority Standards The Dept of Labor administers American Academy of the Employee Retirement Actuaries is supervised by Income Security Act 1974 and the Dept of Labor the Pension Protection Act Standards issued by 2006 Actuarial Standards Board Internal Revenue Service and Securities & Exchange Commission have regulatory and supervisory authority Australian Prudential Standards issued by Regulation Authority Institute of Actuaries of supervises Superannuation Australia Industry (Supervision) Act No oversight body 1993 and has required trustee certification Australian Securities & Investments Commission administers Corporations Law governing financial reporting Reserve Bank of Australia has supervisory authority Coordination provided by the Council of Financial Regulators Financial Accounting Foundation supervises the AICPA Standards issued by Financial Accounting Standards Board Financial Reporting Council supervises Institute of Chartered Accountants in Australia, Certified Practising Accountants Australia and other member bodies Standards issued by Australian Accounting Standards Board Figure 2: UK Occupational Pension Schemes by Type and Status Defined Benefit Status 2000 2004 2005 Open 17.9 6.3 6.2 Closed 11.2 8.7 4.5 Frozen^^ 5.6 3.2 1.3 Total 34.7 18.1 12.0 Accumulation* 2000 43.7 17.7 1.2 62.6 2004 2005 46.8 44.7 10.7 8.3 13.4 .5 70.9 53.5 Total^ 2000 2004 2005 2007 62.1 54.0 50.9 29.6 29.0 19.5 12.8 18.9 6.8 16.6 1.8 4.3 97.9 90.1 65.5 53.0 Data source: Office for National Statistics, 2005, 2007, 2008. Figures shown are in thousands. * Accumulation schemes are known as defined contribution and DC schemes in the US and Australia and as money-purchase schemes in the UK. ^=Excludes some schemes offering DB and DC arrangement. ^^=Excludes schemes that were winding up.