© This is a copyright material and reproduction of this material without obtaining prior permission is strictly prohibited. Plagiarism and other applicable laws could be enforced in case of any violation. 1 1. Introduction 2. Water Pricing Models 3. Water Allocation Models 1. Introduction An effective and holistic approach to water management requires an understanding of all dynamics relating to water policies and it encompasses reasonable knowledge of models which deals with water pricing, governance, etc. Consequently, this chapter presents a succinct overview of literature on some of the leading economic models on water. 2. Water Pricing Models 2.1 Paper by Monteiro (2005) A paper by Monteiro (2005)1 provides a very good summary of important models on water pricing. Interested readers may refer to the paper for detailed information on the economic water pricing models included therein. We, however, reproduce below a table on questions addressed by each of the water pricing models from Monteiro (2005) paper. It basically touches upon almost all aspects on water pricing: Questions Addressed Average vs. Marginal Cost Pricing Seasonal or temporal variations Articles Hirshleifer et al., 1960 Ryordan, 1971 Dandy et al., 1984 Zarnikau, 1994 Chambouleyron, 2003 Gisy and Loucks, 1971 Riley and Scherer, 1979 Manning and Gallagher, 1982 Dandy et al., 1984 Zarnikau, 1994 Monteiro, Henrique (2005), ‘Water Pricing Models: A survey’, Instituto Superior De Ciencias Do Trabalho E Da Empresa, Portugal. 1 2 Capacity constraints or expansion decisions (Peakload pricing) Scarcity Revenue Requirements Optimal number of metered connections Efficiency of block tariffs Second-best pricing Optimal derivation of nonlinear pricing schemes Customer heterogeneity Storage Groundwater Conjunctive use of surface and groundwater Utilization of water as an input Constraints regarding water price changes Pricing of wastewater services Multi-product water supply Dynamic programming techniques Simulation techniques Discounting Elnaboulsi, 2001 Schuck and Green, 2002 Hirshleifer et al., 1960 Ryordan, 1971 Gysi and Loucks, 1971 Riley and Scherer, 1979 Manning and Gallagher, 1982 Zarnikau, 1994 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Griffin, 2001 Moncur and Pollock, 1988 Zarnikau, 1994 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Griffin, 2001 Schuck and Green, 2002 Hirshleifer et al., 1960 Freedman, 1986 Collinge, 1992 Zarnikau, 1994 Kim, 1995 Griffin, 2001 Schuck and Green, 2002 Barrett and Sinclair, 1999 Griffin, 2001 Chambouleyron, 2003 Gisy and Loucks, 1971 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Kim, 1995 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Schuck and Green, 2002 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Chambouleyron, 2003 Riley and Scherer, 1979 Manning and Gallagher, 1982 Moncur and Pollock, 1988 Schuck and Green, 2002 Schuck and Green, 2002 Schuck and Green, 2002 Dandy et al., 1984 Elnaboulsi, 2001 Kim, 1995 Ryordan, 1971 Gysi and Loucks, 1971 Riley and Scherer, 1979 Schuck and Green, 2002 Manning and Gallagher, 1982 3 The most consensual result from the water pricing literature is that efficiency requires marginal cost pricing. While this may be common sense for anyone with a minimum microeconomics background, it has stirred up a lot of articles demonstrating the advantages of marginal cost pricing in relation to the widely used average cost pricing practices of many water utilities. There is, however, some divergence on whether we should consider short-run or long-run marginal cost pricing. Some authors defend even in dynamic contexts multistage short-run marginal cost pricing. Intra-annual price changes or customer differentiation to reflect differences in marginal costs can enhance efficiency. A marginal cost pricing mechanism may signal the value that consumers attribute to further capacity expansions as the water supply system approaches its capacity limit and marginal cost rises. However, pure marginal cost pricing may not be feasible while respecting a revenue requirement because marginal costs may be higher or lower than average costs. The most common ways of combining efficiency and revenue requirements are through the use of two-part tariffs, adjusting the fixed charge to meet the revenue requirement, or through the second-best pricing like Ramsey pricing. It is not evident from the survey whether the best scheme is a two-part tariff or some other pricing mechanism. The role of black rate pricing, increasingly more frequent in actual pricing practices, is yet to be fully investigated. 2.2. Paper by Mohayidin et al. (2009)2 The study by Mohayidin et al. (2009) is somewhat is similar to Monteiro (2005) but with additional citing of some latest papers. For the benefit of readers, we reproduce below table from Mohayidin et al. (2009) paper: Pertinent questions Related articles 1. First best pricing versus second best Tsur and Dinar (1997); Zarnikau (1994); Thobani pricing (1998); Mitra (1997); Monteiro (2005); Lewis (1969); Sahibzada (2002); Johansson (2000); Dandy et al. (1984); Riordan (1971b); Garcia and Reynaud (2004); Small and Carruthers (1991); Mas-Collel et al. (1995). 2. Partial equilibrium versus general Johansson et al. (2002) for PE. Berck et al. (1990) equilibrium for GE 3. Efficiency and fairness concerns Lewis (1969); Seagraves and Easter (1983); Saliba Mohayidin, Ghazali et al. (2009), ‘Review of water pricing theories and related models’, African Journal of Agricultural Research Vol. 4 (13), pp. 1536-1544. 22 4 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. and Bush (1987); Sampath (1991 and 1992); Easter (1997); Small and Rimal (1996); Dinar et al. (1997); Johansson (2000 and 2002) Temporal or seasonal rates Gysi and Loucks (1971); Zarnikau (1994); Dinar et al. (1997); Sahibzada (2002); Schuck and Green (2002); Monteiro (2005) Development decisions or capacity Riordan (1971b); Manning and Gallagher (1982); restrictions Riley and Scherer (1979). Scarcity Moncur and Pollock (1987); Einaboulsi (2001); Griffin (2001); Zilberman (1997); Shah et al. (1995); Easter (1997); Sahibzada (2002); Seagraves and Easter (1983); Monteiro (2005); Sunding (1994); Small and Rimal (1996); Laffont and Tirole (1993). Marginal value product pricing Sahibzada (2002); Sunding (2005); Hussain et al. (2007). Storage Riley and Scherer (1979) Hedonic pricing model or implicit marginal Latinopoulos et al. (2004); Torell et al. (1990); price Faux and Perry (1999); Coelli et al. (1991); Griffin (1985). The theories, reviewed in this paper, explain different aspect of water pricing that can be used as a means to address water scarcity issues in terms of quantity as well as quality. The empirical findings reveal that the first best pricing3 is a widely accepted model for partial or full cost recovery of the irrigation schemes as it considers inefficiencies in water use. On the other hand, the second best pricing4 model sets price of water equal to the marginal cost of providing it or incremental costs associated with incremental production. Most of the economists agree that if water users pay the marginal cost of its supply water use, efficiency would be significantly improved. The marginal product value from price represents inefficient use of input. Finally, there exists currently a debate that while water pricing programs promote economically and environmentally efficient water use, they may not always be appropriate as water pricing is often perceived as a policy intervention that negatively affects poor farmers and small holders. It can 3 Consider a perfectly competitive open economy that no market imperfections or distortions, no externalities in production or consumption, no public goods. The optimal government policy in this case is laissez-faire. Any type of tax or subsidy implemented by the government under these circumstances can only reduce economic efficiency and national welfare. Thus with a laissez-faire policy, the resulting equilibrium would be called first-best equilibrium. Allocation maximizing the total net benefit is called Pareto efficient or first-best. 4 Introducing imperfections or distortions in first-best equilibrium will make it less efficient from a national perspective than when the distortion was not present. In other words, the introduction of one distortion would reduce the optimal level of national welfare. Equilibrium under such a situation is called second-best equilibrium. 5 be concluded that all of the mentioned theories consider water pricing as an important tool which policy makers can apply for management of this valuable resource5. Horbulyk (2010)6 suggests the following approach for water pricing for 2.3. improving water management in Alberta: 1) the pricing of storage uses as well as of the consumptive uses of water; and 2) the option to adopt a refundable or revenue-neutral financing approach that returns fee revenues to the users while preserving users’ incentives to use water efficiently. 3. Forecasting Water Demand Davis (2008)7 opines that a sound demand forecast is critical in water resources planning. He suggests four types of approaches in Water Demand Forecasting viz. Trend Extrapolation, Per Capita, Unit Use and Econometric. In Trend Extrapolation approach, only historical demand data is required and it can be available at a very low cost. However, the problem with this approach is that the model assumes that past trend carries into the future. The approach also cannot account for changes in demographics, weather or other factors. Per Capita approach divides historical total demand by population to arrive at per capita use. Then per capita use can be multiplied by projected population to arrive at the future demand of water. The approach is simple to understand and allows the main driver, population to be accounted for. However, demand may not always follow population growth. The model does not account for factors such as price, income, types of housing, employment trends and other factors. Unit use approach suggests getting sector demands (e.g. single-family, multi-family, nonresidential) and dividing each sector demands by appropriate drivers (e.g. housing or employment) to get unit use. Multiplying unit use by future number of units will give us future Mohayidin et al. (2009), ‘Review of water pricing theories and related models’, African Journal of Agricultural Research Vol. 4 (13), pp. 1536-1544. 5 Horbulyk, Theodore M. (2010), ‘ Water Pricing: An Option for Improing Water Management in Alberta’, Department of Economics, University of Calgary, Alberta, Canada. 7 Davis, William (2008), ‘Forecasting Water Demand’, Paper presented at the American Water Works Association (AWWA) Sustainable Water Source Conference , Reno, NV, USA 6 6 demand for water. The benefit of this approach is that it allows for majors sectors and drivers of water demand to be accounted for. Also each sector demand can be projected independently. However, water demand factors such as weather, income, price and others are not incorporated. The Econometrics approach statistically correlates water demands with factors that influence those demands: Where Qs = Water sector demand I = median household income H = average household size (persons) L = average household density (units per acre) T = maximum temperature R = rainfall P = marginal price of water α = equation constant β1 = elasticities8 of water use factors The model has a significant ability to explain water use over time. However, it is very data intensive and costly to produce. In terms of specification errors, the ranking of the above four types of approaches is as follows (in order of ranking – high to low) – Trend Analysis, Per Capita, Disaggregate Unit Use and Multivariate Models. In terms of cost, their ranking is as follows (from low to high) - Trend Analysis, Per Capita, Disaggregate Unit Use and Multivariate Models. 8 A statistical rate of change that describes how a water use factor influences demand. A price elasticity of -0.10 means that a ten percent increase in real price will result in a one percent decrease in water demand. 7 4. Predicting water quality in distribution systems Deterministic models have been widely used to predict water quality in distribution systems, but their calibration requires extensive and accurate data sets for numerous parameters. In a study by D’Souza and Mohan Kumar (2010)9 alternative data-driven modeling approaches based on artificial neural networks (ANNs) were used to predict temporal variations of two important characteristics of water quality—chlorine residual and biomass concentrations. The authors considered three types of ANN algorithms. Of these, the Levenberg-Marquardt algorithm provided the best results in predicting residual chlorine and biomass with error-free and “noisy” data. The ANN models developed here can generate water quality scenarios of piped systems in real time to help utilities determine weak points of low chlorine residual and high biomass concentration and select optimum remedial strategies. 5. Modeling Water Quality in Drinking Water Distribution Systems by Robert Clark and Walter Grayman This comprehensive text discusses the use of water quality models and their potential for enhancing and understanding the factors that affect water quality in distributed water. It covers the development of the USEPA's EPANET and discusses its application to case studies. The book outlines the major elements involved in water quality modeling. It discusses the development and application of water quality models, and presents the results of applying these models. Storage tank modeling is also covered. Chapter topics include: Distribution system water quality, Modeling distribution systems, Hydraulic analysis, Water quality models, Initial modeling studies, Modeling total trihalomethanes and chlorine decay, Applying water quality models, Modeling waterborne disease outbreaks, Modeling the effects of tanks and storage and Getting started in modeling. D’Souza and Mohan Kumar (2010), ‘Comparison of ANN models for predicting water quality in distribution systems’, e-journal AWWA, Vol. 102, Issue 7. 9 8 6. 6.1 Water Allocation Models In a paper titled ‘Water Allocation Models for Alberta: What’s Available and what are the Needs?, Ali et al. (201010) presents an overview of water allocation models around the world. The authors reviewed the existing water allocation models in order to evaluate to identify the available of suitable mathematical models that could be used to evaluate ways to improve water use efficiencies in Canadian province of Alberta. They found that even the most recent economic optimization model in Alberta is too narrow in scope and spatial coverage to represent the intricacies of competing water users in southern Alberta. The authors identified at least four general areas of improvement that could be made to a recently developed model to improve its analytical capacity – expanding the model structure to include all irrigation districts in southern Alberta, augmenting with modules of other water user sector demands, improving capability to analyze alternative water licensing policies, and developing a field-scale model to help understand the dynamics of micro level decision making on water rights transfers, irrigation technology choices, crop choices, and other decision variables. The primary focus is on basinscale models since it is at this scale that sectoral competition for water can be adequately analyzed to draw essential information for policymakers in their resource management decisions. Although it is at the farm or field-scale where micro level decision making takes place regarding irrigation equipment purchase, crop choice, and water application, extensive data requirement at such fine levels often thwart modeling efforts. Historically, water licenses and rights in Alberta have been based on a system of prior allocation where priority is set by the date of application on the principle of first-in-time-first-in-right (FITFIR). According to the author, the FITFIR system is an impediment to water market development, a solution often touted for efficient allocation of water resources during scarcity, since senior rights holders have little incentive to sell the rights to the newer or junior rights holders. However, since the mid-nineties, there is a move toward transforming these historical licenses and rights into tradable licenses with some government control on the nature of the trade 10 South Alberta Resource Economics Publications, University of Lethbridge, Department of Economics, Alberta, Canada 9 and holdback options. The paper discusses various types of models – physical water allocation models are discussed first, followed by the economic optimization models, and then a short discussion follows with the applications and experiences from other international jurisdictions for additional methodological insights. A summary of the most relevant models is presented in the Table. Table: Summary of the water allocation models at a glance Study Area Scale Southern Alberta: IDM, AAFRD (2002a) SSRB, Alberta Irrigation districts WRMM, AENV (2002) SSRB, Alberta and Basin Saskatchewan FFIRM, AAFRD (2002b) SSRB, Alberta Basin Horbulyk and Lo (1998) Mahan et al. (2000) Cutlac and Horbulyk (2009) He and Horbulyk (2010) Australia: Brooks and Harris (2008) Zaman et al. (2009) SSRB, Alberta SSRB, Alberta SSRB, Alberta BRSB of SSRB Victoria and Southern New South Wales Northern Victoria United States: Vaux and Howitt (1984) California Booker and Young (1991, Colorado 1994) Chatterjee et al. (1998) California Chakravorty and Umetsu California (2003) Wurbs (2003, 2004) Texas Brewer et al. (2009) Western U.S. Other regions: Cortignani and Severini (2009) Central Italy Methodology Calculation of daily water requirements Calculation of physical allocation and deficits based on IDM needs Economic optimization and simulation Basin Economic optimization Basin Economic optimization Basin Economic-hydrologic integrated Irrigation Economic optimization with PMP districts calibration Region Econometric analysis Basin Economic-hydrologic integrated optimization and simulation Region Basin Regional trade Economic-hydrologic integrated Basin Basin Dynamic programming Spatial, optimal control Basin Basin Institutional perspective Model comparison Farm Economic optimization with improved PMP Economic optimization with extended PMP Economic-hydrologic integrated Economic optimization Rohm and Dabbert (2003) Germany Region Rosegrant et al. (2000) Pujol et al. (2006) Maipo, Chile Basin Southern Spain and Basin Italy 10 Qubaa et al. (2002) Benli and Kodal (2003) South Lebanon GAP project, Turkey Farm Economic optimization Economic optimization Other relevant studies: Tsur (2005) Theoretical and mathematical derivation of water allocation and pricing Zilberman and Schoengold Mathematical and graphical (2005) overview of water allocation Schoengold and Zilberman Mathematical and graphical (2007) overview of water allocation Howitt (1995, 2005) PMP calibration McKinney and Savitsky (2006) Setting-up water allocation problems, GAMS codes, solutions Howe (2005) Comparison of water pricing policies in U.S. and Canada Grafton et al. (2009) Comparison of water rights, markets, and trading in southwestern U.S. and MurrayDarling Basin, Australia Notes: IDM = Irrigation District Model; WRMM = Water Resource Management Model; FFIRM = Farm Financial Impact and Risk Model; AAFRD = Alberta Agriculture, Food and Rural Development; AENV = Alberta Environment; SSRB = South Saskatchewan River Basin; BRSB = Bow River Sub-Basin; PMP = Positive Mathematical Programming; GAP = Southeastern Anatolian Project. 6.1.1 Physical Allocation Models One type of model that has been applied to the water allocation problem in Alberta deals with the physical aspects of water allocation – starting from the diversion of water at the head works, through the networks of storage basins, canals and pipelines, to the distribution of water at the irrigated fields. Two such models are known as the Irrigation District Model (IDM) and the Water Resources Management Model (WRMM) (Alberta Environment, 2002). The IDM utilizes two integrated modules – the Irrigation Requirements Module that contains weather and field level data, and the Network Management Module that contains data on canal/pipeline network characteristics in each irrigation districts, storage reservoirs, return flows, and losses. Together, they determine daily farm delivery requirements based on crop growth parameters and translate them into canal flow and diversion requirements. It is the IDM that helps to develop alternative water requirement scenarios depending on the crop mix, irrigation methods, expansion potentials, future demands, and climate predictions. 11 The WRMM is a basin-scale simulation model that takes the irrigation requirements from the IDM as inputs and determines if those requirements could be met following the license priorities and given other major delivery requirements in the non-irrigation sectors such as municipal, industrial, recreation, wetlands, instream flows, and inter-provincial apportionment commitments. The output of the WRMM informs the frequency and magnitude of the irrigation water deficits on a weekly basis. These deficits form the inputs of a third model, the Farm Financial Impact and Risk Model (FFIRM) that analyzes the risk and water shortage impacts on the income for representative farms across the basin. The FFIRM is the only model currently being used by the water managers in Alberta Irrigation that incorporates crop yield-water functions and economic parameters (crop prices, labor, capital, repair & maintenance, and energy costs) to help understand how the water availability and climate conditions translate into economic impacts. It includes two components – an optimization component dealing with the optimal allocation of water demand and supply derived from the IDM and WRMM among four typical farm enterprises across the basin. In case of water shortages, this component of the model allocates water to the most profitable farm enterprise on a priority basis. The other component of FFIRM simulates long term financial viability of these farm enterprises considering risk and crop-water management choices. The FFIRM model does a good job of budgeting farm costs and revenues for given situations but since the IDM and WRMM are not based on farmer responses to economic incentives and price signals, the analyses are non-optimizing and thus, may not represent very well actual farmer behavior. 6.1.2 Economic Optimization Models: Apart from the FFIRM, which involves both economic optimization and simulation approaches, a second type of model applied to the water allocation problem in Alberta involves economic optimization using mathematical programming techniques. Usually, these models have been at the basin scale, involve a high level of aggregation in the input data, have welfare or profit 12 maximization objectives, and assume fully functional water markets in a potential water shortage situation. He and Horbulyk (2010)11 developed mathematical programming model to test the impacts of (i) volumetric water pricing, and (ii) short-term water trading policies among three irrigation districts (Bow River (BRID), Eastern (EID), and Western (WID)) in the Bow River Sub-basin (BRSB) of Alberta. These two market based policies are implemented in a way that treats water pricing as a substitute for the existing seniority-based (FITFIR) transfer allocations. Besides generating some interesting and fairly intuitive results with a rather simple set-up, the He and Horbulyk (2010) model distanced itself from others models with regard to its calibration method. While all previous models were calibrated through modifying the constraints, this model was calibrated through modifying the objective function, a procedure commonly known as positive mathematical programming or PMP. The PMP utilizes dual values of the calibration constraints to modify the objective function such that the base year observed activities are reproduced without the calibration constraints. 6.1.3 Models in other jurisdictions 6.1.3.1 United States The semiarid southwestern United States has been the subject of numerous studies on interstate water allocation, regional water transfer, third-party effects, transaction costs, etc. with a range of trade models, mathematical programming models, and optimal control models. Over 80% of surface and ground water in this region is used for agriculture and the rest for municipal and industrial use.. Vaux and Howitt (1984)12 used a regional trade model with nonlinear regional demand and supply functions to show that regional water transfer could be an effective mechanism to deal with water scarcity in California until 2020. Booker and Young (1991, 1994)13 used a non-linear economic-hydrologic optimization model to estimate economic gain 11 He, L. and T.M. Horbulyk (2010): Market-based policy instruments, irrigation water demand, and crop diversification in the Bow River basin of southern Alberta. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1-23. 12 Vaux, H.J. Jr. and R. Howitt (1984): Managing water scarcity: An evaluation of interregional transfers. Water Resources Research, 20(7), 785-792. 13 Booker, J.F. and R. Young (1994): Modeling intrastate and interstate markets for Colorado River water resources. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 66-87. 13 from intra- and inter-state trade of consumptive and non-consumptive uses of fourteen water demand sectors in the Colorado River Basin under two water flow regimes. Results indicate that within state water transfers yield more economic benefit in the short flow regime induced by a severe drought or climate change. One interesting result of the model is that if on-farm irrigation technology is traditional rather than modern and efficient, basin-wide optimization leads to a significantly higher aggregate economic gain. This is because higher return flow from traditional irrigation technology (e.g., gravity) replenishes groundwater, which appears as a backstop technology for the downstream users. An excellent handbook on setting up the optimization problems, GAMS codes, and illustrative solutions for water allocation among users, optimal management of a single reservoir or a river system, upstream-downstream problems, water rights and markets, etc. is provided by McKinney and Savitsky (2006)14. Howe (2005)15 provides a comparison of water pricing policies in the U.S. and Canada while Grafton et al. (2009)16 provides a comparison of water rights, markets and trading in the U.S. and Australia. 6.1.3.2 Australia Brooks and Harris (2008)17 provide estimates of the magnitude of efficiency gains from water markets operating on weekly basis in three trading zones in Australia. Results indicate a substantial gain in economic efficiency can be obtained by reallocation of water from low to high value uses, which could be further improved if trade restrictions are progressively removed. Another recent study on Australian water markets used an integrated economic-hydrologic 14 McKinney, D.C. and A.G. Savitsky (2006): Basic optimization models for water and energy management. Revision 8. http://www.ce.utexas.edu/prof/mckinney/ce385d/lectures/McKinneySavitsky.pdf 15 Howe, C.W. (2005): The functions, impacts and effectiveness of water pricing: Evidence from the United States and Canada. Water Resources Development, 21(1), 43-53. 16 Grafton, R.Q., C. Landry, G.D. Libecap, and R.J. O’Brien (2009): Water markets: Australia’s Murray-Darling basin and the U.S. southwest. Paper presented at the Water Economic Consortium Meeting, UC Berkeley, Nov 6-7, 2009. http://www.icer.it/docs/wp2009/ICERwp15-09.pdf 17 Brooks, R. and E. Harris (2008): Efficiency gains from water markets: Empirical analysis of Watermove in Australia. Agricultural Water Management, 95, 391-399. 14 model to simulate the short and long-term impacts from water trading (Zaman et al., 2009)18. The authors argue that an integrated model is necessary to improve estimates from market trading as it can induce sudden changes in the demand and/or supply from one region to another that results in significant bottleneck and pressure on the water delivery infrastructure. 6.2 A Model for Optimal Allocation of Water to Competing Demands19 The study develops a simple interactive integrated water allocation model (IWAM), which can assist the planners and decision makers in optimal allocation of limited water from a storage reservoir to different user sectors, considering socio-economic, environmental and technical aspects. IWAM comprises three modules—a reservoir operation module (ROM), an economic analysis module (EAM) and a water allocation module (WAM). The model can optimize the water allocation with any of two different objectives or two objectives together. The two individual objectives included in the model are the maximization of satisfaction and the maximization of net economic benefit by the demand sectors. Weighting technique (WT) or simultaneous compromise constraint (SICCON) technique is used to convert the multi-objective decision-making problem into a single objective function. The single objective functions are optimized using linear programming. The model applicability is demonstrated for various cases with a hypothetical example. 6.3 Optimal Allocation of Reservoir Water20 The purpose of the paper is to determine the optimal allocation of reservoir water among consumptive and non-consumptive uses. A non-linear mathematical programming model is developed to optimally allocate Lake Tenkiller water among competing uses that maximize the net social benefit. A mass balance equation is used to determine the level and volume of water in the lake. The paper examines the effect of water management on lake resources when 18 Zaman, A.M., H.M. Malano, and B. Davidson (2009): An integrated water trading-allocation model, applied to a water market in Australia. Agricultural Water Management, 96, 149-159. 19 Babel et al. (2005), ‘A Model for Optimal Allocation of Water to Competing Demands’, Water Resources Management (2005) 19: 693–712. 20 Debnath, Deepayan (2009), ‘Optimal Allocation of Reservoir Water’, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Oklahoma, Stillwater, Oklahoma 15 recreational values are and are not included as control variables in the optimization process. Results show that maintaining lake level near ‘normal lake level’ of 632 feet during the summer months and shifting releases for hydropower generation to other months increased overall benefits including recreational benefits with only a slight reduction in hydropower generation. 6.4 Basin21 Scenario Analysis of Water Allocation Based on ET Control in Haihe River Rational water allocation is important branch of decision making on water planning and management in Haihe River Basin. Considering condition of water scarcity in Haihe River Basin, ET quota is taken as objective for water allocation in provinces to realize the requirement of water inflow into the Bohai Sea. To make qualified ET distribution and water allocation in various regions, a framework is put forward in the paper, in which two models are applied to analyze the different scenarios with predefined economic growth and ecological objective. The first model figures out rational ET objective with multi-objective analysis for compromised solution in economic growth and ecological maintenance. The second one provides hydraulic simulation and water balance to allocation the ET objective to corresponding regions under operational rules. The scenario analysis could discover the relations between economy and ecology. Models by the United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)22 7. EPA is the world leader in developing modeling techniques and software for Drinking Water, Surface Water and Ground Water as is evident from the following: Centre for Subsurface Modeling Support (CSMoS) provides users with models used to assess ground-water patterns EPANET Drinking Water Model models the hydraulics and water quality of water distribution piping systems Ground Water Compendium contains fact sheets about models that can be used to analyze ground water quality and quantity Jinju, You et al. (2005), ‘Scenario Analysis of Water Allocation Based on ET Control in Haihe River Basin’, Department of Water Resources Research, China Institute of Water Resources Research and Hydropower Research, P.R. China. 22 EPA (www.epa.gov) 21 16 Office of Water Models lists models, databases, and other resources developed at the EPA Office of Water OWA Water Quality Models contains several models that assess different aspects of water quality Storm Water Management Model simulates rainfall runoff in urban areas for single events or long-term data Watershed and Water Quality Modeling Technical Support Center provides access to models and tools that can be used in the development of Total Maximum Daily Loads (TMDL), waste load allocations, and watershed protection plans Watershed Management Tools contains several models that assess different aspects of water quality on a watershed scale. Watershed Mapping tools lists two models that map and simulate watershed development over time. 17