Chapter 4 Activity feedback Activity 4.1 UK and EU legislation What are the differences in passing legislation between the UK and the EU? Which system do you think is more democratic? Feedback There are a number of differences between the UK and the EU systems: The UK has more flexibility in what laws it can introduce (although this is restricted by EU law and by the Human Rights Act). EU law must be based on the treaties. There are formal procedures for consultation in the EU (by the Social Partners). In the UK, consultation is informal. Until the new Constitution is approved, the European Parliament has a consultative rather than a legislative role. Under the new system, the power of the European Parliament is increased, but it will still be less than that of the UK Parliament. The EU has no upper chamber, equivalent to the House of Lords. At present, the UK system is clearly much more democratic than the EU’s. The situation will be much less clear-cut when the new Constitution is ratified. The UK Parliament will be able to reject or amend legislation by a simple majority of those who vote, while the European Parliament will require an absolute majority of all MEPs. However, the UK government has much more power to impose discipline on its MPs through the whip system. The European Commission has no disciplinary powers over MEPs. Activity 4.2 Political Parties 1. What arguments would you put forward if asked to support the argument that ideology and class no longer underpin the present party system? 2. David Farnham argues that there are two crucial differences between a political party and a pressure group (Farnham, 1999, p137): Parties try to win political control to use political power. Pressure groups seek to influence political decisions, not to get in a position where they can make those decisions themselves. The political programmes of parties are broad-based, while pressure groups tend to concentrate on a single issue. Given the above, would you say that the UK Independence Party (UKIP), which won many seats in the EU elections in 2009, is a political party or a pressure group? What about the Scottish National Party? Feedback 1. Increasingly, political parties have recognised that the way to win elections is not to be ideological, which attracts party activists but tends to repel the famous ‘floating voters’ who, in popular opinion, decide elections. Successful parties thus gravitate towards the centre, with the objective of winning power rather than mobilising activist support (the Labour party in the 1980s and the Conservative party in the late 1990s and early 2000s may be exceptions to this trend, which may partly explain their lack of success). Just as political parties have become less ideological, they have become less class-based. It could be argued that ‘we are all middle class now’, so there is no mileage in being a political party committed to exclusively working class interests. Thus the Labour party draws support from across the class spectrum, and so does the Conservative party. Indeed, political parties in the UK were never totally class-based. Even in the nineteenth century, many members of the aristocracy were Liberal, while the mill workers in Lancashire were solidly Conservative, possibly because the mill owners were solidly Liberal! All modern political parties are coalitions of interests, with considerable overlap. Many Liberals would be to the ‘left’ of the Labour party, and on some policies the Labour party is more ‘right wing’ than the Conservative party. Tony Blair made a positive virtue out of lack of ideology, promoting the ‘Third Way’, which was neither left wing nor right wing, and also promoting New Labour as a ‘broad church’. Research seems to suggest that politics today, rather than being onedimensional (left – right) is two dimensional, based on belief in or rejection of both personal and economic freedom. As shown in the diagram (Forman and Baldwin 1999, p9), this permits at least five different currents of political opinion, which do not necessarily correspond to political parties. The percentages refer to an opinion poll carried out during the 1997 General Election: Conservative 38% Economic Freedom Libertarian 19% Centrist 15% Authoritarian 13% Socialist 18% Personal Freedom 2. UKIP has at present no chance of achieving governmental power, and its main chance of influencing policy is to force the Conservative party to move further towards its own anti-EU position. In this sense it is a pressure group rather than a political party, as was its predecessor the Referendum Party in 1997. It is also a single-interest group, advocating withdrawal from the EU, although it does have policies on a few other issues, including immigration. I would argue that it is a pressure group, although it would see itself as a political party. One of its leading lights, Robert Kilroy-Silk, claimed at its 2004 Conference that its aim should be to replace the Conservative party. Interestingly, UKIP’s leading financial backer, Paul Sykes, immediately withdrew his support and returned to the Conservative party, while Kilroy-Silk, who has a political reputation as a loose cannon, quickly fell out with the rest of the UKIP leadership and left the party. The SNP started as a pressure group, with its sole objective being to achieve independence for Scotland. However, since it formed a minority administration in Scotland, it has been forced to become a political party. Underpinning all its policies has been the interests of Scotland, but it has emerged as a left of centre political party. The Ulster Unionist Party is more complex. Arguably it is a single-interest group, seeking to maintain the Union between Great Britain and Northern Ireland, but since the 1920s it has actively sought, and for most of the time held, political power in Northern Ireland. As the governing party it has been forced to develop policies in other areas besides the Union. After the Good Friday Agreement, and the setting up of the Northern Ireland Assembly, it has governed in a power-sharing agreement with Sinn Fein, the traditional enemy. This has forced compromise, as a result of which it has found itself outflanked by Ian Paisley’s Democratic Unionist Party, which is seen by Protestants as more committed to the defence of their interests. My conclusion would thus be that the Ulster Unionist party is a political party, while UKIP is a pressure group. Activity 4.3 A question of influence Make a list of the ways in which pressure groups can influence the government. Feedback There is a whole range of ways in which pressure groups can influence the government: They can directly influence government policy. This might be to persuade the public itself to take action – for example, the boycott of South African products in the 1970s and 1980s, or to encourage the public to put pressure on the government – signing petitions, etc. They can run their own candidates for election to Parliament. This is unusual, but in 1997 was done by the referendum Party and the Pro-Life Alliance. They can make financial contributions to political parties. This is now much more tightly controlled after the ‘sleaze’ scandals of the 1990s. They can seek to influence the passage of legislation, by concentrating campaigning and lobbying on the details of a particular piece of legislation. They can make expert representations to civil servants. It is civil servants who draw up most of the plans for detailed implementation of policy. Activity 4.4 Standard of living How might an individual’s standard of living increase without there being an increase in GDP? Feedback There are a number of differences between GDP and standard of living, which can explain how one can improve while the other doesn’t. GDP includes exports, but excludes imports. So, if you buy a DVD player made in China, this adds to your standard of living, but not the UK’s GDP. Similarly, if you take a holiday in Spain, this is part of your standard of living, but part of Spain's GDP. Conversely, if the UK exports cashmere sweaters to the US, this increases the US’s standard of living, but not ours, although our GDP would grow. GDP records traded output, but excludes non-traded output. Therefore no allowance is made for activities such as DIY, housework or gardening. This produces the anomaly that if a person marries their housekeeper or gardener, and thereafter gave them an allowance exactly equal to their previous wage, GDP would fall. If all services in the household economy were paid for, GDP would probably rise by 35 per cent. Improvements to your home undertaken by you can therefore improve your standard of living, but won’t necessarily count in GDP calculations. Similarly, no allowance is made for the ‘hidden’ or ‘black’ economy – moonlighting, drug dealing and other criminal activities, estimated as 10 per cent of GDP in the UK, and a staggering 30 per cent in Italy. No allowance is made in an average GDP per head figure for distribution of income. If this is very skewed, a few will enjoy very high standards of living at the expense of the majority. Income has become much less evenly distributed in the UK since 1979 (a trend which has continued under New Labour since 1997), so it is possible for some individuals to improve their standard of living, whilst the GDP is static or even falling. Not all elements of GDP form part of consumer standard of living. For example, increased defence spending increases GDP, but does not directly increase standard of living. No allowance is made for the possible social costs of higher GDP – eg air, water or noise pollution – indeed, if higher output causes pollution, and resources are then used to clean up this pollution, GDP increases on both counts, but real standard of living has not changed. No valuation is placed on leisure. Voluntary leisure is part of an individual’s standard of living, but it is not valued. No account is taken of the improved design and quality of goods over time. Activity 4.5 Deflation If the effects of high inflation are adverse, would it be better to have falling prices (deflation), as in 2008–9? Feedback Deflation is decidedly not a good thing. It tends to trap economies in a stagnant cycle from which they cannot escape. The awful warning lesson is what has happened in Japan over the last decade, for most of which prices have been falling. The results of that have been: Consumers know that if they postpone purchases, goods will be cheaper next year than they are now. The result has been a fall in consumer spending and an increase in saving. Nominal interest rates have been very low, normally at or near zero. This means that the Japanese central bank loses all control over monetary policy. It cannot cut interest rates in order to stimulate demand, as it is impossible to have negative nominal interest rates. Cutting taxes doesn’t work either. It puts more money in the pockets of consumers, but they tend to save it rather than spend it because the money will be worth more next year. The result in Japan has been a chronic decade-long recession, which seems to have no end in sight. Activity 4.6 Gordon Brown and the recession The Conservative party blames Gordon Brown for the recession in the UK in 2008–9. Is this fair? Feedback The case against Gordon Brown: Brown was complacent about the risk of recession. He claimed to have ‘abolished boom and bust’. This ignored the economic cycle, which produces a down-turn every eight to 10 years. Brown and his Conservative predecessor as Chancellor, Kenneth Clarke, managed 14 years (from 1993–2007), but another downturn was inevitable at some time. Brown’s handling of the financial sector was too lax. He relaxed controls, and encouraged the financial sector to become too big and too powerful. This produced what Cable calls the ‘Icelandic disease’, (Cable 2009, p165), where the banking sector outgrows the size of the economy, creating chronic financial instability and risk. This was particularly true in Iceland and Ireland, but the same was true to a lesser extent in the UK. In the years running up to 2007, Brown had started to relax his Prudence approach. The public sector deficit was already growing before 2007. Brown had done nothing to control the boom in house prices. The case for Gordon Brown: The recession was a world phenomenon, and there was no way that the UK could have avoided it. The recession started in America, with the reckless monetary expansion after 9/11, and the growth of the sub-prime mortgage market. Once the recession started, Brown took decisive action to counter it. The result is that the recession will turn out to be comparable with that of the early 1990s, rather than, as feared in October 2008, as bad as the Great Depression of the early 1930s. The overall conclusion must be that Brown made mistakes, which probably contributed to the severity of the recession in the UK, but he did not cause it. If one person is to be held responsible for the recession, it is probably Alan Greenspan. Activity 4.7 Teachers and workforce planning Intuitively you would think it would be easy to plan the supply of teachers. After all, you know how many children are born each year and where they are born, because all births have to be registered. Then you just project four years ahead (for primary schools) and 11 years (for secondaries), and you know how many children will be entering each level of school in each year. Adding up the years gives you a total school population. Divide this by your planned pupil-teacher ratio, and you know exactly how many teachers you need in each year. Unfortunately, of course, it doesn’t work like that. Over the period 1946–2001, there was a shortage of teachers (an excess demand) for all but ten years, reaching a peak of 80,000 in the early nineties. There was a surplus (excess supply) for ten years from the mid-1970s to the mid-1980s, peaking at about 15,000 (Dolton 2005). Why is it so difficult to plan the supply of teachers? Feedback Factors, which make it so difficult to plan the supply of teachers can be broken down into demand and supply factors. Demand factors The government doesn’t know the number of children and where they live. Birth registration tells you where children were born, but not where they currently live. It might be possible to get this information from GP records, but this would raise data protection issues. In theory, the Census gives you an accurate picture every ten years, but the 2001 Census has been severely criticised for under-counting, particularly in inner city areas. Immigration further complicates the picture. A sudden influx of immigrants, some of whom will have children of school age, can rapidly distort the picture. This happened with the influx of Poles after 2004. Changes in government policy affect demand. This can range from raising the school leaving age, to a decision to start formal education at four rather than five. Government policy on desirable pupil-teacher ratios can also change. A change in the staying-on rate after the official school leaving age. This is affected by many factors, including the availability of jobs for 16 year olds. Factors such as the development of vocational qualifications in schools can change the demand for subject specialisms. Supply factors The government can supply sufficient teacher training places, but as people have a free choice of jobs, there is no guarantee that they will be taken up. This is particularly true of subjects where rewards outside teaching are high, like mathematics. The government has attempted to tackle this through targeted incentives such as bursaries. The wastage rate from teaching is high, and not entirely predictable. Of those who start teacher training, only half are still in teaching three years after qualifying. Wastage rates among male teachers have been rising in recent years, from three per cent to eight per cent between 1997 and 2001 (Dolton 2005). Women teachers leave to start families, and the rate of early retirement can vary. Age structure of the profession matters, as the higher the average age, the greater the wastage rate. In 2005, 50 per cent of the current stock of teachers would reach retirement age within 10 years. There is a very large pool of inactive teachers. If these could be tempted back into the profession, they would boost the supply considerably. Pay is an issue. It has been estimated that a 10 per cent across the board pay increase would create an extra 20,000 to 34,000 teachers (Dolton op cit). However, for over 40 per cent of drop-out teachers surveyed in 2003, nothing could have made them stay. For the others, change in workload or school characteristics were more Iikely to be cited than salary as an inducement to stay (Dolton, op cit). In other words, higher pay might attract more teachers, but it would not necessarily retain them. All the above factors are essentially macro ones. Even if there was a balance between supply and demand of teachers on a national level, there would still be acute shortages in some less attractive areas and subjects. Seminar Activity 4 Economic development in India and China Between 1985 and 1995, GNP growth in the developing world averaged 6 per cent a year, more than twice that of the developed world (World Bank 2000). This suggests that the developing world will soon catch up with the developed world. Unfortunately, this hopeful forecast ignores two key factors. One is the rapid rate of population growth in the developing world. When this is stripped out, and growth converted to GNP per head, the growth rate per head in the developing world falls to 3.8 per cent, while that of the developed world falls to 2.1 per cent. Secondly, the developing country figures are distorted by the outstanding success of the two most populous countries, India and China. In the period 1985–95, India’s GNP per head rose by 3.2 per cent a year, and China’s by an impressive (although possibly unreliable) 8.3 per cent a year. Stripping out India and China from the figures, the rest of the developing world actually had a GNP per head which fell by nearly 1 per cent a year. Since the 1990s, growth in both countries has accelerated, to 10 percent or more in China, and 8 per cent in India. China’s success has been particularly remarkable. It took England 58 years to double its GDP after 1780, the US 47 years from 1839, Japan 34 years from 1885, and South Korea 11 years from 1966 (Meredith 2007). It took China nine years from 1978. It then doubled again by 1996, and doubled yet again by 2006 (Hutton 2007). Why have India and China done so well? To some extent both countries are returning to their historic position in the world economy. At the time of the Roman Empire, China had 26 per cent of the world’s economy, and India had 33 percent. Even by 1820, China had 33 per cent, India 16 per cent (compared with western Europe at 24 per cent, and the US at 2 per cent (Smith 2007)). It was only in the nineteenth century that the Indian and Chinese economies collapsed. China’s GDP per head in 1950 was only three-quarters of its 1820 value. By the early 1970s, China’s share of world output was only 5 per cent, and India’s 3 per cent, compared to western Europe’s 26 per cent and the US and Canada’s 25 percent. India and China have some distinct similarities in their economies. Both had their year zero in the 1940s, when their political and economic status was transformed – India’s by independence in 1947, China’s by the victory of Mao and the Communists in 1949. Both have huge populations, and a dominant agricultural sector, employing more than half of population. Both went through the same sequence of economic development, of emphasis on heavy industry and a planned economy, followed by agricultural reform, followed by export-led growth, with greater emphasis on the market (Goyal and Jha, 2004). The main difference comes in their political systems. China has been a unitary state since the time of the first emperor (he of the terracotta warriors) in the second century BC. Throughout most of its history, India has been a cultural rather than a political entity, and has only been a single state under foreign conquerors, from the Mughals in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries to the British in the eighteenth to twentieth centuries. China is a one-party state with power centralised in the Communist party; India is a multi-party democracy. China is relatively homogeneous racially, with few religious or racial minorities, except for Muslims in the far west, while India is a heterogeneous state both racially and religiously, with a very large Muslim minority population (India has a bigger Muslim population than Pakistan), and significant numbers of Sikhs, Buddhists and Christians. Both initially made economic mistakes, but both laid the foundations for their future success immediately after their respective Year Zeros. Mao took over a state where illiteracy was rife, with a male illiteracy rate of 70 per cent, and female illiteracy up to 99 per cent in rural areas (Hutton p 76). Mao immediately instituted a crash programme of primary education, and by the mid 1990s adult literacy was up to 80 per cent. It is forecast that by 2025 there will be more English speakers in China than there are native English speakers in the rest of the world (Smith p100). China’s economic policy was eccentric and destructive until the 1970s. The Great Leap Forward between 1958 and 1961 tried to industrialise China through village communes, which predictably proved to be a failure, while the whole Chinese economy was torn apart by the Cultural Revolution between 1966 and 1976. India after independence went for a moderate socialist economy similar to that constructed in the UK in the 1940s, with extensive nationalisation of key industries, and also, following the ideas of Gandhi, opted for economic selfsufficiency (autarky). Small industries were encouraged, and tariff barriers were high. The economy was also highly bureaucratic (known as the Permit Raj), and this discouraged entrepreneurialism. However, many small to medium sized firms prospered under this benign and protectionist regime, and India developed skills in small-scale manufacture. The first Prime Minister of India, Pandit Nehru, was also, like Mao, committed to education. His legacy was the foundation of a group of seven Indian Institutes of Technology, founded in 1947. Although small, these were excellent, rated in 2005 as the third best institutions of technology in the world, behind only MIT and the California Institute of Technology. Graduates from the IITs were later to develop the Indian software industry, as well as much of Silicon Valley. China’s switch to a high-growth economy began in 1978, when the veteran communist Deng Xiaoping came to power. Deng realised that results were more important than ideology. One of his sayings is ‘it doesn’t matter whether a cat is black or white as long as it catches mice.’ Deng dismantled the rural communes, giving land back to the peasants, which immediately led to a rise in agricultural output. He ensured that state enterprises were run by managers rather than party bureaucrats, and he set up Special Economic Zones, tax-free enclaves which welcomed foreign investment, initially from the Chinese diaspora in Hong King, Singapore and Taiwan, but later from the west, particularly the US. He cut tariffs on imports, and launched a huge programme of infrastructure investment, with tens of thousands of miles of motorway and dozens of new international airports being built. The combination of good infrastructure and plentiful, cheap but welleducated labour proved irresistible to foreign investors. By 2008, China made two-thirds of the world’s photocopiers, shoes, toys and microwaves, half the DVD players, digital cameras and textiles, a third of the desktop computers, and a quarter of the mobile phones and TVs (Jacques 2009). China’s manufactured exports have boomed, although there has been some criticism that the result is that goods are ‘made in China’, but not ‘made by China’ (Hutton p114). There are very few major Chinese-owned companies, and none which are truly world-class. However, the success of Chinese companies like Galanz (see Case Study 1.6) suggests that this will soon change. Potentially the Chinese economy was at severe risk from the onset of world recession in 2008, because one of the first manifestations of the recession was a collapse in world trade. This hit China hard, as its economy was crucially dependent on exports of manufactured goods, particularly to the US. However, the Chinese government took quick and decisive action, putting a large fiscal stimulus into the economy, and switching production to the home market. For over forty years, India bumbled along, with some economic growth, but not sufficient to cut rural poverty significantly (what J K Galbraith described as ‘functioning anarchy (Smith p172)). Despite the success of the IITs, illiteracy, especially in rural areas, remained high, and India was also held back by its caste structure. Since independence, discrimination against dalits (untouchables) has been illegal, but in practice it persisted. Only 20 per cent of rural residents are dalits, but they make up 38 per cent of the very poor. A further 11 per cent are adavasis (members of tribal groups), but they are even poorer, making up 48 per cent of the very poor (Meredith p119). India’s point of change came in 1991, when the country faced a financial crisis. This led to reforms introduced by Manmohan Singh, the finance minister, and now (2007) Prime Minister of India. He liberalised external trade and deregulated the domestic economy, copying Deng’s concept of Special Economic Zones. The growth rate accelerated, reaching 8 per cent by 2000. India built on its strength in small and medium sized manufacturing, backed by highly skilled craftsmen. Whereas China was the country of choice for mass production, India concentrated on short, highly specialised production runs. More important, India latched on to the boom in new technology in the 1990s. Not only did it scoop the market in call centres and business process outsourcing, by the 2000s taking a 48 per cent share of the world market (Smith p132), but it also developed a world class software industry, centred on the southern city of Bangalore, where Infosys and Wipro are world class and rapidly growing software companies. The software for Apple’s highly successful iPod was developed in India (and the product assembled in China) (Meredith p102). Services now account for more than half of India’s GDP (Rudiger 2008). Older industry also started to flourish, led by the long-established conglomerate Tata, which now owns Corus (the ex British Steel) as well as a range of western companies including Tetley Tea. It subsequently bought Jaguar and Land Rover from Ford in 2008 for $2.3 billion. In 2007, India became the world’s twelfth largest economy (De Vita 2009). India seems to have weathered the world recession without too much damage, and expects economic growth soon to return to the pre-credit crunch figure of 9 per cent. India also had great institutional strengths – the English language, a vibrant democracy, a free press, and universal acceptance of the rule of law. Hutton sees these soft attributes as key. However, like China, India has weaknesses. Its literacy rate lags well behind China, and its physical infrastructure is very weak. Its roads, with a few exceptions, are appalling, and anyone who has experienced Agra airport will know that the same can be said for most of its airports. Each of the 28 Indian states has its own border controls and regulations. Smith describes a lorry journey from Kolkata (Calcutta) to Mumbai (Bombay), a distance of 2150 kilometres, which took eight days, including 32 hours waiting at border toll booths (Smith p164). However, the latest Five Year Plan (2007–12) has earmarked $500 billion for infrastructure improvement. Like China, India also suffers from endemic corruption. In 2007, Andrew Wileman described an attempt to transport a bull elephant from Kerala to Bangalore in order to take part in a Hindu ceremony at one of the IT companies, Aditi. The 300 mile journey involved the payment of £250 in bribes at every state border to and from Bangalore, because ‘elephant transportation papers were not in order’. He also tells the story of the auto-rickshaws in Delhi. Apparently there are 500,000 of these, but only 100,000 official licences. The other 400,000 stay in business by paying regular ‘fines’ to the traffic police (Wileman 2007). As a democracy, India is relatively slow to take decisions, and to make major shifts in policy. On the other hand, decisions in India have democratic legitimacy. China can take quick decisions, and tends to be better at taking long-term decisions, as its government is not answerable to an electorate, while decisions in India are shorter-term, and geared to the electoral cycle. As a result, China was better placed to make long-term investments in its education and health programmes, and to steamroller through its infrastructure improvements. Despite its centralised political system, China has been very effective at decentralising economic decision-making. It has given a great deal of economic autonomy to the growth areas of Shanghai, Quangdong and Hong Kong. China has also been more effective at opening its economy to the west and at encouraging foreign direct investment through a stable exchange rate and low real interest rates. India has gained through the widespread use of English in its higher education system, which has led to the outsourcing of large numbers of service jobs from the west. China has tended to gain from the outsourcing of manufacturing rather than service jobs. This has led to a big increase in Chinese exports, particularly to the US and Japan. Both countries clearly have economic systems which are highly effective at generating economic growth. As an authoritarian stare, China has been able to be more single-minded in its pursuit of growth, and as a result has achieved a higher rate of growth. However, there are costs in the Chinese system. As the development economist Amartya Sen has pointed out, no democratic country has experienced a devastating famine, whereas authoritarian states like China have (Steele 2001). It appears that a combination of authoritarian political control and a decentralised market-run economic system seems to be highly effective at producing economic growth, but with accompanying costs like loss of freedom, economic inequality and social disruption. However, it is possible to over-hype the success of China. (Hilton 2004). It took until 1993 before China’s exports were back at the level they reached in 1928, before the Japanese invasion, and despite its vast population, China’s GDP in 2000 was only a quarter that of Japan. The dash for growth has also caused enormous environmental degradation. China has 16 of the world’s 20 most polluted cites. Which do you think is more likely to sustain its economic growth in the long term, India or China? There are three excellent books, all published in 2007, which provide background material for this Seminar Activity. Two are journalistic accounts of the economic rise of India and China. David Smith’s The dragon and the elephant; China, India and the new world order, examines the issues from a UK perspective. Robyn Meredith’s The elephant and the dragon: the rise of India and China and what it means for all of us, covers much the same ground from a US perspective. Will Hutton’s The writing on the wall takes a more analytical approach, concentrating on China, and is as much a critique of the west as it is of China. A further book, published in 2009, is Martin Jacques’ When China rules the world, which takes a mainly cultural perspective on the rise of China. Feedback India and China can be compared and contrasted on a number of issues. 1. Growth rate: Is the Chinese growth rate of 10 per cent a year sustainable? Hutton argues that it is not. If the current growth rate continued until 2020, Chinese exports would be $5 trillion a year, half of all world exports, and the whole of China’s then GDP. Clearly this would be unsustainable, and indeed China expects that its growth rate will slow to a more manageable 5–6 per cent a year. India’s present GDP per head is only half that of China’s, and its growth rate slower. India can maintain its present growth rate for longer than China before it hits market buffers. 2. Pollution and the environment: China’s cities are already the most polluted in the world. So are India’s, but India has fewer huge cities, and has taken measures to attempt to cut pollution – all Delhi’s busses, for example, run on relatively unpolluting natural gas. More serious in the long run is that if India and particularly China continue their present rates of growth of oil consumption, uncontrollable global warming will make the whole world economy unsustainable. 3. Industrial structure: China has concentrated on manufacturing, India on services. It could thus be argued that India has leapfrogged China to a more advanced form of economy. However, someone has to make things, and there appears to be no conceivable serious rival to China. More serious is that China has not developed its own indigenous industry. Its factories are assembly plants for foreign owners, with little technology transfer to Chinese-owned firms. India has already developed world-class service industry firms, which may make it more viable in the long run. 4. Infrastructure: China’s physical infrastucture is unquestionably far superior to that of India. However, it may be too good – better than China needs. Part of China’s problem is that it has vast amounts of savings seeking investment – up to 40 percent of GDP. As a result, much of its investment produces very low returns. India’s infrastructure, although poor, is not a great handicap to its service industries, which communicate with the rest of the world electronically, not via the road system. 5. Population structure: India’s population is much younger than China’s, and so potentially more adaptable. China also has the problem that in 20 years’ time, it will have to support a growing proportion of old people. Traditionally, this was the responsibility of sons and daughters, but the Chinese one child policy ensures that fewer of these will be available. 6. Education: China’s primary education system is vastly superior to India’s. Only in 2001 was primary education made both compulsory and free in India. As a result, China’s literacy rate is better than India’s. On the other hand, India’s higher education is superior, particularly in technology and engineering, and traditionally has always used the medium of English. 7. Social structure: China’s population is homogeneous, and has also tended to be relatively docile. India’s population is much more heterogeneous, and is still plagued by the problem of caste. 8. Corruption: Both India and China have endemic corruption. They rank as joint 70th on the Transparency International world corruption index. However, most Indian corruption is relatively low-level, and not particularly effective. China’s corruption is more institutional, and usually involves party officials, often very high-ranking. The Chinese have tried to tackle this, but with extremely heavyhanded methods, including hundreds of executions. 9. Political system: For Hutton this is the key issue. India is a thriving dynamic democracy, and a pluralist society. Indians are notoriously argumentative, and this stimulates new ideas. It also has a vibrant free press, and an established rule of law. China is a one-party state, which is prepared to ride rough-shod over individual rights. Historically, this has tended to lead throughout Chinese history to violent protests and uprisings. Hutton fears that if Chinese growth falters, the result might be popular protests, or an attempt by the regime to divert attention through risky foreign adventures, perhaps including an invasion of Taiwan. 10. Quality In the summer of 2007 there were a number of complaints about the quality of Chinese products, particularly toys supplied for the US market which contained excessive amounts of lead. There have also been complaints about the quality of some Indian call centres The overall evidence is clearly mixed, but on balance I would see India as having the better long-term prospects.