The Midi, the Métropole and the Marshall Plan. To what extent did concepts of post-war recovery affect regional institutions and identity? A study of the Midi vignerons in the French Fourth Republic. Andrew W. M. Smith Supervisor: Dr. S. Tyre This thesis is submitted in partial fulfillment for the degree of M.A. Honours in the Department of Modern History, School of History, University of St Andrews 2007 I, Andrew William Macrae Smith, attest that this dissertation, for submission to the Department of Modern History, St Andrews University, is entirely my own work. 2 Contents Preface 4 List of Abbreviations 5 Introduction 6 Chapter 1 8 The Government, State Intervention and Attempts to Alter the Status Quo Chapter 2 Local Power Structures and the Rise of the Cooperative 26 Chapter 3 Tending Vines and Picket Lines: The People of the Midi 41 Conclusion 61 Appendix 63 Bibliography 65 3 Preface Both the Monnet Plan and the Marshall Plan had pivotal roles to play in the redevelopment of the post-war French economy, but exacted what can be described as the wages of modernisation from areas like the Midi, centred on agricultural production and mired in retrograde methods. Recovery necessitated heavy regulation and stringent planning which rendered the wine industry structurally dependent on the government, as the solution to increasing market instability was seen in more exacting controls. The traditional left-wing slant on Southern politics was exemplified in the stand made by Southern political organisations against the impositions of central government, which struggled to find the balance of intervention set against the political instability of the Fourth Republic. Governmental instability exacerbated a situation in which producers became politicised, as rural protest became a combatative assertion of regional identity in a world which was rapidly expanding in terms of European integration and globalisation. By focussing on the nature of French regional identity in response to external pressure, it becomes important to gauge both the nature of the reaction as well as the nature of the pressure and to this end this study will encompass: interviews conducted in the region; American state documents detailing the thought behind the Marshall Plan and French state documents regarding the interaction of Paris and the Midi. Today, the French wine industry bears the scars of structural dependence, fractured regionalism and excessive regulation, phenomena which have direct roots in the post-war period, resulting in the qualitative retardation and quantitative superfluity of the industry which has plagued it since. The study of the period remains a juxtaposition of stark economic realities and fin de siècle sentimentality, wherein poetry, the civilisation of the vine and the traditional 4 solidarity of the agricultural proletariat jar with an unapologetically modern global market. Table of Abbreviations A.O.C. Appellation d’Origine Contrôlée C.G.V. Confédération Générale des Vignerons C.R.A.V. Comité régional d'action viticole E.E.C. European Economic Community HL Hectolitre (100 litres) HA Hectare (10,000 square metres) P.C.F. Parti Communiste Française 5 Introduction In the post war period the Languedoc Roussillon faced the challenges of economic recovery whilst undergoing a crisis of identity. The traditional decline of agricultural communities against the backdrop of “la permanence de la crise viticole”1 intensified and articulated the crisis. The complex nature of this identity crisis renders it largely unquantifiable, but what this study intends in part to illustrate is the intrinsic interrelationship of political association and traditional cultural ties in informing twentieth century identity in rural France. This was shaped in the post-war period, representing the start of the transition towards a recognisably modern mindset as the Midi vignerons faced the upheavals of modernisation and a national identity forcefully revised by post-war international relations. In this study I intend to pursue a ‘top-down’ analysis of the period: examining relevant reforms and parliamentary debate at governmental level before exploring the effect of implementation on the regional level and culminating in an analysis of events at an interpersonal level. My study will focus around the LanguedocRoussillon region in the South of the country - the largest wine-producing area in France. This area has generally been the source of much of France’s vin de table, contributing 39% of total French wine production in 1957 alone2, and has thus played a vital role in the national economy by supplying much of the ‘drinking wine’ to the North. The largescale nature of monocultural investment has meant that it has tended to act as a lens, magnifying issues affecting the wider viticultural sector, augmented by the notional southern predilection to protest. As such, the study of this area helps to develop a greater O. Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, Journée d’études AFSP/Groupe Local et politique, IEP de Rennes – 8 février 2002 p6 2 A. Girard, ‘Région Languedoc-Roussillon. Economie et Population’, Population (French Edition), vol. 12 no. 3 (July - September 1957) p513 1 6 understanding of the health of the national economy and wider agricultural sector, as well as attempting to explore predicators of the perceived distinct Southern identity. Indeed, the period plays witness to a wholesale decline in the relevance of regional identity, eroded by the collapse of traditional communities as a result of the modernisation of the economy and progressive demographic trends. These factors become increasingly important when studying periods of significant change in French life, such as the period after the Liberation and spanning the lifetime of the Fourth Republic, on which this study will centre. Thematically there are four key concepts which permeate the investigation: reactions to modernisation; reluctance to embrace extra-local pressures for change; the importance of left wing politics; and a regional tradition of resistance. In observation of these themes, I intend to trace their development through the three levels of my study, in a negotiation designed to highlight the controversy involved in manipulating traditional concepts of identity. Whether within global, national or local political frameworks the relevance of these concepts was challenged by the increasingly global context of post-war recovery plans. 7 Chapter 1: The Government, State Intervention and Attempts to Alter the Status Quo When considering the economic performance of the Fourth Republic, it is important to dissociate notions of political instability from the larger truth of economic progress. The political climate at the start of the Fourth Republic all but governed its future, with a hasty conglomeration of Gaullists and the left producing a political stalemate which represented a “fertile field”3 for the flourishing of small interest groups. It is an historical irony that in the midst of the instability and political infighting of the Fourth Republic, France’s economy evolved with a large degree of economic planning and involved reform. The war, and poor pre war economic situation, can be seen to have forced reform in certain key areas. This was a result of developing social trends such as migration away from agriculture, described as ‘the hidden hand’ of economic processes.4 There is likewise a debate regarding the, possibly accidental, positive influence of the Vichy regime on post-war modernization, as its corporatist policy eventually meshed with the large-scale program of industrial amalgamations, for example in the coal and steel industries, which took place under the Fourth Republic. However, France’s recovery is not merely attributable to such incidental historical phenomena, as both agriculture and industry witnessed incisive, effective and deliberate political intervention to encourage modernisation. 3 I. M. Wall, The United States and the Making of Postwar France (Cambridge, 2002) p36 H. Schmiegelow; M. Schmiegelow, ‘The New Mercantilism in International Relations: The Case of France's External Monetary Policy’, International Organization, 29 (Spring 1975) p368 4 8 Stability was made possible by the relative continuity in ministerial positions set against the background of larger cabinet instability in the Fourth Republic, which was a result of the parliamentary system and the fluid nature of the cabinet majority. This left a situation whereby the frequent collapses of prime ministers failed to bring about significant change in many ministerial posts (with the average ministerial continuation throughout the first 8 cabinet reshuffles of the Fourth Republic being 50%5). Such background stability lent a greater degree of authority to government bureaucrats usually reined in by strong political leadership, which in turn influenced the tone and execution of reform. Representative of this empowerment of bureaucrats was Jean Monnet, at no point elected to ministerial position but regarded, due to his exceptional financial background, as one of the primary reformers within the Republic. Horrified by the violence of two world wars, Monnet sought to preclude the reoccurrence of such conflict by diminishing nationalist sentiment through a program of wider European integration. Monnet himself recognised the strange political situation, highlighting that “in the twenty years that followed [World War Two], three planning commissioners outlived twenty eight governments.”6 The keen influence of conservative individuals such as Monnet on post-war reform is perhaps best evidenced by the respective high profile plans unveiled by the British and French government after the war. The post-war British Labour government ushered in the liberal welfare state in response to the Beveridge Report whereas France undertook a decidedly more conservative program of industrial and fiscal reform as part of the Monnet Plan. This individualistic influence on policy was directly 5 6 R.C. Macridis, ‘Cabinet Instability in the Fourth Republic’, The Journal of Politics, 14 (1952) p647-8 J. Monnet, Memoirs (Glasgow, 1976) p261 9 derivative of Monnet’s personal role in securing American aid and his heightened importance in the political climate.7 As such, it is important to look at the economic measures promulgated from Paris with a sense of their development over the chronology of the Fourth Republic, whilst remembering that the period witnessed an empowered bureaucratic civil service often acting in place of direct political influence. Planning and State Intervention Important in the rejuvenation of the post-war agricultural climate was the influence of structures and governance upon the fertile areas of France “where the physical environment has not been a handicap, but the influence of man has been decisive in the eventual success of viticulture and its economic consequence.”8 Indeed, external governance has often been seen by growers themselves as an impediment to the success of the industry, with the observation that it is the land which has enabled the industry “to live and die and live again.”9 As such, the government’s role in viticulture has largely been one of regulation, although it is similarly important to consider the significance of subsidies, taxation, price fixing and rationing, as these constituted the principal governmental tools for managing the viticultural economy. Part of the dynamism of the interchange, however, consists of the inter-relationship of traditional local elites with external influences such as the government. This interplay in turn helped shape the nature of the institutions that interpreted and implemented extra-local policy directives. F.M.B. Lynch, ‘Resolving the Paradox of the Monnet Plan: National and International Planning in French Reconstruction’, The Economic History Review, Vol. 37, No. 2. (May, 1984), p232 8 G.G. Weigend, ‘The basis and significance of viticulture in Southwest France’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, vol.44 no.1 (Mar., 1954) p75 9 R. Scruton, ‘Peasants’ Revolt’, New Statesman, 17/07/06 p48 7 10 The interaction of enterprise, regional elites and national government shaped the nature of the economic planning which by and large steered France towards post-war recovery. The Plans orchestrated by the Planning Commissariat were, by definition, indicative and not authoritarian, as dialogue was enshrined in the process of their inception, which saw “economic, social and political considerations… inextricably linked”10. This interaction was essential, due to the fact that over 50% of capital investment could be influenced by state decisions11, placing an enormous amount of pressure on the government as a central body of prescriptive investment. This dynamic stance, coupled with the consultant nature of the relationship, helped ensure the accuracy of forecasts included in the Plan, with both the First and Second Plans exceeding targets.12 Indeed, forecasting only represented part of the function of the Plans as they were constantly modified in attempts to ensure the continued dynamic operation of the national economy. In this sense Economic Planning did not represent the outright control of the economy by the government but increased and involved intervention during a period in which the prospect of economic disaster was very real. The Planning Commissariat thus served the role of post-war training wheels for the national economy of the new Republic, allowing space for development whilst maintaining supervisory control. The main tools of the government in pursuing the aims of the planning commissariat were of subsidy, taxation and price fixing. Governmental use of subsidy was designed to alleviate strains on winemakers whilst helping to encourage greater fiscal responsibility in the means of their delivery. The immediate post-war period saw the creation of the “viticultural nest-egg”, which 10 G.M. Holmes; P.D. Fawcett, The Contemporary French Economy (London, 1983) p31 P. Coffey, The Social Economy of France (London, 1973) p72 12 Holmes; Fawcett, The Contemporary French Economy, pp.30-31 11 11 constituted the delivery of surcharges on the fixed price of wine at production level.13 The subsidy was granted with the express aim of reconstituting vineyards after wartime destruction, but carried within it the subtext of modernisation, with its usage limited to replanting vines and the purchase of modern equipment. In an attempt to show the growers the way to the bank, the subsidy was paid directly into the regional Crédit Agricole.14 This move eventually failed due to the limitations placed on the usage of the first ‘nest-egg’, but the subsidy remained in place, delivered thereafter in currency to allay the immediate needs of vignerons. Dynamism was achieved through the focus on indirect taxation pursued in the planning structure, allowing for a relatively immediate effect on the economy and avoiding difficulties in collection.15 Taxation has represented a long-time problem in the Midi, where regional agricultural organisations frequently advised members to withhold tax as a means of protest.16 Wines were evaluated for tax by their degree of alcohol, with higher taxes attempting to ward off high yield and highly alcoholic wines, generally of poor quality. As the government’s least popular economic tool, taxation strained the relationship between vignerons and government, with the suddenness of imposition frequently causing difficulties for smaller producers.17 The directness of taxation frequently gave way to more indirect means of attempting to guide the viticultural economy, ceding to protest from local vignerons about the limits placed on their activity. Price-fixing and rationing allowed the government to attempt to control the market for wine, rather than the productive sector itself. By artificially propping up 13 C.K. Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government since 1875, (New York, 1960) p165 Ibid, p165 15 P. Coffey, The Social Economy of France (London, 1973) p64 16 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p166 17 ibid p166 14 12 prices, as done immediately after the War, the government attempted to encourage growers to avoid the active black market and stay legitimate despite rising costs and small yields.18 In the face of these problems price-fixing proved to be rather toothless in isolation, and the policy required revision in the late 1940s with the associated introduction of a two-tiered market, consisting of a free sector for a small proportion of a producer’s wine and a price controlled sector for the majority.19 Although paying lipservice to market reform, tiering the sale of wine did little to encourage change in the region due to the small amount of wine saleable within the free sector, itself largely a concession to the greed of producers. The government’s tools in attempting to regulate the market and the productive sector were, therefore, fairly limited. Any ability to effect significant change in the market was resultantly lost in the largely palliative and indirect measures which the government had available, perpetuating the cycle of market fluctuations from which the Midi wine industry suffered. Intervention in Action The nature of the Midi’s dependence on a monocultural agricultural industry renders it largely susceptible to unfavourable market conditions which can devastate the regional economy and have done so cyclically from the outbreak of Phylloxera in 1863 until today. After the Liberation, many growers felt that the Midi was the worst affected by the wartime productive slump, and hoped for increased government support beyond traditional credit structures.20 Immediate measures to stimulate production were undertaken by the government in the provision of equipment such as fertiliser and horses, 18 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p166 ibid p167 20 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p162 19 13 coupled with the promise of subsidies,21 as mentioned previously. Heavy involvement persisted until 1947, whereupon the government decided to ease regulation in favour of greater market liberty.22 This situation prevailed at the start of the Fourth Republic period, much to the chagrin of the Midi vignerons, who sought heavy regulation as a shield against the crises brought about by market fluctuation. These crises are generally referred to in the region as crises de mévente23, and occurred during the Fourth Republic in the years of 1953 and 1956. The severity of these market fluctuations is demonstrated by the fact that the real value of wine dropped 20% between the periods 1949-1950 and 1953-1954 as a result of the first crisis of the period.24 The abundant harvest of 1953 led to a drop in prices which the government sought to tackle initially by issuing a decree in December of that year reclassifying viticultural territories in an effort to reduce expected volume.25 The crisis set the government reeling, with inaccurate assessment having estimated the drop in the value of wine over the preceding four years as 50%26 and barricades being erected all over the Midi as vignerons took to the street.27 A period of furious protest, coinciding with a general strike, saw the government eventually arrive at a legislative review in the form of the new Code du vin. Little advance was made with this review however, as, despite superficial changes, 1953 saw a return to the measures 21 ibid p164 ibid p168 23 J. Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique et Syndicale dans les Campagnes Viticoles du Midi’, La Diffusion des Idées Progressistes dans le Monde Rural de la Révolution au XX e Siècle. Actes du colloque de Châteauroux 1998 (Châteauroux, 2000) p7 24 J. Dubos, ‘Les Mutations de la Viticulture Française Contemporaine’ in J. Sagnès (ed.), La Viticulture Française aux XIXe et XXe Siècles (Béziers, 1993) p85 25 L. Loubère, The Vine Remembers, (New York, 1985) p172 26 Journal officiel de la république française. Documents parlementaires de l’Assemblée nationale, 1953, p980 (annex 6399) 27 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p183 22 14 introduced in the Statut Viticole in 1931, increasing the use of sales blockage and compulsory distillation.28 The falling price index of wine in the years running up to the “grande crise de 1953”29 had, however, seen preliminary measures introduced in an attempt to stave off further crisis. Efforts were made to reduce yields across the board, with the uprooting of vines intended to decrease the regional output and stabilise market value. These measures largely failed due to their voluntary nature, with distillation merely a palliative and the uprooting (or ‘grubbing up’) of vineyards, effectively eroding the future productive potential of vignerons and offering them only short-term financial remuneration. A program of voluntary distillation was instituted by central government, at which wine was bought at the going rate to be distilled into industrial spirit. Between 1948 and 1952 distillation of surplus wines cost the state 9694 million Francs per year30, with minimal long term benefit, whilst creating a new form of overproduction in the distilled alcohol sector.31 Likewise, attempts to encourage voluntary uprooting of vineyards by the decree of November 1954 failed, with an outcome of only 4% of vines uprooted by 1957.32 The later crisis can be attributed to a variety of factors, notably the very harsh frost in 195633, which combined with a period of declining consumption (from 139 litres per head per annum in 195434 to 124 litres per head per annum in 196335). 1954 actually represented the point from which consumption never recovered in France, facing regular 28 G. Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon (Montpellier, 1960), vol.2, p319 O. Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, Journée d’études AFSP/Groupe Local et politique, IEP de Rennes – 8 février 2002p7 30 Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon, vol.2, p320 31 Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique…’, pp.9-10 32 Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon, vol.2, p322 33 J.M. Jeanneney, Forces et Faiblesses de l’Économie Française, (Paris, 1959) p66 34 Dubos, ‘Les Mutations de la Viticulture Française Contemporaine’, p85 35 ibid p87 29 15 diminishment thereafter.36 Galtier labelled this crisis as “above all else a crisis of under consumption”, highlighting the fact that in 1955 sales of mineral water reached 920 million bottles, compared to 198 million in 1938.37 Likewise, the crisis of 1956 can be seen to have been one of the contributory factors in the rapid decline of agricultural workers, dropping from 5 million to 1.5 million 1955-1988.38 The government’s methods in tackling the crisis focussed initially on traditional methods, such as blocking surplus wine from sale (8.5 million HL)39 and the distillation of surplus wine into industrial spirit (6 million HL) 40, but going beyond earlier palliative measures by enforcing these as obligatory. Innovative methods were also introduced in an attempt to break the cyclical pattern of these market crashes, with 1.8 million Francs set aside in the 1955 budget to help encourage the exportation of Languedoc-Roussillon wines by granting massive subsidies to exporters.41 The recovery of the market was gradual but, as government initiatives took effect, prices returned to 1949 levels by the end of June 1957, having dropped as low as 74% in February 195642 (see figure 3). The ability of the government to solve market crises was demonstrable, therefore, although it encountered difficulty in trying to address the structural causes of the crises. INRA, ‘La consommation de vin dans les pays traditionnellement viticoles’, 2emeSymposium International sur la Production et la Consommation du Vin dans le Monde, (Ljubljana, 1979) p24 37 Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon, vol.2, p304 38 G. Gavignaud-Fontaine, La révolution rurale dans la France contemporaine : XVIIIe-XXe siècle (Paris, 1996) p167n2 39 Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon, vol.2, p319 40 ibid vol.2, p320 41 Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon, vol.2, p320 42 ibid, vol.2, p335 36 16 Attempts to Tackle Structural Problems Overproduction has been a constant structural frailty in the Midi, and the focus has been increasingly placed on programs of ‘grubbing up’ vineyards, compulsory distillation and reducing yields across the board. As early as 1946, the government attempted to implement uprooting programs, calling for reductions in the area under vine in both France and Algeria, however, the “clamour of thirsty consumers” dictated that this reduction was curtailed by the necessity of substantive recovery.43 Warner considers that the lesson provided by this too-rapid recovery was ignored in the long-term, as further reductions were not pursued aggressively enough in the legislative review of 1953.44 Between 1955 and 1956, the government increased their drive to reduce vine coverage in the Languedoc-Roussillon and, indeed, one witnesses a reduction in vine coverage in France from 1,391 million HA in 1954 to 1,173 million HA in 1958, a 15.7% decrease.45 What Dubos fails to incorporate in his citation of these figures is the reason behind the 1956 crisis, the extreme frost which caused widespread devastation, and actually led to the lifting of regulations regarding the planting of vines, allowing growers to plant new vines without uprooting old stock.46 Thus, whilst it is clear that the government pursued attempts to encourage reductions in the area of vines throughout the post-war period, it was seldom tackled courageously. The political instability of the Fourth Republic did not allow for such an overt challenge to a lobby group like the vignerons, for whom reducing output has perennially represented an unpalatable medicine, with the long term benefits of increasing prices obscured by the immediate 43 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p189 ibid p189 45 Dubos, ‘Les Mutations de la Viticulture Française Contemporaine’, p85 46 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p213 44 17 shock delivered to income. Even foreign appraisals of the French wine industry’s health focussed on the strength of “local resistance” to structural change and terming the frailties all but intractable.47 However, the economic imperatives of reducing output and increasing quality seemed the surest and most stable paths for the health of the industry, and have seen continued service at a national and supra-national level. However, these efforts have largely failed due to the vocal opposition presented to such plans. Criticism still can be heard from purists accusing the commission of bowing to “health fascists” and prescribing the cure for overproduction as increased consumption.48 The government, they say, is completing the work of Phylloxera.49 This attitude seems short-sighted at best and highlights the extent to which opposition to political measures can be seen to correlate with self interest in the Midi, muddying the praxis of protest otherwise informed by broader ideological concepts, as will be further explored in Chapter 3. Not only the opposition but the impetus behind reform was shaped by the broader ideological concerns writ large over the period. Attempts to tackle the innate problems of the Languedoc-Roussillon region were multi-faceted, but took on a new tone in the technocratic atmosphere of the Marshall Plan, determined to dispel the “drudgery of bygone times.”50 Schemes to irrigate the Rhone Valley were conceived of, broadly based on the success of the Tennessee Valley Authority which had prospered in America in the 1930s. Recently returned Marshall Plan exchange workers brought new perspectives to old problems, conceiving of a series of hydroelectric plants spanning newly irrigated 47 W. Meiklereid, Economic and Commercial Conditions in France, (London, 1953) p22 Scruton, ‘Peasants’ Revolt’, p48 49 ibid p48 50 ‘Europe – Ruins to Recovery’, Archive Hour, BBC Radio 4 23/09/06 48 18 canals, and allowing increased production of food crops as well as energy provision (See Figure 1 for route of canal). In addressing two of Monnet’s core problem industries, French engineers attempted to tackle the problem in a firmly Marshall Plan tone, but with a European flavour, highlighting that the progress of electrification took place in the landscapes of the “paintings of Paul Cézanne.”51 The Bas-Rhône-Languedoc scheme to irrigate large sections of the Midi region came into fruition under the second plan, building on the research done during the early years of post-war recovery.52 The project, however, was blighted by the inability of the government to suggest a “remunerative substitute crop”53 to growers eager to produce traditional products in an area where the vine flourished. The tone of these technocratic developments only served to galvanise opposition to what was seen as a “crash programme for reconstruction”54 which had already failed to address agricultural frailties during the first economic plan. Such attempts characterised the Fourth Republic period as, despite attempts at regional consultation, economic planning led to a situation which relied on the success of “basic sectors” rather than focussing on the “basic actions” needed to alter the problems of these sectors.55 The translation of the technocratic ideals proposed by the economic planners into reality fostered increasing local resentment of external pressures. 51 ibid M.C. Maclennan, ‘Regional Planning in France’, Journal of Industrial Economics, vol.13 (1965) p64 53 Meiklereid, Economic and Commercial Conditions in France, p22 54 J. Hackett; A. Hackett, Economic Planning in France, (London, 1963) p26 55 Hackett; Hackett, Economic Planning in France, p27 52 19 Difficulties of Imports To the producers of the Midi, imports of foreign table wines have always represented a visible and alacritous danger, menacing them with “prix competitifs.”56 This is especially so due to the high percentage of regional vinous production which fell under the Vin de Table classification, and, despite efforts to the contrary, the near total monoculture of the region which engenders total reliance on sales of basic wine.57 Other viticultural regions, such as Burgundy or the Loire, face a much lesser threat from imports, owing to their largely higher quality output and widespread polyculture.58 As such any similar low quality wine, imported from countries such as Italy, claimed a noticeable share of an already precarious market, and was highly visible as a grievance for regional agitators. The climate of tariff relaxation which accompanied the immediate postwar aid agreements therefore raised particular problems for the wine industry.59 Precedents exist that make plain the positive effect that imported wines can have on the national economy, as demonstrated in 1927, when the government temporarily lifted import duty to compensate for the poor harvest which had failed to yield enough wine to satisfy the market.60 Increased demand upon the enfeebled supply created a situation wherein wine that had been selling previously for 70F p/HL rocketed to 230F p/HL in February 1927 and continued rising to a high of 270F p/HL by the 15th of April.61 The controversial solution to the problem was accepted on the premise that the situation was temporary, and the promise that the imports (from Spain, Portugal, Italy and Greece) 56 Interview with Alain Trille, Château des Batilles, 04/08/06 Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, p3 58 Loubère, The Vine Remembers, p21 59 Lynch, ‘Resolving the Paradox of the Monnet Plan’, p231 60 Commission des Douanes, ‘Levée temporaire des droits de douane sur les vins étrangers en vue de la baisse du prix du vin de consommation courante en France’, Chambre des Députés, no. 4000 (Paris, 23 avril 1927) 61 ibid 57 20 would sate but not flood the market – merely reducing a market shortfall of 10 million HL to 8 million HL.62 This scenario helps to illustrate the positive nature of the manipulation of import tariffs as an economic tool, but also demonstrates plainly the impact that imports could have even as early as 1927, with a less developed international trade network in place. Indeed, the situation helps to elucidate the standpoint of the Midi vignerons in their opposition to further European integration in 1957, promising as it did the permanent relaxation of trading tariffs as a spur to burgeoning continental economic prosperity. Attempts made to counter this negative perception of increased European integration largely failed, mainly due to the inconsistent manner in which they were pursued. The formation of what can be termed as a ‘regional’ trade federation, the European Economic Community (E.E.C.), in the wake of the Second World War elicited an inconsistent portrayal in American produced propaganda of the period and the attitudes expressed privately by statesmen. The multilateralism created by a federation of united European states offered an attractive trading partner for America, as well as obvious political stability in the face of a perceived developing Eastern threat. As such, the prospect was widely represented as a positive step in the American media; with Gene Kelly taking a break from dancing to condescendingly report on the progress made in Geneva, fast becoming “the most important city in Europe”, as talks of union progressed.63 National borders became a thing of resentment for the economic wizards of the Marshall Plan, representing the last bastion of petty nationalism against the broad unity which Europe so desired in the late 1940s. Yet by the 1950s the focus had shifted to 62 63 ibid ‘Europe – Ruins to Recovery’, Archive Hour, BBC Radio 4 23/09/06 21 the celebration of economic and cultural individualism in response to the increasingly depersonalised political unity of the Eastern bloc.64 During discussion of the Marshall Plan, American government papers warned about the danger of the oversimplification of Europe resulting in a “renunciation… of the values of individual responsibility and political restraint”65. E.E.C. integration in the latter half of the twentieth century altered the tack of interrelationships. The post-war focus on multilateralism was largely replaced by the increasing solidarity within regional federations as a genuine response to the creeping influence of globalisation, allowing greater management of regional economies.66 Indeed, trading blocs such as the European Union have represented a continuously controversial notion in market economics, as they can be seen as contributory to the greater liberalisation of world trade or, indeed, as a threat to the spirit of multilateral trade liberalization.67 The dark realities which haunted Monnet’s dream of unity thus manifested themselves in the larger simplification of the E.E.C.’s diversity in its infancy. This simplification affected almost all constituent member states as the traditional geopolitical axis became realigned by the opening of markets and scaling down of protectionism and economic nationalism which resulted from increased inter-penetration. Traditional agricultural areas in France, for example, lying in the South of the country, were shifted effectively northwards by the incorporation of more southerly territories, for example Italy, stripping the areas of much of their economic relevance.68 The 64 ibid “Certain Aspects of the European Recovery Problem”, July, 1947; ERP [folder 2]; Subject File, 1916 1960; Clark Clifford Papers. 66 W. Michalak; R. Gibb, ‘Trading Blocs and Multilateralism in the World Economy’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, vol.87, no.2 (1997) p265 67 ibid p265 68 Interview with Edouard Raymond, Domaines Lacassagne, 03/08/06 65 22 aforementioned vulnerability of the Midi vignerons to cheap imported wine was therefore brought to the fore by the establishment of the E.E.C., and helps to explain their resistance to the introduction of wine into the Common Market, propounded principally by syndicalist agitators, leaving France exempt from E.E.C. winemaking laws until 1970.69 Erstwhile saviour and oft cited strain on the industry, Maghrebin wines played a largely ancillary role in French winemaking. The wines of the South can, amongst lower quality releases, have a tendency towards a certain thinness and low alcohol content, making for a largely unpalatable and even more unmarketable wine. The traditional solution to this problem was for vignerons to blend their wine with Algerian stock, often “riches en alcool”70 and extremely full in body (though lacking the complexity lent by the Midi wines in blending), which led to a degree of symbiosis between the respective markets. In the post-war period, this practice was largely in decline, influenced by the move towards better quality wines by independent producers seeking the higher price bracket guaranteed by Appellation d’Origine Controlée (A.O.C.) status.71 Indeed, Communist analyses of the viticultural situation rested upon the negative impact of the import of Algerian wines for the smallest producers of the Midi. It was with this in mind that workers’ representatives called for an end to Algerian imports in the 1930s, as they became less relevant to the health of the industry.72 Indeed, the existence of “the Algerian problem” throughout the late 1950s led to speculation that an increasing mobilisation of viticultural capital would precede a large-scale abandonment of Algerian vineyards in the J. Martin, ‘Winegrower’s Syndicalism in the Languedoc: Continuity and Change’, Sociologia Ruralis, vol.36, no. 3, p335 70 H. Isnard, La Vigne en Algérie (Paris, 1947) p231 71 Dubos, ‘Les Mutations de la Viticulture Française Contemporaine’, p84 72 Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique et Syndicale…’, p11 69 23 long term.73 Independence was largely seen as freeing France from the obligation to purchase almost all of Algerian production, allowing for a greater equilibrium in the market.74 This outcome represented one of the few structural problems in which the Midi saw any resolution, as the drastic severing of ties was clearly forced upon policy-makers outwith concerns for regional reaction. Due to the inability of the government to push through meaningful structural reform on a regional level, the Monnet Plan is widely judged not to have properly addressed agriculture as an activité de base.75 The difficulties in reducing output due to political resistance derailed many of the efforts to reduce the area under vine in France as a whole, with Warner stressing the importance of the ‘alcohol lobby’ and its “immense” influence over the press.76 This lobby intensified traditional attitudes, wherein an ambiguous attitude to the state was prevalent, and thereby welcoming state promotion of economic or social progress but offering bitter criticism of its failures.77 Recognition of this attitude seemed to tie the government to constant recapitulation of palliative regulatory measures, frequently missing the opportunity for decisive change in regional structural problems. This climate of regulatory control necessitated constant investment by the government to maintain unviable agricultural ventures, as they struggled to modernise their methods to meet changing market demands. The climate of European integration offered many boons to the French government in the postwar period,78 but gains for the industrial sector did little to quell the problems created for vignerons by the 73 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p193 Dubos, ‘Les Mutations de la Viticulture Française Contemporaine’, p86 75 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p214 76 ibid p215 77 Holmes; Fawcett, The Contemporary French Economy, p33 78 Lynch, ‘Resolving the Paradox of the Monnet Plan’, p242 74 24 opening up of markets across Europe. This was concurrent with the Monnet Plan’s objective of managing the relation of the French economy to the international system, but was not effective for stimulating regional reform. As such, the structural problems of the Midi wine industry faced “une durable stagnation”79 during the period of the Fourth Republic, despite tangible efforts for reform. These challenges only served to further mire the region in its cyclical boom and bust economy and increase the structural dependence of the industry on government intervention. Thus, it is necessary to examine the local power structures which constituted the strongest conglomeration of viticultural interests designed to protect the monocultural regional economy. The failure of the government to exact meaningful development in the world of the winegrower was, in part, due to their conception of the path to postwar recovery. By focussing on economic planning and state intervention, the government’s ability to alter regional issues was diminished by planning on a national level, alienating regional political elites without fully including them in the modernisation drive. The influence of local elites was to be central in the postwar regional viticultural economy, wherein regional successes could have become the building blocks of national prosperity. 79 R. Pech, Enterprise Viticole et Capitalisme en Languedoc-Roussillon: du Phylloxera aux crises de mévente (Toulouse, 1975) p411 25 Chapter 2: Local Power Structures and the Rise of the Cooperative Within a region as obstinately autonomous as the Midi, local power structures exert a large degree of influence over resident political structure. The centrality of the vine to life in the region empowered the voice of viticultural elites within these local power structures, mandating a focus on issues affecting the value of and market for wine. The importance of the cooperative movement as the regional economy’s main productive force is hard to exaggerate. As the birthplace of the cooperative venture, the Midi shares a special bond with its structure, as well as a preponderance of their occurrence. By articulating notions of regional autonomy, left-wing ideology and militarism the cooperative structure can be seen to act as a conceptual locus within which it is possible to examine the politics and power structures of the Midi. Structures Affecting Value The economic performance of the wine industry has been perennially tied to the concept of a strong product/area bond80, and this was enforced in a regulatory manner with the introduction of the A.O.C. system in the 1920s and 30s. The flaws of the A.O.C. system lie largely in its development, whilst originally seen to strengthen the industry, there is growing recognition that there must be changes “au système dirigeant viticole.”81 In a modern sense, the A.O.C. system is widely criticised as it has grown to become 80 81 G. Robinson, Geographies of Agriculture, (London, 2004) p87 Interview with Alain Trille, Château des Batilles, 04/08/06 26 restrictively complex and is seen to hamper export82, although in the period of the Fourth Republic there were substantially few classifications. The need for the existence of the system stems partially from the concerns of the growers themselves. Fraud, or the perception of it, constitutes one of the principal triggers of agricultural protest, as shown in the 1907 wine crisis83, and the struggle against it remains a maxim of protest organisations today. The complexity and the appeal of the A.O.C. system lie in the fact that the qualities it controls “cross time and space and are anchored in a specific place and history.”84 In this sense, Von Thüren’s classical rent theory allies itself to an analysis of France’s post-war agricultural climate, explaining the link between terroire and brand. Von Thüren’s equation calculates the value of land, and thereby distinguishes its rent value by considering environmental variables, notably: land rent; yield per unit of land; production expenses per unit of land; market price per unit of commodity; freight rate; and distance to market.85 This theory was originally applied to nineteenth century German property, but its analytical approach remains valid in the context of determining the spatial importance of vineyards in France, especially during a period of difficulty for the economy which rendered analysis largely analogous to that of earlier markets. In the post-war period of rebuilding, in which many free-market tendencies were sacrificed in favour of stability (with the introduction of such measures as price-fixing and rationing), the proto-capitalist rent model is strongly evident in the system of appellations, which 82 Interview with Edouard Raymond, Domaines Lacassagne, 03/08/06 W. Lem, Cultivating Dissent (New York, 1999) p57 84 L. Bérard; P. Marchenay, ‘A Market Culture’ in S. Blowen et al. (ed.), Recollections of France, (Oxford, 2000) p154 85 W. Moran, ‘The Wine Appellation as territory in France and California’, Annals of the association of American Geographers, vol.83 no.4 (1993) p695 83 27 saw a further upgrading in the Languedoc region during the post-war period, dominated by the creation of A.C. Fitou in 1948.86 Terroire distinctions, made plain with the institution of hierarchical appellation systems, became a major force in differentiating the “isotropic space”87 of Von Thüren’s model, influencing all factors of his economic equation. This wide-ranging influence was made possible by the fact that A.O.C.’s superseded mere sectorial territoriality, moving beyond the basic “rent-distance relationships”88 which dominated “crude and unarticulated”89 agricultural models, and encompassed non-territorial restrictions governing production methods, thus affecting almost every aspect of its market performance. Best placed to manipulate the restrictions of the AOC system, the ‘artisan spirit’ of the vignerons is fiercely declaimed as exclusive by independent producers themselves.90 Indeed, independents are often characterised as the romantic stereotype of the vignerons by outsiders, perpetuating the belief that “le vin n’est pas une boisson industrielle.”91 Although possessing a “shared occupational identity”92, the distinction between the independent grower and the cooperative is significant. As a rule of thumb cooperative endeavours represent a collectivised agrico-industrial process, whereas independent producers represent the AOC system in action, developing and building individual brands within the wine world. As such, the status of an independent cultivator served as an aspirational position, representing the goal for many cultivators involved in 86 H. Johnson; J. Robinson, The World Atlas of Wine, (London, 2005) p140 W. Moran, ‘The Wine Appellation as territory in France and California’, Annals of the association of American Geographers, vol.83 no.4 (1993) p695 88 W.L. Garrison; D.F. Marble, ‘The Spatial structure of agricultural activities’, Annals of the association of American Geographers, vol. 47, no.2 (Jun, 1957) p138 89 ibid p138 90 Interview with Edouard Raymond, Domaines Lacassagne, 03/08/06 91 R. Badouin, ‘L’Économie Viticole au temps des incertitudes’, Revue D’Économie Méridionale, Vol.42, No.168 (April, 1994) p11 92 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p33 87 28 other collective structures. The number of independent growers is accordingly vastly smaller than those involved in collective ventures, representing a higher echelon of status which Lem estimates to represent a mere 7% of Midi growers.93 In this sense, it is possible to view some independent producers as a minority of successful individuals, many of whom have a past in the largely preponderate cooperative production.94 The political voice of the independent small-holder, therefore, tended to be dominated by the concerns of the cooperatives, which represented a unity of expression from a significant amount of regional workers. Importance of the Cooperatives to the Regional Economy The unity provided by cooperative organisations of vignerons offers a largely chequered significance. They are widely acknowledged to have failed to enrich the solidarity of the communities within which they operate, whilst promoting stagnation in terms of quality.95 Nevertheless, they serve an important function in allowing smallholders, otherwise unable to afford the means of production, to operate in a financially viable manner.96 Modern vignerons tend to acknowledge the rationale behind the long standing cooperative tradition although they are cognizant of the fact that, in terms of over-production and poor quality, they represent part of the problem rather than part of the solution.97 The rise to prominence of cooperative structures informs much of what has become negative about the movement, with its roots a major factor in colouring the viewpoint of adherents. 93 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p114 ibid p210 95 Interview with Edouard Raymond, Domaines Lacassagne, 03/08/06 96 ibid 97 Interview with Edouard Raymond, Domaines Lacassagne, 03/08/06 94 29 Cooperatives enjoyed a rapid growth in popularity throughout the early half of the twentieth century, especially in the period between the two later crises de mévente in 1936 and 1951. The rise was purported to have been fuelled by a combination of the Popular Front’s encouragement of collectivist endeavours (1936 – 1938) and a parochial sense of one-upmanship which set the foundation of cooperatives on a similar footing to the frenzied erection of churches witnessed in the thirteenth century, as rural villages sought to heighten their regional importance.98 Indeed, Sagnès highlights the degree to which competition between villages in the South has been a perpetual bone of contention, referring to them as “maison serrées”, and the extent to which “le développement de la vigne a accentué des tendences fort anciennes”99 These cyclical instances of communal self assertion are built into the structure of rural society, with local elites playing “un rôle clef”100 in encouraging regional mobilisation. From a governmental perspective, the encouragement of cooperative enterprise, especially within the framework of the A.O.C. system, constituted an effective means of mobilising cross sections of the countryside in a cohesive fashion.101 Concurrently, the rise of cooperatives was augmented by the trend of land reparcelling which accompanied the breaking up of large estates, as many agricultural labourers began to inherit small pieces of land attributable to the “decline of former bourgeois proprietors.”102 This created a new class of small-holder who increasingly looked to cooperative ventures to enable the viable economic operation of L. Temple, J. Touzard, F. Jarrige, ‘La Restructuration des coopératives vinicoles en LanguedocRoussillon : du modèle communal à la diversité des adaptions actuelles’, REM vol.44 no.176 (4/1996) p76 99 J. Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique et Syndicale dans les Campagnes Viticoles du Midi’, La Diffusion des Idées Progressistes dans le Monde Rural de la Révolution au XX e Siècle. Actes du colloque de Châteauroux 1998 (Châteauroux, 2000) p1 100 O. Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, Journée d’études AFSP/Groupe Local et politique, IEP de Rennes – 8 février 2002 p3 101 M. Demossier, ‘Culinary Heritage and Produits de Terroir in France’ in S. Blowen et al. (ed.), Recollections of France, (Oxford, 2000) p148 102 L. Loubère, The Vine Remembers, (New York, 1985) p34 98 30 their land. Strangely, this trend took place against the tide in other countries, which saw smaller land units being reparcelled into larger estates, as with the German flubereinigung in the 1950s103. This difference can be largely attributed to the distortive level of monoculture in the Languedoc-Roussillon, and the umbrella structure of cooperatives which drew small-holders towards collectivisation. The fragility of the agricultural market in an area dominated by monoculture had been demonstrated clearly by the cyclical wine crises, shepherding many towards the greater security offered by cooperatives which, by virtue of their independent marketing, could shelter adherents from market forces with collective capital, stabilizing inter-annual price fluctuation.104 As the industry crept towards a glut of concentrated modernisation in the post-war period, the network of cooperative structures played an important supplementary role to the Crédit Agricole initiative in providing funds for mechanisation, allowing pooled purchase of new materials such as tractors and cuvéries.105 The availability of credit fed into the dominant cooperative structure and allowed for a degree of mechanisation to occur stemming from local impetus rather than outside pressure and further galvanising regional solidarity. Indeed, cooperatives represented not only an opportunity for collective purchasing power but also “constituent la base d‘un lobby régional capable de négocier une politique favorable à la stabilisation du marché national de vin de table.”106 Importantly, the emphasis of this analysis is on the stability of the market rather than development, highlighting the extent to which the organisations were geared towards the perpetuation of influence as opposed to genuinely adding value to the market. 103 C. Fielden, Exploring Wines & Spirits (W.S.E.T Advanced. Textbook), (London, 2001) p158 Temple, Touzard, Jarrige, ‘La Restructuration des coopératives vinicoles…’ p77 105 ibid p77 106 Y. Chiffoleau et al., ‘Qualité et Solidarité dans les Coopératives Viticoles’ in J. Touzard (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation, (Paris, 2003) p293 104 31 Cooperatives and Regional Politics The dualistic and contentious role served by Cooperatives in the development of the identity of the industry can be thematically linked to the ideological development of “l’agrarisme viticole de gauche.”107 The cooperative enthusiasm exhibited in the Langudeoc-Roussillon region rooted itself in the traditional anti-clericalism extant amongst the “true rural proletariat”108, constituted by the mass of agricultural labourers centred around this traditional area of monoculture. What these links suggest, and indeed confirm, is the collectivist and socialist mindset which conceived of the first cooperative institutions at the turn of the century.109 Cooperatives have enjoyed almost unchecked development throughout the twentieth century, surviving sanction even during the reign of the Vichy regime, whose quasi-fanatical rural values saw peasant organisation as entirely “compatible with the corporatist state.”110 This example serves to highlight the fickle ideological underpinning of the collectivist initiative as it was taken to support often contradictory ideological goals by diametrically opposed governments such as the Popular Front and Vichy. The Cooperative trend developed, in the period leading up to the Fourth Republic, alongside the transformation of the Southern leftist movement into a tri-partite ‘rouge’ wing pursuing distinct goals by various means, constituted by and large by the Confédération Générale des Vignerons (CGV), the Parti Communiste Française (PCF) and the dynamic syndicalist movement. All three threads can be traced back to the J. Sagnès, ‘Viticulture et Politique dans la 1ere moitié du XXe siècle : aux origines du Statut de la Viticulture’ in J. Sagnès (ed.), La Viticulture Française aux XIXe et XXe siècles, (Béziers, 1993) p51 108 L. Loubère, The Vine Remembers, (New York, 1985) p54 109 Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique…’. p7 110 L. Loubère, The Wine Revolution in France (Princeton, 1990) p146 107 32 1907 ‘crise du vin’, with largely parallel lines of development, in which one can see social radicalism, labour unionism and “a nucleus of anarcho-syndicalism”111. Phrases like ‘anarcho-syndicalism’ can present lazy monikers for disparate movements, but in this instant it is intended to denote a vein of syndical particularism. Specifically, this was rooted in the strongly perceived notion of independence from national agricultural organisations, representing a “distinction plus marquée”112 from the cooperative movement by its autonomy and its militancy. This regional distinction suggests another principal reason behind the success of the cooperative structure, as it fed notions of regionalism in the South, devolving power towards increasingly local bases whilst fostering Midi solidarity. The ‘particularism’ of the syndicates is found, according to Sagnès, in the 1890s and the birth of truly leftist politics in the region, wherein socialism appealed to the peasantry in general whilst syndicalism spoke to “journaliers agricoles.”113 It was with these agricultural labourers and campaigns in the countryside that syndicalists made their best gains at the start of the twentieth century, more so than in urban centres.114 This factor preserved the independence of the Midi syndicalists, as their early successes in the South amongst principally agricultural workers characterised the movement as one which owed its roots to the vine. The “puissants syndicats”115 therefore represented a regional base of strength for national left wing organisations, whose importance grew in the postwar period. 111 L. Loubère, The Vine Remembers, (New York, 1985) pp43-44 R. Mauget; S. Koulytchizky, ‘Un siècle de développement des coopératives agricoles en France’ in J. Touzard (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation, (Paris, 2003) p58 113 Sagnès, ‘La Gauche, p5 114 ibid p6 115 P. Gachon, Histoire de Languedoc, (Paris, 1926) p271 112 33 The Second World War had, in turn, galvanised the structure of many militant leftist parties whilst imbuing in many people a genuine desire for change. Worries that France might turn “communistic”116 seemed well-founded in the immediate aftermath of the Liberation, as the men of the Resistance found themselves increasingly incorporated in the political sphere, especially in the South. This desire for change was represented in a fervour which gripped the region as immediately as 1944, with government advisory bodies warning of “a surge of violent opinion in the Midi.”117 To a large extent, the integration of leftist parties into the political sphere meant a greater representation for the working class population of the region, which in the Midi saw viticultural demands well represented amongst this surge of opinion. Indeed, political organisations, even as far back as the 1907 revolt, can be seen to have represented the social unity of the independent growers and the agricultural labourers.118 The expansion of these representative political organs was indicative of the interminable slide towards economic marginality faced by the precariously monocultural local economy in a century of rapid modernisation. Traditions of rural protest thus developed as the wine industry struggled to keep pace with an increasingly capitalist market, the distinction between industrial worker and vine worker being that whereas “workers go on strike… farmers demonstrate and protest.”119 This can be exemplified by the non payment of taxes in 1946 in response to government measures, the political unrest of 1951 as leftist Deputies protested government policy and the violent mass protests which took place after the wine crisis of J.F. Bell, ‘Problems of Economic Reconstruction in France’, Economic Geography, Vol.22, No. 1 (January, 1946) p54 117 C.K. Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government since 1875, (New York, 1960) p164 118 J.H. Smith, ‘Agricultural Workers and the French Wine-Growers' Revolt of 1907’, Past and Present, no.79 (1978) p103 119 Lem, Cultivating Dissent p90 116 34 1953. This normalisation of protest informed a process wherein the determinants of future struggle were commonly located in the political inferences of historical demonstrations, creating a positive feedback loop in which protest became a selfsustaining aspect of regional political currency, celebrating the distinction of local identity from national or Parisian identity. This phenomenon was fostered by the institutionalisation of vested interests which occurred via the enshrinement of local elites in the process of communicating local grievances. There is a popular recognition of this incorporation of viticultural actors into local politics, with a realisation that “by institutional thickness, [one] really means the wine cooperative system.”120 As such there was a degree of regime building, consisting of a nexus of local interests as viticultural elites “articulated, prioritized and formalized local responses to global (including supranational) regulatory pressures.”121 In this context, local power bases largely took their character from constituent members, creating “new power constellations”122 by virtue of the alignment of common interests. These power bases in the Midi, informed by the preponderance of viticultural interests, meant that the character of ‘rural regimes’ reflected the repeatable cultural characteristics of the region. Concrete institutional bases sprang up with the progressive and dynamic development of grass-roots level administration in the post-war period. This enshrinement of the “élus du vin” in the political setup was resultant of the confluence of interests which governs the A. Jones; J. Clark, ‘Of Vines and Policy Vignettes: Sectoral Evolution and Institutional Thickness in the Languedoc’, Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, New Series, vol.25, no.3 (2000) p335 121 Jones; Clark, ‘Of Vines and Policy Vignettes’, p335 122 ibid p333 120 35 monocultural area and perpetuated by “la posture tribunicienne” adopted by establishment members during times of viticultural crisis.123 These structural factors meant that concrete local political institutions became bridged by a cultural consensus, as the character of the institutions outlived individual actors. There was, therefore, a situation of continuity in the regional level of political power as “long established political elites” associated their authority “with emergent economic and cultural forces… to ensure the continued hegemony… in the face of relatively turbulent socio-economic environments.”124 This dynamic self-preservation adapted well to a situation of regional self-assertion, as it controlled the mechanism of authority with which to strengthen and refocus local consensus institutions, in direct response to extra-local concrete institutions.125 However, the situation became problematic during the postwar period as the restructuring of agriculture required by the Monnet plan implied distinct changes in levels of production and the organisation of productive forces. ‘Rural regimes’ responded poorly to efforts to restructure local institutions from outwith, as the important role of consensus institutions within local power structures meant that any drastic change would have to result from a reconfiguration of the viticultural constituency. The mutually compatible objectives of the viticultural elite and their constituency (regarding price, production levels, taxes and regulation) meant that external pressure for change was unlikely to alter regional core concerns. Vignerons offered a mutual resistance to the terms imposed by the national plan for modernisation, and using consensus cultural O. Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, Journée d’études AFSP/Groupe Local et politique, IEP de Rennes – 8 février 2002 p1 124 Jones; Clark, ‘Of Vines and Policy Vignettes’, p336 125 Jones; Clark, ‘Of Vines and Policy Vignettes’, p336 123 36 dominance equated this modernisation with a challenge to their culture and identity. As such, the government failed to significantly alter the status quo within the Midi during the period of the Fourth Republic as it failed to engage adequately with ‘rural regimes’. Whilst the government pursued national economic development on the road to recovery, the Midi vignerons were reaffirming a cycle of self interest which was incompatible with national goals, their interests focussed on a rejection of modernisation. The persistence of the representation of vignerons in the local elite is part of a cycle which affirms both their product and their culture: wine, as a product, offers an identifier of specific regional identity whilst seeing reciprocal administrative protection from those who seek to preserve this identity. This heritage is one which evolved in thrall to local elites intent on “emblematising” their culture.126 By singling the Midi out culturally as an area reliant on the poignant collective memories of the vignerons, the mass movements of 1907 and thereafter became their cultural emblems. As such, the legacy of political protest became enshrined in cultural values and contributed to a wider normalisation of protest. Rural society remained governed by “des hiérarchisations sociale qui articulent les perceptions de chacun”127 , in the interest of exercising their cultural relevancy. Although the negative interpretation of regional southern administrative institutions would term them “corporatist hierarchies”128, one can see the self-preservation of these rural elites as a form of cultural currency. As the most vocal proponents of regional identity, local elites sustained the importance of regional issues by M. Demossier, ‘Culinary Heritage and Produits de Terroir in France’ in S. Blowen (et al.)(ed.), Recollections of France, (Oxford, 2000) p148 127 F. Bort, ‘Du Rouge aux Terroirs’ in J. Touzard (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation, (Paris, 2003) p95 128 J. Loughlin, ‘"Europe of the Regions" and the Federalization of Europe’, Publius, vol.26, no.4, (1996) p141 126 37 maintaining their position, serving as a legitimate mainstream reminder of issues which persisted outside the realm of political due process. The Politics of Identity In terms of post-war recovery, the economic restructuring of the viticultural industry promised a restatement of one of the nation’s core social identifiers, whilst simultaneously emphasising the greater importance of wine to regional than national identity.129 Promotion of this ‘heritage’ was largely propounded by a multitude of social actors, comprising local viticultural elites, the most vocal and effective of which were the producers themselves.130 As such, it is important to consider the actions of the Languedoc vignerons, in their social context, as indicative of a widening dissatisfaction with governmental influence and a development of the “sense of communal identity”131 which stemmed from collective action. Indeed, this trend was one which had gathered pace much earlier, with the social eruption of the 1907 ‘crise du vin’, which served as a point of reference in the early 1950s for those on the left looking for a rebalancing of the economic infrastructure. Such a rebalancing was widely seen to be a positive step, despite the debt that it owed to the old Statut Viticole, focussing on a lowering of the compulsory blockage and distilling introduced to tackle the troublesome 1951 harvest. In this vein, Communist representatives serving on the government’s Commission des Boissons, called for a return to the Statut in the summer of 1952, emphasising the “social 129 Interview with Raymond Laporte, Domaine Laporte, 03/08/06 L. Bérard; P. Marchenay, ‘A Market Culture’ in S. Blowen (et al.)(ed.), Recollections of France, (Oxford, 2000) p162 131 Jones; Clark, ‘Of Vines and Policy Vignettes’, p341 130 38 character” of the old order with its roots in the “spirit of 1907.”132 Furthermore, Communists suggested that surplus wines should be distributed to the poor rather than face distillation, although this idea received little serious support as it involved the introduction of free wine into an already saturated market, further increasing consumption whilst doing little for the health of the industry.133 The idea of returning to such a pre-war institution lent the viticultural industry a veil of continuity, belying the interruption of the Second World War and highlighting the institutional heritage of the industry. Such an underpinning of the economy to collective notions of identity is concurrent with Keynes’ concept of “animal spirits”134, illustrating the shifting of mood within a country that can so radically alter economic progress. This alteration was not tied to an upsurge in the wine industry, but arose rather as a result of the developing crisis that saw wine prices plummet amidst constant over-production. It was this shift in the ‘mood’ of the industry, which saw the 1953 Code du vin usher in a “general sentiment of relief”135 amongst the vignerons, as it finally seemed that the decline of the industry had been halted with a restatement of traditionalist values. The profusion of cooperative structures meant that traditional concepts of communal cooperation were thoroughly ingrained in the regional system, perpetuating themselves as the surest means for small producers to operate. The people of the Midi’s proclivity to congregate led to an explosion of cooperatives, creating repertoires of capital and influence amongst viticultural elites. These elites became increasingly important after the Second World War both due to the traditional popularity of the Left in 132 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p179 Journal officiel de la république française. Débats de l’Assemblée nationale, 1952, pp.3569-70 134 J.M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, (Cambridge, 1936) p161 135 Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government, p188 133 39 the Midi, and the extent to which radical Leftists had been rehabilitated by their role in the War. These viticultural elites closed ranks to advance a cultural redefinition in response to the challenges faced in recovering from collaboration. The invigorated regional identity they proposed bridged the gaps perceived in local concrete political institutions by cultivating cultural consensus amongst a region determined to restate its identity. The centrality of regionalism to this identity led to a fostering of resistance against perceived outside pressure, in favour of the continuity implied by ‘invented tradition’. In understanding the structures with which the voice of the Midi became articulated, it is necessary to analyse the extent to which the local population presented coherent demands. In the following chapter I will move on to further explore the processes by which specific challenges to identity resulted in a widespread rejection of contemporary plans for modernisation. 40 Chapter 3: Tending Vines and Picket Lines: The People of The Midi The people of the Midi are, in reality, the most important consideration when investigating the effects of post-war reconstruction efforts, as it was with them that efforts for renewal stood or fell. In studying their role in the performance of the postwar wine industry, there are two clear factors to consider: their reactions to modernisation by varied forms of resistance and assertions of regional identity; along with the shift from regional self-assertion to anti-Americanism, placing the question of modernisation in a wider context. Within these factors I will distinguish several thematic threads which help delineate a greater understanding of events and their legacy to the contemporary industry. The revolt against change pursued by the vignerons can be viewed as a form of political populism, but one which stemmed from the rather more complex origins of the mythical ‘Midi Rouge’; a myth which one sees repeated confirmation of, in terms of a concentration of left-wing support amongst wide tracts of people. Indeed, this left-wing prominence and the important legacy of Second World War resistance strengthened the voice of the productive class, itself preponderant in the vastly agricultural area. As such, cultural tendencies and traditions which relied on mass intransigence were party to intensification during a period of uncertainty in the Midi, especially with the visible involvement of outside actors. America’s role in French plans for postwar recovery filled many Frenchmen with suspicion, especially in the Midi, where the new Coca-cola bottling plant in Marseilles seemed like an American outpost in the heart of the wine lands. These factors were set against a decline in the bonds between traditional 41 communities, influenced by the modernisation drive, and creating a need for greater regional self-assertion both politically and culturally. Identity Collapse and Attempts to Reprise the Community The post-war period was harried by the “Devil of Declining Growth”, as the population yet again fell after decades of repetitive stagnation, albeit with the Second World War occasioning a smaller loss than the First.136 The decline of communities presented one of the most profound and damaging blows to the regional population137, as the decline of traditional regional identity (centered around community, religion and agriculture) left many people isolated in the wake of attempts to modernise. An increasing standard of living, denoted in the age of American economic dominance by the increasing possession of televisions, refrigerators and cars, eroded traditional communities by removing the necessity for interaction. The average person in France became increasingly exposed to these luxury goods through the press, radio and cinema as expectations were subtly aligned with a more consumptive culture associated with the American capitalist model.138 However, a seeming decline in traditional communal identity was met with the emergence of “invented tradition.”139 This constituted a restatement of perceived traditional communal values, for example the neighbourliness of villages. This facilitated the creation of an underground labour market amongst viticultural labours at village level focussing on neighbourly interaction. Increasingly, this informal economy flourished during periods like the harvest as villagers exchanged J.J. Spengler, ‘Population: Notes on France’s Response to her Declining Rate of Growth’, Journal of Economic History, Vol.11, No.4 (Autumn, 1951) p403 137 Interview with Alain Trille, Château des Batilles, 04/08/06 138 G.M. Holmes; P.D. Fawcett, The Contemporary French Economy (London, 1983) p25 139 W. Lem, Cultivating Dissent (New York, 1999) p166 136 42 labour in a casual sense in an effort to avoid state taxation.140 This informal labour market depicts the extent to which ‘invented tradition’ became the means of operating within, but latently resisting, a modern capitalist economy. The reinvigoration of traditional values became part of a political and economic strategy designed to enact resistance to the dominance of the regional market by outside forces.141 Thus, by presenting an air of continuity, it was possible to reconstitute regional identity centred on a new purpose. In this way, political identity became a crutch for the increasingly enfeebled traditional cultural identity of the South, augmenting traditional myths of the ‘Midi Rouge’. However, these positive assertions of regional identity constituted manifestations of opposition to supra-regional pressure and described by Lem as resisting the terms of the national “modernity project.”142 Thus, new cultural touchstones were mired in the necessity of perpetual opposition as a key factor of self-definition. Accordingly, Keiger asserts that “in the twentieth century the Anglo-Saxons enabled the French nation to continue to define itself and added further cement to its nation building.”143 However, in the South, with the decline of regional identity at a peak, negative self definition moved beyond what can be considered the ideal, miring the reactionary concept of identity in the realm of fractious regionalism rather than the “sense of nationhood”144 admired by Jules Michelet. Specifically, cultural identity became inextricably tied to the “spirit of 1907”145, which increasingly represented the episode in which “the energy of a whole generation… [had come]… to a head in a long fine flash.”146 To the militant vignerons 140 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p181 ibid p195 142 ibid p11 143 J.F.V. Keiger, 'France and the World' (London 2001) p161 144 ibid p160 145 C.K. Warner, The Winegrowers of France and the Government since 1875, (New York, 1960) p179 146 H. S. Thompson, Fear and Loathing in Las Vegas, (London, 1993) p 67 141 43 “1907 then is our own history, our collective memory, a piece of the map of identity of each winegrower.”147 Indeed, one can imagine that atop the mountains around Tuchan, “with the right kind of eyes you can almost see the high water-mark – that place where the wave finally broke and rolled back”148 colouring the expectations of what could be extracted from the government, and demonstrating the underlying regional solidarity which could be found therein. Attempts to use the memory of 1907 accordingly took on many forms, passing into the cultural vocabulary of the Midi, most blatantly in the songs of protest sung from barricades at every crise with calls of “To arms, wine growers!”149 Identity became refocused on sustainable concepts as the twentieth century progressed, and moved away from declining features such as local festivals and regional dialect. A need to attach dwindling regional dialects to a restatement of cultural values meant that their practice became a sign of resistance to societal change in itself.150 In turn, regional festivals which survived, such as the Carnaval in Broussan, largely served to highlight local solidarity in the face of external pressure, embodied in the burning of effigies of political figures at these festivals.151 Such festivals were rooted in the centrality of the vine to the Midi, embodying not only the way of life but the spirit of the region.152 These acts of resistance constituted a concerted effort by sectors of society within the Midi, anxious to protect their communities from the effects of modernisation. Increasingly it was seen that “the new technology of entertainment has fragmented the community”, whilst the draw of urban centres lured the young away from rural ‘Comité Régionale d’Action Viticole Manifesto’ quoted by W. Lem, Cultivating Dissent (New York, 1999) p77 148 Thompson, Fear and Loathing, p68 149 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p45 150 L. Loubère, The Vine Remembers, (New York, 1985) pp.39-40 151 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p94 152 Interview with Alain Trille, Château des Batilles, 04/08/06 147 44 villages.153 Additionally, mechanisation meant that work in the fields became less labour intensive, displacing agricultural labourers from traditional communities. Between 1948 and 1963 French agriculture as a whole witnessed its greatest increase in the use of tractors.154 Etienne Hirsch, a colleague of Monnet in the Planning Commissariat, is quoted as commenting that “a farmer driving a tractor will no longer think like a farmer following a horse.”155 Although this approach can be held to largely symbolise the government’s hopes for the success of its modernisation drive, it is not necessarily true. Hirsch’s mistake lay in failing to recognise that, at times, farmers followed horses by choice. For many the choice was not “modernisation or decadence”156 but simply the means of survival. Modernisations as a concept involved moving away from the past, and those left behind seldom welcomed their redundancy. As ever, the post-war modernisation drive produced its own share of ‘losers’, amongst those unwilling or unable to keep up with the march of progress who, in turn, vocally equated this with the “sacrificing of individual independence to progress.”157 The downturn which had mired the agricultural (and especially viticultural) industry in such dire straits forced many to reduce expenditure in an increasingly demanding marketplace. Such reductions fostered a fondness for concepts of “primordiality”158 and traditional values, as the capitalist marketplace eroded traditional rural bonds and set some vignerons to the task of restoring the old order. 153 Loubère, The Vine Remembers, p77 G.M. Holmes; P.D. Fawcett, The Contemporary French Economy (London, 1983) p73 155 J. Monnet, Memoirs (Glasgow, 1976) p259 156 ibid p259 157 S. Fitzgerald, ‘The Anti-Modern Rhetoric of Le Mouvement Poujade’, Review of Politics, vol.32, no.2 (1970) p190 158 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p166 154 45 Two factors here presented the greatest obstacles to the true development of the post-war wine industry: the inability of producers to finance modernisation and the unwillingness of many to sacrifice regional identity upon the altar of modernisation. A similarity may be drawn here between the protest organisations created by wine producers, such as the Comité régional d'action viticole (C.R.A.V.), and the later ‘Poujadist’ movement of small shopkeepers which arose in 1956, headed by the Union de Défense des Commerçants et Artisans. Both movements share similar themes in their opposition to the marginalisation of regional economies in the seeming progressive inevitability of Parisian economic dominance as well as the long term transformation of the market towards a more Anglo-American capitalist model. Both movements have likewise become synonymous with an aversion to change and propagation of rural sentimentality. The ‘Poujadist’ movement, however, gained greater prominence by its diversification of relevance, whereas viticultural movements remained largely esoteric; thus, the survival of the Poujadist movement as a political force into the Fifth Republic became eased as they encompassed a rural value-set, whereas the viticultural organisations remained a firmly single-issue group, limiting their potency outwith the political instability of the Fourth Republic.159 Trends of Modernisation The traditional development model of ‘Paris and the French Desert’, originally propounded by M.J.F Gravier in 1947, is largely unhelpful in studying both the post-war period and the Languedoc-Roussillon region, as a result of the fluid nature of reform which was sweeping the country. The timing of the report renders it largely irrelevant due 159 Fitzgerald, ‘The Anti-Modern Rhetoric of Le Mouvement Poujade’, p167 46 to governmental initiatives taken in the following years, which sought to tackle the problem of unequal development which constituted a symptom of rapid post-war recovery, as resources were focussed on specific problem industries.160 Whilst Paris represented the most distinct pole of growth, the distortive influence of its economic power affected industry rather more so than agriculture, although there did develop a trend for young people to “monter à Paris.”161 Such economic models rely largely on the notion of agricultural communities as the domain of a backwards peasantry, mired in structural frailty. However, vignerons conform poorly to the simplistic definitions of peasantry, integrated as they are into the market and forced to fulfil multiple roles, especially in the Languedoc-Roussillon with the proximity of Marseille and Toulouse to agricultural centres.162 What this argument moves to dispel is not the existence of a shift away from the countryside as a general trend, but the simplicity of the town-country model in diagnosing this trend. The vignerons themselves represented a group “fort liée aux villes et menant de plus en plus une vie de type urbain.”163 In itself, it is likewise inadequate to equate a trend of modernisation with a trend of urbanisation, concurrent though they may be at times.164 The traditional model of the rural exodus is not a permanent one, and what we can discern is that population shift marks not merely an interminable slide towards city life but a cyclical pattern of migration that is dictated as much by economic and social factors as by broader demographic trends. Indeed, 1954 does represent the M.C. Maclennan, ‘Regional Planning in France’, Journal of Industrial Economics, vol.13 (1965) p62 J. Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique et Syndicale dans les Campagnes Viticoles du Midi (1848-1939)’, La Diffusion des Idées Progressistes dans le Monde Rural de la Révolution au XX e Siècle. Actes du Colloque de Châteauroux, (Châteauroux, 2000) p14n24 162 E. Font, ‘Un Schéma d’Evolution Démographique pour les Communes Rurales’, REM, vol.42, no.165166 ( January & February 1994) p47 163 G. Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon (Montpellier, 1960) vol.2 p132 164 Font, ‘Un Schéma d’Evolution Démographique pour les Communes Rurales’, p46 160 161 47 beginning of a rural exodus which, however, stabilised from 1962 to 1975 and triggered a repopulation from that point.165 This presents a somewhat confusing trend, agricultural employment having fallen 32.4% between 1962 to 1975166, but one which highlights the extent to which those in the Midi developed their long history of pluriactivity (engaging in non-agricultural income sources), with the number of households involved rising from 15% in 1956 to 42% in 1988.167 Increased reliance on pluriactivity, combined with government initiatives to encourage polyculture with irrigation programs, created a situation which defied traditional notions of an agricultural peasantry, inherent in the maintenance of simplistic models of a dialectic shift towards urbanisation. Indeed, resistance to external policies, focussed largely on simplistic models of Parisian economic dominance, saw markedly reduced success compared to those focussed on specific regional issues espoused by, or in partnership with, local institutions such as the Rhone Valley Irrigation Project. In presenting resistance to centralised modernisation programs, vignerons were not pursuing retrograde notions of the pastoral idyll but seeking a different path from the generally accepted notions of liberal capitalism which informed economic policy. This “counter-tendency to urbanisation”168 was linked to the land, and a celebration of customary traditions and character in the face of the economic and social future promulgated from above. Such resistance became important in the restatement of regional identity, as it represented a pole of growth for the identity of the Midi vignerons, drawing together a traditionally left wing populace and those eager to affirm their independence from Paris. 165 ibid p35 Ministère de l’Agriculture, L’Emploi et les Activités en Milieu Rural (Paris, 1981) p38 167 G. Robinson, Geographies of Agriculture, (London, 2004) p137 168 M. Demossier, ‘Culinary Heritage and Produits de Terroir in France’ in S. Blowen (et al.)(ed.), Recollections of France, (Oxford, 2000) p144 166 48 The Politicisation of a Culture of Protest Thus, sustainable and repeatable regional characteristics became a desirable touchstone for a fading historical identity. Opposition to centralisation and Parisian influence presented those of the Midi with a chance to restate regional identity by virtue of its distinctness from Paris. With this desire, instances of communal self assertion became the cultural currency of the regional population, as they looked to examples of combatative self-assertion to provide historical rallying points. Indeed, it is in the nature of protest that regionalism largely exists as a cultural construct, for example in the Languedoc with the profusion of Occitan symbolism and historical references during mass protests. The C.R.A.V. represents a militant group of winemakers which is largely covert in nature; it has existed in some form or another since the riots of 1907 and is seen as strongly representing the interests of the vignerons of the Midi, often with what could be termed terrorist attacks. Support for the C.R.A.V. is diffuse and often tacit due to their means, but graffiti still lines many bridges and walls around Béziers in support of the group. The C.R.A.V. frequently fly the red banner of Occitania when protesting169, as a means of mobilising distinct local dissatisfaction with external government. Demossier points out the extent to which this is a natural situation, casting producers of regional “produits de terroir” as the natural guardians and exponents of “their provincial roots.”170 Expressions of Occitan identity have thus become “politically charged with the sentiments of opposition, resistance, and challenge to exploitation and domination by the 169 170 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p91 Demossier, ‘Culinary Heritage and Produits de Terroir in France’, p144 49 state”.171 Sagnès points to a Revolutionary heritage as one of the principal determinants of a culture of popular politics which so often resorted to protest.172 In this vein, the relevance of the 1907 crisis in informing contemporary struggle is made plain in the 1947 Parti Communiste Française (P.C.F.) commemoration of the revolt, celebrating “l’esprit de lutte paysanne.”173 After all, in the eyes of those most intent on maintaining Midi culture, it was “le pays de révoltes, de Montmorency des hommes de 1848, des hommes de 1851, des hommes de 1871, des révoltes de 1907, des maquisards de 40-45... "174 By focusing on traditional notions of protest, it became possible to emblematize local culture and inherently politicize subscribers whilst focusing on continuity. Protest against modernization, therefore, became a way of fighting for the past. The violence and ferocity of protest can be explained by the corrosion of character brought about by a shift towards insecure, non-tenured labour.175 This trend, exacerbated by the difficulties in the post-war agricultural economy, represented traditional friction between small-producers in the regional peripheries of France and the state. The Midi vignerons were cast as the victims of modernisation as the government pursued what seemed to be a Malthusian and teleological set of structural reforms designed to offer the brightest future to those in tune with the institutional vision.176 As such, protest became characterised by the refusal of these actors to integrate fully with a system which they railed against, promoting a vein of collective action which occurred 171 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p91 Sagnès, ‘La Gauche Politique’, p2 173 ibid p13 n19 174 O. Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, Journée d’études AFSP/Groupe Local et politique, IEP de Rennes – 8 février 2002 p1 175 ‘Violent Night’, Thinking Allowed, BBC Radio 4 19/07/06 176 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p49 172 50 outside of political due process.177 This political externalism fed into the creation and sustenance of organisations like the C.R.A.V., as actions outwith the political spectrum took on increasingly surreptitious characteristics and an increasingly guerrilla structure. Violent acts could be used to express the feelings of these organisations during periods of pressure, when dialogue seemed at its most fruitless. This was demonstrated in the 1953 bombing of the local prefecture in Carcassonne by militant vignerons, who subsequently occupied the major highways of the Midi in protest to government reactions to the 1953 crisis.178 The same round of demonstrations led to the use of tear gas by police, as a response to being stoned by gangs of vignerons.179 This violence represents a continuing trend, as even in 2005 riots involving the CRAV resulted in €500,000 worth of damage.180 What this indicates is a normalised culture of protest within which the violence of groups motivated by a desire to represent regional will saw maintenance and tacit support. Traditional fears about the nature and direction of government policy were largely augmented by the role of American aid in the post-war restructuring of France. To traditional antagonist forces, the spectre of American involvement served to confirm the direction of government policy as France moved towards a rather more Anglo-Saxon model of haut capitalism. Instances of rural protest thus seem to share two concurrent themes: a rejection of a shift towards increasingly insecure employment and an outcry against the social alienation inflicted upon the vulnerable classes by economic stagnation. In this context, the Midi vignerons were not protesting against a single ministry or the 177 ibid p48 L. Loubère, The Wine Revolution in France (Princeton, 1990) p234 179 ‘Protest by Growers of Surplus Wine’, The Times 29/07/1953 p5 180 J. Anson, ‘Fruit Bombs’, Wine & Spirit, August 2006, p36 178 51 government in general, but “taking action as a highly motivated and sophisticated pressure group”181 in trying to force an institutional response to their specific grievances. Loubère describes this process as “demonstration democracy”182 and goes on to highlight the extent to which it represented a particular weapon of those in the Midi, an area with ten times more Trade Union activity than Bordeaux or the Champagne region since 1900.183 These themes see a marked recurrence and refocusing in the post-war Marshall Plan climate, as even some American observers feared the Plan was “an absurd attempt to graft our [American] type of free enterprise… onto a different business structure”184, resulting in the marginalisation of those already on the fringes of the post-war economy. For many Frenchmen, America offered little cultural worth whilst seeking to gain much in a material sense, its culture having been “massacred by the engineers and inventors.”185 Although Coca-cola and Hollywood represented vestiges of a crass consumerist society, American machines, machine-tools and industrial methods played an important role in rebuilding Europe. By adopting a technocratic structure, proponents of the Marshall Plan made modernisation throughout European industry and agriculture the ultimate goal of policy. However, there was a massive difference in terms of the application of these methods, and a quantifiable difference between a uniform 1,000 HA grain farm in Tennessee and a small parcel of vines in the Midi.186 This remoteness coloured the perceptions of Europeans by emphasising the differences in situation, whereas it only served to heighten the already lofty American conception of their own 181 Loubère, The Wine Revolution in France, p239 ibid p239 183 ibid p255 184 Galbraith to Kindleberger, October 25, 1946; Memoranda, 1946; State Department File; Charles P. Kindleberger Papers. p2 185 B. Grantham, Some Big Bourgeois Brothel, (Luton, 2000) p13 186 ‘Europe – Ruins to Recovery’, Archive Hour, BBC Radio 4, 23/09/06 182 52 actions. Republican solidarity was the watchword of America’s idealists, convinced that the Marshall Plan could represent repayment for early French intervention in the American Revolution with cries of: “Lafayette we are here!”187 In this sense, America’s self-professed magnanimity struck Frenchmen as patronising, as they recognised that France’s weakness transformed any integration with a greater power into domination. Differences in perception between nations heightened the difficulties of rebuilding states, as rapprochement between France and America proved forced at best. American sources fairly accurately surmised the challenges facing Europe in its post-war recovery as being multifaceted and largely long-term. With such a fresco of malaise, America was considered to have had a duty to help European powers recover their position, and yet it became apparent that such a climate of supra-national intervention could overshadow and jeopardise unifying local initiatives. The extent to which these societal rallying points began to focus on opposition to supra-regional pressures is critical, as it founded new conceptions of identity in the essentially negative definition of regionalism as a rival to national identity. The Resistance and the Rehabilitation of the Left The timing of this study is important as profound shocks were delivered to the French political system due to the immediate post-war reconstitution of administrative bodies which occurred in tandem with l’épuration. In the South, where the Maquis were especially active, the legacy of the Resistance had rehabilitated many left-wing militants 187 M. Hopkins, ‘For European Recovery’, URL= http://www.loc.gov/loc/lcib/970623/marshall.html 53 who had previously been stranded in the “socio-political ghetto”188 of extremism. The operations of these groups during the Occupation had similarly reinforced the revolutionary structures of organisations such as the C.R.A.V, which had existed as a sort of ad hoc chimera throughout the first half of the century. Communist activists, whatever their individual merits, emerged from the Second World War as “men who had not been sullied by collaboration with the national enemy.”189 The election of deportees in their absence, which occurred in the first municipal elections of 1945,190 meant that those Resistance fighters, arrested and deported for actions against the Vichy government, returned to a situation where they held political sway. ‘The Return’ was an event quickly effaced from the popular memory, as it was incompatible with the official myth of the Liberation. Returning deportees “subverted the myth’s assertion of equal victimhood”191, creating a rift between the official stance and the impression amongst regional populations of the role of the internal resistance, spearheaded by the political left. Thus, we see a greater sympathy, especially in traditional leftist strongholds such as the Midi, for Leftist causes after the Liberation, largely representing the rehabilitation of erstwhile political radicals. Protesters against central government policy in reaction to the crisis of 1953 were accordingly led “by their mayors, their district councillors and in some cases by their Members of Parliament”.192 This demonstrates the extent of “le passage de la résistance à la haute fonction publique.”193 As well as local government structures, leftists were incumbent in many regional institutions, such as l’Institut d’Études I.M. Wall, ‘The French Communists and the Algerian War’, Journal of Contemporary History, 12 (1977) p.524 189 G.M. Holmes; P.D. Fawcett, The Contemporary French Economy (London, 1983) p214 190 M. Koreman, ‘A Hero’s Homecoming: The Return of the Deportees to France’, Journal of Contemporary History, Vol.32, No.1 (January, 1997) p14 191 ibid p21 192 ‘Protest by Growers of Surplus Wine’, The Times 29/07/1953 p5 193 Dedieu, ‘Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien’, p14 n61 188 54 Occitanes formed in 1945.194 By attaching themselves to the last vestiges of positive regional identity, the Communists were able to garner support as the champions of regionalism, as defined in opposition to the State, and defending the interests of the largely working class regional population. Lem diagnoses the broad and poorly defined nature of Occitan nationalism as a means of expressing “historical grievances and articulating the parameters of injustice”195, and indeed the movement seems largely intended to serve as cultural currency in the battle against perceived central government attempts to homogenize French identity. This led to an enrichment of this reactionary concept of identity in opposition to supra-regional pressures by virtue of the institutionalisation of radical elements in local government and organisations in the immediate post-war period. By examining the particular concept of identity espoused by the Midi vignerons as a form of cultural currency (i.e. in direct competition to vying regional concepts of identity), we can analyse its development not only abstractly and in isolation, but in relation to broader concepts of national identity and their development in corresponding periods. As such, the conflict between the Midi vignerons and the government can be broadly juxtaposed with the conflict which began to develop between the French people and the particular notion of teleological modernisation which came to be identified with America. The correlatory trends apparent are a culture of dependence and a reliance on regulation which had fostered resentment in the dependent. Thus we can diagnose these symptoms not only in the ‘regional – Parisian’ conflict but also in a broader ‘Gallic Anglo-Saxon’ conflict. This is represented on a grand scale by the resentment generated 194 195 J. Sagnès, Le Midi Rouge: mythe et réalité, (Paris, 1982) pp.301-2 Lem, Cultivating Dissent, p230 55 by France’s economic dependence on the United States due to the limits it put on French foreign policy. The Blum-Byrnes negotiations in 1946 absolved French lend-lease war debt and offset low-interest loans against the post-war financial crisis conditional on the reduction of French trade tariffs. The resultant accord saw the French thwarted in their desires to pursue both an independent policy regarding Germany and to continue accepting American aid; the message was startlingly clear: dependence could not equate with independence.196 Indeed, directly after the Liberation, as De Gaulle jealously sought to assert French independence, it fell to Monnet to set down the “basis of French economic dependence.”197 I will shortly move on to analyse the debate surrounding Coca-cola, but it is relevant at this point as an illustration of the sentiment regarding the United States. For some, De Gaulle’s ‘third way’ was still a viable option in the delicate international power balance, and this was embodied by French resistance to economic dominance by either super power. As one journalist in the Témoignage Chrétien summated, “the wine of France will do. Neither Coca-cola, nor vodka.”198 Such a desire to subscribe to whatever form of independence was available highlights the flashpoints which occurred when there was a simultaneous threat to both regional and Gallic identity. External Pressures The reliance of French modernisation upon external aid, by way of the Marshall Plan, produced a largely negative popular response. Already troubled by a continued corrosion of character and the need for a post-war restatement of national identity, the encroachment of the Anglo-Saxon capitalist powers by economic means was viewed with 196 I. M. Wall, The United States and the Making of Postwar France (Cambridge, 2002) p35 ibid p36 198 R. Kuisel, Seducing the French, (Berkeley, 1996) p69 197 56 suspicion and resentment. Across France as a whole, public opinion linked the Marshall Plan and American products, strengthening communist led fears of imperialism.199 Indeed, it seems understandable that overtures made by the American government were seen as patronising, with even Kindelberger himself referring to Marshall Aid recipients as “step-children.”200 The program was sold to a “recalcitrant American Congress”201 as a way of setting up a bulwark against the advance of communism, yet for many it simultaneously represented an act of “enlightened self interest”202, as a nation convinced of its own virtue sought to liberate Europe from themselves. Marshall Plan propaganda presented an image of progress to its European audience, grounded in a vocabulary of technocratic market liberalism, albeit generally presented in cartoon form, with shoemakers and hatters acting as ciphers for industrialists and agriculturalists.203 The American government espoused to its public, however, that the Marshall Plan was essential, with a quantification of the Plan’s aims (achieved by statistically studying policy speeches made by American politicians key to the Plan) indicating that it was presented principally as a means to secure stable liberal economies to trade with rather than as a means to give urgent humanitarian aid.204 (See Figures 2.1 and 2.2) This demonstrated the extent to which depictions of the aims of the Marshall Plan altered in relation to their intended audience, as well as suggesting the reason for widespread suspicion of the motives of American economic intervention. 199 Kuisel, Seducing the French, p38 Kindleberger to de Wilde, March 24, 1947; Memoranda, 1947; State Department File; Charles P. Kindleberger Papers. p2 201 Wall, The United States and the Making of Postwar France, p73 202 ibid p73 203 ‘Europe – Ruins to Recovery’, Archive Hour, BBC Radio 4 23/09/06 204 G.R. Winham, ‘Developing Theories of Foreign Policy Making’, Journal of Politics, vol.32, no.1 pp.4950 200 57 Indeed, it seems historically that Coca-cola, as the symbolic vanguard of American cultural and economic values, has represented the nemesis of traditional Gallic Republican values. The champions of these virtues in this particular conflict during the Post-war period were largely represented by the foremost figures of the agricultural sector. Clearly there were vested interests involved, and the issue grew increasingly politicised as it became associated not only with French producers but also the Communist party, opposed as ever to the anticipated ‘coca-colonisation’ which represented the perceived conclusion of the issue. With the wine industry still mired in its largely deleterious post-war slump, Coca-cola became a symbol of the success which could be enjoyed with a relaxation of production controls, as it benefited from the relaxed trading restrictions originally agreed on in the Blum-Byrne accord. French opposition to Coca-cola’s ingression largely represented the desire for a level playing field. Indeed, much of the contention centred on demands for the clear citation of both ingredients and production methods. The secrecy of the mysterious formula for the soft-drink’s blend, “7X”205 jarred against the regulation placed on labelling and production methods for French vignerons. With the Midi targeted as one of the initial zones of focussed marketing for the Coca-Cola Company, Paris being the other, it was of little surprise that local interests were compromised. Opponents called for the drink to rightly abide by French beverage regulations, due to worries about its secret composition cloaking an addictive substance, seemingly substantiated by the ubiquitous free samples for new consumers.206 However, this opposition was buttressed and intensified by a degree of anti-Americanism aroused by the suspicion of an American cultural invasion. The left- 205 206 R. Kuisel, Seducing the French, (Berkeley, 1996) p54 ibid p57 58 wing Catholic newspaper, Témoignage Chrétien, labelled Coca-cola the “avant-garde of an offensive aimed at economic colonisation”207, and this attitude permeated the press, especially those traditionally sympathetic to the influence of the ‘alcohol lobby’. The perceived cultural offensive of the United States was all the more alarming due to the access granted for American cultural produce to the French market by the Blum-Byrne accords, in which resurgent postwar French creativity was seen to be crushed by Hollywood and “US political muscle.”208 Popular opinion saw reinforcement in its anti-American fears, as the media paired the influx of Coca-cola with the increasingly predominant Hollywood movies to diagnose the first signs of cultural imperialism.209 Such a trend of feeling undeniably added to insecurities surrounding regional culture, as it threatened to undermine the larger umbrella of French culture as a whole. The vulnerability of “traditional cultures” to the expansion of “American culture” framed the problem of identity collapse within the vocabulary of modernisation, which only served to exacerbate concerns.210 As already stated, a climate of regional insecurity served to create a nexus of resentment fuelled by fundamental challenges to identity. This phenomenon clearly found its source both within and without the Midi, with international events such as the Blum-Byrne accords adding to the extra-local pressure felt by the vignerons. The “societal earthquakes”211 which occurred by virtue of these nexuses of resentment were the product of confluences of supra-regional and supra-national pressures impressing resentment on both a regional and national sense. This combination 207 Kuisel, Seducing the French, p64 Grantham, Some Big Bourgeois Brothel, p60 209 ibid, p16 210 ibid, p18 211 Loubère, The Vine Remembers, p17 208 59 became so potent as a result of the politicisation of culture which can be traced to the reestablishment of local elites in the immediate aftermath of the Second World War. The successful mobilisation of regional culture to political ends greatly increased the voice of regional elites, as in France there is a recognition of the fact that “culture transcends political division”, as voiced originally by Gaullist Culture minister Jacques Toubot and concurred with by his Socialist successor Jack Lang.212 This cultural analysis of the Midi points to a situation whereby challenges to regional identity elicited a response which was characterised by the dominance of left-wing sentiment in the area and a prevalent spirit of autonomy. This became most potent when combined with challenges to national identity, as extra-local pressures expanded from Paris to include the United States. Resistance to modernisation formed a major determinant in the nature of the Midi’s intransigence, as a general reluctance emerged to accept extra-local terms for modernisation. This reluctance came to be identified with supporting a perceived continuity of local values, largely consisting of the response formulated by regional elites as ‘invented tradition’. These factors formed a feedback loop in which regional identity relied on resistance to outside pressure as a core social identifier, whilst perpetuating the structural problems inherent in the region and the continued need for outside intervention. In this way, the identity of the Midi vignerons became significant cultural capital, as it defied and yet fostered constant national involvement in the region. In much the same way as De Gaulle sought to maintain French national grandeur by abrasive action in an international context, the vignerons of the Midi sought to maintain investment and relevance by acting abrasively in a national context. D. McMahon, ‘Echoes of a Recent Past: Contemporary French Anti-Americanism in Historical and Cultural Perspective’ <http://www.ciaonet.org/wps/mcd01/> 212 60 Conclusion Attempts by the government to conceive of postwar recovery on a national basis succeeded in boosting most of Monnet’s activités du bas, but failed to incisively address the structural problems extant in some regional economies. In failing to tackle the structural problems of the Midi, the government unswervingly played its role as both regulator in normal circumstances and saviour during the cyclical crises. The Fourth Republic constituted a period in which a government, largely unable to impose its will upon the vocally resistant Midi, ceded substantial ground to articulate local elites who grew increasingly aloof from the Parisian consensus. The frequent repetition of market crises within the wine industry engendered a degree of alienation amongst the local elites of the Midi, increasingly seeing themselves as losing out in the modernity drive being undertaken by France. This feeling of alienation was exacerbated both due to the changing nature of society, which saw rural communities undergoing a demographic downturn, and increased American dominance in the world scene, which convinced many of a new ideological ‘coca-colonisation’. The regional importance of cooperative organisations helped mobilise and vocalise regional identity in the face of these external pressures. In a region famed for its intransigence, alienation bred protest and protest became a watchword for regional solidarity as elites sought to highlight the Midi’s historical legacy. By correlating the regional debate (Occitan against Paris) with the modernisation debate (France against America), the Midi vignerons brought about the inculcation of politics into culture and a resultant normalisation of protest. This fed into a restatement of local identity in the face of extra-local pressures, strengthening traditional resentment to terms imposed by higher authorities. Thus, externally imposed concepts of 61 postwar recovery occasioned a grass roots reaction amongst rural communities which led to a restatement of regional identity, largely redefined in opposition to these plans for recovery. The surprising factor in this analysis is that in a period seen to represent the decline of traditional communities, we witness their rebirth. Focussed on agitating for specific gains, the anti-modernisation program of the vignerons offered no clear path for progress, yet maintained a partnership with government which allowed it to extract significant gains through mass mobilisation. By politicising their culture, viticultural elites developed a cultural and political currency grounded in the principles of left-wing politics and regionalism, which bought them an incommensurately significant voice during the uncertain times of the Fourth Republic and beyond. Whilst perpetuating a system of qualitative retardation and quantitative superfluity, winegrowers helped shape, through protest, a system which enabled them to rely on governmental support, underwriting the industry in the interest of producers. Whilst struggling to earn a living in an increasingly dynamic market, the Midi vignerons found an identity which had seemed lost, and moulded it to maintain regional relevance on an international scene, sacrificing national interest for regional survival. 62 Appendix 63 Index of Prices 1956-57 (100=1948-1949 price p/HL) 120 100 60 40 20 ‘5 Au 6 gu st Se ‘5 pt em 6 be r‘ 56 O ct ob er N ov ‘5 6 em be D r‘ ec 56 em be r‘ 56 Ja nu ar y Fe ‘5 7 br ua ry ‘5 7 M ar ch ‘5 7 Ap ri l ‘5 7 M ay ‘5 7 Ju ne ‘5 7 ‘5 6 Ju ly ‘5 6 Ju ne ‘5 6 M ay ‘5 6 Ap ri l M ar c h ‘5 6 0 Fe br ua ry Indice 80 Month Source: G. Galtier, Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon (Montpellier, 1960), vol.2, p335 64 Bibliography Primary Interview with Edouard Raymond, Domaines Lacassagne (03/08/06) Interview with Raymond Laporte, Domaine Laporte (03/08/06) Interview with Alain Trille, Château des Batilles (04/08/06) Printed Primary Commission des Douanes, ‘Levée temporaire des droits de douane sur les vins étrangers en vue de la baisse du prix du vin de consommation courante en France’, Chambre des Députés, no. 4000 (Paris, 23 avril 1927) Journal Officiel de la République Française. Débats de l’Assemblée nationale, (Paris, 1946-1958) Journal Officiel de la République Française. Documents parlementaires de l’Assemblée nationale, (Paris, 1946-1958) Ministère de l’Agriculture, L’Emploi et les Activités en Milieu Rural (Paris, 1981) “Certain Aspects of the European Recovery Problem”, July, 1947; ERP [folder 2]; Subject File, 1916 1960; Clark Clifford Papers <http://www.trumanlibrary.org/whistlestop/study_collections/marshall/large/index.php> <Accessed: 10/10/06> Galbraith to Kindleberger, October 25, 1946; Memoranda, 1946; State Department File; Charles P. Kindleberger Papers. <http://www.trumanlibrary.org/whistlestop/study_collections/marshall/large/index.php> <Accessed: 10/10/06> Kindleberger to de Wilde, March 24, 1947; Memoranda, 1947; State Department File; Charles P. Kindleberger Papers <http://www.trumanlibrary.org/whistlestop/study_collections/marshall/large/index.php> <Accessed: 10/10/06> Secondary Anson, J., ‘Fruit Bombs’, Wine & Spirit (August, 2006), pp.34-36 Badouin, R., ‘L’Économie Viticole au temps des incertitudes’, Revue D’Économie Méridionale, Vol.42, No.168 (April, 1994) pp.5-19 65 Bardissa, J., Cent Ans de Guerre du Vin (Paris, 1976) Bell, J.F., ‘Problems of Economic Reconstruction in France’, Economic Geography, Vol. 22, No. 1 (January, 1946) pp54-66 Bérard, L.; Marchenay, P., ‘A Market Culture’ in S. Blowen (et al.)(ed.), Recollections of France (Oxford, 2000) pp.154-167 Bort, F., ‘Du Rouge aux Terroirs’ in J. Touzard (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation (Paris, 2003) p95 Chiffoleau, Y. ; Dreyfus, F.; Ewert, J. ; Martin, C. ; Touzard, J. ; Williams, G., ‘Qualité et Solidarité dans les Coopératives Viticoles’ in J. Touzard (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation (Paris, 2003) pp.289-303 Coffey, P., The Social Economy of France (London, 1973) Dedieu, O., Les élus locaux face à la crise du vignoble Languedocien <http://www.afsp.msh-paris.fr/archives/archivesgroupes/local/local080202/dedieu.pdf> <Accessed: 14/09/06> Demossier, M., ‘Culinary Heritage and Produits de Terroir in France’ in Blowen, S. (et al.)(ed.), Recollections of France (Oxford, 2000) pp.141-153 Dubos, J. ‘Les Mutations de la Viticulture Française Contemporaire’ in Sagnès, J. (ed.), La Viticulture Française aux XIXe et XXe Siècles (Béziers, 1993) Fielden, C., Exploring Wines & Spirits - W.S.E.T. Advanced Textbook (London, 2001) Fitzgerald, S., ‘The Anti-Modern Rhetoric of Le Mouvement Poujade’, Review of Politics, Vol. 32, No. 2 (1970) pp.167-190 Font, E., ‘Un Schéma d’Evolution Démographique pour les Communes Rurales’, Revue D’Économie Méridionale, Vol.42, No.165-166 (January-February, 1994) pp.27-47 Gachon, P., Histoire de Languedoc (Paris, 1926) Galtier, G., Le Vignoble du Languedoc Méditerranéen et du Roussillon (Montpellier, 1960) Garrison W.L.; Marble, D.F., ‘The Spatial structure of agricultural activities’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 47, No.2 (June, 1957) pp.137-144 Gavignaud-Fontaine, G. La révolution rurale dans la France contemporaine : XVIIIeXXe siècle (Paris, 1996) 66 Girard, A., ‘Région Languedoc-Roussillon. Economie et Population’, Population (French Edition), Vol.12, No.3 (July-September 1957) pp.509-516 Grantham, B., Some Big Bourgeois Brothel (Luton, 2000) Hackett, J.; Hackett, A., Economic Planning in France (London, 1963) Holmes, G.M.; Fawcett, P.D., The Contemporary French Economy (London, 1983) Hopkins, M., ‘For European Recovery’, <http://www.loc.gov/loc/lcib/970623/marshall.html> <Accessed: 11/10/06> INRA, ‘La consommation de vin dans les pays traditionnellement viticoles’, 2emeSymposium International sur la Production et la Consommation du Vin dans le Monde (Ljubljana, 1979) Isnard, H., La Vigne en Algérie (Paris, 1947) Jeanneney, J.M., Forces et Faiblesses de l’Économie Française (Paris, 1959) Johnson H.; Robinson J., The World Atlas of Wine (London, 2005) Jones A.; Clark J., ‘Of Vines and Policy Vignettes: Sectoral Evolution and Institutional Thickness in the Languedoc’, Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, New Series, Vol. 25, No. 3 (2000) pp.333-353 Keiger, J.F.V., France and the World (London, 2001) Keynes, J.M., The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (Cambridge, 1936) Koreman, M., ‘A Hero’s Homecoming: The Return of the Deportees to France’, Journal of Contemporary History, Vol.32, No.1 (January, 1997) pp.9-22 Lem, W., Cultivating Dissent (New York, 1999) Loubère, L., The Wine Revolution in France (Princeton, 1990) Loubère, L., The Vine Remembers (New York, 1985) Loughlin, J., ‘"Europe of the Regions" and the Federalization of Europe’, Publius, Vol. 26, No. 4 (1996) pp.141-162 67 Lynch, F.M.B., ‘Resolving the Paradox of the Monnet Plan: National and International Planning in French Reconstruction’, The Economic History Review, Vol. 37, No. 2 (May, 1984), pp. 229-243 Maclennan, M.C., ‘Regional Planning in France’, Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol.13 (1965) pp.62-75 Martin, J., ‘Winegrower’s Syndicalism in the Languedoc: Continuity and Change’, Sociologia Ruralis, Vol.36, No. 3 (1996) pp.331-337 Mathieu, A., ‘Des influences de la politique agricole commune en LanguedocRoussillon’, Revue D’Économie Méridionale, Vol.40, No.159 (March, 1992) pp.3-18 Mauget, R. ; Koulytchizky, S., ‘Un siècle de développement des coopératives agricoles en France’ in J. Touzard (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation (Paris, 2003) pp.51-75 McMahon, D., ‘Echoes of a Recent Past: Contemporary French Anti-Americanism in Historical and Cultural Perspective’ <http://www.ciaonet.org/wps/mcd01/> <Accessed: 19/10/06> Meiklereid, W., Economic and Commercial Conditions in France (London, 1953) Michalak W.; Gibb, R., ‘Trading Blocs and Multilateralism in the World Economy’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 87, No. 2 (1997) p265 Moran, W., ‘The Wine Appellation as territory in France and California’, Annals of the association of American Geographers, Vol. 83, No. 4 (1993) pp.694-717 Pech, R., Enterprise Viticole et Capitalisme en Languedoc-Roussillon: du Phylloxera aux crises de mévente (Toulouse, 1975) Robinson, G., Geographies of Agriculture (London, 2004) Sagnès, J., ‘Campagnes en Révolte’, <http://www.univ-montp3.fr/urbi/contenu/articles> <Accessed: 24/08/2006> Sagnès, J., ‘La Gauche Politique et Syndicale dans les Campagnes Viticoles du Midi (1848-1939)’, La Diffusion des Idées Progressistes dans le Monde Rural de la Révolution au XXe Siècle. Actes du Colloque de Châteauroux, (Châteauroux, 2000) Sagnès, J., Le Midi Rouge: mythe et réalité (Paris, 1982) Sagnès, J. (ed.), La Viticulture Française aux XIXe et XXe siècles (Béziers, 1993) Scruton, R., ‘Peasants’ Revolt’, New Statesman (17/07/06) p48 68 Spengler, J.J., ‘Population: Notes on France’s Response to her Declining Rate of Growth’, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 11, No. 4 (Autumn, 1951) pp.403-416 Smith, J.H., ‘Agricultural Workers and the French Wine-Growers' Revolt of 1907’, Past and Present, No.79 (1978) pp.101-125 Temple, L. ; Touzard, J. ; Jarrige, F., ‘La Restructuration des coopératives vinicoles en Languedoc-Rousillon : du modèle communal à la diversité des adaptions actuelles’, Revue D’Économie Méridionale, Vol. 44, No. 176 (April, 1996) pp.73-93 Thompson, H. S., Fear and Loathing in Las Vegas (London, 1993) Touzard, J. (ed.), Les coopératives entre territoires et mondialisation (Paris, 2003) Wall, I.M., ‘The French Communists and the Algerian War’, Journal of Contemporary History, 12 (1977) pp.521-543 Wall, I. M., The United States and the Making of Postwar France (Cambridge, 2002) Warner, C.K. The Winegrowers of France and the Government since 1875 (New York, 1960) Weigend, G.G., ‘The basis and significance of viticulture in Southwest France’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 44, No. 1 (March, 1954) pp.75-101 Winham, G.R., ‘Developing Theories of Foreign Policy Making’, Journal of Politics, Vol.32, No.1 (February, 1970) pp.49-50 ‘Violent Night’, Thinking Allowed, BBC Radio 4 (19/07/06) ‘Europe – Ruins to Recovery’, Archive Hour, BBC Radio 4 (23/09/06) ‘Protest by Growers of Surplus Wine’, The Times (29/07/1953) p5 69