PROPERTY I & II 1999-2000 Professor Krier I. Introduction to Fundamentals Chapter 1 – First Possession: Acquisition of Property by Discovery, Capture, and Creation real property- land personal property- property other than land A. Acquisition by Discovery- the sighting or finding of hitherto unknown or uncharted territory; frequently accompanied by a landing and the symbolic taking of possession, acts that give rise to an inchoate title that must be perfected within a reasonable time by settling in and making and effective occupation. 1. acquisition by conquest- the taking of possession of enemy territory through force, followed by formal annexation of the defeated territory by the conqueror 2. occupancy theory and the principle of first in time- the notion that being there first somehow justifies ownership rights 3. labor theory and John Locke- the labor of one’s body and the work of one’s hands are one’s own; whatsoever one removes out of the state that nature has provided and mixed his labor with, thereby makes it his property. B. Acquisition by Capture 1. Pierson v. Post FACTS: Post was hunting a fox. Pierson, knowing this, killed the fox and carried it off. HOLDING: Property in wild animals is only acquired by occupancy, and pursuit alone does not constitute occupancy or vest any right in the pursuer. The mortal wounding of an animal or the trapping or intercepting of animals so as to deprive them of their natural liberty will constitute occupancy. Here, however, Post only sows pursuit. DISSENT: (Livingston) a new rule should be adopted: that property in wild animals may be acquired without bodily touch, provided a pursuer be in reach or have a reasonable prospect of taking the animals. a. Justinian Code- a collection of imperial constitutions drawn up by a commission of ten persons appointed by Justinian and published in AD 529 which replaced all prior law. 2. Ghen v. Rich 1 FACTS: Rich purchased a whale at an auction from a man who found it on the beach washed up. The whale had been killed at sea by the crew of Ghen’s whaling sip which left Ghen’s identifying bomblance in the animal. HOLDING: when all that is practicable in order to secure a wild animal is done, it becomes the property of the securer who has thus exercised sufficient personal control over the wild animal. While local trade usages should not set aside maritime law, the custom can be enforced when it is embraced by the entire industry and has been concurred for a long rime by everyone engaged in the trade. This particular trade usage was necessary to the survival of the whaling industry, for no one would engage in whaling if he could not be guaranteed the fruits of his labors. 3. Keeble v. Hickeringill FACTS: Keeble contended Hickeringill scared ducks away from his pond resulting in damage. HOLDING: Damages may be recovered for the intentional frightening of wild game off another’s land. Although no title to the game existed, Keeble was using this land in a lawful manner. Thus, Hickeringill interfered with this lawful use and must pay damages. NOTES: (1) capture or control, in conjunction with being first in time, guides legal analysis of the ownership of wild animals. The present case represents somewhat of a departure from these rules, yet is still viewed as a natural and logical extension of them. a. ratione soli- refers to the conventional view that an owner of land has possession, constructive possession, of wild animals on the owner’s land; landowners are regarded as prior possessors of any animals ferae naturae on their land until the animals take off. b. Interference with capture- 37 states have enacted legislation outlawing hunter harassment on stateowned land 4. Rule of Capture and Wild Animals- a trespasser who captures a wild animal on the land of another might still have no rights to the animal as against the landowner, even though the land owner never had actual possession or control and even tough the 2 trespasser does. The court might say that the landowner had constructive possession of the animal. 5. Rule of Capture and Other Fugitive Resources (resources that wander from place to place)- courts sometimes liken these to wild animals and determine their cases according to rule of capture. They belong to the owner of the land and are a part of it, so long as they are on or in it, and are subject to his control; but when they escape, and go into other land, or come under another’s control, the title of the former owner is gone. a. Ground water: In some states (western) water is allocated according to the rule of prior appropriation (the first to put it to good use). In other states (eastern) water is allocated according to various riparian rights. 6. Demsetz’s Theory of Property Rightsa. the emergence of new property rights takes place in response to the desires of the interacting persons for adjustment to new benefit-cost possibilities b. property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains of internalization become larger than the cost of internalization 7. Externalities- a function of transaction costs; encourage the misuse of resources. Exist whenever some person makes a decision about how to use resources without taking full account of the effects of the decision. a. not simply an effect of one person’s activity on another person; rather, it is an effect that the first person is not forced to take into account. b. Do not necessarily lead to inefficient resource use, but do encourage it c. Reciprocal; they arise from interactions or conflicts among people in the use of resources C. Acquisition by Creation- any expenditure of mental or physical effort, as a result of which there is created an entity, whether tangible or intangible, vests in the person who brought the entity into being, a propriety right to the commercial exploitation of that entity, which right is independent and separate from the ownership of that entity. You own the fruits of your labor 1. Cheney Brothers v. Doris Silk Corporation 3 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. FACTS: Cheney Brothers, unable to patent or copyright a garment pattern, sought damages for the copying thereof HOLDING: IF a person cannot obtain a patent or copyright on its product, it cannot recover for the copying of it by others. In the absence of the statutory protection given a man’s creations by patent or copyright law, a man’s property is limited to the tangible objects which embody his invention. When another creates a chattel through imitation, the imitated person has no remedy. Here, it is conceded that the creations of Cheney were neither patentable nor copryrightable, and therefore there is no remedy. NOTES: (1) probably the latest developing area of property law, intellectual property has become a hot topic in the information age. There has been considerable development in the field since this decision. (2) The idea is to grant a limited monopoly: a monopoly in order to encourage productive incentives, but a limited one in order to promote competition International News Service v. Associated Pressnews is property to the first to create it Smith v. ChanelCan imitate b/c no patent Moore v. Regents of the University of California FACTS: Researchers at UCLA, unbeknownst to Moore, used specimens of his tissue to produce a potentially lucrative cell line. HOLDING: a person whose tissue is used for profitable research and development without his knowledge may not maintain a conversion act thereunder. IT cannot be said that a person’s tissue is property. Such a notion is at odds with common law ideas of ethics. Jacque v. Steenberg Homes Private landowners should feel confident that wrongdoers who trespass upon their land will be appropriately punished. When landowners have confidence in the legal system, they are less likely to resort to self help remedies State v. Shack FACTS: Tejeras and Shack entered upon private property, against the orders of the owner of that 4 property, to aid migrant workers employed and housed there. HOLDING: Real property rights are not absolute, and necessity, private or public, may justify entry upon the lands of another. NOTES: (1) generally the right to exclusive possession is considered the oldest and most widely recognized right of private property in land. This case, though, illustrates the central limitation on the right to possession or use of private property, i.e. it may not be used to harm others. Here, the exclusion of Tejeras and Shack was invalid b/c it would harm a very disadvantaged segment of society. 7. The Right to Exclude a. several limitations b. legal rules limiting the right to exclude can all be justified by the reliance interest in property Chapter 2 – Subsequent Possession: Acquisition of Property by Find, Adverse Possession, and Gift A. Acquisition by Find 1. Armory v. Delamirie FACTS: Armory found a jewel which he took to Delamirie, a goldsmith, for appraisal, but Delamirie’s apprentice removed the stones which Delamirie refused to return. HOLDING: the finder of lost property, although he does not acquire absolute ownership, does acquire title superior to everyone else except the rightful owner. Such title is a sufficient property interest in the finder upon which he may maintain an action against anyone (except the rightful owner) who violates that interest. Additionally, Delamirie was liable as he was responsible for the actions of his apprentice NOTES: (1) title or ownership is relative. The rule that the prior possessor prevails over a subsequent possessor applies in cases involving land as well as in cases involving personal property. 2. Hannah v. Peel FACTS: Hannah found a broach at Peel’s home during WWII and sought to recover it after police handed it over to Peel. 5 HOLDING: the finder of a lost article is entitled to it against all persons except the real owner. 3. McAvoy v. Medina FACTS: a wallet was inadvertently left at a barber shop, a customer found it, and the barber asserted ownership. HOLDING: misplaced goods (items intentionally placed by the owner where they are found and then forgotten or left there) are deemed to be in the bailment of the owner of the property on which they were left NOTES: (1) the focus of the lost or misplaced property cases is to determine whether it is likely that the true owner can ever be found. Therefore, b/c the finder was in the first possession, he will have paramount rights. On the other hand, where the goods have been voluntarily placed there and forgotten, the true owner is much more likely to be found. As the true owner would be more likely to return to where he remembered placing the article, the owner of the premises will be deemed the bailee for the true owner. B. Acquisition by Adverse Possession 1. Theory a. Powell- the theory upon which adverse possession rests is that the adverse possessor may acquire title at such time as an action in ejectment by the record owner would be barred by the statute of limitations. b. Ballantine- the statute has not for its object to reward the diligent trespasser for his wrong nor yet to penalize the negligent and dormant owner for sleeping upon his rights; the great purpose is automatically to quiet all titles which are openly and consistently asserted, to provide proof of meritorious titles, and correct errors in conveyancing 2. Van Valkenburgh v. Lutz FACTS: Beginning around 1920, Lutz traveled across a triangular tract to reach his home on a nearby parcel and also built a shed and kept a garden on the tract, but in 1947 P purchased the tract at a tax sale, and when P demanded that Lutz vacate the land, Lutz obtained a judgment that granted him a right of way by prescription over the tract and 6 then in a judicial proceeding established title to the tract by adverse possession. HOLDING: title to a parcel may vest in an adverse possessor who occupies the parcel under claim of right, protects the parcel by an enclosure, improves or cultivates the parcel, and maintains that state of affairs for the statutory period NOTES: (1) the traditional requirements for adverse possession are that the possession be actual, open, notorious, exclusive, adverse, or hostile, continuous, under a claim of right, and for the statutory period. These requirements are variously expressed in the statutes and the cases. (2) The sort of entry and exclusive possession that will ripen into title by adverse possession is use of the property in the manner that an average true owner would use it under the circumstances, such that neighbors and other observers would regard the occupant as a person exercising exclusive dominion. (3) Distinguish the adverse possessor’s absence from the property, on the one hand, and abandonment on the other. If the adverse possessor abandons the propre – leaves with no intention of returning – before the statute has run, the statute stops, a new entry is required, and the whole process must begin anew. Distinguish also interruption by the true owner before the statute has run – say by bringing a successful ejectment action against the adverse possessor, or by re-entering the property. (4) State of mind of the adverse possessor is approached in three different ways: (1) it is irrelevant (2) the required state of mind is that he thought he owned it (3) the required state of mind is he knew he didn’t own it, but intended to take it. (5) When a property interest is protected by a property rule, the interest cannot be taken from its owner without the owner’s consent; all transfers are voluntary. When a property interest is protected by a liability rule, the interest can be taken without the owners consent but only upon payment of judicially 7 determined damages; transfers are forced. Ordinarily adverse possession doctrine protects (1) the owner’s interest with a property rule before the statute of limitations has run, then (2) the adverse possessor’s interest with a property rule after the statute has run. 3. Color of Title and Constructive Adverse Possession a. claim of title is simply one way of expressing the requirement of hostility or claim of right on the part of the adverse possessor. b. Color of Title, on the other hand, refers to a claim founded on a written instrument or a judgment or decree that is for some reason defective and invalid. Even though this is not a prerequisite for AP, it has certain advantages for the AP. c. Actual possession under color of title of only part of the land covered by a defective writing is constructive possession of all that the writing describes. 4. Manillo v. Gorski FACTS: P filed a complaint seeking a mandatory and prohibitory injunction against an alleged trespass upon their lands. D counterclaimed for a declaratory judgment which would adjudicate that she had gained title to the disputed premises by adverse possession HOLDING: any entry and possession for the required period of time which is exclusive, continuous, uninterrupted, visible, and notorious, even though under mistaken claim of title, is sufficient to support a claim of title by adverse possession. No presumption of knowledge arises from a minor encroachment along a common boundary. In such a case, only where the true owner has actual knowledge thereof may it be said that the possession is open and notorious. NOTES: (1) boundary disputes may also be resolved by the doctrines of agreed boundaries, acquiescence, or estoppel. The three doctrines are interwoven by the court. 5. Mechanics of Adverse Possession a. Howard v. Kunto FACTS: The land occupied by Kunto was not that to which he had record title, but he appealed a 8 judgment quieting title in Howard who did have record title. HOLDING: where several successive purchasers received record title to tract A under mistaken belief that they were acquiring tract B, immediately contiguous thereto, and where possession of tract B is transferred and occupied in a continuous manner for more than 10 years by successive occupants, there is sufficient privity of estate to permit tacking and thus establish adverse possession as a matter of law. b. Tacking- to establish continuous possession for the statutory period, an adverse possessor can tack onto her own period of adverse possession any period of adverse possession by predecessors in interest. Thus, separate periods of actual possession by those holding hostilely tot he owner can be tacked together, provided there is privity of estate between the adverse possessors. Privity of estate in this context means that a possessor voluntarily transferred to a subsequent possessor either an estate in land or physical possession. c. Improvements and Encroachments- buildings or fixtures erected without right, whether in good faith or not, become the property of the Landlord. The modern tendency is to soften the impact of this rule on innocent improvers either by granting them compensation equal to the market value of the improvement or permitting the removal of the improvement. A party who intentionally encroaches does so at his peril. d. Disabilities- Most statutes give additional time to bring an action is the owner is under a disability. A disability is immaterial unless it existed at the time when the cause of action accrued. e. AP against the government- Under the common law, AP does not run against the government – state, local, or federal. American courts have relied on this rule. 6. Adverse Possession of Chattels a. O’Keefe v. Snyder FACTS: Snyder contended that he acquired one of O’Keefe’s paintings by adverse possession HOLDING: the discovery rule provides that, in appropriate cases, a cause of action will not 9 accrue until the injured party discovers, or by exercise of reasonable diligence and intelligence should have discovered, facts which form the basis of a cause of action I. The System of Estates Chapter 3 – Possessory Estates A. Up from feudalism 1. Tenure 2. Feudal Tenures and Services a. Free Tenures – In establishing their rule, the Norman conquerors had principally in view military security, economic support, and support of the church. Accordingly, they developed three major tenurial structures to organize three social orders: men who fight, me who work, and men who pray. (1) military tenures – the mounted knight was the central figure in warfare in those days and the tenant by knight service was required to provide a specified number of men to fight for the king. (2) economic tenure - to provide subsistence and maintenance for the overlords, the tenure of socage developed. (3) religious tenures – service from the ecclesiastics required, which might be knight service or socage or singing mass every Friday night b. Unfree Tenures – peasants who worked the manorial lands were called villeins. They held their land at the will of the lord and were denied protection by the king’s courts. 3. Feudal incidents – Besides the services, a tenant owed other duties and was subject to several liabilities benefiting his lord. Feudal services were fixed obligations. a. homage and fealty – protection lay in the strength and backing of a powerful overlord. Hence, homage, binding man to man, was one of the most significant features of feudal society. Each military tenant did his homage to his overlord in a solemn ceremony. b. Aids – in a financial emergency a lord could demand aid from his tenants c. Forfeiture – if a tenant breached his oath of loyalty or refused to perform feudal services, his land was forfeited to the lord. 10 d. liabilities at death of tenant – (1) wardship and marriage – when a tenant died, leaving an heir under 21, the tenant’s lord was the heir’s guardian. The lord also had the right to sell the heir in marriage. (2) Relief – when a tenant died, the heir had to pay the lord an appropriate sum, perhaps a year’s rent, to come into his inheritance (3) Escheat – if a tenant died without heirs, the land returned to the lord from whom it was held. Similarly, if a tenant were convicted of a felony, the land escheated to the lord after the king had exercised his right to waste the land for a year and a day. 4. Avoidance of Taxes – two ways to transfer possession of land – A tenant in demesne could substitute himself for some new tenant who would hold the land from his lord or the tenant could add, without the lord’s consent, a new rung to the bottom of the feudal ladder, becoming a lord himself and having a tenant who rendered him services. - Subinfeudation 5. Statute Quia Emptores (1290) – the king and his barons, with much to lose by subinfeudation, did much to curb this practice. The Statute Quia Emptores prohibited subinfeudation altogether and thus the mischief of devaluing feudal incidents. The statute was a great statute which attempted to shore up the feudal system but actually ended up marking the beginning of the end. * The major historic consequences: 1. The statute established the principle of a free alienation of land, which turned out to be a major force in the development of property law and 2. In time, with the working of escheat and forfeiture, existing mesne lordships tended to disappear and most land came to be directly held from the crown. 6. The Decline of Feudalism – after the Quia Emptores, with free substitution permitted, the relation between tenant and lord was basically an economic one. The tenant was now the “owner” and services and incidents were now a form of taxes. The personal relationship was dying. After the Black Death, survivors could obtain well-paid work outside the manor, and many became wage earners. Wages continued to rise and peasants continued to escape form the communal obligations of manorial life. 11 B. The Fee Simple – out of feudalism developed a system of estates in land. A tenant had status as a tenant of the fee or a tenant for life. In the course of time, status became estate. Each estate is defined by the length of time it may endure. 1. How the fee simple developed a. Rise of heritability- One of the key features of feudalism after the conquest was that the land was not owned by the possessor but was held by the possessor as a tenant of someone else. The tenants holding could not be inherited by his heir, in effect the tenant had only a lifetime tenure. Customarily, for an appropriate sum, the lord would regrant the land to the heir. In time, the lord recognized an obligation to admit the dead tenant’s son and would consent to descent in advance of death. The advance was denoted by a conveyance from the lord “to A and his heirs” b. Rise of alienability – in the great expansion of land of the rural population in the 13th century, leaseholders were frequently tempted to sell before they died and cut off the heirs’ right to succession. With the increasing demand for land, the ides that the tenant should be able to convey the fee to another during his life openly and without the lord’s consent began to gain currency. Quia Emptores began, eventually, to settle that the fee was freely alienable. c. rise of fee simple estate – the fee simple is absolute ownership, so far as our law recognizes absolute ownership. It is the largest estate in terms of duration. It may endure forever. 2. Creation of fee simple – the words “and his heirs” inserted in a conveyance, indicated that A’s interest in the land was inheritable by his heirs, but such words did not give A’s prospective heirs any interest in the land. (words of limitation, whereas to A is a word of purchase). 3. Inheritance of a fee simple – a. heirs – if a person dies intestate (w/o a will) decedent’s real property descends to his or her heirs. (persons who survive the decedent and are designated as intestate successors under the state’s statute of descent. NO ONE is an heir of the living 12 C. Today, in almost all states, a spouse is designated as an intestate successor of some share of decedent’s land. Preferred heirs: issue, is no issue – parents, if nonecollaterals b. Issue (descendants) – is the decedent leaves issue, they take to the exclusion of all other kindred. Does not refer to children only but also includes further descendants. If any child of the decedent dies before the decedent leaving children who survive the decedent, such a child’s share goes to his or her children by right of representation. (per stirpes) until 1925 primogeniture applied to most land in England c. Ancestors (parents) – by statute, parents usually take as heirs if the decedent leaves no issue d. Collaterals – all persons related by blood to the decedent who are neither descendants not ancestors are collateral kin. (brothers, sisters, uncles, aunts, cousins). If a decedent leaves no spouse, no issue, no ancestors – the brothers and sisters take in all jurisdictions. e. Escheat – is a person died intestate w/o any heirs, the person’s real property escheated to the overlord, in feudal times. Now, such property escheats to the state where the property is located. f. Devisees – devised land g. Legatees – bequeathed personal property * heirs take when decedent leaves no will, legatees and devisees takes under a will. The fee tail – invented to keep land safe for succeeding generations, desire to keep land inalienable. The purpose was to give the land to A and his descendants generation after generation. Expires when the original tenant in fee tail, and all of A’s descendants are dead. Fee tail tenant had the power to disential simply by conveying a fee simple by deed to another. * fee tail was abolished by Thomas Jefferson and today, fee tail can be created only in Delaware, Maine, Massachusetts, and Rhode Island. (in these states a fee tail can be converted into a fee simple by a deed executed during life, but cannot bar the entail by will). 13 States w/o fee tail: 1. statutes provide that a limitation “to A and the heirs of his body” creates a fee simple in A, and that any gift over on A’s death w/o issue is void. The statute disentails and destroys the interests of A and B automatically. 2. Statutes provide that a limitation “to A and the heirs of his body” creates a fee simple in A, but they further provide that a gift over to B if A dies w/o issue will be given effect if and only if, at A’s death A leaves no surviving issue. D. The life estate- b/c the early feudal relation between lord and tenant involved only lifetime tenure, the law had little problem recognizing an estate for life. Two important consequences of judicial recognition: 1. it meant that the grantor of the life estate can control who takes the property at the life tenant’s death 3. as land and stocks and bonds came to be viewed as income-producing capital, trust management for the life tenant developed A can transfer his life estate to B, in Which case B has a life estate – pur autre vie – that is, an estate that is measured by A’s life-span, not B’s. If B dies during A’s lifetime, the life estate passes to B’s heirs or devisees until A dies. Every life estate is followed by a future interest – whether a reversion in the transferor or a remainder in the transferee. 1. Rule against direct restraints on alienation is an old one, going back to the 15th century or perhaps even earlier. a. restraints make property unmarketable b. restraints tend to perpetuate the concentration of wealth by making it impossible for the owner to sell property and consume the proceeds of sale c. restraints discourage improvements on the land. d. Restraints prevent the owner’s creditors from reaching the property, working hardship on creditors who rely on the owner’s enjoyment of the property in extending credit. 14 e. restraints classified: (1) disabling restraint: withholds from the grantee the power of transferring his interest (2) forfeiture restraint: provides that if the grantee attempts to transfer his interest, it is forfeited to another person. (3) Promissory restraint: provides that the grantee promises not to transfer his interest. If valid, is enforceable by contract remedies of damages or an injunction. FEE SIMPLE: absolute restraint on a fee simple is void, partial restraint is valid if, under all of the circumstances of the case, the restraint is found to be reasonable in purpose, effect and duration. LIFE ESTATE: absolute restraint is void, but a forfeiture restraint is valid. 2. valuation of life estate and remainder – for lack of a better method, courts, taxing authorities, and insurance companies value life estates and remainders by resort to life expectancy tables. 3. Waste – the law of waste becomes relevant whenever two persons or more have rights to possess property at the same time. The central idea of the waste concept is that A should not be able to use property in a manner that unreasonably interferes with the expectations of B. It is designed to avoid waste.. the use of property that fails to maximize the property’s value. a. affirmative waste – arising from voluntary acts, liability results from injurious acts that have more than trivial effects. Generally injurious has meant acts that substantially reduce the value of the property in question. b. Permissive waste – arising from a failure to act, essentially a question of negligence and failure to take reasonable care of the property. 4. seisin- possession of a freehold estate in land, ownership. E. Leasehold Estates – non-freehold possessory estates, tenants do not have seisin. F. Defeasible Estates – any estate can be created so as to be defeasible upon the happening of a future event, 15 1. The most common kind of defeasible freehold estate is a fee simple defeasible. This is an estate that may last forever or may come to an end at the happening of a certain event in the future. 2. A fee simple determinable is a fee simple so limited that it will end automatically when a stated event happens. Sometimes called a fee simple on special limitation, indicating that the fee simple will expire by this limitation if it occurs. Created by language connoting any words with a durational aspect. accompanied by a future interest...future interest is retained by the transferor in a possibility of reverter. 3. A fee simple subject to condition subsequent is a fee simple that does not automatically terminate but may be cut short or divested at the transferor’s election when a stated condition happens. Created by language such as “but if…” “provided” “however” etc. future interest retained by the transferor to divest a fee simple subject to condition subsequent is called a right of entry Chapter 4 – Future Interests A. Introduction B. Future Interests in Transferor 1. Reversion – the interest left in an owner when he carves out of his estate a lesser estate and does not provide who is to take the property when the lesser estate expires. Because reversions result from a hierarchy of estates, they are thought of as the remnant of an estate that has not entirely passed away from the transferor. * NO SUCH THING AS THE POSSIBILITY OF REVERSION! 2. Possibility of Reverter- arises when an owner carves out of his estate a determinable estate of the same quantum. (usually the carving of a fee simple determinable out of a fee simple absolute. For all practical purposes a possibility of reverter is a future interest remaining in the transferor or his heirs when a fee simple determinable is created. 3. Right of Entry – when an owner transfers an estate subject to condition subsequent and retains the power to cut short or terminate the estate, the transferor has a right of entry. 16 C. Future Interests in Transferees 1. Remainders – a future interest that is capable of becoming possessory at the termination of the prior estate. It is not required that the future interest be certain of future possession, only that it be possible for the interest to become possessory when the prior estate ends. a. a remainder is vested if: 1. It is given to an ascertained person AND 2. It is not subject to a condition precedent (other than the natural termination of the preceding estates) b. a remainder is contingent if 1. It is given to an unascertained person OR 2. If it is made contingent upon some event occurring other than the natural termination of the preceding estates. c. A remainder may be indefeasibly vested, meaning that the remainder is certain of becoming possessory in the future and cannot be divested. d. RULE TO BET ON: if the first future interest created is a contingent remainder in fee simple, the second future interest in a transferee will also be a contingent remainder. If the first future interest created is a vested remainder in fee simple, the second future interest in a transferee will be a divesting executory interest. the owner of a vested or contingent remainder may transfer the remainder during life, or the owner may transfer the remainder by will or intestacy if he dies during the life tenant’s life, unless the instrument creating the remainder requires the remainderman to survive the life tenant. The general rule is that a requirement of survivorship is not implied. Law has a preference for a vested remainder and where an instrument is ambiguous, the courts construe it in favor of a vested remainder. 2. Executory interests – future interest in a transferee that must, in order to become possessory, (1) divest or cut short some interest in another transferee (shifting) OR (2) divest the transferor in the future (springing) 17 a. Two Prohibitory Rules: No Shifting Interests; No Springing Interests – Prior to 1536 common law courts laid down two rules... the first of these was that no future interest could be created in favor of a transferee if the interest could operate to cut short a freehold estate. The second rule was that no freehold estate could be created to spring up in the future. b. The Rise of Use – the chancellor was concerned with conscience, not seisin, and paid no attention to the seisin rules of the law courts. When he thought persons should be required to perform their moral duties, the chancellor would step in and protect a transferee, regardless of what his legal rights might be. There developed in equity a protected interest known as “use.” so far as the law was concerned, the feoffment with livery of seisin created a fee simple absolute in X; the law courts refused to compel the feoffee to uses, X, to hold the land for the benefit of A. The chancellor, however, thought X had a good faith duty to hold seisin for the benefit of A, the cest que use, a corruption of the one for whom the benefit was made. Another common method of creating a use was the bargain of sale and deed. Springing uses as well as shifting uses might be created in equity. Particularly b/c of its success in avoiding those medieval taxes known as feudal incidents, the use became universally popular. c. The Abolition of the Use: the Statute of Uses – provided that if any person or persons were seised to the use of any other person or persons, the legal estate (seisin) would be taken away from the feoffee to uses and given to the one to whom the benefit was made. AKA: the statute executed the use, that is converted it into a legal interest. expanded legal future interests by converting what were “shifting uses” and “springing uses” in equity before 1536 into legal “shifting executory interests” and “springing executory interests” what are called executory interests today are interests that would have been void prior to 18 the Statutue of Uses b/c they violated the two rules above. Statute seemed to have the power to destroy the power to devise land in equity b/c it converted equitable interests into legal interests and land could not be devised at law. Statute also made legally valid those deeds of land that had previously been valid only in equity. d. Modern Executory Interests – the effect of the statute of uses was to permit the creation of a new estate: a fee simple subject to an executory limitation. This is a fee simple that, upon the happening of a stated event, is automatically divested by an executory interest in a transferee. executory interests are ordinarily treated as contingent interests, because they are subject to a condition precedent. But where an executory interest is to become possessory upon an event certain to happen, it may be treated as a vested interest. A possibility of reverter or a right of entry can be created only in the transferor; an executory interest can be created only in a transferee. At common law there were differences between the executory interest and the remainder. The rules separating the two have been abolished in all but a handful of states, and where abolished, there may be no significant differences in legal consequences between executory interests and remainders. Modern statutes often include executory interests in an all-inclusive definition of a remainder. D. Rules Furthering Marketability by Destroying Contingent Future Interests 1. The rule in Shelley’s Case – one of the earlier rules favoring marketability, recognized in Abel’s case was given definite form. In addition to furthering alienability, the rule prevented feudal tax evasion; feudal incidents were due only if land had descended to the heir, not if the heir took as purchaser. A simplified statement of the rule: 19 If one instrument creates a life estate in A, and purports to create a remainder in persons described as A’s heirs (or the heirs of A’s body), and the life estate and the remainder are both legal or are both equitable, the remainder becomes a remainder in fee simple (or fee tail) in A. the doctrine of merger merges the life estate in A into a vested remainder in fee held by A. the life estate cannot merge into a vested remainder in fee simple if there is an intervening vested life estate, blocking merger. Rule in Shelley’s case applies only to remainders and not executory interests. Rule applies only when the gift in remainder refers to an indefinite line of succession, rather than to a specific class of takers. a. Abolition of the rule in Shelley’s case – rule has been abolished in most states, but in few states, however, abolition by statute is fairly recent and does not apply retroactively. 2. The Doctrine of Worthier Title- the old common law drew distinctions between titles acquired by inheritance and titles acquired by purchase (that is, other than by inheritance). Title by inheritance was deemed worthier, so the law forbade a person’s heir to take by purchase from his own ancestor. the common law Doctrine of Worthier Title provides that where there is an inter vivos conveyance of land by a grantor to a person, with a limitation over to the grantors OWN heirs either by way of remainder or executory interest, no future interest in the heirs is created, but a reversion is retained by the grantor. Furthers alienability, but is abolished now in a number of states 3. Destructibility of Contingent Remainders – moved by the requirement that someone must always be seised of the land, and hence responsible for the feudal dues, the judges laid down this rule: A remainder in the land is destroyed if it does not vest at or before the termination of the preceding freehold estate. If the 20 remainderman is not ready to take seisin when it is offered, he is wiped out and the seisin moves on to the next vested estate. Reeve v. Long established the principle, accepted today for determining all questions of property rights, that where it is for the child’s benefit, a child will be treated retroactively as in being from the time of conception is the child is later born alive. a. Abolition of the destructibility doctrine – to curb executory interests the Rule against Perpetuities was developed. It appeared to be a good idea to subject all contingent future interests in transferees to one rule and to abolish the destructibility doctrine. 4. The Rule Against Perpetuities a. The Common Law Rule – the culmination of the long struggle between the landowners who wanted to keep the land within the family and the royal judges who for centuries had tried to stand firm against these efforts is this Rule. No interest is good unless it must vest, if at all, not later than twenty-one years after some life in being at the creation of the interest. (property may be tied up with contingent interests for lives in being plus 21 years thereafter, but no longer) Permits a man of property to provide for all of those in his family whom he personally knows and the first generation after them upon attaining majority. It is a rule of logical proof. You must prove that a contingent interest will necessarily vest or fail within 21 years after some life in being at the creation of the interest. If you cannot prove that, the contingent interest is void form the outset. Looking for a person who will enable you to prove that the contingent interest will vest or fail within the life of, or at the death of, the person, or within 21 years after the death of the person. This person, if found, is called the validating or measuring life. Validating lives do not have to be people mentioned in the instrument, but they do have 21 to be people who can affect vesting of the interest. Future interests retained by the transferor reversions, possibilities of reverter, and rights of entry – are not subject to the rule against Perpetuities. They are treated as vested as soon as they arrive. (1) gifts to classes- a gift to a class is invalid if it might vest in one member of the class too remotely. the gift to the class must stand or fall as a unit If the gift to one member of the class might vest too remotely. The whole class gift is void. A class gift is not vested in any member of the class until the interests of all members have vested. A gift that is subject to open is not vested under the Rule against Perpetuities EACH and EVERY member of the class must be IDENTIFIED and ALL conditions precedent for EACH and EVERY member of the class must be satisfied within the perpetuities period. Chapter 5 - Co-ownership and Marital Interests A. Common Law Concurrent Interests 1. Types, Characteristics, Creation five types of concurrent interests (partnerships and coparceny are ignored) leaving only tenancy in common, the joint tenancy, and the tenancy by the entirety. Tenants in common- have separate but undivided interests in the property; the interest of each is descendible and may be conveyed by deed or will. Each tenant in common owns an undivided share of the whole. Joint tenants – have the right of survivorship and together are regarded as a single owner. In theory then, each owns an undivided whole of the property. When one joint tenant dies, nothing passes to the surviving joint tenant or tenants. Rather, the estate simply continues in survivors freed from the participation of the decedent, whose interest is extinguished. Common law insisted that the 22 interests be equal in al respects and four “unities” were essential to a joint tenancy. (1) time- interest of each tenant must be acquired or vest at the same time (2) title- all joint tenants must acquire title by the same instrument or by joint adverse possession. A joint tenancy can never arise by intestate succession or other act of law. (3) Interest- all must have equal, undivided shares and identical interests measured by duration. (4) Possession- each must have a right to possession of the whole. After a joint tenancy is created, however, one joint tenant can voluntarily give exclusive possession to the other joint tenant. Tenancy by the entirety- can be created only in husband and wife. The tenancy by the entirety is like the joint tenancy in that the four “unities” plus a fifth- marriage, are required, and the surviving tenant has the right of survivorship. Considered to hold as one person at common law; both are seised of the entirety. Neither husband nor wife, acting alone, has the right to judicial partition of property held as tenants by the entirety. Divorce terminates the tenancy by entirety b/c it terminates the marriage, which is a requisite for a tenancy by entirety. Avoidance of probate- a joint tenancy is the practical equivalent of a will, but at the joint tenant’s death probate of the property is avoided. * probate- the judicial supervision of the administration of the decedent’s property which passes to others at the decedent’s death: the probate court appoints an administrator or executor who collects the decedent’s assets, pays the debts and taxes, and distributes or changes title to the property to the beneficiaries. A joint tenancy avoids probate b/c no interest passes on the joint tenant’s death. Under the theory of joint tenancy, the decedent’s interest vanishes at death and the survivor’s 23 ownership of the whole continues without the decedent’s participation. Congress has provided that when a joint tenant dies, his share of the jointly held property is subject to federal estate taxation. Under the state inheritance taxes, the fractional share of a joint tenancy owned by the decedent is taxed; the federal who-furnished-theconsideration test is not followed. 2. Service of Joint Tenancies a. Riddle v. Harmon FACTS: Mr. and Mrs. Riddle purchased a parcel of real estate, taking title as joint tenants. Several months before her death, Mrs. Riddle retained an attorney to plan her estate. He advised her that the property was held in joint tenancy and that, upon her death, the property would pass to her husband. She requested that the joint tenancy be terminated so that she could dispose of her interest by will. As a result, the attorney prepared a grant deed whereby Mrs. Riddle granted to herself an undivided one-half interest in the property. HOLDING: the court discards the archaic rule that one cannot enfeoff oneself which, if applied, would defeat the clear intention of the grantor. There is no question but that the decedent here could have accomplished her objective by one of a variety of circuitous processes. One joint tenant may unilaterally sever the joint tenancy w/o the use of an intermediary device. IMPORTANT PRECEDENTS: Clark v. Carter (strawman is indispensable and the two-to-transfer notion); Burke v. Stevens (intermediary strawman used); Reiss v. Reiss (transferred bare legal title to son, as a trustee for her use and benefit. The son promised to re-convey the property to his mother or to whomever she selected at any time upon her demand and the court upheld the arrangement); Henderickson v. Minneapolis Federal Sav. & Loan ASS’n (no fictional transfer by conveyance and re-conveyance through a strawman was required) Uniform simultaneous Death Act- provides that one-half the property is distributed as if A survived and one-half as if B survived. 24 Uniform Probate code- provides that the murder severs the joint tenancy and coverts it into a tenancy in common. The killer loses his right to survivorship in the decedent’s share. b. Harms v. SpragueFACTS: Plaintiff William Harms and his brother John Harms took title to real-estate as joint tenants. Meanwhile, defendant Sprague entered into an agreement with the Simmons (who owned property in the town) to purchase their property. B/c Sprague had no security deposit, he asked john Harms to so-sign the note and give a mortgage on his interest I joint tenancy property. John agreed and the two jointly and severally executed a promissory note to the Simmons’s. John executed a mortgage in favor of the Simmons, on his undivided one-half interest in the joint tenancy property. William was unaware of the mortgage given to his brother. John Harms died and by his will, Sprague was the devisee of his entire estate. HOLDING: the court found that b/c a mortgage given by one joint tenant of his interest in the property does not sever the joint tenancy, the plaintiff’s right of survivorship became operative upon the death of his brother. The mortgage executed by John Harms does not survive as a lien on the plaintiff’s property – a surviving joint tenant succeeds to the share of the deceased joint tenant by virtue of the conveyance which created the joint tenancy, not as a successor of the deceased. While John was alive his mortgage existed as a lien on his interest in the join tenancy, but upon his death his interest ceased to exist and along with it the lien of the mortgage title theory- under this form of mortgage the mortgagee takes legal title to the land; the mortgagor has only the equity of redemption. Lien theory- hold the mortgagor keeps legal title and the mortgagee has only a lien on the property. 3. Relations Among Concurrent Owners- “Each tenant owns an interest in the fee and each has an equal right to possession of the whole... neither a joint tenant nor a tenant in common can do any act to the prejudice of his covenants in their estate” By 25 definition each tenant is entitled to possession of the entire parcel of land, yet he cannot exercise that possession without coming into conflict with the reciprocal right of his co-tenant. a. Partition- the privilege of each co-owner to transform a concurrent estate into estate held in severalty. Equitable action of partition is necessary if termination of the tenancy can not be accomplished through a voluntary agreement. The action is available to any joint tenant or tenant in common; it is unavailable to tenants by the entirety. i. Delfino v. VealencisFACTS: plaintiff and defendant own, as tenants in common, real property in Conn. The property consists of 20.5 acres of land a dwelling of the defendant in the extreme western end of the property. The defendant occupies the dwelling and a portion of the land, form which she operates a rubbish and garbage removal business. The plaintiffs, one of whom is a residential developer, propose to develop the property, upon partition, into residential building lots. Defendant moved for a judgment of in-kind partition and the court denied and ordered the property sold at auction with the proceeds to be given to the parties in accordance with their interests. HOLDING: It has long been the policy of the court to favor in-kind partitions to sale. Partition by sale should be ordered only if: (1) the physical attributes of the land are such that a partition in-kind is impracticable or inequitable; (2) the interests of the owners would better be promoted by a partition by sale. Since the property in this case may practicably be physically divided, and since the interests of all owners will better be promoted is a partition in-kind is ordered, we conclude that the trial court erred in ordering a partition by sale, and that, under the facts as found, the defendant is entitled to partition of the property in-kind. b. Sharing the Benefits and Burdens of Co-ownershipthere is a need for independent property rules to determine how the benefits and burdens of ownership are to be shared by the co-owners i. Spiller v. Mackereth- 26 FACTS: Plaintiff and defendant owned a building in downtown Tuscaloosa as tenants in common. when a lessee, which had been renting the building vacated, Plaintiff entered and began using the structure as a warehouse. Defendant then wrote a letter demanding that Plaintiff either vacate half of the building or pay half of the rental value, and, when plaintiff did neither, she brought suit. The trial court awarded defendant rent money and plaintiff appealed HOLDING: Each tenant in common has an equal right to occupy; and unless the one in actual possession denies to the other the right to enter, or agrees to pay rent, nothing can be claimed for such occupation. since there was no agreement to pay rent, there must be evidence which establishes ouster before plaintiff is required to pay rent to defendant. Ouster can describe either (1) the beginning of the running of the statute of limitations for adverse possession or (2) the liability of an occupying co-tenant for rent to other co-tenants. Fiduciary duties- generally co-tenants are not fiduciaries with respect to each other; each co-tenant is expected to look after his or her own interest. A fiduciary duty is imposed most commonly in one of two situation: (1)where one co-tenant buys in concurrently owned property at a mortgage foreclosure or tax sale and then asserts a superior title against co-tenants and (2) where a claim of adverse possession by the co-tenant in exclusive possession arises. ii. Swartzbaugh v. SampsonFACTS: plaintiff iii. Accounting for Benefits, Recovering Costsconcurrently owned property can yield a variety of benefits. Of course, concurrent ownership can also give rise to a variety of expenditures. A co-tenant making such expenditures might seek to recoup some or all of them through a partition action or an action for an accounting or an action for contribution from other cotenants. 27 (1) (2) (3) (4) Rents and profits: in all states, a cotenant who collects from third parties rents and other payments arising from the co-owned land must account to cotenants the amounts received... he must account for net rents, royalties, and other proceeds in excess of his share. This is only based on actual receipts, not market value. Taxes, mortgage payments and other carrying charges: a cotenant paying more than his share of taxes, mortgage payments, and other necessary carrying charges generally has the right to contribution from the other cotenants, at least up to the amount of the value of their share in the property. This imposes on each a duty to contribute to the extent of his proportionate share the money required to make such payments. Repairs: as to necessary repairs, a cotenant making or paying for them has no affirmative right to contribution from the other cotenants in absence of an agreement. This is considered the rule by “weight of authority and reason.” The character and extent of repairs are too uncertain for the law to settle. Cotenant does receive credit for reasonable repairs in a partition action, though. Improvements: as with repairs, a cotenant has no right to contribution from other cotenants for expenditures for improvement and receives no credit for the cost of the improvements in accounting or partition actions. The general rule is that the interests of the improver are to be protected if this can be accomplished without detriment to the interests to the other cotenants. In accounting for rents and profits, the improver is allowed all increments in value (if any) attributable to the improvements. 28 Part III Leaseholds: The Law of Landlord and Tenant Chapter 6 – Tradition, Tension, and Change in LandlordTenant Law A. The Leasehold Estate- tenancies, or leaseholds – of which the principal ones are the term of years, the periodic tenancy, and the tenancy at will – are nonfreehold estates. 1. The Term of Years- an estate that lasts for some fixed period of time or for a period computable by formula that results in fixing calendar dates for beginning and ending, once the term is created or becomes possessory. Must be for a fixed period but it can be terminable earlier upon the happening of some event or condition. No notice of termination is necessary to bring the estate to an end. 2. The Periodic Tenancy- a lease for a period of some fixed duration that continues for succeeding periods until either the landlord or tenant gives notice of termination. If notice is not given the period is automatically extended for another period. Common law rules: half a year’s notice is required to terminate a year-to-year tenancy. For any periodic tenancy less than a year, a notice of termination must be given equal to the length of the period, but not to exceed six months. Death: the death of the landlord or tenant has no effect on the duration of a term of years or periodic tenancy, but it does on the tenancy at will. 3. The Tenancy at Will- a tenancy of no fixed period that endures so long as both landlord and tenant desire. If the lease provides that it can be terminated by one party, it is necessarily at the will of the other as well IF a tenancy at will has been created. The tenancy at will ends, among other ways, when one of the parties terminates it. It also ends at the death of one of the parties. a. Garner v. GerrishFACTS: In 1977 Robert Donovan owned a house and leased his premises to tenant Lou Gerrish. With respect to the duration of the tenancy, the lease provides it shall continue “for and during the quiet enjoyment form the first day of May, 1977 which term will end – Lou Gerrish has the privilege of termination [sic] this agreement at a date of his own choice. Donovan dies and Garner, the 29 executor of Donovan’s estates, served Gerrish with a notice to quit the premises. When Gerrish refused, Garner commenced this summary proceeding to have him evicted. ISSUE: whether a lease which grants the tenant the right to terminate the agreement at a date of his choice creates a determinable life tenancy of the tenant or merely establishes a tenancy at will. (or in other words, whether the lease should be literally construed to grant the tenant alone the right to terminate at will, or whether the landlord is accorded a similar right by operation of law. HOLDING: the lease expressly and unambiguously grants to the tenant the right to terminate, and does not reserve to the landlord a similar right. To hold that such a lease creates a tenancy terminable at the will of either party would violate the terms of the agreement and the express intent of the contracting parties. * the lease in this case simply grants a personal right to the named lessee, Gerrish, to terminate at a date of his choice, which is a fairly typical means of creating a life tenancy terminable at the will of the tenant. 4. The Tenancy at Sufferance – arises when a tenant remains in possession (holds-over) after termination of the tenancy. Common law rules give the landlord confronted with the hold-over essentially two options: eviction (plus damages) or consent (express or implied) to creation of a new tenancy. a. Crechale & Polles, Inc. v. Smith FACTS: Crechale and Polles, Inc. entered into a lease agreement with John D. Smith and Gloria Smith. The lease was for a term of five years. Smith was informed near the end of his lease that the new building which he planned to occupy would not be complete until a moth or two after his present lease expired. Arranged a meeting with his landlord for negotiating an extension of the lease on a month-to-month basis. Crechale maintains that he told Smith to he did not want to get involved in a month-to-month while Smith asserts that cRechale said he could stay. Smith’s attorney presented a lease that Crechale refused to sign, saying “oh go ahead…it’s alright.” Later letters were sent back and forth confirming and denying the oral agreement. Crechale eventually stopped accepting 30 B. checks from Smith and refused to inventory. Later, Crechale wrote to Smith telling him he saw the situation as a hold-over and that he was treating it as a renewal to the yearly lease. Crechale started to suit to recover back rent. HOLDING: the appellant is not entitled to require appellees to p0ay rent for a new term of the rental contract as a hold-over tenant b/c Crechale at one point wrote to Smith denying their agreements and demanding that Smith vacate the premises. According to AmJUR, once the LL has once exercised his election not to hold the tenant for another term, his right to hold him is lost. The landlord refused to accept Smith’s check as payment then later attempted to change his position by telling tenant his was going to be treated as a hold-over tenant. in most jurisdictions holding-over gives rise to a periodic tenancy; in the balance, it results in a term. The tenancy resulting form the hold-over is usually subject to the same terms and conditions as those in the original lease, unless the parties agree otherwise or unless some term or conclusion is regarded as inconsistent with the new situation. Holds that the double rent statute was intended by the legislature to provide the sole action for damages as the result of the tenant’s holdover. The common law rule has been abrogated once and for all and may no longer be used to impose the renewal of an expired lease. the Lease- an arrangement that resembles a lease – indeed, an arrangement explicitly declaring itself, in writing, to be a lease – might nevertheless be held by the courts to amount to something else, such as a license or a life estate. 1. Bearing on the question are: a. intentions of the parties b. the number of restrictions on use c. the exclusivity of possession d. the degree of control retained by the granting party, the presence of absence of incidental services 2. It matters primarily whether or not an arrangement is a lease b/c a lease gives rise to the landlord31 C. tenant relationship, which carries with it certain incidents – certain rights and duties and liabilities and remedies – that do not attach to other relationships 3. A lease is a conveyance and a contract 4. Statute of Frauds- intended to prevent fraud, provides that leases for more than one year must be in writing 5. Form leases- standardized documents offered to all tenants on a take-it-or-leave-it basis, with no negotiation over terms (seller is trying to avoid the costs of negotiating and drafting a separate agreement with each purchaser) Selection of Tenants- once free to discriminate, landlords are now constrained. 1. Federal Fair Housing Act (1868)a. partially exempts religious groups and private clubs under certain circumstances, single family houses sold or rented by the owner, rooms in dwellings containing living quarters occupied by no more than four families living independently of each other b. attempts to combat discrimination run back to the adoption of the 14th amendment and its guarantee of equal protection c. as originally enacted in 1968, the FHAA did not prohibit discrimination on the grounds of sex, handicap, or familial status. Sex discrimination was added to the Act in 1974; amendments in 1988 added the prohibitions regarding familial status and handicapped persons. 2. The Civil Rights Act of 1866 provided that “all citizens of the US shall have the same right in every State and Territory as is enjoyed by white citizens thereof to inherit, purchase, lease, sell, hold, and convey real and personal property. d. Soules v. US Dept. of Housing and Development FACTS: Soules attempted to rent an apartment from defendant realtor, Downs, who managed and rented several properties. Downs asked Soules about her children’s ages before allowing her to see the apartment due to the elderly neighbors below the unit. Soules contacted HOMES alleging discrimination. HOLDING: Because the question concerning the age of the Soules’ child was motivated by what the ALJ considered legitimate reasons – securing quiet 32 neighbors for the elderly downstairs, he shifted the burden to the petitioners to demonstrate that Downs’ allegedly legitimate reason for not renting to the Soles the apartment was pretextual. Soules did not carry the burden. NOTES: (1) a discriminatory motive need not be proved in order to make out a prima facie case under the Federal Fair Housing Act; proof of discriminatory effect is sufficient. Claims under the civil rights act probably do require proof of intentional or purposeful discrimination. (2) Even if a prima facie case of disparate impact of numerical occupancy restriction on families with children was made out, occupancy restriction could be justified on ground it maintained economic value of the property. (3) Many states and localities prohibit discrimination in the leasing of housing. State and local measures may not, of course, operate to narrow the rights and remedies available under federal law, but they may and sometimes do have a broader reach, covering, for example, marital status and sexual orientation. (4) FHA provides for the award of reasonable attorney’s fees to successful aggrieved parties from losing landlords. This is to encourage victims of discrimination to seek judicial relief. Award of attorney’s fees for defendants who prevail is permitted only if the complaint is frivolous or in bad faith. e. Bronk v. Ineichen FACTS: Plaintiffs, profoundly deaf women, sued their landlord for not allowing them to have a hearing dog, despite his no-pets policy. HOLDING: Given the level of uncertainty and conflicting evidence about the dog’s training level, it was well within the province of a rational jury to conclude that the dog’s utility to the plaintiffs was as a simple house pet and weapon against cranky landlord, and not necessarily in that order. If the dog was not necessary as a hearing dog, then his presence in 33 D. E. the townhouse was not necessarily a reasonable accommodation. Delivery of Possession 1. Hannan v. Dusch FACTS: Hannan, the leasee, alleged that Dusch, the lessor, failed to deliver possession of rented property by allowing a former tenant to remain in possession. HOLDING: Under the American Rule, a landlord does not impliedly covenant against the wrongful acts of others, and is not responsible for the tortious acts of third parties unless he expressly contracts so. Where a new tenant fails to obtain possession of rented premises solely b/c a former tenant wrongfully holds over, his remedy is against the former tenant and not the landlord. Under the English Rule, in the absence of express provisions to the contrary, there is I every lease an implied covenant by the landlord that the premises will be open to entry by the tenant at the time of the beginning of the term. 2. Case law on the matter of delivery of possession remains divided, with substantial support for both the English and the American rules. Under the American rule, the tenant’s remedies are against person wrongfully in possession; He may sue to recover possession and damages. AS to remedies under the English rule, the tenant may terminate the lease, sue for damages, take possession of the remainder of the property if the third party only possesses a portion, he may stop paying rent, go directly against the third party, and may collect appropriate damages 3. The American rule seems to be founded on the argument that the tenant has sufficient legal and equitable remedies available to protect himself against a third party wrongfully in possession and a greater incentive to use them than the landlord. Subleases and Assignments 1. Ernst v. Conditt FACTS: after Ernst leased the property to Rogers, who assigned his lease to Conditt, Ernst sought damages from Conditt for past due rent and removal of improvements HOLDING: Under the common-law rule, if an instrument purports to transfer the leasee’s interest for the entire remainder of the lease 34 2. term, an assignment has occurred. However, if the instrument purports to transfer the leasee’s interest for any length of time less than the remainder of the lease term, a sublease has been established. Under the modern rule, the intention of the parties governs in constructing deeds, leases and other written transfers of property interests. Here, under both common law and the modern rule, the agreement between Rogers and Conditt is an assignment rather than a sublease. Rogers did not retain any interest in the lease, and he also did not reserve a right of re-entry in the event of a breach of any of the conditions. Kendall v. Ernest Pestana, Inc. FACTS: Ernest Pestana, Inc. Arbitrarily withheld permission from Kendall, its tenant, to sublet its leasehold. HOLDING: Absent contractual language to the contrary, a lessor may not arbitrarily withhold consent to an assignment. The basic social policy in this area is that interests in property, including those of a leasehold nature, should be freely alienable. Restrictions on alienability are to be strictly construed against the lessor. The lessor does have a reversionary interest in the property, and therefore is entitled to assurance that the lessee will not sublet to an irresponsible person who may commit waste. This is a commercially reasonable rationale for denying permission to sublet. There are no doubt others. Absent some sort of reasonable basis for denial of permission, however, it seems that public policy favoring free alienability should override whatever minor interest a lessor might have in arbitrarily denying permission to sublet. The major arguments in favor of retaining the right are unpersuasive. The lessor’s common law right to look to no one but the lessee for rent has been curtailed. The argument that the lessee could have bargained for free subletting does not stand up to scrutiny. What the parties contemplated is not always clear, and doubts should be resolved in favor of alienability. Finally, the argument based on stare decisis is also to be found wanting. When changed conditions warrant overruling precedent, the court may do so. Here, since the complaint alleged that 35 F. Pestana had unreasonably withheld approval, a cause of action was stated. NOTES: (1) residential real property leases involve different public policies than commercial real property leases. No state court has acted to create a reasonableness requirement in a case involving only a residential lease. Courts are not precluded that there is such a necessity of reasonable alienation of residential building space that they ought to impose on residential landlords a reasonableness requirement to which they have not agreed. (2) It is never “commercially reasonable” to deny consent to a transfer solely on the basis of personal taste, convenience or sensibility as the court in Kendall puts it. (3) Rule in Dumpor’s Case: would terminate the prohibition against assignment when the landlord consents to an assignment unless he specifically reserves the right to prohibit future assignments The Tenant Who Defaults 1. The Tenant in Possession a. Berg v. Wiley FACTS: Wiley, lessor of commercial property to Berg for the purpose of operating a restaurant thereon, locked Berg out of the premises when Berg delayed making certain remodeling changes to meet health code requirements. HOLDING: The evidence amply supports the jury’s finding that Berg did not abandon or surrender the premises, and the lockout was thus not justified on the ground of abandonment and surrender. AS to self-help procedures employed by landlords to remove defaulting tenants, the common law rule was to permit such removal if accomplished peacefully. Wiley contended that only actual or threatened violence constitutes a nonpeaceable entry. This is not correct. In response to a long-applied policy to discourage landlords from taking the law into their own hands, the modern trend is to dispossess a breaching tenant, and this represents the rule that should be applied here. A landlord may not remove a breaching or defaulting tenant’s 36 b. possessions or bar tenant’s access to the leasehold without resorting to judicial remedies. Wiley’s failure to resort to judicial remedies rendered the lockout wrongful as a matter of law. NOTES: (1) the court’s reasoning would seem to apply to all leases, residential and commercial alike. The reasons that may be states to justify treating residential leases differently are that loss of residence has a greater psychological impact than loss of possession of a place of business, and the need for immediate replacement of commercial space is less vital. Moreover, in the commercial setting, there is more likely to be equal bargaining power between the parties (2) several state courts have invalidated another related self-help remedy- distraint, or distress for rent – on due process grounds. Under the common law remedy of distress for rent, a landlord could seize a defaulting tenant’s property found on the premises and retain it until payment of overdue rent, all without prior hearing. The absence of prior hearing has proved vulnerable to modern courts. Note: Summary Proceedings (1) at one time self-help was a very important remedy for the landlord who sought to recover possession of leased premises, because the only alternative was a cumbersome, time-consuming, common-law procedure called ejectment. (2) A response to the shortcomings of the system began to develop in the 19th century – legislative provisions for summary proceedings. Today every state provides some form of summary proceedings. (3) Summary proceedings are intended to be just what the name implies – a quick and efficient means by which to recover possession and in some jurisdictions rent, after termination of a tenancy. (4) Any matter extrinsic to the issue of possession is normally excluded. 37 (5) The difficulty is that typical summary procedures can be time-consuming and expensive, even if uncontested. c. Note: Landlord’s Remedies in Addition to Eviction 2. The Tenant Who Has Abandoned Possession a. Sommer v. Kridel FACTS: Kridel, the lessee, vacated the apartment which he leased from Sommer, before the end of the lease term. HOLDING: A landlord does have an obligation to make a reasonable effort to mitigate damages when a tenant defaults on a lease. The landlord’s duty to mitigate consists of making reasonable efforts to re-let the apartment. The burden of proof shall be upon the landlord to establish that he used reasonable diligence in attempting to re-let the premises. Among the factors to be considered in determining whether the landlord has exercised reasonable diligence are whether the landlord has offered to show the apartment to any prospective tenants, or whether the availability of the apartment was advertised in local newspapers. Here, despite the availability of a prospective tenant who was ready, willing and able to rent the apartment, Sommer allowed the apartment to lie empty in order to increase the amount of damages. Sommer could have reasonable avoided the damages which accrued by virtue of the apartment lacking a tenant. NOTES: the Restatement offers other justifications than the court in its surprising position against the duty of mitigation: abandonment of property is an invitation to vandalism, and the law should not encourage such conduct by putting a duty of mitigation of damages on the landlord. Surrender: is a term of art that connotes quite neatly a tenant’s offer to end a tenancy. It terminates the lease, provided, of course, that the landlord accepts the tenant’s offer. If he does- if the surrender is effected- this extinguishes the lessee’s liability for future rent but not for accrued rent or for past breaches of other covenants. Although Sommer refers to the no-mitigation rule as the majority rule, according to a 38 G. recent opinion by the Supreme Court of Texas, forty-two states and the D. of C. now hold that landlords have a duty to mitigate damages. Court in Sommer held that the landlord must treat the abandoned premises as “vacant stock” and presumably the landlord must take the same effort to rent the abandoned premises as he makes to rent other vacant units. b. Notes: Landlord’s Remedies and Security Devices (1) rent and damages: the landlord’s right to sue for back rent and damages occasioned by the tenant’s breach of lease obligations is straightforward. If the tenant is in possession, the landlord may also terminate the lease and recover possession. Associated with the doctrine of anticipatory breach (or repudiation) (2) security devices: there is an old saw that the landlord’s best security is judicious selection of tenants. Most landlords want more and they have developed techniques to protect themselves: a. security deposits: the purpose is to protect the landlord in the event a tenant defaults in rent, damage to the premises, or otherwise breaches the lease. In practice the landlord has an incentive to imagine all sorts of reasons why he should be entitled to retain the deposit and with money in hand he has the leverage to permit abuse. b. Other techniques: considerations, bonuses for the execution of the lease, designating the payment as advance rent, or having a liquidated damages clause. Duties, Rights, and Remedies (Especially Regarding the Condition of the Condition of the Leased Premises) - leases give rise to a problem called :moral hazard,” a piece of jargon first used to describe the “tenancy of an insured to relax his efforts to prevent the occurrence of the risk that he has insured against b/c he has shifted the risk to the insurance company.” Once a lease is entered into, the landlord has an incentive to neglect everyday repairs b/c the costs of neglect are borne primarily 39 by tenants. Tenants, in return, have an incentive to neglect maintenance, especially towards the end of the term, b/c the costs of neglect will soon shift to the landlord. 1. Landlord’s Duties; Tenant’s Rights and Remedies - the early common law implied covenants concerning title and possession, but not concerning the condition of the premises. Absent some clause in the lease providing otherwise, the tenant took the premises “as is” and landlords were under no obligation to warrant their fitness. - The process of change began well over a century ago and led to the development of a body of law that was for a long time, very stable. But with the 12960’s there began a period of sweeping reform – most of it concerned with residential tenancies, much of it initiated by courts rather than legislatures. - The reforms have not so much replaced conventional doctrine as riddled it. A given jurisdiction might adopt one new reform and not another. a. Quiet Enjoyment and Constructive Eviction (1) Reste Realty Corp v. Cooper FACTS: After being sued for back rent, Cooper claimed the defense of constructive eviction due to the substantial amount of water in her premises after every rain storm. HOLDING: Ordinarily a covenant of quiet enjoyment is implied in the lease. When there is such a covenant, whether express or implied, and it is breached substantially by the landlord, the doctrine of constructive eviction is available as a remedy for the tenant. An act or omission by the landlord which renders the premises substantially unsuitable for the purposes for which they are leased, or which seriously interferes with the beneficial enjoyment of the premises, is a breach of the covenant of quiet enjoyment and constitutes a constructive eviction of the tenant. Here, there was sufficient interference with the use and enjoyment of the leased premises to justify Cooper’s departure and to relieve her from the obligation to pay rent. NOTES: (1) under the common law, a breach by a landlord gave a tenant a cause of action 40 (2) (3) (4) (5) for damages, but not the right to suspend rent payments or terminate the tenancy. The obligation to pay rent was dependent upon the tenant’s having possession undisturbed by the landlord, however. If the disturbance was so substantial as to amount to eviction, and if the tenant thereafter abandoned the premises, then it is as though the tenant were evicted (the eviction was constructive). And once evicted, of course, the tenant was relieved of the obligation to pay rent. The covenant of quiet enjoyment was initially limited to cases in which the tenant actually ousted physically, but with time it was expanded to include beneficial enjoyment. Without doctrines of quiet enjoyment and constructive eviction, breach of such obligations would ordinarily entitle the tenant only to sue for damages. With the doctrines, the tenant may also abandon if the breach is substantial. Eviction is not necessary to complete the breach. A tenant should be able to stay in possession and sue for damages equal to the difference between the value of the property with and without the breach. The Illegal Lease: The court sketched out the contours of the illegal lease doctrine in a quick series of decisions after Brown v. Southall Realty Company. It does not apply if code violations develop after the making of the lease. Minor technical violations do not render the lease illegal, nor do violations which the landlord had neither actual nor constructive notice. A tenant under the illegal lease is a tenant at sufferance and the landlord is entitled to reasonable rental value of the premises, given their condition. From the tenant’s point of view the chief attraction of the illegal lease is the leverage it provides: the tenant can withhold rent and still stave off the landlord’s 41 inevitable action to evict for nonpayment. b. The Implied Warranty of Habitability (1) Hilder v. St. Peter FACTS: Hilder leased an apartment from St. Peter. During the course of the tenancy various problems with the apartment manifested themselves, including sewage leaks, nonfunctioning toilets, water leaks, failing plaster, and broken locks. These were brought to St. Peter’s attention, but nothing was done. Hilder paid the agreed rent, but after 14 months of renting the premises, she brought an action seeking recovery of rental monies. The trial court awarded damages to Hilder and St. Peter appealed. HOLDING: An implied warranty of habitability exists in residential leases. The old view of leases was that the lessee took the property as he found it. The view was proper in an agrarian society, but in a modern urban setting, this is improper. The modern tenant bargains for viable habitation, and if he receives less, he is not getting that for which he contracts in the lease. For this reason, a rented dwelling which is not habitable amounts to a breach of contract by the lessor, and standard contract damages are available, as well as tort damages therefrom. NOTES: (2) the implied warranty of habitability does not render pointless the doctrines of quiet enjoyment, constructive eviction, and illegal leases considered earlier. First of all, a good handful of jurisdictions have yet to adopt the IWH. Second, the IWH generally does not apply across the board to all residential leases; single family residences might be excluded, for example, or agricultural or long-term leases might be excluded. Third, a majority of jurisdictions has declined to extend the idea to an implied warranty of fitness or suitability for purpose in commercial leases. (3) The standard of IWH and the shortcomings that amount to breaches of the standard, appear to vary among jurisdictions, but the differences 42 are probably more nominal than real when it comes to actual cases. The place has to be uninhabitable in the eyes of a reasonable person. (4) A number of cases agree with Hilder that in the case of a breach, the tenant may avail himself of al of the basic contractual remedies – damages, recession, and reformation. The tenant may withhold rent, retain possession, and have the agreed rent reduced by virtue of the landlord’s breach. There is considerable disagreement about how to calculate the rent reduction or damages. (5) Note: Retaliatory Eviction a. retaliatory eviction by the landlord is forbidden by statute. A fairly common approach is to create a refutable presumption of retaliatory purpose if the landlord seeks to terminate a tenancy, increase rent, or decrease services within some given period after a good faith complaint or other action by a tenant based on the condition of the premises. H. The Problem of Affordable Housing 1. Chicago Board of Realtors, Inc. v. City of Chicago FACTS: Chicago Board of Realtors, a group of property owners, challenged the constitutionality of Chicago’s Residential Landlord and Tenant Ordinance contending that it violated various clauses of the Constitution. POSNER: the majority opinion, although reaching the right opinion, does not go far enough. It makes the rejection of the appeal seem easier than it is by refusing to acknowledge the strong case that can be made for the unreasonableness of the ordinance. While the stated purpose is the promotion of public safety, health, and welfare and the quality of housing in Chicago, it is unlikely that this is the real purpose and it is not the likely effect. Forbidding landlords to charge interest market rates on the late payment of rent could hardly be thought to improve the health, safety, and welfare of Chicagoans, and it may have the opposite effect. The initial consequence of the rule will be to reduce the resources that landlords devote to improve the quality of housing by making the provision of rental housing more costly. Landlords will try to offset 43 the higher cost by raising rents. The ordinance is not in the interest of poor people. The principal beneficiaries will be middle class. 2. Note: the Debate over Landlord-Tenant Reforms 3. Michael H. Schill, Privatizing Federal Low Income Housing Assistance: The Case of Public Housing Chapter 9 – judicial Land-Use Controls: The Law of Nuisance A. Remedies (and some substantive law) 1. Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co. FACTS: A group of land owners (P), complaining of injury to their property from dirt, smoke, and vibration emanating from a neighborhood cement plant (D), brought an action to enjoin the continued operation of the plant and for damages. The trial court held that the plant constituted a nuisance, found substantial damage, but b/c an injunction would shut down the plant’s operation, refused to issue one. Permanent Damages of 185,000 were awarded the group of land owners instead. HOLDING: Damages may be awarded as an alternative to an injunction in nuisance cases. Another alternative would be to grant the injunction but postpone its effect to a specified date in the future to give an opportunity for technical advances to permit the company to eliminate the nuisance. However, there is no assurance that any significant technical improvement would occur. Moreover, the problem is universal, and can only be solved by an industry-wide effort. Permanent damages would themselves be a spur to conduct more research. Future owners of this land would not be able to recover additional damages, since the award is to the land. NOTES: (1) the court denied injunctive relief and did so by “balancing the equities” (2) a court’s injunction need not ban an activity altogether. Indeed, it is quite common for courts to fashion specific orders to fit particular cases. Thus a D might be required to install a certain kind of noise abatement technology or reduce air pollution emissions to a stated level and so forth. 2. Spur Industries, Inc. v. Del E. Web Development Co. FACTS: In 1956, D predecessors in interest developed feedlots in an are some 15 miles west of 44 the urban area of Phoenix. In May 1959, P began to plan the development of an urban retirement area known as Sun city, by purchasing 20,000 acres of farmland near Spurs feedlots. In 1960, D purchased the property in question and began a rebuilding and expansion program extending to the north and the south of the original feedlot facilities. Homes were first offered for sale by Web in 1960, when odors from Spur feedlot were not considered to be a problem. In December 1967, Web filed suit, complaining that in excess of 1,000 in its development were unfit for sale b/c of the operation of the Spur feedlot. Web alleged that the Spur feeding operation was a public nuisance b/c of the flies and odor which were drifting over Sun City. The trial court permanently enjoined Spur from operating a cattle feedlot near Sun City and Spur appealed. HOLDING: Spur’s operation was enjoinable as a public nuisance as far as the people in the southern portion of Webb’s sun City were concerned. Spur’s operation, which constituted a breeding place for flies, was a public nuisance dangerous to the public health, and Webb, having shown a special injury in the loss of sales, has standing to bring suit to enjoin the nuisance. However, there was no indication here at the time Spur and its predecessors located in the area that a new city would spring up, full-blown, alongside the feeding operation and that the developer of that city would ask the court to order Spur to move b/c of the new city. Spur is required to move not b/c he is wrong, but b/c of the proper and legitimate regard of the courts for the rights and interests of the public. Having brought people to the nuisance to the foreseeable detriment of Spur, Webb must indemnify Spur for a reasonable amount of the cost of moving or shutting down. Affirmed in part and reversed in part, remanded for further proceedings. NOTES: (1) A public nuisance, according to the Restatement “is an unreasonable interference with a right common to the general public"; whether the conduct in question significantly interferes with public health, safety, peace, or convenience; whether the conduct is proscribed by statute or ordinance; whether 45 the conduct is of a continuing nature or has produced a permanent or long-lasting effect are all things for the court to consider. There must be a substantial harm caused by the intentional and unreasonable conduct or by conduct that is negligent, reckless, or abnormally dangerous. (2) The difference between public and private nuisance is in the interests of those that are protected: public nuisance protects public rights; private nuisance protects rights in the use and enjoyment of the land. (3) The distinction between private and public nuisance can be important in several respects. First, since a private nuisance arises from interference with the use and enjoyment of the land, only owners of interests in land can bring suit. Second, since a public nuisance arises from interference with public rights, any member of the affected public can sue, but usually only if the person bringing suit can show special injury. (4) The Restatement’s objective is to leave courts free to proceed with recent developments expanding citizen access to the courts. (5) The prevailing view is that moving into the vicinity of a nuisance does not completely bar a suit for damages or injunctive relief but it is a relevant factor for the court to consider. (6) A conventional view of long standing held that nuisance claims could be resolved in one of these three ways: abate the activity in question by granting the P injunctive relief; let the activity continue if the D pays damages (Boomer); or let the activity continue by denying all relief. Spur adds a new possibility: abate the activity of the P pays damages. The court in Spur, it appears, developed the rule out of logic 3. Note: Nuisance Law and Environmental Controls a. nuisance law has an obvious bearing on environmental problems – pollution, for example, interferes with the use and enjoyment of the land as well as with public rights and thus, seems a natural target for control as a nuisance. 46 b. That the law of nuisance has a place in environmental control seems clear, but there are a number of reasons to conclude that its contributions must be limited ones. Nuisance litigation is an expensive, cumbersome, and somewhat fortuitous means for resolving modern environmental problems, typified as they are by continuing and multiple causes, widespread effects and multiple victims, and scientifically complex issues as to cause, effect, and remedy. There are weak incentives to bring expensive lawsuits. c. Judgments are better left to politically accountable government branches. d. A regulatory program typically proceeds by prohibiting certain activities, requiring installation of prescribed technologies, and setting standards limiting emissions from pollution sources. Incentive systems stand in sharp contrast. Rather than command, they induce. A variant – marketable or transferable rights- sets a fixed number of pollution rights, distributes them by one means or another and then permits trading in the rights thereafter. Incentive systems encourage more technological innovation than does regulation. e. While regulation remains the dominant approach to environmental problems in the US, incentive systems have made substantial inroads that may prove to be of enormous significance. Chapter 10 – Private Land-Use Controls: The Law of Servitudes - usually, but not always, the agreements involve two or more parcels of land and the purpose of the agreement is to increase the total value of all of the parcels involved. Usually, but not always, the effect of the agreement is to burden one parcel of the land for the benefit of the other - these agreements create interests in land, binding and benefiting not only the parties to the agreement in question, but also their successors. These interests are commonly called servitude’s. Modern servitude’s can be divided into two major types: easements and covenants. A. Easements 1. Historical Background 47 2. Creation of Easements- an easement, being an interest in land, is within the Statute of Frauds (so too for profits). Creation of an easement generally requires a written instrument signed by the party to be bound thereby. However, in addition to the usual exceptions of fraud, past performance, and estoppel, an easement may, under certain circumstances, be created by implication or by prescription. a. Willard v. First Church of Christ Scientist FACTS: Although when Peterson bought a lot from McGuigan, the deed reserved an easement on the lot for the use of the Church, Peterson then sold the lot to Willards without the easement. HOLDING: contrary to the ancient common law rule, modernly, a grantor, in deeding property to one person, may effectively reserve and vest an interest in the same property in a third party. Today, courts primarily try to give effect to the grantor’s intent, whereas the common law rule would defeat that intent. Also, it must be recognized that due to the encumbrance on the property, the grantee paid a reduced price for it. Therefore, it would be inequitable to allow him to remove the third party’s interest, thereby greatly increasing the property’s value. The determination of whether the common law rule should still be used involves a balancing of equitable and policy requirements. NOTES: (1) Restatement third of Property provides that an easement can be created in favor of a third party, but contrary authority in a number of states is cited. (2) The court holds that an easement can be reserved in favor of a third party but states in footnote 8 that an easement cannot be excepted in favor of a third party. (3) A reservation is a provision in a deed creating some new servitude which did not exist before as an independent interest. (4) An exception is a provision in a deed that excludes from the grant some pre-existing servitude on the land. (5) English courts ultimately found a way around English common-law holdings that stated that easements could not be reserved b/c it did 48 not issue out the land granted. They held that an easement “reserved” by the grantor was not a reservation at all, but a re-grant of an easement by the grantee to the grantor. Because the reserved easement theoretically involved a re-grant by the grantee, the Statute of Frauds required the deed to be signed by the grantee as well as by the grantor. American courts held that the grantee had, by accepting the deed, made it her own and adopted the seal and signature of the grantor. (6) An easement appurtenant benefits the owner of the easement in the use of the land belonging to the owner. It attaches to the dominant tenement and goes with it to successive owners. (7) An easement in gross does not benefit the owner of the easement in the use of the land belonging to the owner, but benefits the owner without regard to the ownership of the land. b. Licenses: (1) an easement must be distinguished from a license. A license is permission given by the occupant of the land allowing the licensee to do some act that otherwise would be a trespass. (2) The privilege to use the land resembles an easement, but the license is revocable whereas the easement is not (3) Two distinct exceptions to the rule that a license is revocable: First, a license coupled with an interest cannot be revoked. Second, a license that becomes irrevocable under the rules of estoppel. A license that cannot be revoked is something very akin to an easement. c. Holbrook v. Taylor FACTS: Taylor used a road which ran across Holbrook’s property. HOLDING: A right to the use of a roadway over the lands of another may be established by estoppel. One may acquire a license to use a roadway where, with the permission of a licensor, the licensee makes substantial expenditures, erects improvements, or uses it for other 49 d. purposes in reliance on the licensor’s grant of permission. Under these conditions, the license becomes in reality a grant through estoppel, and it becomes irrevocable and continues for so long a time as the nature of the license calls for. Here, the use of the roadway by Taylor in constructing Taylor’s home, the improvements made to the roadway, the maintenance of the roadway, and the construction by Taylor of a residence, all with the actual consent of Holbrook, indicated that the license to the use of the roadway may not be revoked. Van Sandt v. Royster FACTS: Van Sandt found his cellar flooded with sewage and discovered for the first time the existence of a sewer drain across his property. Royster and Gray refuse to stop using the drain. HOLDING: whether there is an implied easement on certain property will be implied from the intentions of the parties, and such inference will be drawn from the circumstances under which the conveyance was made. Parties to a conveyance will be assumed to know and contemplate the continuance of reasonably necessary uses which have so altered the premises as to make them apparent upon reasonably prudent investigation. ****When one utilizes part of his land for the benefit of another, a quasi-easement exists. The part of the land being benefited is referred to as the quasi-dominant tenement, and the part being utilized is referred to as the quasiservient tenement. If the owner of the land, one part of which is subject to quasi-easement, conveys the quasi-dominant tenement, and easement corresponding to such quasi-easement is vested in the grantee, provided such quasi-easement is apparent and continuous. An implied easement, in favor of either the grantor or the grantee arises as an inference of the intentions of the parties. This inference is drawn from the circumstances under which the conveyance is made. Factors to consider include whether the claimant is the grantee or grantor, the terms of the conveyance, the consideration given, the extent of the necessity of the easement and the extent to which the use was or might have been known to the parties. Where the land may be used without an 50 e. easement, but cannot be used without disproportionate effort and expense, an easement may be implied on the basis of necessity alone. NOTES: (1) the law does not favor implied easements since they are in derogation of the rule that written instruments speak for themselves. They also retard building and improvements and violate the policy of recording acts. Othen v. Rosier FACTS: Othen and Rosier own tracts of land that were formerly a part of one larger parcel. In order to reach any public highways, Othen must cross over someone else’s property. Othen had used a road which ran across Rosier’s property, which Rosier kept in repair. As a result of encroaching surface waters, Rosier erected a levee on his property, which made the road so muddy that for weeks at a time it was impassible except by horseback. Othen filed a suit for injunctive and declaratory relief, and for damages. The trial court found that Othen had acquired an easement of necessity. HOLDING: Before an implied easement by necessity can be held to be created, it must be shown that there was a unity of ownership of the alleged dominant and servient estates; that the roadway is a necessity and not a mere convenience; and that the necessity existed at the time of severance of the two estates. Here, there was unity of ownership of the lands now owned by Rosier and Othen. However no easement may be implied for the road b/c the original owner did not reserve such an easement when he first sold the property now owned by Rosier. The record does not indicate that the roadway was a necessity as of the date of the original grant deed, rather than a mere convenience. Othen has additionally not acquired an easement by prescription, b/c his use of the road was not under claim of right. Othen’s use of the roadway was merely permissive and therefore constituted only a license, which could not and did not ripen into a prescriptive right. NOTES: 51 - - - - - - (1) several states have attempted to solve the problems posed by landlocked property through statutory provisions providing for condemnation of private ways. While the statutory provisions vary from state to state, all jurisdictions require payment to be made for the land taken by the owner of the benefited property. The degree of necessity required for condemnation also varies; some states require a showing of strict necessity; while others only require that the necessity be reasonable under all of the circumstances. f. Easement by Necessity In the early English cases, it was said that one who grants a thing must be understood to have granted that without which the granted thing cannot exist. By the seventeenth century, an easement by necessity came to be supported by a public policy that no land be made inaccessible. The easement by necessity was said to carry out the presumed intent of the parties. In most cases, it does not matter which justification is given, but if the parties expressly provide that no way of necessity exists, the court must decide whether such a provision is valid. There is some conflict in the cases over the degree of necessity required for an easement by necessity. Most courts, like the court in Othen, required strict necessity, but some have granted an easement by necessity where access to the land exists but is claimed to inadequate, difficult or costly. An easement by necessity endures only so long as it is necessary. If the dominant owner secures another way out from the landlocked parcel, the easement by necessity ceases. In some states, mainly in the West, statutes give an owner of landlocked land the right to condemn an easement across neighboring land upon showing the requisite necessity. The condemnation is a judicial proceeding, and the landowner must pay damages to the owner of the land. Under these statutes, it does not matter how the landlocking occurred; prior common ownership of the dominant and servient estates is not required. g. Easement by Prescription easements may be acquired by prescription, which in many ways is similar to adverse possession but in 52 - - - - - - some ways distinctly different. Adverse possession involves a statute of limitations running on a right to bring an action to recover possession of the land; the statute operates to extinguish the remedy of the previous owner, leaving the adverse possessor in indefeasible possession. A statute of limitations upon the recovery of possession does not cover actions concerning easements, which involves use and not possession of land. Inasmuch as legislatures enacted no legislation to protect ancient easements, courts developed the doctrine of prescription. Prescription rests upon the idea that rights can be acquired simply by a passage of time. In 1189, American courts rejected the theory that prescriptive easements rest upon use from time immemorial. They developed the law of prescription, applying by analogy the statute of limitation relating to the recovery of possession. Generally required the same manner of use as is required for adverse possession: open and notorious, continuous, adverse, and under claim of right. Once the prescriptive easements were put on the same basis as adverse possession, the lost grant theory should have been seen as irrelevant. Under the lost grant theory, the owner of the land is presumed to consent or acquiesce in the use; after all, the owner is thought to have granted the easement. On the other hand, if the use is made with the permission of the owner, the use is not adverse. To secure a prescriptive easement under the lost grant theory, the claimant must show that the use was not permissive and also that the owner acquiesced. In a jurisdiction not following the fiction of the lost grant, to prevent a prescriptive easement from being acquired, the owner must effectively interrupt or stop the adverse use. In order to gain title by adverse possession, a person must show exclusive possession for the required period. The majority of courts requires exclusive use for the prescription, but defines it differently from the adverse possession requirement. Exclusivity does not require a showing that only the claimant made use of the way, but that the claimant’s right to use the land does not depend on a like right in others. 53 In most states, a public prescriptive easement can be obtained only by long continuous use by the public under a claim of right. The landowner must be put on notice, by the kind and extent of the use, that an adverse right is being claimed by the public, not by individuals. Some courts use the theory of implied dedication, rather than prescription, for public easements. 3. Assignability of Easements- the benefits and burdens of appurtenant easements pass automatically to assignees of the land to which they are appurtenant. Where the benefit is in gross, however, the easement may not be assignable. a. Miller v. Lutheran Conference & Camp Association FACTS: Miller sought to prevent the Association from using the lake for swimming or boating. HOLDING: The deed from 1899 from the Pocono Springs Water Ice Company to Frank Miller clearly did not convey any bathing rights. However, Frank did establish title to bathing rights by prescription b/c the rights were used systematically for commercial purposes. An adverse enjoyment of an easement in gross may ripen into title thereto by prescription; and therefore Miller and Miller acquired title by prescription. Further, Frank made a valid assignment of one-fourth interest in all rights to Rufus. The rights of fishing and boating were conveyed to Frank thus showing that the grantor company intended to attach the attribute of assignability to the privilege granted. However, even though easements may be divided amongst different title holders, the easements must be used or exercised as an entirety. They cannot be commercially used and licenses thereunder cannot be granted without common consent and joinder of the Millers, who own a portion of the easement. It follows that the estate of Rufus did not have the right, by themselves, to grant a license to the association. NOTES: (1) the modern trend rejects the old notion that the benefit of the easement in gross was not assignable. The Restatement view is that easements in gross, if of a commercial character, are alienable property interests. Commercial characters is defined as when the - 54 use authorized by it results in economic benefit rather than personal satisfaction. (2) When an easement is appurtenant, the burden on the servient tenement is limited by the needs of the dominant tenement. An easement in gross has no such limitation, therefore, American courts have attempted to prevent the burden on the servient tenement from increasing beyond what was intended by the original parties. (3) More recent cases permit any easement in gross to be assignable if the parties so intended. About the only easements that are not assignable under the modern cases are recreational easements. (4) Restatement Third of Property provides that easements in gross may be divided unless contrary to the intent of the parties creating the easement or unless the division unreasonably increases the burden on the servient estate. 4. Scope of Easements a. Brown v. Voss FACTS: the court of appeals held that an easement granted for the benefit of the dominant estate could be used for two dominant estates where no increased burden to the servient estate is shown. The servient tenement appeals. HOLDING: if an easement is appurtenant to a particular parcel of land, any extension thereof to other parcels is a misuse of the easement, unless the use does not overburden the easement. The easement received no greater use as a result of Brown’s acquisition, and thus the injunction was correctly denied. NOTES: (1) this case illustrates that while the law of easements can be traced back to the common law, it is subject to judicial interpretation. Here, the reasonableness of the development, in the eyes of the court, served as a basis for denying the injunction. (2) The manner, frequency, and intensity of the beneficiary’s use of the servient estate may change over time to take advantage of developments in technology and to 55 accommodate normal development of he dominant estate or enterprise benefited by the servitude. (3) A private easement of way does not usually permit the easement owner to install on the easement aboveground or underground utilities, such as electrical lines and sewer pipes. Most courts hold such uses are not reasonably foreseeable by the parties. Such courts view the purpose of the easement of way as an entrance and exit of people and vehicles. (4) The general rule is that the location of the easement, once fixed by the parties, cannot be changed by the servient owner without permission of the dominant owner. (5) A prescriptive easement is not as broad in scope as an easement created by grant, by implication, or by necessity. Although the uses of a prescriptive easement are not confined to the actual uses made during the prescriptive period, the uses made of a prescriptive easement must be consistent with the general kinds of uses by which the easement was created and with what the servient owner might reasonably expect to lose by failing to interrupt the adverse use. 5. Termination of Easements a. Presault v. US FACTS: RR track on the P property was turned into a bike path and P sued. HOLDING: whether, at the time a RR applies to abandon its use of an easement limited to R purposes, a taking occurs under an ICC order to “railbank” the easement for possible future RR use, and allowing in the interim for use of the easement for trail purposes, is a question not now before us. Occupation was a taking an requires compensation. 6. Negative Easement - the right of the dominant owner to stop the servient owner from doing something on that servient land. - English courts recognized four types: the right to stop your neighbor from blocking your windows, interfering with the air flowing to your land in a defined channel, removing the support of your 56 building, and interfering with the flow of water in an artificial stream. - Judges were not disposed to permit the creation of new types of easements, negative easements in particular - Traditional negative easements could arise by prescription in England... American courts have held that negative easements cannot be acquired by prescription. - In all American courts, a recording system existed to protect purchasers against unrecorded claims - American courts accepted the English restrictions on creating new types of easements. Nonetheless, the list of four is not necessarily closed in the US. B. Covenants Running With the Land 1. Historical Background a. Covenants Enforceable at Law: Real Covenants - thwarted by the law courts’ refusal to recognize new types of negative easements, landowners turned, to the law of contracts. - Bargaining among neighbors can serve to minimize the harmful impacts (external costs) that arise from conflicting resource uses. - Where there is privity of estate, judges held, the contract is enforceable against assignees. - Spencer’s case laid down three propositions about the running of the burden of covenants: (1) a covenant relating to something not in esse will not bind assignees of the covenantor unless the covenantor expressly agrees to bind successors. (2) For the burden of a covenant to run, it must touch and concern the land (3) Must be privity of estate for a covenant to run - In England, the courts decided that privity of estate, required for the burden of a covenant to run at law to successors, was satisfied only by a landlord-tenant relationship. - American courts developed the real covenant, a promise respecting the use of the land that runs with the land at law. - Horizontal privity- privity between the original parties - Vertical privity- privity between promisee or promisor and an assignee 57 - - - - The question of whether a covenant runs arises only when a person who is not a party to the covenant is suing or being sued. Test for the running of a burden is traditionally more onerous than a test for the running of a benefit. Restatement declared that there must be either a mutual or successive relationship between the promisor and the promisee for the burden of a covenant to run at law. Went on to say that horizontal privity is not required for a benefit to run. Privity requirement, though, continues to exist in many states and it is often unclear whether the courts are referring to horizontal or vertical privity. b. Covenants Enforceable at Equity: Equitable Servitudes i. Tulk v. Moxhay FACTS: Moxhay indicated an intention to build upon an open ground, even though he was aware of an original prohibitive covenant passed on by Tulk, 40 years earlier, which forbade any construction on the ground HOLDING: Privity of estate notwithstanding, a person who acquires real property with notice of a restriction placed upon it will not be allowed, in equity, to violate its terms. To hold otherwise would make it impossible for a land owner to sell part of it without running the risk of seeing the part he retained rendered worthless. At issue is not whether the covenant “runs” with the land, but whether a party may violate a contract entered into by his vendor by using the land in a inconsistent manner. If there was a mere agreement and no covenant, a court would enforce it against a party purchasing with notice; so long as an equity is attached by an owner, no one purchasing with notice can stand in a different situation than the original purchaser. NOTES: (1) in 1881, it was settled that in England only negative covenants were enforceable as equitable servitudes. 58 (2) Equitable servitude is a covenant respecting the use of the land enforceable against successor owners or possessors in equity regardless of its enforceability at law. Equity requires that the parties intend the promise to run, that a subsequent purchaser have actual or constructive notice of the covenant and that the covenant touch and concern the land (3) Most recent cases support the property theory that equitable servitudes are negative easements. Facilitates the holding that, after the original promisor has conveyed the burdened land, the promisor cannot be sued on the covenant in law or in equity. The original promisor has lost control of the land when she assigns her entire interest and it would be unfair to penalize her for the conduct of some future owner. (4) Even though an equitable servitude is a property interest, it arises out of a contract and many contract doctrines are applicable to it. 2. Creation of Covenants- a real covenant must be created by a written instrument signed by the covenantor. It is an interest in land within the meaning of the Statute of Frauds. A real covenant cannot arise by estoppel, implication, or prescription, as can an easement. a. Sanborn v. McLean b: Sanborn and McLean trace the titles to their adjoining lots to the proprietor of the subdivision. Residences are built on all of the surrounding lots. Sanborn objected to McLean’s erection of a gas station on her lot. HOLDING: the doctrine of reciprocal negative easements makes restrictions which are of benefit to the land retained mutual so that the owner can do nothing upon the land he has retained that is forbidden to the owner of the lot sold. In this case, McLaughlin deeded lots with the restriction that only residences be built upon them. Such restrictions were imposed for the benefit of the lands retained by McLaughlin to carry out the scheme of a residential district, and a restrictive negative easement attached to the 59 b. lots retained. Since his was one of the lots retained in the December 1892 and July 1893 deeds, a reciprocal negative easement attached to the lot which later became McLean’s. Reciprocal negative easements are not personal to owners but are operative upon use of the land by any owner having actual or constructive notice thereof. In this case the reciprocal negative easement attached to McLean’s lot may now be enforced by Sanborn provided that had constructive knowledge of the easement at the time of purchase. At the time of purchase, McLean had an abstract title showing the subdivision and the 97 companion lots adjacent to his lot. He could not have avoided noticing the strictly uniform residence character of the companion lots and the least inquiry would have revealed the fact that his lot was subject to a reciprocal negative easement. NOTES: (1) reciprocal negative easements must start with common owners. They cannot arise and fasten upon one lot by reason of other owners conforming to a general plan. Such easements are never retroactive and as demonstrated here, they pass their benefits and carry their obligations to all purchasers of land provide that the purchaser has constructive notice of the easement. Neponsit Property Owners’ Association v. Immigrant Industrial Savings Bank FACTS: Neponist conveyed the land now owned by the Bank to Deyer and wife by deed. That original deed contained a covenant providing: (1) that the conveyed land should be subject to an annual charge for improvements upon the entire residential tact then being developed (2) that such charge should be a lien (3) such charge should be payable by all subsequent purchasers to the company or its assigns, including the property owners association which might thereafter be organized (4) and such covenant runs with the land. Neponsit brought an action based upon the above covenant to foreclose a lien upon the land which the Bank now owns, having purchased it at a judicial sale. The bank 60 appealed from an order denying their motion for judgment on the pleadings HOLDING: a covenant will run with the land and will be enforceable against a subsequent purchaser if: (1) the grantor and the grantee intend that the covenant will run with the land; (2) the covenant touches or concerns the land with which it runs; (3) there is privity of estate between the party claiming the benefit of the covenant and the party who rests under the burden of the covenant. In the instant case the grantor and the grantee manifested their intent that the covenant run with the land by so stating in the original deed. The covenant touches or concerns the land in substance no in form (i.e.: the covenant alters the legal rights of ownership of the land) by providing that the burden of paying the cost of maintaining the public improvements is inseparably attached to the land which enjoys the benefits of such improvements. the concept of privity of estate between the parties usually requires that the party claiming benefit from the enforcement of a covenant own the property which benefits from such enforcement. Although Neponsit, the corporation, does not own the property which would benefit from the enforcement, the corporation is acting as the agent of the property owners and should therefore be considered in privity in substance if not in form. Since the covenant complies with the legal requirements for one which runs with the land and is enforceable against subsequent purchasers, the order which denied the Bank’s motion for judgment on the pleadings is affirmed. c. Restatement Third of Property, Servitudes: Modification or Termination of Certain Affirmative Covenants - a covenant to pay money or provide services terminates after a reasonable time if the instrument that created the covenant does not specify the total sum due or a definite termination point - a covenant to pay money or provide services in exchange for services or facilities provided to the burdened estate may be modified or terminated if the obligation becomes excessive in relation to the cost of providing services or facilities or to the value received by the burdened estate 61 d. Caullet v. Stanley Stilwell & Sons, Inc. FACTS: Stilwell, a developer, contended that it had an enforceable covenant restricting the use of Caullet’s land. HOLDING: Restriction on the use of r5oprety will not be enforced unless their meaning is clear and free from doubt. Here, the provision is unenforceable b/c it is descriptive of neither the type of structure to be built, the cost of the structure, or the duration of Caullet’s obligation. Further, the provision does not satisfy the primary requirement of covenants directly restrictive of tittle to land: that they touch and concern the subject property. To qualify as a covenant properly affecting the property, the deed provision must define in some measurable and reasonably permanent fashion the proscriptions of and limitation on the uses to which the premises may be put. Here, the provision is a personal arrangement which is designed to insure Stilwell a profit on the erection of a dwelling on the land. Where, as here, the burden is placed on the land, and the benefit is personal to one of the parties and does not extend to his or other lands, the burden is generally held not to run with the land. NOTES: (1) English common law courts held that only negative covenants, to the exclusion of a affirmative covenants, were enforceable as equitable servitudes. This was because those courts treated equitable servitudes as equitable interests analogous to negative easements. Thus, only restrictive covenants were accorded status as equitable servitudes. e. Note: Defeasible Fees as Land Use Control Devices - defeasible fees may be employed to control land use. A defeasible fee differs from a servitude in that the remedy for its breach is forfeiture, whereas the remedy for a breach of a servitude is damages, injunction or enforcement of a lien. - Infrequently used today to control land use except as gifts for charitable purposes 3. Scope of Covenants a. Hill v. Community of Damien Molokai 62 FACTS: Hill seeks to enjoin the further use of a property in his neighborhood as a group home for individuals with AIDS. Neighborhood covenant provides that no lot shall ever be used for any purpose other than single family residence purposes. HOLDING: the community is entitled to continue operating its group home for individuals with AIDS both under the Four Hills restrictive covenants and under the Fair Housing act. Accordingly, the trial court’s ruling is reversed and the injunction is vacated. NOTES: (1) what constitutes a “single family” for the purpose of restrictive covenants has been the subject of considerable litigation when a group home is involved. b. Shelley v. Kraemer FACTS: In the first case, Kraemer, owner of property subject to a covenant restricting sales to white sonly sued to prevent Shelley, an African American, from taking possession of a neighboring house in violation of the covenant. In the second case, owners of a property subject to a similar restrictive covenant sued to enjoin a husband and wife, also African Americans, from occupying the house they had purchased. HOLDING: judicial enforcement of racially restrictive covenants constitutes impermissible state action in support of racial discrimination. NOTES: (1) a covenant with a racially discriminatory effect may violate the federal Fair housing Act, enacted as Title VIII of the Civil Rights act of 1968. This act makes it unlawful to refuse to sell or rent or otherwise make unavailable a dwelling to any person b/c of race, color, religion, sex, national origin, familial status, or handicap. Also prohibits the publishing or printing of any statement indicating a racial, religious, or ethnic preference with respect to the buyer of a dwelling. 4. Termination of Covenants a. Western Land company v. Truskolaski FACTS: Western Land wanted to build a shopping center near property owned by Truskolaski, who 63 argues that such construction would violate a restrictive covenant. HOLDING: A restrictive covenant is enforceable so long as its provisions remain of substantial value (can be accomplished and there is still a benefit by enforcement) NOTES: (1) several states have now enacted statutes which terminate restrictive covenants or limit their application by requiring that they be rerecorded after a specified period of time. Perhaps typical of the duration to be accorded these covenants are provisions contained in the statutes of Georgia (20 years) and Massachusetts (30 years). In a few states, restrictive covenants will not be enforced is the covenant carries no substantial benefit, or where there has been substantial compliance for a reasonable period of time. b. Rick v. West FACTS: West, owner of a half-acre lot in a residential subdivision, refused to consent to a release of a covenant in her favor restricting the lots to single-family dwellings, thereby frustrating Rick’s plans to construct a hospital in the subdivision. HOLDING: courts will not engage in balancing of equities but will enforce restrictive covenants unless there is a substantial change of conditions in the general neighborhood. West had a right to continue to rely on the covenant. NOTES: (1) Massachusetts has a statute which requires that a person seeking to enforce the servitude show that the restriction actually benefits her. However, damages are the only remedy that will be rewarded is there have been changes in the neighborhood which reduce the need for restriction, or if continuation of the restriction would impede reasonable use of the land for purposes for which it is most suitable or would impair the growth of the neighborhood. 5. Common Interest Communities - the condominium form: very popular b/c of the rising costs of single family homes, the availability of shared amenities at a lower cost, the tax subsidy to the owner-occupied housing, the 64 increasing affluence of apartment dwellers permitting a greater proportion to invest in equity ownership, the belief that real estate is an inflation proof investment, - each condo unit is owned separately in fee simple by an individual owner. The exterior walls, the land beneath, the hallways, and other common areas are owned by the unit landowners as tenants in common. Can be adapted to residential or commercial use. - For a condo, the declaration of condominium must be filed before the first sale is made, will provide for an association of unit owners to make and enforce rules, to manage the common areas, and to set maintenance charges levied against unit owners. a. Nahrstedt v. Lakeside Village Condominium FACTS: P kept her three cats in her condominium in violation of the CC&Rs, prompting D to assess penalties against her increasingly large amounts. HOLDING: the courts should leave the enforcement of covenants and restrictions to homeowners associations unless constitutional principles are at stake, enforcement is arbitrary, it imposes burdens on the use of the lands it affects that substantially outweigh the restriction’s benefits to the developments residents, or violates a public policy. Individual unit owners must relinquish a degree of freedom of choice that they might have otherwise enjoyed in order to promote health and happiness of the majority of the unit owners. The reasonableness and unreasonableness of a condo use restriction that the legislature has made subject to section 1354 is to be determined not by reference to facts that are specific to the objecting homeowner, but by reference to the common interest development as a whole. NOTES: (1) The Restatement draws a distinction between direct restraints on alienation of property and indirect restraints. Direct restraints are valid if “reasonable.” Direct restraints clearly interfere with the operation of the free market economy. Common types of these restraints include prohibitions on transfer without the consent of the Association, rights of first refusal, and requirements that transfers be made only 65 to persons meeting certain eligibility requirements. (2) In direct restraints are invalid only if lacking in rational justification, a less demanding requirement. In direct restraints include use restrictions or other restrictions such as pet, paint color, etc, that limit the potential market for the property. (3) Restatement draws a distinction between regulations included in the deeds or declaration of the common interest development and the regulations subsequently adopted by property owners associations for community governance. A reasonableness standard is applied to the latter (4) The new Restatement sets the standard of reasonableness: determining reasonableness requires balancing the utility of the purpose served by the restraint against the harm likely to flow from its enforcement (5) Business judgment rule: prohibits judicial inquiry into actions of corporate directors taken in good faith and in the exercise of an honest judgement in the lawful furtherance of corporate purposes. Chapter 11: Legislative Land Use Controls: the Law of Zoning A. Introduction: 1. Historical Background - from the end of the civil war to the beginning of the twentieth century, city life changed more dramatically than at any time since the founding of the republic. - Ideological roots are traceable to Ebenezer Howard. Proposed resettling people in new towns in the country where they would have ample space to live healthy and useful lives. Uses of land would be separated so one would not harm another. - At the core of Howard’s scheme was wholesome housing, each house with a small garden and set apart from its neighbors to provide light, and air and be protected from incompatible uses. The Garden City would evolve into homogenous cities. - American city planners were interested in the principles underlying Howard’s ideal community and turned them into the foundation for the modern city 66 planning: (1) separation of uses; (2) protection of the single family home; (3) low rise development; and (4) medium density population - Frank Lloyd Wright envisioned the city of the future as the extended city based on the automobile and alternating urban and agrarian uses. - Burnham helped fire up the beautiful city movement – to beautify cities with great civic monuments and public works. Within 20 years the movement ran out of steam. - LeCorbusier made observation that the Garden city took up too much land... proposed the vertical Garden City... Radiant City. - Zoning laws spread rapidly in the early 1900s – especially after the appearance of the Standard State Enabling Act of 1922. With the spread of zoning ordinances came constitutional attacks – assertions that the new controls effected takings of property without compensation or worked deprivations of property without due process of law. 2. Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co. FACTS: Euclid zoned property of Amber Realty in a manner which materially reduced its potential value. HOLDING: A zoning ordinance, as a valid exercise of the police power will only be declared unconstitutional where its provisions are clearly arbitrary and unreasonable, having no substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare. Zoning ordinances, and all similar laws and regulations, must find their justification in some aspect of the police power, asserted for the public welfare. Until recent years, urban life was comparatively simple; but with the general increase and concentration of population, problems have developed which require new restrictions on the use and occupation of private lands in urban communities. There is no serious difference of opinion on the state power to avoid the nuisances which industry may cause in a residential area. As for residential regulation, many considerations point toward their validity. Segregation of residential business and industrial building makes it easier to provide appropriate fire apparatus, for example. Further, it is often observed that the construction of one type of building destroys an area for other types. In 67 light of these considerations, the court is not prepared to say that the end of public welfare here is not sufficient to justify the imposition of this ordinance. It clearly cannot be said that it “passes the bounds of reason and assumes the character of a merely arbitrary fiat.” The decree must be reversed. No injunction may be had. NOTES: (1) landmark supreme Court decision on zoning ordinances as valid exercises of police power. Essentially, any zoning ordinance which is tied to public health, safety, morals, or welfare will be upheld unless clearly arbitrary or unreasonable. So –called Euclidean Zoning, which resulted from this decision, usually consists in the division of areas into zones, in which building use, height and area are regulated in a manner designed to guarantee homogeneity of building patterns. All too often, however, zoning operates not so much to protect the public as to protect the vested interests in a community. Building restrictions may all too easily be used as an economic sanction by which social segregation is perpetuated. (2) Under Euclidean Zoning the uses permitted in each district are cumulative; higher uses are permitted in areas zoned for lower uses but not vice versa. In an attempt to preserve large tracts for future industrial use, improving the fiscal base, some cities have turned to non-cumulative zoning, prohibiting houses and commerce in industrial zones. (3) Zoning ordinances are routinely upheld in the face of takings allegations, especially if they are controlling nuisance-like conditions or so long as they leave the property owner with some reasonable use. (4) Supreme court held zoning in general to be constitutional, but added that concrete applications of specific provisions could prove to be arbitrary and unreasonable. (5) Today, zoning is virtually universal in the metropolitan areas of the US 3. The structure of Authority underlying zoning a. enabling legislation 68 all states have adopted enabling acts that delegate zoning authority to local governments. - Standard Zoning Enabling Act was adopted at one time or another in all fifty states and is till in effect in many of them. b. The comprehensive plan - a comprehensive plan is a statement of the local government’s objectives and standards for development. - Plan is based on surveys and studies of the cities present situation and future needs, the idea being to anticipate changes and promote harmonious development - Courts don’t take the requirement too seriously... the plan need not be written down, for many courts, separate from the zoning ordinance itself. - The emphasis has always been whether the zoning ordinance is a comprehensive plan, not whether it is in accordance with such a plan. Little more has been required than that zoning be reasonable and impartial. B. The Nonconforming Use 1. PA Northwestern Distributors, Inc. v. Zoning Hearing Board FACTS: three weeks after P opened an adult book store in Moon Township, the Board of Supervisors adopted an ordinance restricting permissible locations for book stores and allowing only 90 days for nonconforming uses to either comply or shut down. HOLDING: A zoning ordinance which requires the amortization and discontinuance of a lawful preexisting nonconforming use is confiscatory and violative of the state constitution as a taking of property without just compensation. Contrary to the appellate court’s interpretation, Sullivan is not a correct statement of the Penn law regarding amortization provisions. The usual presumption of a zoning ordinance’s validity must be tempered by the fact that the zoning involves a governmental restriction on a property owner’s constitutionally guaranteed right to use his property , except where the use violates a law or creates a nuisance. Municipalities lack the power to compel change in the nature of an existing lawful use of property. A lawful non-conforming use established in the property owner a vested property right which cannot - 69 be abrogated or destroyed. A taking under the Penn constitution is not limited to actual possession or seizure of the property. If the effect of the zoning law is to deprive an owner of the lawful use of his property, it amount to a taking for which he must be compensated. In this case, the amortization ordinance deprived P of the lawful use of its property b/c it forced it to cease using its property as an adult book store within 90 days. Therefore, the amortization provision was unconstitutional on its face b/c it effected a taking of the P property without just compensation CONCURRENCE: Although the amortization provision in this case is unreasonable and must be struck down b/c it failed to provide adequate time for elimination of the nonconforming use, the per se prohibition against amortization provisions advanced by the majority is too restrictive. Amortization provisions that provide adequate notice to the property owner so that he is not deprived of the property interest or its use are an effective way to reconcile the community interests with the business needs. NOTES: (1) Penn is part of a small minority of states that forbid amortization ordinances altogether. In most states, a requirement that a non-conforming use cease within certain time period does not constitute a taking, so long as the time period is reasonable. If the time period gives the owner adequate time to make new plans, any loss he suffers may be offset by the monopoly position he occupies for as long as the nonconforming business remains in the place. (2) If nonconforming use is abandoned , it may be terminated. Some ordinances go further and to eliminate litigation over intent, the continuation of a nonconforming use if it is discontinued for any period of time. (3) Courts approving an amortization provisions tend to require a reasonable period for a particular nonconforming use in question. In practice, however there appears to be a considerable deference to rough and ready lines. For any given use, one can find cases going either way. This kind of sloppiness 70 threatens to make amortization vulnerable to challenge. (4) Factors usually listed as relevant tot he assessment of reasonableness of a particular amortization period are the nature of the use in question, the amount invested in it, the number of improvements, the public detriment caused by the use, and the character of the surrounding neighborhoods. (5) Related to the law of non-conforming uses is the more general doctrine of vested rights. In the case of non-conforming uses, a preexisting operation is protected; plans to engage in some particular use are insufficient. In the case of vested rights doctrine, a proposed use might be protected if sufficient commitments have been made- plans drawn, permits obtained, the site prepared, construction begun – in reliance on existing zoning requirements. (6) Another theory is estoppel is sometimes applied where developers rely reasonably and to their detriment on the issuance of a permit and proceed to make substantial expenditures. Reliance, though, has to be reasonable. C. Achieving Flexibility in Zoning- by binding limited classes of uses into tightly drawn districts, Euclidean zoning can work inequitable hardships and promote inefficient patterns of land use; it can also inhibit socially and aesthetically desirable diversity. There must be a means for providing flexibility in zoning. The power to regulate flexibility can be the power to favor or disfavor for illegitimate reasons. 1. Variances and Special Exceptions- Section 7 of the Standard State Enabling Act authorizes appointment of a board of adjustment that may “in appropriate cases and subject to appropriate conditions and safeguards, make special exceptions tot he terms of the ordinance in harmony with its general purpose and intent. a. Commons v. Westwood Zoning Board of Adjustment FACTS: Westwood refused Commons a zoning ordinance variance, finding that the proposed development of the property (a house) would impact adversely upon the economic and aesthetic qualities of the community and that a refusal to 71 b. grant the variance would not impose undue hardship. HOLDING: a denial of a zoning ordinance must be based upon sufficient findings on whether the areas will be adversely impacted, and whether the denial will work a hardship on the owner of the property. In this case, the board failed to consider the efforts made to abide by the zoning ordinance such as the sale of the lot or the purchase of the adjoining lots. Also, no consideration was given to the hardship imposed by the ordinance which rendered the lot virtually undeveloped. As a result, the case must be remanded for sufficient findings. NOTES: (1) in granting a variance, zoning boards may impose reasonable conditions related to the use of the property that minimize the adverse impact of the use upon neighbors. On the other hand, zoning boards may not condition a variance upon use of the property by the original owners only, as this has no relation to ameliorating the effects of the proposed land use and is unrelated tot he legitimate purposes of zoning. A variance must run with the land. (2) Existing violations cannot be a basis for further violations. (3) Court looks to see if the hardship is selfimposed. Cope v. Inhabitants of the Town of Brunswick FACTS: D contended that it had the power to grant zoning variances in the public welfare. Cope sought a variance from a zoning ordinance restricting the construction of apartment buildings. A request was presented to Brunswick which rejected it under its power granted by the ordinance to reject variances which were not in the public welfare. HOLDING: A zoning ordinance may not delegate to a local board a legislative authority. The generality of the ordinance does not provide sufficient legislative control over the conduct of the local board. Thus the board is free to act legislatively and such is impermissible delegation of power. As a result, the ordinance is invalidated. 72 NOTES: (1) variance: administratively authorized departure from the terms of the zoning ordinance, granted in cases of unique individual hardship, in which a strict application of the terms of the ordinance would be unconstitutional. (2) an exception is a use permitted by the ordinance in a district in which it is not necessarily incompatible, but where it might cause harm is not watched. Exceptions are authorized under conditions which will insure their compatibility with the surrounding uses. (3) The theory of special exception is clear enough: practice under the theory varies. There are efforts by zoners to use the special exceptions as essentially a discretionary device: listed uses will be granted only I very general criteria are mer. An alternative approach reduces discretion by listing detailed criteria regarding exceptions. If the proposed use meets the criteria, an exception must be granted. 2. Zoning amendments and the Spot Zoning Problem a. Fasano v. Board of County Commissioners of Washington County FACTS: In 1959, the county commissioners adopted a comprehensive land use plan for the County as required by the Oregon statute. In 1963, they adopted a new zoning classification, Planned residential which provided for high density multi-family development. A developer sought to change a 32 acre parcel that was zoned for single family residential to a P-R zone so that he could develop a mobile home park. Fasano opposed the change. The county commissioners approved the change after a hearing. Fasano brought suit. The trial court reversed the decision of the commissioners. As appeals court affirmed. The Board of county commissioners of Washington County appeals contending that their decision was valid, that it was not necessary to show a change of conditions before a zone change could be accomplished, and that the change was in accordance with the comprehensive plan. 73 b. HOLDING: A change in zoning must conform with the comprehensive plan of land use. Judicial review is not limited to a determination that a zoning change is arbitrary or capricious. The purpose of zoning ordinances is to implement and carry out the comprehensive plan. Therefore, any change in zoning must be proven to conform with the plan. This proof, at a minimum should show: (1) that there is a public need for the change in question and (2) that need will be best served by changing the classification of the particular piece of property in question as compared with other valuable property. The burden of proof should rest on the party seeking change, and the more drastic the change the greater the burden will be. Here, the burden is not sustained. The only evidence brought before the court is a conclusionary report of the staff of the planning department. Conclusion without facts is insufficient to support change. NOTES: (1) The statutory requirements for the adoption of the comprehensive plans were designed to prevent haphazard piecemeal planning which could greatly affect property owners within an area. The object of these plans is to promote appropriate use of the land throughout a municipality. There is some authority for the contention that a plan can be portrayed by the zoning ordinance itself, or as the end product of a package of zoning ordinances. Arnel Development Co. v. City of Costa Mesa FACTS: Arnel sought to build apartments on his land, which was properly zoned. A group passed an initiative rezoning the property to prevent the development. Arnel sued, contending that the selective zoning was invalid. The trial court upheld the ordinance. The court of appeals reversed, holding that rezoning of specific small parcels was judicial rather than legislative matter. Costa Mesa appealed. HOLDING: All zoning is legislative in nature. It has long been settled that zoning, regardless of the size of the parcel is not a judicial function. None of the many precedents draws any distinction between the size of the properties 74 involved. The sudden shift to judicial zoning would cause undue confusion and lead to unnecessary litigation. As a result, the initiative effectively recognizes the property. NOTES: (1) the court rejected the landowner’s argument that in a case involving such specific parcel of land, the rezoning must be adjudicatory to uphold due process rights. If it is legislative in nature, no hearing would be provided prior to a decisions being made. The court reasoned that the public hearing is inherent in the legislative process and no rights would be prejudiced. (2) Spot zoning means the improper permission to use an island of land for a more intensive use than permitted on adjacent properties. Some courts use the term spot zoning to describe certain sets of facts so that the term is neutral with respect to validity or invalidity. Other courts use the term spot zoning to describe a set of facts where zoning is applied is invalid. (3) Spot zoning is invalid if: 1. A small parcel of land if singled out for special and pri9vilegded treatment; 2. The singling out is not in the public interest but only for the benefit of the landowner and 3. The action is not in accord with a comprehensive plan. (4) Usually arises from legislative zoning amendments, although administrative variances and special exceptions are sometimes invalidated by reference to the same concept. (5) The underlying concern in spot zoning cases is that special favors have been granted in response to bribes or more subtle influences such as politics. (6) The traditional reasonableness standard for judicial review of legislative regulation of economic activities – including zoning regulations – is extraordinary permissive, amounting to virtual deference on the part of the courts. Zoning amendments must be justified by showing a mistake in t he 75 original ordinance or a change in conditions subsequent to its enactment (7) Fasano illustrates a different approach to the problem, rejecting the requirements of mistake or change and substituting a more intensive judicial review when zoning amendments are of an essentially adjudicative nature. (8) In the case of a referendum, the local governing body approves an ordinance and then refers it to the electorate for final decision. (9) An initiative goes right from a qualifying petition, initiated by citizens, to the ballot. Arnel included a rezoning initiative, and gave rise to the legislative-adjudicative issue because referendums and initiative are reserved fort legislative functions. D. Expanding the Aims (and exercising the muscle) of Zoning. - early objective of zoning were little more than the control of nuisances, though in a comprehensive fashion - over the years after Euclid, the aims of zoning gradually expanded, no doubt for a host of reasonspopulation, growth, etc 1. Aesthetic Regulation a. State ex rel. Stoyanoff v. Berkeley FACTS: Berkeley desired to build a home in the City of Ladue which is one of the finer suburbs of the city of St. Louis. The plans called for a home of pyramid shape. A city ordinance established an architectural board to ensure that the new residences conformed to certain minimum architectural standards of appearance and conformity with the surrounding structures and that unsightly, grotesque and unsuitable structures detrimental to the welfare of the surrounding property were to be avoided. Berkeley’s application for a permit was denied. HOLDING: The stabilizing of property values and giving some assurance to the public that, if property is purchased in a residential neighborhood, its value will be preserved is a legitimate objective for zoning ordinances. Property use that offends the sensibilities and 76 b. decreases the property values affects not only the adjoining property owners but also the general public as well. When the property values are destroyed or seriously impaired the tax base of the community is affected and the public suffers economically as a result. Here, the denial of the building permit for Berkeley’s highly modernistic residence in an area where traditional Colonial, French Provincial, and Tudor styles of architecture are erected does not appear to be arbitrary and unreasonable when the basic purpose to be served is the generals welfare of the persons in the entire community. NOTES: (1) courts developing the law of nuisance declared an ugly sit a nuisance. Courts early viewed zoning under the police power a form of nuisance control. Naturally then, by analogy tot he nuisance, they held that a police power can be exercised to further public health, safety, and general welfare, but not for purely aesthetic purposes. (2) Not until the 1950s did the courts begin to accept that the legitimacy of zoning could be based exclusively on aesthetic considerations. Expanded the definition of public welfare. As a result of this judicial change of view, architectural review boards have proliferated in many states. (3) Aesthetic considerations are an important factor in historic zoning and historic preservation legislation, and in these contexts the courts have felt less inhibition in admitting the legitimacy of aesthetic objectives. (4) Court here did not rest its decision on the legitimacy of aesthetics as a zoning ordinance, relying instead largely on protection of property values. Anderson v. City of Issaquah FACTS: P owned property and applied to the City for a land use certification to develop the property. The property is zoned for general commercial use ,but P desired to build a 6800 square foot commercial building for several retail tenants. He submitted the project to 77 c. several city departments and the process went smoothly until the Issaquah Development Commission approval was sought. Various building design objectives were stated in the IMC and P thought he complied, but was denied by the Commission because his façade did not fit with the concept of the surrounding area. P modified the design with the advice of the Commission and resubmitted the plan. He was denied again and again until finally P filed suit. HOLDING: A statute which either forbids or requires the doing of an act in terms so vague that men of common intelligence must necessarily guess at its meaning and differs as to its application, violates the first essential of due process of law. The purpose of the void for vagueness doctrine is to limit arbitrary and discretionary enforcement of the law.. Ordinary citizen reading the design sections of the IMC would get no guidance as to what the Commission will and will not approve. Provisions in the codes must be written in understandable terms with clear guidance given to all. The land use certifications were met except for those provisions which are unconstitutional anyway. Land use should be granted. NOTES: (1) architects felt they should be required to express themselves without having to be subjected to a standard of beauty. (2) If the Anderson case had involved a dispute between the property owner and an architectural control committee by private covenants, Anderson very likely would have lost. Private architectural restrictions are governed by a different standard than public restrictions. (3) No court has ever held that architectural expression is protected by the First Amendment, but it is a common view of commentators that design regulation, because it implicates expressive values, should at least by subject to close scrutiny City of Ladue v. Gilleo FACTS: Margaret Gilleo owns one of 57 single family homes in a subdivision. On December 8, 1990 she placed a sign on her front lawn that was 78 printed with the words “say no to the war in the Persian Gulf, call Congress now.” After that sign disappeared, she put up another one but it was knocked to the ground. When Gilleo reported these incidents to the police they advised her that such signs were prohibited in Ladue. The city council denied her petition for a variance. The district court issued an injunction and Gilleo placed the sign in her upstairs window. The city responded to the injunction by repealing its ordinance and enacting a replacement which contained a general prohibition on signs and defined them broadly. The court of appeals ruled that the ordinance was unconstitutional b/c it was content based restriction. HOLDING: It is common ground that the government can regulate the physical characteristics of signs. Precedents in this area identify two analytically distinct grounds for challenging the constitutionality of a municipal ordinance regulating the display of signs. One is that the measure in effect restricts too little speech b/c its exemptions discriminate on the basis of the signs’ messages. Alternatively, such provisions are subject to attack on the ground that they simply prohibit too much protected speech. Ladue prohibits too much speech by totally eliminating a common form of speech. There are no adequate substitutes for signs in communication. NOTES: (1) government controls based on the content of communication are said to be subject to closer judicial scrutiny than controls that simply regulate the time, lace, and manner of communication. (2) In recent years the Court has approved two distinct approaches to control – in each instance against strong dissents that the zoning measures were obviously not contentneutral bc/ they imposed selective limitations based exclusively on content. Disperse or concentrate the activity to be regulated. 2. Controls on Household Composition a. Village of Belle Terre v. Boraas 79 FACTS: Belle Terre is a village on Long Island’s north shore of about 220 homes inhabited by 700 people. Its total land area is less than one square mile. It has restricted land use to one family dwelling, exclusion lodging houses, boarding houses, fraternity houses, or multiple dwelling houses. Boraas and five other students at State University at Stony Brook, who were not related to each other by blood, adoption, or marriage, rented a home in Belle Terre in December 1971. When Belle Terre served the owners of the home with an Order to Remedy Violations of the ordinance, the owners plus three other tenants brought an action under the Civil Rights Act for an injunction and a judgement declaring the ordinance unconstitutional. The court of appeals held that the law was unconstitutional and Belle Terre appealed. HOLDING: the concept of the public welfare is broad and inclusive. The ordinance does not burden any fundamental rights guaranteed by the Constitution, nor does it inflict procedural disparities on some but not others. Rather, this ordinance is in the field of economic and social legislation and will be upheld if it bears a rational relationship to a permissible state objective. A quiet place where yards are wide, people few, and motor vehicles restricted are legitimate guidelines in a land use project addressed to family needs. The police power is not confined to the elimination of filth, stench, and unhealthy places. It is ample to lay out some where family values, youth values, and the blessings of quiet seclusion and clean air make area a sanctuary for people. DISSENT: the ordinance in this case unnecessarily burdens the first amendment freedom of association and the right to privacy. The first and fourteenth amendments protect the freedom to chose ones associates. Constitutional protection is extended not only to modes of association that are political in the usual sense, but also to those that pertain to the social and economic benefit of the members. The choice of household composition companions involves deeply personal considerations as tot he 80 b. kind an quality of intimate relationships within the home. That decision surely falls within the ambit of the right to privacy protected by the constitution. NOTES: (1) the Supreme Court in a later decision invalidating an ordinance which defined family to include no more than one set of grandchildren, limited the holding of this case: the ordinance of Belle Terre affected only unrelated individuals. East Cleveland, in contrast, has chosen to regulate the occupancy of its housing by slicing deeply into the family itself. The city undertakes such intrusive family regulation that the usual judicial deference to the legislature is inappropriate. (2) The ordinance has but a tenuous relationship to the alleviation of the conditions mentioned by the city. The Constitution protects the sanctity of the family. (3) Occupancy restrictions based upon biological or legal relationships, the court said, had no reasonable tie to the city’s objectives. (4) The state constitution and other cases endorsed traditional notions of family. There is no doubt that there is a governmental interest in marriage and in preserving the integrity of the biological or legal family. There is no concomitant governmental interest in keeping together a group of unrelated persons, no matter how closely they simulate a family. City of Edmonds v. Oxford House FACTS: in the summer of 1990, respondent Oxford house opened up a group home in the city of Edmonds, Washington for 10 to 12 adults recovering form alcoholism and drug addiction. The group home is located in a neighborhood zoned for single family residences. Upon learning of the home, the city issued criminal citations to the owner and a resident of the house. The citations charged violation of the zoning code rule that defines who may live in a single family dwelling unit. The occupants of such units must compose a “family” and family under the City’s defining rule. Oxford houses houses more than 81 five unrelated persons and therefore does not conform to the code. HOLDING: discrimination covered by the FHA includes “a refusal to make reasonable accommodations in rules, pollicies, and or services when such accommodations may be necessary to afford handicapped persons equal opportunity to use and enjoy a dwelling. To limit land use to single family residences, one must define family. Maximum occupancy restrictions, in contradiction, cap the number of occupants per dwelling, typically in relation tot he available floor space or the number or types of rooms. These restrictions ordinarily apply uniformly to all residents of the dwelling. Rules that cap the number of persons fall within the excpetions to the FHA. Rules for compositions to a household do not. Edmonds rule was a rule for compositions and there is a separate provision for the number of occupants. NOTES: (1) group homes is a generic term for any number of small, decentralized treatment facilities, housing for foster children, etc. 3. Exclusionary Zoning and Growth Controls a. Mount Laurel (I) HOLDING: Mt. Laurel must, by its land use regulations, make realistically possible the opportunity for an appropriate variety and choice of housing for all categories of people who may desire to live there, of course including those of low and moderate income. It must permit multiple family housing, without bedroom or similar restrictions, as well as small dwellings on very small lots, low cost housing of other types, and , in general, high density zoning, without artificial and unjustifiable minimum requirements as to lot size, building size, and the like, to meet the full panoply of theses needs. In other words, the municipality must zone primarily for the living welfare of people, and not for the benefit of the local tax rate. Under present NJ legislation, zoning must be on an individual municipality basis, rather than regionally. So long as that kind of binding agreement under the present tax structure exists, 82 b. all municipalities of the region must bear their fair share. Southern Burlington County NAACP v. township of Mount Laurel (II) FACTS: The NAACP sued Mount Laurel, contending that the municipality’s zoning scheme violated the NJ constitution by failing to provide for low income housing outside depressed areas. The NJ Supreme Court invalidated the ordinances and remanded for further proceedings. The trial court held that it was sufficient that Mount Laurel had made a bona fide effort to comply with the Supreme Court decision and upheld the new ordinance enacted in response. The NAACP appealed contending that a mere attempt to provide such zoning did not discharge Mount Laurel’s constitutional obligations. HOLDING: Municipal land use regulations must provide a realistic opportunity for low and moderate income housing. Such obligation extends beyond attempting to provide for such housing. The housing must be in direct proportion to the percentage of lower income residents in the city. To reach this goal, an affirmative governmental action may be required. The elimination of some obstacles and the creation of new zoning ordinances may be frustrated by other restrictions which effectively deprive the poor of adequate housing. Therefore, zoning schemes which merely manifested an intent to abide by the original supreme court holding are insufficient to discharge Mount Laurel’s constitutional obligations. Reversed and Remanded NOTES: (1) the rationale behind the case is that the use of all land is controlled by the state. The state has constitutional obligations to all its residents whether rich or poor. Municipalities, as state subjects, must set aside a fair share of its land for low income housing. They cannot allocate only dilapidated land for the poor and retain valuable land for the rich exclusively. While this rationale appears clear in theory, in execution it has proven very difficult. The main difficulty is developing an equitable formula for 83 (2) (3) (4) determining “fair share.” Until a definitive formula is developed, this will prevent widespread application of this rule. The straightforward way to achieve relatively low taxes is to have a handsome tax base, well to do residents, and low demand for such public services as water and sewer, schools, police, fire departments, public assistance programs, and so on. Translated into public policy, this means measures to ensure a community of substantial and desirable industrial issues and expensive homes located ion a low density manner. Residents will ne3cessarily tend to have high incomes and as a result, will probably be white. There are a number of techniques people might use to exclude people whose characteristics would interfere with the ideal picture a. minimum housing cost and minimum floor area: now regulated by housing codes which establish minimum standards for all housing within the municipality, they cover required facilities and are similar to building codes, but apply only to housing. b. Minimum lot size: have been upheld in most cases, if they find rational justification in the conditions of particular community c. Minimum set back requirements: have been upheld b/c they increase light and air, reduce danger form fire, and advance aesthetic concerns. Have been almost universally upheld. d. Barring mobile or manufactured homes: from residential areas or perhaps the entire community were almost always upheld in early cases. And even today when manufactured homes must meet federal safety standards, prejudice against them exists. In a few states, court appear to be standing up against the prejudice. It appears the idea behind Mt. Laurel was essentially deregulation: remove obstacles 84 that local government had put in the way of less costly housing and let the market respond. Newly constructed housing, even of modest residences, might be beyond the reach of low-income people, but the increased supply would let the used housing trickle down to them at affordable prices. Things did not work out that way, though, b/c communities read Mt. Laurel as applying only to developing communities. (5) Mt. Laurel opinion confirmed a builder’s remedy under which the trial court could allow a developer to go forth with low income project event though the municipality had not granted a permit if the court found that the municipality had not fulfilled its Mount Laurel obligations (6) An interesting feature of the Fair Housing Act in NJ provides for regional contribution agreements whereby suburbs, may, with Council approval, compensate cities for agreeing to absorb up to half of the suburbs’ fair share obligation. This makes use of the existing house stock and contributions will make it possible to rehabilitate substandard housing. (7) Exclusionary zoning can be practiced anywhere and not all state courts have responded on the activist fashion of the NJ Supreme court: some state courts still presume ordinances to be constitutional. Other courts adopt a middle ground by maintaining a presumption of validity but judging the rationality of the measure in question by reference to the regional as opposed to the purely local interests. (8) In Massachusetts, an applicant can appeal to a state housing appeals committee. The committee may reverse the denial if it is not consistent with local needs for low income and moderate income housing. (9) Connecticut has similar legislation.... expedited appeals. (10) In Oregon a state land conservation and development commission has authority to require a municipality to plan for higher residential densities and permit multiple 85 unit dwellings when its finds that the municipality lags in meeting the housing needs of the region. (11) Inclusionary zoning consists of a number of devices designed to require or encourage developers to supply low income and moderate income housing c. Growth controls - growth controls aim – normally anyway – to keep out everybody; the idea is to stop or to slow development - timing controls required developers to accumulate points before a project could go forth. An eager developer could earn point faster by providing some of the sewage systems, schools, roads, parks, etc needed to develop. The court approved this scheme as a means not as exclusionary, but to provide a balanced community and efficient land use. - The use of quotas was upheld as rationally related to the social and environmental welfare of the community - Growth controls have proliferated over the last decade - Most studies find that they increase housing prices E. Is Zoning a Good Thing? - the free market pricing system for land use does not take into account the external costs one development may have upon others. Zoning intervenes to correct the market’s failure to take account of these externalities. - Yet zoning is fraught with abuses - Between the marked decentralization of the market and the centralized control of development in western Europe rest other methods, studied earlier, like nuisance and covenants. Zoning is an American invention, unknown in Europe, and European land use controls may have illuminating lessons. In most countries in Western Europe, land is completely controlled by the state. The land owner has no right to develop, only the right to continue the existing use of the land. The distinction between existing use value and development value is a fundamental one in zoning. Chapter 12- Eminent Domain and the Problem of Regulatory Takings- taking property form owners and reallocating it to its own governmentally preferred uses. The government’s 86 power of eminent domain is well beyond dispute, but there are limitations. The Fifth Amendment enjoins, “nor shall private property be taken for public use without just compensation A. The Power of Eminent Domain: Sources and Rationales - the power of the government to force transfers of property form owners to itself - orig9ins can be traced back to ancient Rome and English sovereigns enjoyed similar powers - in early America, the power of the government to take private property was recognized, though compensation was hardly universal in colonial times. Gradually, however, statutes came to provide for compensation and some judges required it even in the absence of legislation. - By the time the US Constitution was to held to require compensation by the states, they were already providing it on their own – through constitutional or judge made law. - Various rationales for the taking power have been offered over the years: sovereign states had original and absolute ownership of property, individual possession derived from grants from the state, and as a remnant of feudal tenures. - Posner sketches a fictional justification for the taking power, a justification that stresses efficiency: it is necessary to prevent a monopoly especially ion cases of railroads, or pipelines b/c people owning the land in the path will be tempted to hold out for a very high price – a price in excess of the opportunity cost of the land higher prices will encourage the RRs to substitute other inputs for land they would have bought. As a result of all of this, land that would be more valuable to a right of way company than its present owners will remain in its existing, less valuable uses, and this is inefficient if low transaction costs, the parties should transact in the market if high transaction costs, the courts should be allowed to shift resources - private developers must get land without eminent domain- use buying agents, option agreements, and 87 straw transactions on their efforts – apparently often successful – to deal with the problem of holdouts. - Assembly through voluntary transactions is usually an unattractive alternative for the government b/c it often seeks to acquire larger, more sitedependent parcels than do private developers, and b/c it would have greater difficulty maintaining secrecy for effective use of assembly techniques and the controlling opportunities for corruption that would arise - Posner also suggests an economic rationale for the compensation doctrine: without it, the government would have an incentive to substitute land for other inputs that were cheaper to society as a whole but more expensive tot he government - In any world lacking compensation there is a fear that the government will take the land and so under investment of capital results B. The Public-Use Puzzle (and a note on just compensation) - fifth amendment’s mention of public use is read to mean that property may be taken only for such uses; the government may not condemn for “private purposes” however willing it may be to pay compensation for the forced transfer. The reach of the power, then, hinges on the breadth or narrowness of the meaning attached to pubic use. 1. Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff FACTS: the state of Hawaii through its housing authority, sought to redistribute land held in fee simple from a few families to the population in general. Condemnation proceedings were instituted, and Midkiff and other fee holders sued, contending the statute allowing for such eminent domain exercise violated the just compensation clause of the fifth amendment. The trial court upheld the statute, while the court of appeals reversed. The Authority petitioned the Supreme Court of the US for writ of certiorari, contending that the statute reasonably related to a legitimate purpose and was constitutional. HOLDING: the pubic use clause of the fifth amendment does not proscribe the exercise of eminent domain power where such is reasonably related to a conceivable public purpose. The purpose of the statute in this case was to allow 88 for more widespread land ownership. This in turn would allow for a more diversified program of land development and add stability to the state’s economy. As a result, the statute clearly related to a legitimate governmental interest, and it therefore was constitutional. NOTES: (1) the greatest criticism of the result in this case is that it sanctions the taking of private property, albeit for just compensation, in order to benefit another private party. The traditional use of the eminent domain power involves the ultimate use of the land by the condemning governmental entity. However, the police power of the individual state is relied upon to justify the condemnation of property in this and similar cases, and so long as a governmental purpose can be identified, the action will be upheld. (2) The precise view of the “public use” requirement has varied over time and according tot he type of taking involved. There are two basic opposing views of the meaning of the phrase: the term means advantage or benefit to the public (the so-called broad view) the term means actual use or right to use of the condemned property by the public (the socalled narrow view) the broad view has returned to favor. (3) Berger suggested that one test for public use focuses on the contemplated ends of an act of condemnation. If the ends are sufficiently public in one sense or another, the test is passed. (4) Another way to see if the use is pubic is to focus on the means used to accomplish the condemnation: (Merill) the courts decide if the government may proceed with the police power or if it must use the taking power. (5) Merill thins condemnation through eminent domain only when the costs are so high as to frustrate voluntary transaction in the market b/c sellers have the power to hold out. B/c eminent domain entails costs that market exchange does not - legislative authorization, judicial proceedings, professional appraisals, 89 etc. the government will have a healthy incentive to avoid eminent domain whenever possible. (6) Delegation of the power of eminent domain to private corporations and individuals engaged in public services is permitted and well settled as acceptable. 2. Poletown Neighborhood Council v. City of Detroit FACTS: Detroit planned to condemn a residential neighborhood, clear the ;and, and convey it to General Motors as a site for construction of an assembly plant HOLDING: condemnation for a private use is forbidden, but governmental action of the type contemplated here meets a public need and serves an essential pubic purpose. The benefit of the municipality invoking the power of eminent domain is clear and significant and is a legitimate object of the Legislature. DISSENT: the transfer to GM is not incidental and this case is altering the law of eminent domain 3. City of Oakland v. Oakland Raiders FACTS: the owners of the Oakland Raiders professional football team decided to move the franchise to LA. Oakland thereafter sought to keep the team by acquiring it through eminent domain. HOLDING: the taking of the tam by the city would violate the commerce clause and so the Raiders will remain in LA. 4. Note: Just compensation - compensation in the constitutional sense is not always full compensation. The market value is not the value that every owner of property attaches to his property but merely the value the marginal owner attaches to his property. - Some owners have idiosyncratic values for the house and are hurt when the government takes their property and gives them just the market value in return. - Supreme Court has rejected the idea of including personal value I the compensation formula C. Physical Occupations and Regulatory Takings - if the government wished to condemn private property for public use, it must comply with procedure designed to assure owners of due process. file a petition in court 90 notice to all persons with an interest in the property trial where government has to establish authority to condemn government gets permission to enter and inspect the property government pays a deposit for the property pay compensation plus interest - jury decides the amount of compensation an the court decides necessity and public use questions - the rules of takings have developed in stages 1. Rules of Decision (Before 1987) a. Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp. FACTS: NY enacted a statute which required apartment house owners to provide tenants with access to cable television reception. Loretto brought a class action against D contending that its placement of its cable television installation equipment constituted trespass and that the statute allowed for a taking of her property without just compensation. The trial court granted summary judgment for D, upholding the constitutionality of the statute. The appellate court affirmed, and Loretto appealed to the US Supreme Court HOLDING: Any permanent physical occupation of an owners property which is authorized by the government constitutes a taking of property which requires a payment of just compensation. Any occupation, no matter how slight, impacts on the owner’s right to exclusive possession of his property. In this case, the equipment occupied a very small area of the property. Yet its presence constituted a physical occupation and thus necessarily must be classified as a taking of property within the meaning of the fifth amendment. Therefore, just compensation must be paid. DISSENT: the court goes against the established precedent by recognizing a per se taking rule. It has previously been held on many occasions that each taking case must be considered on its peculiar facts. A rigid per se rule finding that a taking in every physical encroachment will require compensation in situations not justified 91 b. under previous interpretations of the Takings clause. NOTES: (1) the court recognizes the fundamental inconsistency with the elements of private ownership presented by any physical occupation of the property by a stranger. When such an invasion is authorized by the government, a compensable taking occurs. The amount of money necessary to constitute just compensation will vary with the case. The court declined to rule on whether $1 per unit payment was sufficient in this case. (2) On remand, the ?court of Appeals sustained the validity of the statutory provision empowering the Commission to set compensation for the takings in question at $`. This was sufficient, they decided, b/s the presence of cable would increase the building value. (3) The majority decide the case in terms of a per se categorical rule: a permanent physical authorization by the government is a taking, period. There is no set formula. (4) The distinction, in this case, is between permanent occupations and temporary invasions. Hadacheck v. Sebastian FACTS: Hadacheck (P) was convicted of a misdemeanor for the violation of a Los Angeles city ordinance making it unlawful for nay person to establish or operate a brick yard or a brick kiln within the city limits. P whose business was established before the ordinance was enacted, asserted that his business was not a nuisance as defined under state statues. The enforcement of the ordinance according to P amounted to a taking of property without compensation, violating guarantees of due process. The California Supreme Court upheld the ordinance as a valid nondiscriminatory regulatory measure. HOLDING: the imperative necessity of the police power precludes any limitation on its use when it is not exerted arbitrarily. There must be progress, and if in its march private interest are in the way they must yield to the good of the community. Even granting P’s business was not a 92 nuisance per se, the municipality found that fumes and dust from the brick making plant had occasionally caused sickness and serious discomfort to those living in the vicinity. IT may be that brick yards in other localities where the same conditions existed were not regulated pr prohibited, but it does not follow that they will not be. That P’s business was first in time to be prohibited does not make its prohibition unlawful. NOTES: (1) the doctrines of eminent domain and police power are distinct and separate powers of the government. In eminent domain proceedings, land is taken by the state b/c it will thereby be more of a use to the public. Under the police power, private property rights re impaired by the state not b/c they have become necessary or useful o the public, but because there free exercise is believed to be harmful to important public interests. (2) Case can be read to suggest that if government action in question is depicted as a nuisance control measure, then there is no taking notwithstanding the loss worked by the regulation. The underlying notion is that the government is curbing a public bad rather than expropriating a public good (3) Under the police power, rights of property are impaired not b/c they become useful or necessary to the public or b/c of some public advantage, but b/c their free exercise is believed to be detrimental to public interests; it may be said that the state takes property by eminent domain b/c it is useful to the public and under the police power b/c it is harmful. Yet the former recognizes a right to compensation, while the latter principal does not. (4) Though not completely without defenders, the nuisance or public bad test has been rather roundly criticized as a basis for deciding when a regulation amounts to a taking (5) The idea is that compensation is required when the public helps itself to a good at a private expense, but not when the public 93 c. simply requires one of its members to stop making a nuisance of himself. Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon FACTS: In 1878, D transferred certain real estate property to Mahon (P) by a deed in which D reserved the mineral rights on the property and P waived all rights to object to or receive damages for the removal of such minerals. In 1921, the Penn legislature enacted the “Kohler Act” which forbade the mining of coal in such a way as to cause the subsidence of any human habitation. When D decided to exercise its mineral rights pursuant to the deed, P instituted an action for an injunction on the grounds that the mining would violate the Kohler Act by causing the subsidence of his home. From a decree granting the injunction, the D appealed, contending that such an application of the statute would constitute a taking without compensation contrary to the Due Process clause. HOLDING: private property may be regulated pursuant to the police power of the state to protect public health, safety, and moral; but if the regulation goes as far as to destroy or appropriate a property right, it becomes a “taking” under the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments, requiring compensation therefor. IT is well established, of course, that some property rights must yield to the public interest and the police power. Here, however, the limited public interest in protecting P’s surface rights does not justify the total destruction of the mineral rights which D reserved in its deed to P. AS such, the Kohler Act is unconstitutional insofar as it fails to provide for compensation fort he taking of D’s property rights. The decree which was based upon it is accordingly reversed. DISSENT: no taking occurred here. Rather, the state merely exercised the police power to prevent a noxious use of the property. The property remains in the possession of the owners. NOTES: (1) we have thus far considered two categorical tests or per se rules of decision for taking cases: permanent physical occupations are 94 d. always takings; nuisance control measures are never takings. (2) Penn Coal is a classic statement of a different sort of test: concerned with differences of degree rather than differences in kind, inquiring whether- on balance- matter have gone “too far.” The test says, in essence, that when a governmental regulation of a use that is not a nuisance works too great a burden on the property owners, it cannot go forth without compensation. (3) Rule is usually referred to as the diminution in value rule. But diminution relative to what? (4) Pennsylvania law recognizes three separate estate in mining property: in the surface, in the minerals, and in support of the surface. Holmes saw the Kohler act as purporting to abolish the third estate entirely. Brandeis, in the dissent, on the other hand, reasoned that the rights of an owner as against the public are not increased by divining up the interests in his property. Keystone Bituminous Coal Association v. DeBenedictis FACTS: in 1996, PA enacted legislation designed, as was the Kohler Act, to control subsidence form coal mining. The legislation, here called the Subsidence Act, requires mine operators to keep up to 50 percent of their coal in place and to repair surface damage caused by subsidence even if the owners waived their rights. Four mining corporations challenged the constitutionality of the legislation, claiming it was among other things, a taking of their property. HOLDING: court holds that Penn Coal does not control this case. The character of the governmental action involved here leans heavily against finding a taking. The government acted to arrest what it perceives to be a significant threat to the common welfare. Unlike the Kohler Act, the Subsidence Act does not merely involve a balancing of private economic interests of coal companies against the private interests of the surface owners. The Penn legislature 95 e. specifically found that public interests are served by enforcing a policy that is designed to minimize subsidence in certain areas. The Commonwealth is acting to protect the public interests in health, the environment, and the fiscal integrity of the area. Under our system of government, one of the state’s primary ways of preserving the public weal is restricting the uses individuals cam make of their property. While each is burdened somewhat by such restrictions, we, in turn, benefit greatly from the restrictions that are placed on others. No basis for treating the less than 2% of petitioners coal as a separate parcel of property. Penn Central Transportation Company v. City of New York FACTS: NY’s landmark Preservation commission, acting under the authority of the city’s Landmarks Preservation Law, designated Grand Central Terminal a landmark. The Terminal, owned by the Penn Central Transportation Co. and its affiliates, is one of NY’s most famous buildings. Designation as a landmark resulted in restrictions upon the use of the Terminal. In particular, changes to the its exterior architectural features had to be approved in advance by the commission. In 1968, Penn Central entered into a contract with UGP Properties to construct a multi-story office building above Grand central Terminal. After the Commission rejected its application, Penn Central filed suit alleging that the application of the law had taken its property without just compensation in violation of the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments. The New York ?Court of Appeals no denial of due process, and the Penn central appealed. HOLDING: A city may [place restrictions on the development of individual historic landmarks without effecting a taking requiring just compensation. The focus is on both the character of the action and on the nature and extent of the interference with the rights of the parcel as a whole. DISSENT: The City of NY has imposed a substantial cost o less than one tenth of a percent of the buildings in NYC for the general 96 2. benefit of all its people. Its exactly this imposition of general costs on a few individuals at which the taking protection is directed. NOTES: (1) Keystone and Penn Central clearly reject the idea of conceptual severance. The majority opinion in Penn added something new to the conventional collection of takings test, but just what is less clear. The distinct investment backed expectations formulation is obviously drawn from Professor Michelman’s essay on takings. (2) There is some suggestion in case law that distinct investment backed expectations – and thus takings- are more likely to be fond when regulations interfere with investments that property owners have already made, as opposed to regulations limiting possible future investment opportunities. (3) Transferable development rights (TDRs) like those involved in Penn Central represent a relatively new, and very controversial approach to land use planning. The TDR approach severs development rights from other rights in land and treats them as a separate item. Owners of the restricted land are given TDRs that can be used for development, beyond which would otherwise be permitted on receiving lots or in so-called transfer areas. Recipients of the TDRs may sell their rights or use them on the land they own. Provides some form of compensation. (4) TDRs do amount to just compensation, in fact, even though the value of the TDRs may fall short of the fair market value ordinarily required in cases of condemnation. Matters of Remedy the remedy should be compensation. After all, if the government takes property – condemns it – under the power of eminent domain, the obligation to pay just compensation follows. A suit for compensation would usually proceed by way of a so-called inverse condemnation action: the claimant rather than the government institutes the suit, alleging that 97 a. a taking has occurred and seeking recompense for it The remedy was routinely granted as to takings by physical occupation (including the category of loss of access, destruction of property, or an actual transfer of title, possession, or control to the government) but it was typically denied as to regulatory takings. Instead, the courts awarded declaratory or injunctive relief invalidating the regulation or its application First English Evangelical Lutheran Church of Glendale v. County of Los Angeles FACTS: the church owned land downhill from land owned by the National Forest Service. A forest fire and subsequent flooding on the National Forest induced Los Angeles to enact an ordinance precluding building on church owned land. The Church sued, contending that the ordinance constituted a taking without just compensation. The trial court ruled such an ordinance constituted a regulatory taking which until found to violate due process did not give rise to the obligation to compensate. The court of appeals affirmed, the California Supreme court denied review, and the US Supreme Court granted a hearing. HOLDING: A landowner whose property is taken by a land use regulation may recover for the time before final determination that a constitutional taking has occurred. Temporary takings which deny a landowner all use of his property are not different in kind from permanent taking for which just compensation is mandated. The purpose of the fifth amendment just compensation clause is to prevent the government from forcing some people alone to bear the burden. Thus, the judgment is vacated and the decision reversed. DISSENT: the decision invites useless litigation. Only physical takings are compensable. Regulatory takings are compensable only in the extreme case. State remedies should be exhausted before federal relief is obtained. NOTES: (1) this case overrules in part a decision of the CA Supreme Court on this issue. In Agnis v. Tiburon, it was held that 98 (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) compensation was not due until a constitutional taking occurred. A regulatory taking was not considered intrusive enough to require compensation. Although the US Supreme Court affirmed Agnis on other grounds, it never reached the issue presented here until this case. The court found that the ordinance did not work a taking b/c it did not deny all use of the property and uses it did deny could be constitutionally prohibited to protect the public safety. Eight states, after the case, had state constitutions that required damages to be paid when a regulation goes too far, and seven required compensation for temporary takings. The cutting edge of the land use decisions is found in the state supreme court where, for a number of reasons, issue of local government and if its regulation seem to be better under stood than they are in Washington DC Cons of compensatory remedy: inhibits community planning and chills exercises of police power, usurps the legislature’s power to make decisions about public expenditures, P may recover a windfall if the regulation is later repealed after compensation has been paid for the temporary taking Pros of compensatory remedy: regulatory action can destroy use and enjoyment of property just as effectively as physical occupation or destruction, overzealous regulation can also be compensable, especially b/c invalidation of itself fails to compensate for losses that were wrongfully imposed The threat of governmental financial liability for unconstitutional exercises of the police power would help produce more rational land-use controls, ones that more carefully weighed costs against benefits. What is the measure of damages? There are various possibilities, such as fair rental value, option price, interest on lost 99 profits, before and after valuation, and the benefit to the government (9) Inverse condemnation suits seeking compensation for regulatory takings are generally to be pursued in the first instance in state courts. Constitutional challenges in federal courts are not usually ripe until a state denies compensation, b/c states are free to take property for legitimate governmental purposes, provided that only they pay. (10) The Tucker Act and the Court of Federal Claims: the Tucker Act provides jurisdiction in the US Court of Federal Claims for damages claims against the federal government founded on the constitution, a regulation, or an express or implied contract. IF a regulation works a taking, then the claim for compensation is founded on the constitution and within the court’s jurisdiction. This is to provide a forum for monetary claims against the government and effectively move a large number of takings cases against the federal government into the court of Federal Claims – a point that would perhaps be unremarkable were it not for the fact that the court is thought by some observers to have titled to the right. 3. Rules of Decision (1987 and beyond) a. Nollan v. California Coastal Commission FACTS: The Nollans owned certain beach front property. They applied for a permit to build a residence upon it. The CA Coastal Commission (D), finding that such a sue would impeded public viewing of the beach, conditioned the permit upon the Nollan’s granting of a public easement permitting lateral movement along the Nollan’s property to adjacent public beaches. The Nollan’s challenged this as a deprivation of property rights without due process. The trial court agreed and enjoined the condition. The court of appeal reversed. The US Supreme Court accepted review. HOLDING: A state may not condition a property use on an act not addressing the problem caused by the permitted use. A land use regulation does 100 b. not effect a taking is it substantially advances legitimate state interests and does not deny an owner economically viable use of the land. Thus, when state finds a public interest and does not leave the owner with useless property, no taking occurs when a land use is prohibited. However, this constitutional propriety disappears when the condition substituted for outright prohibition fails to further the end advanced as the justification for the prohibition. When his occurs, the prohibition no longer becomes a vehicle for advancing a state interest, but rather a manner of extorting a property right without paying just compensation. Here, the recognized public interest was preventing the blockage of the beach from public view. The condition, providing an easement for lateral public access along the beach, does nothing to alleviate this perceived problem. The conditional use, therefore, fails to advance a state interest and therefore constitutes a taking. Reversed NOTES: (1) The court was far from clear as to what sort of nexus must exist between a condition and the interest advanced by the original prohibition. A tone point, the opinion notes that a taking will occur is there is utterly no connection, which implies only a slight relationship being necessary. On the other hand, language in the opinion speaks of a substantial relationship being necessary. Dolan v. City of Tigard FACTS: The state of Oregon enacted a comprehensive land use management program in 1973 that required property owners in the area zoned as Central Business District to comply with the 15% open space requirement and landscaping that limited the total site coverage; including structures and paved parking lots to 85% of the parcel; required that new development dedicate land for pedestrian and bike pathways; and required in accord with a Master Drainage plan, various improvements tot he Fanno Creek Basin. Petitioner owns a [plumbing and electric supply store located on Main Street in the City and Fanno creeks flows along its western boundary. 101 Petitioner applied to the city for a permit to redevelop the site and her proposed plans called for nearly doubling the size of the store and paving a parking lot. The proposed expansions and the intensified use were consistent with the city’s zoning scheme. The city planing Commission granted the permit application subject to conditions imposed by the city’s CDFC: sufficient open land for a greenway adjoining the floodplain, and construction of a bike path. Petitioner requested variances since the dedication required 10%of her property and was denied. The Land Use Board of Appeals assumed the city’s findings about the impact of the development were correct and affirmed b/c there was a reasonable relationship between the development and the requirements. The court of appeals also confirmed and Petitioner kept appealing HOLDING: one of the principle purposes of the takings clause is to bar the government from forcing some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole. The public access required of Petitioner would deprive petitioner of the right to exclude others, one of the most essential sticks in the bundle of rights that are commonly characterized as property. No doubt the prevention of flooding along Fanno Creek and the reduction of traffic congestion in the Central Business District qualify as the type of legitimate purpose we have upheld. While the city has alleged that the traffic would increase and the floodplain is necessary, if the local government cannot demonstrate that its exaction is directly proportional to the specifically created need, the exaction becomes a veiled exercise of the power of eminent domain and a confiscation of the private property behind the defense of police regulations. Municipalities must show a rough proportionality between the required dedication and the impact of the proposed development. The findings of fact that the bike path OCULD offset some of the traffic demand is a far cry from the finding that the bike path WILL or is LIKELY TO offset some of the traffic demand. No mathematical calculation is 102 c. required, but the city must make some effort to quantify its findings in support of the dedication for the bike path beyond a conclusory statement that it could offset some of the traffic demand generated. It is also difficult to see why a public greenway as opposed to a private one is required in the interest of flood control. Therefore, the judgment is reversed and the case is remanded for further proceedings consistent with this opinion. NOTES: (1) exaction’s of the sport at issue in Nollan and Dolan are local government measures that requires developers to provide goods and services or pay fees as a condition to getting project approval. Exactions quickly became a common way of funding public improvements and became so common and troublesome that the Supreme Court intervened. (2) In Nolan the court held that there must be some logical connection – some nexus – between exaction and the regulation excepted in exchange for it. In Dolan, the court went further and held that even when a nexus exists, there must also be some rough proportionality between the thing exacted and the development permitted in exchange. (3) Impact fees are exactions too but they exact money instead of goods. Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council FACTS: Lucas purchased residential lots for $975,000 on the Isle of Palms, a barrier island off the coats of South Carolina, on which he planned to build single family homes. The Isle of Palms development, of which Lucas was a coowner, was located on highly unstable ground, prone to flooding and erosion. At the time of the purchase, the state, county and town had not imposed any restrictions on the residential use of property. However, two years after P’s purchase, but before construction, D enacted the Beachfront Management Act, in an attempt to counteract the critical erosion if the SC Beaches. The Act prohibited, without exception, the construction of any habitable improvements seaward of the baseline connecting historical 103 points of erosion on the Isle of Palms. P'’ lots were located within the restricted area. He filed suit against D contending that the Acts’ ban on construction amounted to a taking of his property without just compensation. He conceded that the act was lawful exercise of SC’s police power but claimed that the act rendered his property valueless, entitling him to compensation. The trial court agreed and ordered South Carolina reversed ruling that when an otherwise valid regulation respecting the use of property is designed to prevent public harm, as was this act, no compensation was owned. Lucas appealed. HOLDING: The state mist compensate a landowner when a regulatory action denies an owner economically valuable use of his land, unless prohibited use of the land constitutes a nuisance under state common law. Traditionally, compensation has been required for two separate categories of regulatory actions: those that cause a physical invasion of private property, and those that deprive a landowner of all economically beneficial or productive use of the land. However, there is also a long line of cases denying compensation to owners whose property is regulated to prevent a public harm in which the law prohibits use without compensation. The co9urt’s contemporary analysis is that there is no taking if a land-use regulation substantially advances a legitimate state interest. Whether the regulation prevents a harmful use can no longer be the basis for an exception from the rule that total regulatory taking must be compensated; if it were, no compensation would ever be necessary, since most regulations may be described as mitigating some harm, depending on the observer’s point of view. Instead, a better test is that confiscatory regulations, i.e. those that prohibit all economically beneficial use of the land, may not be enacted without compensation unless the relation serves to prohibit a purpose that was already unlawful under existing nuisance and property law. In this case, the act rendered Lucas’ lots valueless by remaining that they remain in their natural state. Therefore, D must 104 d. either identify their relevant common law principles of nuisance and property that would prohibit construction on the beach front property or compensate him for the value of the property. DISSENT: the court has consistently upheld regulations that prohibit an owner from using his property in a way that is harmful to the public. P never challenged the legislature’s findings that a building ban was necessary to profit property and life and therefore, the lower court correctly found no taking. The majority has created a new rule and a new exception, based on the trial court’s finding that the property had lost all its economic value. There is no reason to believe that the majority’s claim that the new interpretation of the old common-law nuisance doctrine will be any more objective or value-free than reliance on legislative judgments of what constitutes a harm. NOTES: (1) Lucas altered the nuisance exception. Court, not legislature, now has the authority as to what land use is injurious. (2) The court noted that the Lucas regulation was passed after the P’s acquired title and this is important (3) Generally speaking state courts appear to reject conceptual severance; they consider the impact of land use regulation on the value of a property owner’s entire parcel as opposed to its impact on just the regulated part (4) Not many court actually relied on Lucas... courts rarely find the condition that all economic use is gone Notes: Academic Perspectives on Taking 105