TAKINGS AND THE ENVIRONMENT SEMINAR ASSIGNMENT 5 Kelo and Its Progeny Reading: Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005) Notes and Questions: 1. Following the Supreme Court’s decision in Kelo, the law of public use—which seemed to be well-settled after Midkiff—became one of the most controversial doctrines in American constitutional law. According to a Wall Street Journal/NBC News poll, “In the wake of the court's eminent domain decision, Americans overall cite ‘private-property rights’ as the current legal issue they care most about, topping parental notification for minors’ abortions or state right-to-die laws.” Wall Street Journal, July 15, 2005, at A4. 2. As Justice Stevens explains in his opinion of the Court, condemnation of private property for civic redevelopment projects has been recognized as a public use since Berman, and the constitutional policy of judicial deference to federal, state, and local governmental decisions about the appropriate use of the power of eminent domain goes back as far as Gettysburg. Would the dissenters overrule these decisions? Please note that, while Justice O’Connor observes that Midkiff recognized that a “purely private taking” would violate the public use requirement, she does not mention the deferential standard of review of this question that she articulated in her opinion of the Court in Midkiff: “Where the exercise of the eminent domain power is rationally related to a conceivable public purpose, the Court has never held a 1 compensated taking to be proscribed by the Public Use Clause.” Does Justice O’Connor persuasively distinguish her own opinion of the Court in Midkiff? 3. What standard of judicial review of public use cases would the Kelo dissent adopt? Would the dissenters in Kelo overrule Midkiff? Would it be good policy to hold that all condemnations of private property for civic redevelopment projects—at least where the property will be owned and managed by another private entity following completion of the project—are unconstitutional? Under this standard, what degree of public ownership, control, or access would satisfy the public use standard? Who would make this decision—the courts or the governmental entity that exercised the power of eminent domain? What standard of judicial review should apply to this analysis? 4. Are you persuaded by Justice Thomas’ analysis of the history of takings for public use? Do the 19th and early 20th Century cases support his interpretation? Do you agree with Justice Thomas’ emphasis that the public use requirement (as well as the takings clause generally) creates a judicially enforceable right of equal status with other provisions of the Bill of Rights? 5. If the Kelo dissenters gain a majority and overrule the governing public use law, which of the following projects would satisfy their public use standard: Condemnation of a variety of retail stores, small businesses, and private rental housing to make way for construction of a new Transbay Terminal in San Francisco. Condemnation of Red’s Java House on the Embarcadero for construction of a new deepwater port for cruise ships docking at the Port of San Francisco. What if the project includes a variety of private businesses, such as restaurants and shops? Condemnation of private homes and residential rental units in a “blighted” part of San Francisco as part of an urban redevelopment project that will include new housing and retail establishments. 6. What is the point of Justice Kennedy’s concurring opinion in Kelo? Does it limit the majority’s definition of public use in any significant way? 7. The reaction to Kelo was highly critical. The Wall Street Journal’s editorial, published just after the decision, provides a good example of the tenor of the debate: They Paved Paradise Wall Street Journal, June 20, 2005 Last week's Supreme Court ruling that local governments have more or less unlimited authority to seize private property has had us thinking of an old Joni Mitchell lyric: "They paved paradise and put up a parking lot/With a pink hotel, a boutique and a swingin' hot spot." "The Big Yellow Taxi" ought to be the theme song for the grassroots movement that is springing up in reaction to the Court's ruling in Kelo v. New London. Many people 2 aren't too familiar with the government's power of` "eminent domain." But when they learn that five Supreme Court justices believe New London, Connecticut, was justified in trying to evict homeowners in order to make way for a private hotel and corporate offices, the reaction is: How can I keep that from happening to me? As it happens, the Court's ruling offers a way out, inviting states to take remedial action. "Nothing in our opinion precludes any State from placing further restrictions on its exercise of the takings power," Justice John Paul Stevens wrote for the 5-4 majority. At least 10 states—Arkansas, Florida, Illinois, Kentucky, Maine, Michigan, Montana, South Carolina, Utah and Washington—already forbid the use of eminent domain for economic development (while permitting it for legitimate "public use," such as building a highway). Six states—Connecticut, Kansas, Maryland, Minnesota, New York and North Dakota—expressly allow private property to be taken for private economic purposes. The rest haven't spoken on the issue. But just wait. In Connecticut this week the house and senate debated legislation to forbid the taking of private homes for private economic development except in the case of blight. The bill failed, but Robert Ward, the Republican house minority leader and the bill's sponsor, says he plans to widen it to include takings of all private property and reintroduce it next month. He already has indications of support from Democrats who have been hearing from constituents outraged over Kelo. In Washington, Senators John Cornyn (R., Texas) and Bill Nelson (D., Florida) introduced legislation this week to bar the feds from using the power of eminent domain for private economic development as well as prohibit states from using federal money for that purpose. Scott Bullock, a lawyer who represented the New London homeowners in the Supreme Court, says his clients have been "besieged with expressions of support." Yesterday the Institute for Justice, the public interest law firm for which Mr. Bullock works, announced a $3 million "Hands Off My Home" campaign. It will work with local activists to fight government seizures of private property and pass state laws limiting the use of eminent domain. Meanwhile, Justice David Souter may soon get an up-close-and-personal lesson in how Kelo can affect ordinary homeowners. An outraged citizen announced this week that he is starting the application process to build a hotel on property owned by the Justice in New Hampshire. The "City of Weare will certainly gain greater tax revenue and economic benefits with a hotel on 34 Cilley Hill Road than allowing Mr. Souter to own the land," Logan Darrow Clements said in a press release. Mr. Clements plans to call his new development the "Lost Liberty Hotel." [Fortunately for Justice Souter, the Town Council voted down the condemnation proposal.] 8. The following week, Professor Richard Epstein of the University of Chicago Law School published a highly critical commentary on Kelo:: 3 Richard A. Epstein, Supreme Folly Wall Street Journal, June 27, 2005 Last week's regrettable 5-4 decision in Kelo v. City of New London marks a new low point in the Supreme Court's takings jurisprudence. The Constitution allows private property to be taken for public use only on payment of just compensation. But what counts as public use? In Kelo, Justice John Paul Stevens held that courts, especially federal courts, should be hugely deferential to a government decision, done after comprehensive hearings, to displace one private property owner in favor of a second private party in the name of overall economic development. To understand why Kelo is truly horrible, it is necessary to look both at Kelo and the constitutional logic of public use requirement. On the former, the declining economic fortunes of New London spurred the city elders to embark on a general urban development plan, underwritten by $73 million in state money devoted to general planning, physical infrastructure and environmental cleanup. The plan lacked only one ingredient—some real live developer prepared to risk his own capital to build any office or hotel on part of the 90 or so acres the City already had. Not content with its overheated vision, New London's plan envisioned taking down about 15 old homes overlooking Long Island Sound, to be used for some unidentified form of "park support." Fancy new private homes were not listed on the plan. None of the endless frustration and delays in implementing its grand plan were attributable to the decision of some landowners to fight New London. Quite simply, the slow rate of development made obsolete some of the original projects, such as a luxury hotel to support a new nearby Pfizer facility. Pfizer could not wait 10 years to house its visiting dignitaries. One obvious compromise position, therefore, should have appealed even to the five member majority on the Supreme Court: to force the City to postpone the condemnation of these private homes until the City revealed its hand. No such luck with Justice Stevens, for in his view New London had made its case when it asserted, without evidence, that the new projects would both increase tax revenues and create new jobs. It hardly mattered that its projections had been pulled out of thin air and were already hopelessly out of date when the case reached the Supreme Court. All that need be shown to Justice Stevens was procedural regularity and some claim that the proposed project served some "public benefit." Astute readers will quickly note that the phrase "public benefit" is far broader than the constitutional words "public use." That last phrase clearly covers only two situations. The first arises when land is taken to build government facilities, such as forts, or to construct infrastructure, such as highways, open to all. The second covers those cases where property is taken by, or conveyed to, private parties who are duty bound to keep it open to all users. Private railroads and private grist mills, both of which are subject to the common carrier obligation of universal service, are two obvious examples. Note too that once a given use is properly identified as public, it does not matter for constitutional purposes whether the project is wise or is as foolish as New London's redevelopment program. The constitutional inquiry is over once it is proved that the project falls into these categories. Factually, the standard of review hardly matters, for it takes little genius to prove that a given structure is a fort or a highway. There are, however, good reasons why the public use language has long been extended to cover some cases of takings for private purposes with indirect public benefits. One recurrent problem of social coordination arises when one party is in a position to blockade the productive 4 ventures of another. To take a real historical example, assume that the owner of a mine (who has no choice on where to dig) can only get his ore to market by ferrying it over scrub lands owned by another individual. That second landowner can demand a huge chunk of the mining profits for his trivial contribution to the overall venture. For over 100 years, the Supreme Court has allowed the state to condemn the obstructing property for the mine owner upon payment of just compensation, here measured by the trivial losses sustained by the obstructing landowner. The net gains from blocking the holdout are huge. The great intellectual blunder of the public use law over the past 50 or so years is that it has wrenched the public benefit language out of this narrow holdout context. In the mid-1950s, the Supreme Court held that takings were for public use when they were intended to relieve various forms of urban "blight"—a slippery term with no clear constitutional pedigree. Thirty years later, the Court went a step further by allowing Hawaii to force landlords to sell their interests to sitting tenants, as a means to counteracting ostensible "oligopolistic" market conditions. Now any "conceivable" indirect social benefit would do, without regard to the attendant costs. Given this past legacy, Justice Stevens found it easy to take New London at its word. Any comprehensive public project will produce some benefit for someone, so that—as Justices O'Connor and Thomas stressed in dissent—his test always allows the legislature to gin up some rationale for taking public property for just compensation (which alas falls far short of making the individual landowner whole: legal, appraisal and moving costs, for example, are systematically ignored). But the slightest bit of reflection should have shown just how the new public use cases have migrated from the old mining cases, or even under the Hawaii statute, which did not displace sitting tenants. In the present case, Susette Kelo and her fellow plaintiffs have not tried to extract some unconscionable gain out of some sensible business venture. They have no desire to sell their homes at all. At the same time their subjective losses have been enormous. It was a perfectly sensible line for the Court to say when subjective values are high, and holdout problems are nonexistent, the requisite public use is not present. The Court could only arrive at its shameful Kelo ruling by refusing to look closely at past precedent and constitutional logic. Courts that refuse to see no evil and hear no evil are blind to the endemic risk of factional politics at all levels of government. And being blind, this bare Supreme Court majority has sustained a scandalous and cruel act for no public purpose at all. 9. Following the decision in Kelo, forty-four states enacted legislation to restrict the authority of state agencies and local governments to condemn private property for public use. See CASTLE COALITION, 50 STATE REPORT CARD TRACKING EMINENT DOMAIN REFORM LEGISLATION SINCE KELO. A link to this report may be found on the “Assignments” web page. 10. California changed its eminent domain law by initiative in June 2008, when the electorate passed Proposition 99 by a vote of 62% to 38%. Proposition 99 amended Article I, Section 19 of the California Constitution to provide: (b) The State and local governments are prohibited from acquiring by eminent domain an owner-occupied residence for the purpose of conveying it to a private person. 5 (c) Subdivision (b) of this section does not apply when State or local government exercises the power of eminent domain for the purpose of protecting public health and safety; preventing serious, repeated criminal activity; responding to an emergency; or remedying environmental contamination that poses a threat to public health and safety. (d) Subdivision (b) of this section does not apply when State or local government exercises the power of eminent domain for the purpose of acquiring private property for a public work or improvement. Is this an adequate and appropriate response to Kelo? Are the exemptions set forth in subsections (c) and (d) likely to swallow the change in the law contained in subsection (b)? 11. The other state laws are a mixed bag. Some of the new laws directly address the issue in Kelo. According to Professor Ilya Somin: Fourteen state legislatures have enacted laws that either abolish or significantly constrain economic development takings. The most sweeping of these laws are Florida’s and New Mexico’s, which not only abolish condemnations for economic development, but also ban all blight condemnations, even those that occur in areas that would meet a strict definition of the term. Florida and New Mexico therefore became the second and third states to abolish blight condemnations, following in the footsteps of Utah, which did so prior to Kelo. Ilya Somin, The Limits of Backlash: Assessing the Political Response to Kelo, 93 Minn. L. Rev. 2100, 2138 (2009). Many of the other laws, however, create or preserve exemptions for “blighted areas,” and they define blight so broadly that most buildings in low income areas would qualify for condemnation. The Illinois eminent domain statute is representative. As described by Professor Somin, this statute exempts blight condemnations from its ban on economic development takings and retains its preexisting definition of blight, which defined a blighted area as one where “industrial, commercial, and residential buildings or improvements are detrimental to the public safety, health, or welfare because of a combination of 5 or more of the following factors.” The list of factors include dilapidation; obsolescence; deterioration; below minimum code standards; illegal use of structures; excessive vacancies; lack of ventilation, light, or sanitary facilities; inadequate utilities; excessive land coverage and overcrowding of structures and community facilities; deleterious land use or layout; environmental clean-up; lack of community planning; or an assessed value that has declined three of the last five years. The concept of “detriment” to “public welfare” is extremely broad and surely includes detriment to local economic welfare and development. Id. at 2125 (quoting 65 Ill. Comp. Stat. 5/11-74.4-3(a)(1) (2006)). 12. Other aspects of the political aftermath of Kelo are described in the following articles: Carolyn Lcohhead, Foes in Congress Unite in Defense of Property S.F. Chronicle, July 1, 2005 House and Senate Republican leaders, backed by Democratic African American liberals, moved rapidly Thursday on legislation to blunt last week's Supreme Court decision allowing local 6 governments to seize private property for economic development projects. Rep. Maxine Waters, a liberal Democrat from South Central Los Angeles, and Rep. Richard Pombo, a rock-ribbed conservative Republican from rural San Joaquin County—who rarely join forces on any issue— were among a group that introduced a bill to cut off federal funds for cities that use eminent domain for such projects. "Democrats and Republicans, conservatives and liberals are going to be organizing behind opposing the Supreme Court decision,'' Waters said. "It's like undermining motherhood and apple pie. I mean, people's homes and their land—it's very important, and it should be protected by government, not taken for somebody else's private use." Pombo, a longtime property rights advocate, said anger at the court's 5-4 decision in a case from New London, Conn., had united rural landowners with suburbanites and city dwellers fearful that cities will eye their homes for hotels, malls or any commercial use they think will generate more tax revenue. The Supreme Court "is way out of line on this,'' Pombo said. "There's nothing in the Constitution that allows them to step in and take property away from an individual and give it to somebody else." The action in Congress comes just months after Republicans suffered intense criticism for trying to intervene in court decisions to remove life support for Terri Schiavo in Florida and as Capitol Hill readies for a clash over a potential Supreme Court vacancy. The case was brought by the libertarian Institute for Justice and pitted nine landowners in New London against the city's efforts to build a marina, office and retail space on waterfront property near a new $300 million research facility built by pharmaceutical giant Pfizer Corp. The nine homeowners included Susette Kelo, who bought her home in 1997, and Wilhelmina Dery, who has lived in her home since her birth in 1918. The Fifth Amendment's eminent domain clause allows government to take private property for public use. Traditionally, this has meant land to build railroads, highways, schools and other public facilities. The government pays property owners a fair market price in exchange for the land. The question before the court was whether economic redevelopment projects that convert private property to other private uses constitute a "public purpose." The court, led by Justice John Paul Stevens, concluded that it does, arguing that the justices should defer to the decisions of local governments rather than "crafting an artificial restriction on the concept of public use." Justice Sandra Day O'Connor dissented, joined by three conservative justices, saying the decision would allow condemnation of any property. "For who among us can say she already makes the most productive or attractive possible use of her property?" O'Connor argued. "Nothing is to prevent the state from replacing any Motel 6 with a Ritz-Carlton, any home with a shopping mall, or any farm with a factory." In eight states, not including California, state high court rulings provide a higher level of property protection than the U.S. Supreme Court decision, said Dana Berliner, a lawyer with the Institute for Justice. The legislation introduced Thursday, backed by the chairman of the House Judiciary Committee, Rep. James Sensenbrenner, R-Wis., and its ranking Democrat, Rep. John Conyers of Michigan, would deprive cities of any federal funds for redevelopment projects that use the power of eminent domain. In a first step toward the legislation, the House voted 231-189 Thursday in favor of an amendment to an appropriations bill that would bar the departments of 7 Transportation, Treasury, and Housing and Urban Development from providing money to cities that use eminent domain for profit-making projects. Pombo said he has no worries about criticism that Congress is again trying to interfere with the judiciary, "because we're right on this. Honestly, I'd be shocked if anybody voted against this bill." Pombo noted that two prominent liberal organizations, the NAACP, a civil rights group, and AARP, a retiree group, sided with the property owners. "It doesn't take a genius to look at this and figure out who's going to be hurt by it," Pombo said. "It's not the big developers. It's not the wealthy. They have influence. They can stop the city council from taking their property. It's the poor guy who doesn't even know who his city councilman is that's going to be hurt." Pombo, of Tracy, won his seat in Congress and now chairs the House Natural Resources Committee in part because of his long crusade to protect landowners from alleged "regulatory takings" of their property through enforcement of such laws as the Endangered Species Act. The Kelo decision raises the stakes, he said. "This isn't about taking some farmer's ranch for endangered species habitat," Pombo said. "This is about taking your house because the city thinks it has a better use. This affects every homeowner in the country." House Democratic leader Nancy Pelosi of San Francisco opposes the bill and said Republicans are trying to interfere with the judiciary again. "This is in violation of the respect for separation of . . . powers in our Constitution," Pelosi said. Pelosi was careful not to say she approved of the high court's ruling. But she said the decision has been made and will require a constitutional amendment to reverse. People for the American Way, which is leading liberal opposition to President Bush's judicial nominees, noted that the Kelo ruling is among several narrowly divided decisions that demonstrate the importance of the fight over any Supreme Court vacancy. Elliot Mincberg, the group's legal director, said the case had been brought by the Institute for Justice as part of an effort by conservatives to elevate property rights to the same level of civil rights such as freedom of speech and religion, in effect taking the nation back to the pre-New Deal days when the courts ruled child labor laws unconstitutional. Mincberg said the court had ruled that "legislatures should decide if a taking is for public use, and we shouldn't get to review it based on the vague wording of the Constitution." Waters countered that city councils are not a good place for such decisions. "I am offended by the idea that a big, rich pharmaceutical company could get this kind of decision to build condominiums around a complex they built," Waters said. "I worry about these little cities and towns where big, wealthy developers can influence elected officials with large campaign contributions and undermine what public use and eminent domain was meant to be." Berliner, of the Institute for Justice, said poor areas were not the only ones targeted. "Developers want prime real estate, so that's what cities condemn," Berliner said. "That means waterfront property, property in the center of cities, property near transportation hubs, property in areas that are up and coming. All of those routinely get condemned for private development." [The Private Property Rights Protection Act, H.R. 4128, 109th Cong. (2005), passed the House of Representatives by a 376 to 37 margin, but died in the Senate.] Jim Herron Zamora, Eminent Domain Ruling Chills Property Owners 8 S.F. Chronicle, July 18, 2005 An Oakland auto shop owner wants to save a business his family has owned since 1949. The owner of a dilapidated Art Deco theater in Alameda is resisting plans to replace it with a multiplex, while a 70-year-old man who wants to erect a "green" building in Santa Cruz is fighting city efforts to seize his vacant lot. Those and other property battles in Northern California have gained new attention since the U.S. Supreme Court's 5-4 decision last month made it easier for local governments to force unwilling property owners to sell using eminent domain. The decision, based on a Connecticut case in which a city wanted to tear down an older waterfront neighborhood and turn it over to a developer, makes it easier for cities and counties to help rebuild aging downtowns and construct projects such as BART transit villages. Emboldened by the high court's ruling, the agencies argue that economic development benefiting a region outweighs individual property rights. But it has also led to a growing backlash and galvanized an odd coalition: Conservative property rights advocates see eminent domain as big government run amok, while liberals and minorities view it as a tool for powerful developers to tear up communities and bully the little guy. "No one should have to worry about losing your home to some politically connected developer," said state Sen. Tom McClintock, R-Thousand Oaks. "There are 6,000 public agencies in California that now have the power to seize your home, pay you pennies on the dollar for it, and then give it to somebody else for their own personal gain and profit." On Thursday, McClintock and state Sen. Dean Florez, D-Shafter (Kern County), introduced a bill to prevent public agencies from taking land from one private owner and giving it to another for development purposes. And conservative U.S. Rep. Richard Pombo, R-Tracy, is working with liberal urban representatives Maxine Waters, D-Los Angeles, and John Conyers of Michigan to deny federal funds to cities that use eminent domain to benefit private developers. "It's kind of a strange coalition," Pombo said Friday. "But there is something about taking your property this way that makes lots of Americans angry. The reason that we have a Bill of Rights is to protect individuals from the majority." If passed, the bills would stop projects in Alameda and Santa Cruz, and could force changes in Oakland and dozens of other cities. Redevelopment is a process that allows cities to keep a bigger portion of future property tax revenues in a given area, which can amount to millions of dollars if businesses move in and new homes are built. That process has allowed San Francisco to rebuild much of the South of Market area and Emeryville to transform itself from an industrial slum to a regional shopping hub. Cities with pending projects point out the long-term benefits of redevelopment. In Santa Cruz, the city has rebuilt much of downtown after the Loma Prieta earthquake devastated the area in 1989. In Alameda, city officials are using redevelopment to bring in new businesses, including what they hope will be the city's first multiplex theater. Local government must declare the target zone to be blighted in order for it to become eligible for redevelopment. That once was relatively easy in many communities. Much of Oakland below Interstate 580, for example, has been a redevelopment area for decades. But with property values skyrocketing in the Bay Area, many residents have become wary of redevelopment and panic at the idea of eminent domain. "Redevelopment is good way to keep money in a community and fund improvements that we can't afford any other way," said Oakland 9 City Councilwoman Jane Brunner, who has been meeting with skeptical residents and neighbors about plans to turn much of the North Oakland flatlands into a redevelopment area. "But I respect the concerns of people who worry about this. . . . This is a discussion we need to have." At a community meeting Wednesday, Brunner pointed out projects that redevelopment has funded in the city—new development adjacent to the Fruitvale BART station and attractive new sidewalks and bike trails along Mandela Parkway in West Oakland. In Oakland, many of the properties that the city has bought and resold to developers in the past were nearly abandoned structures or buildings that were covered with graffiti. But on July 1, John Revelli and Tony Fung were evicted from their profitable but small owner-operated auto repair shops near the 19th Street BART station to make way for the Uptown Project, which is expected to include nearly 1,200 apartments and condominiums. The development, which is receiving a $61 million public subsidy, is the centerpiece of Mayor Jerry Brown's plan to bring 10,000 more residents to downtown Oakland. Revelli, 65, grew up helping his father and uncle in the family tire shop and worked there full time since he was 19. "I just want to stay in business," Revelli said after giving his keys to a city employee. "But it's impossible for me to find another location that good in downtown Oakland. We owned the property and had low overhead. I can't match that at another site. They put me out of business." Eminent domain has also left bitter feelings in San Jose and Redwood City, where property owners successfully resisted efforts to force them to sell. In San Jose, a multiethnic group of merchants at the Tropicana Shopping Center won its court battle in 2003 and stopped a city effort to condemn the mall as blighted and turn it over to a private developer for redevelopment. City officials have not decided whether to try again in light of the Supreme Court decision. In Redwood City, the Celotti family finally agreed last year to sell their downtown property to city's redevelopment agency—for about five times its original offer. Their decision followed a San Mateo County Superior Court ruling that the city could not use eminent domain to condemn the property. But the ruling came too late—the Celottis' building had been demolished in 2003. The city paid them $3 million and made a formal apology as part of the settlement. Ron Lau of Santa Cruz and John Cocores in Alameda are fighting redevelopment efforts despite the Supreme Court decision. Lau, 70, owns a now-vacant lot that formerly housed a popular downtown bookstore and cafe that were seriously damaged in the earthquake. Lau, 70, wants to create "a self-sufficient, fully green building" on the lot but has been unable to obtain financing for his project. In an effort to hasten development, the city is trying to force him to sell so another developer can take over. "I don't like being pressured,'' said Lau, who rejected $1.6 million for his lot on Pacific Avenue. "I care about this property and what happens to it. Otherwise I would have sold out." Cocores owns the 1932-vintage Alameda Theater and some adjacent storefront property on Central Avenue near Park Street in Alameda. The city offered him $1.5 million in May for the 33,000-square- foot concrete and steel- frame structure. But Cocores' real estate agent said the property would be worth more than twice that figure if not for the looming threat of eminent domain. "We're real far apart on the price," said Cocores' agent, Don Lindsey. "That property was appraised at $3 million. It's not fair to force him to take less." 10 Pombo, who tracks local eminent domain disputes, pledges that help is on the way. "A movie theater, a department store or a mall are not public uses," Pombo said Friday. "They are not taking this land to build roads to schools or parks; they are just helping politically powerful interests. I'd like to stop projects like these dead in their tracks. " Ralph Blumenthal, Humble Church is at Center of Debate on Eminent Domain N.Y. Times, Jan. 25, 2006 With bulldozers churning up the earth at the front door, the small Centennial Baptist Church in this struggling industrial hub west of Tulsa seems about to fall to the wrecker. But the construction is just roadwork, for now. And that is all it will ever be if the congregation has its way. "The Lord didn't send me here to build a mini-mall," said the longtime pastor, the Rev. Roosevelt Gildon. In what a local newspaper called "a battle between God Almighty and the almighty dollar," Sand Springs is moving ahead with a redevelopment plan to clear the church and other occupants from the rundown district near downtown to make way for superstores like the Home Depot. "I'm open to anyone telling me how we're going to pay for city services," said Mayor Bob Walker, who said the city was seeking to negotiate fair prices with Mr. Gildon and other property owners—41 offers have been accepted—and would use eminent domain only as a last resort. Strengthened by a United States Supreme Court ruling last summer that approved the condemnation of private property by New London, Conn., for resale to other private interests for what the court called "public purpose," municipalities around the country are considering similar forced takings, to a chorus of opposition by local interests and state legislators. Bills to block such seizures are on the docket in Oklahoma and many other states, along with other ballot initiatives. Last summer, the Texas Legislature banned the taking of private property for more lucrative public ventures. Here in Sand Springs, a city of 17,600 on the Arkansas River founded by Charles Page, the oilman, industrialist and philanthropist, the redevelopment plan dates from 2003. County voters agreed to add fractions of a penny to the sales tax for special projects, in the Sand Springs case $14.5 million to acquire private tracts on 96 acres along the highway for redevelopment. But the project was thrust into the national spotlight on Jan. 17 with an article posted on National Review Online by a conservative group, Americans for Limited Government, based in Glenview, Ill., that has been working with Oklahomans in Action and other groups to gather signatures for the "Protect Our Homes" movement and budget-curbing measures on state ballots. "It's not just grandma's house we have to worry about," wrote Heather Wilhelm, communications director for the limited government group. "Now it's God's house, too." The Sand Springs Leader stepped up coverage of Mr. Gildon, and a local radio host, Dillon Dodge, broadcast a program on the dispute. "Hannity and Colmes," the talk show on the Fox News Channel, plans a program from Sand Springs on Wednesday, Ms. Wilhelm said. City officials, mortified at being portrayed as villains, protested that they had not seized any property and might not. "Eminent domain is not being used at this time to acquire property," City Manager Loy Calhoun said in a statement Friday. "Media reports to the contrary are inaccurate." But in interviews, Mr. Calhoun and Mayor Walker acknowledged that it remained a last resort if the city and property owners could not agree on price. 11 Mr. Gildon, sitting in a pew of the church that he has led for 14 years, the last seven in a new building that cost $90,000, said he and other leaders of the congregation met last week with a relocation agent working for the city, the Cinnabar Service Company, and came away believing that they had little choice but to sell. "If you tell me this is going to happen," he said, "that tells me it's eminent domain." He said the offer of $142,000 for the church and two extra lots was not enough to move to a new location where he could serve his 50 or so regular members. He said he was "praying over" the question of a counteroffer. "If I have to move," he said, "we're not going out of existence." Mr. Gildon, 48, who works full time for a machine tool manufacturer and is paid $520 a month by the church, said he was not leading a crusade on the issue and made a point of not bringing it up it up in his sermons. "I've had to say, 'Don't let it go to your head,' " he said he told congregants. "We're not celebrities. We're here for God." But he said he was no pushover, either. He taped the meeting with the Cinnabar agent, John Thomas, and said he told city officials, "The Lord did not lead me here to sell out the church." If the parties cannot agree, a team of three appointed appraisers devises a final offer, and whether or not the seller is happy, the city can take it for that price - and sell it to someone else. Other property owners in the first 25-acre redevelopment zone said they felt that the city's initial offer of $1 a square foot was far too low. A fairer figure, several said, would be $8.50. "I don't have a problem with the city," said Joe Harrison, who runs the Firestone dealership downtown. "I just don't want them stealing my land." In the Muffler Stop a few blocks from the church, Ernie Nanney said the city first offered him $65,000 "which is less than I paid 25 years ago." He said that he counter-offered $350,000 and that the city came back with $85,000. In her small wood-frame house on Oak Street, Ray Jean Smith-Knight, 72, said that when she grew up a few houses away the neighborhood was "a little old Wall Street" of black professionals, and survivors of the Tulsa race riot of 1921 were welcomed to Sand Springs by Charles Page. Ms. Smith-Knight said that she had yet to receive a buyout offer and that despite the deterioration of the area did not relish leaving. "I'm not happy about it but I don't have a choice," she said. "So many people have passed away that used to be fighters. One or two cannot fight." Ruth Ellen Henry, founding director of the Sand Springs Cultural and Historical Museum, recalled a cleanup of the neighborhood a dozen years ago that removed a million pounds of debris but failed to halt its slide. She still has many friends there, she said, "but you can't say they tore down paradise and built a parking lot." John M. Broder, States Curbing Right to Seize Private Homes N.Y. Times, Feb. 21, 2006 In a rare display of unanimity that cuts across partisan and geographic lines, lawmakers in virtually every statehouse across the country are advancing bills and constitutional amendments to limit use of the government's power of eminent domain to seize private property for economic development purposes. The measures are in direct response to the United States Supreme Court's 5-to-4 decision last June in a landmark property rights case from Connecticut, upholding the authority of the City of New London to condemn homes in an aging neighborhood to make way for a private development of offices, condominiums and a hotel. It was a decision that one justice, who had written for the majority, later all but apologized for. 12 The reaction from the states was swift and heated. Within weeks of the court's decision, Texas, Alabama and Delaware passed bills by overwhelming bipartisan margins limiting the right of local governments to seize property and turn it over to private developers. Since then, lawmakers in three dozen other states have proposed similar restrictions and more are on the way, according to experts who track the issue. The National League of Cities, which supports the use of eminent domain as what it calls a necessary tool of urban development, has identified the issue as the most critical facing local governments this year. The league has called upon mayors and other local officials to lobby Congress and state legislators to try to stop the avalanche of bills to limit the power of government to take private property for presumed public good. The issue is not whether governments can condemn private property to build a public amenity like a road, a school or a sewage treatment plant. That power is explicit in the takings clause of the Fifth Amendment, provided that "just compensation" is paid. The conflict arises over government actions to seize private homes or businesses as part of a redevelopment project that at least partly benefits a private party like a retail store, an apartment complex or a football stadium. "It's open season on eminent domain," said Larry Morandi, a land-use specialist at the National Conference of State Legislatures. "Bills are being pushed by Democrats and Republicans, liberals and conservatives, and they're passing by huge margins." Seldom has a Supreme Court decision sparked such an immediate legislative reaction, and one that scrambles the usual partisan lines. Condemnation of the ruling came from black lawmakers representing distressed urban districts, from suburbanites and from Western property-rights absolutists who rarely see eye to eye on anything. Lawmakers from Maine to California have introduced dozens of bills in reaction to the ruling, most of them saying that government should never seize private homes or businesses solely to benefit a private developer, no matter what compensation is paid. The Supreme Court seemed to invite such a response in its narrowly written ruling in the case, Kelo v. City of New London. Justice John Paul Stevens, writing for the majority, expressed sympathy for the displaced homeowners and said that the "necessity and wisdom" of the use of eminent domain were issues of legitimate debate. And, he added, "We emphasize that nothing in our opinion precludes any state from placing further restrictions on its exercise of the takings power." Two months after the ruling, addressing a bar association meeting, Justice Stevens called it "unwise" and said he would have opposed it had he been a legislator and not a federal judge bound by precedent. Plenty of legislators took the hint. The issue was one of the first raised when Connecticut lawmakers returned to session early this month. There are bills pending in the Legislature to impose new restrictions on the use of eminent domain by local governments and to assure that displaced businesses and homeowners receive fair compensation. (The New London project is essentially delayed, even after the Supreme Court go-ahead, because of contractual disputes and an unwillingness to forcibly remove the homeowners who sued to save their properties.) In the New Jersey Legislature, Senator Nia H. Gill, a Democrat from Montclair who is chairwoman of the Commerce Committee, proposed a bill to outlaw the use of eminent domain to condemn residential property that is not completely run down to make room for a redevelopment project. The bill, which is pending, would require public hearings before any taking of private property to benefit a private development project. State Senator John A. DeFrancisco of New York has proposed a measure similar to one in several other states that would remove the right to exercise condemnation power from unelected bodies like an urban redevelopment authority or an industrial development agency. Mr. 13 DeFrancisco, a Republican from Syracuse, cited the case of a development agency in his hometown that has used its power to take valuable leases from existing mall tenants to allow a private developer to expand. Texas was one of the first states to act after the Kelo ruling, taking up the issue in a special legislative session that was supposed to focus solely on education. Gov. Rick Perry, a Republican, signed a bill on Sept. 1 that prohibits use of eminent domain to benefit a private party, with certain exceptions. Among those exceptions is the condemnation of homes to make way for a new stadium for the Dallas Cowboys. The sponsor of the Texas measure, Senator Kyle Janek, Republican of Houston, said the state was weighing a constitutional amendment to cement the eminent domain restrictions, but that process can take years. He sponsored his bill, he said, because "We wanted something in place quickly that the governor could sign and would take immediate effect." The bill could affect a huge highway project now in the planning stages known as the Trans-Texas Corridor, a public-private toll road and rail project that would require the taking of large swaths of privately owned land. There are six proposed laws and five constitutional amendments before the California Legislature, as well as several proposed citizen initiatives to curb the eminent domain power. The bills are supported by, among others, the California Farm Bureau Federation, which fears that the Kelo ruling will empower cities to gobble up more farmland to build subdivisions and strip malls. The lobbyist for California's local economic development agencies said the ruling and the resultant legislation had been a nightmare. "My life hasn't been the same since June 23, 2005," said the lobbyist, John F. Shirey, executive director of the California Redevelopment Association, referring to the date the Supreme Court handed down the ruling. The group represents 350 local redevelopment authorities around California and believes such agencies need the eminent domain power to rebuild distressed cities. "I've had to spend practically full time dealing with this issue and trying to get people to understand the Supreme Court decision didn't change anything in California law," Mr. Shirey said. Ohio's legislature, acting swiftly and unanimously after the Kelo decision, declared a moratorium on all government takings until the end of 2006. The state has created a 25-member bipartisan panel to study the issue and make recommendations for changes, if necessary, in Ohio's eminent domain statutes. The sponsor of the moratorium measure, Senator Timothy J. Grendell, a Republican lawyer who specializes in property rights cases, noted that the Ohio Supreme Court was now weighing a potentially critical eminent domain case involving the city of Norwood, a suburb of Cincinnati. In that case, city officials have approved a plan to condemn about 60 private homes to make way for an upscale office and retail complex. The homeowners are represented by lawyers from the Institute of Justice, a public interest law firm that litigates against what it calls eminent domain abuse and that represented the plaintiffs in the New London case. Scott G. Bullock of the Institute for Justice described the Norwood case as an important test of property rights law in the post-Kelo era, but would not predict how the Ohio court would rule. He said he hoped to take another case before the Supreme Court in the next few years to determine whether the courts can curb eminent domain power further, even as state legislatures act on their own. Mr. Bullock said he expected municipal officials and redevelopment authorities to try to fight the wave of eminent domain legislation by offering cosmetic changes to existing law, for example by requiring an extra hearing or an economic impact statement. But he said that major changes were coming in how the takings power of government is used. "Our opposition to eminent domain is not across the board," he said. "It has an important but limited role in 14 government planning and the building of roads, parks and public buildings. What we oppose is eminent domain abuse for private development, and we are encouraging legislators to curtail it." More neutral observers expressed concern that state officials, in their zeal to protect homeowners and small businesses, would handcuff local governments that are trying to revitalize dying cities and fill in blighted areas with projects that produce tax revenues and jobs. "It's fair to say that many states are on the verge of seriously overreacting to the Kelo decision," said John D. Echeverria, executive director of the Georgetown Environmental Law and Policy Institute and an authority on land-use policy. "The danger is that some legislators are going to attempt to destroy what is a significant and sometimes painful but essential government power. The extremist position is a prescription for economic decline for many metropolitan areas around the county." Patrick Hoge, Vote Goes Against Wal-Mart S.F. Chronicle, May 24, 2006 The Hercules City Council voted unanimously Tuesday night to take the unprecedented step of using eminent domain to prevent Wal-Mart from building a big-box store on a 17-acre lot near the city's waterfront. The vote caused most of the 300 people who had packed Hercules City Hall for the meeting to break out in cheers and applause. "The city of Hercules is very unique. People from the outside have to understand that," said Hercules Vice Mayor Ed Balico just before the vote. During a 90-minute public comment period that preceded the vote, nearly everyone who spoke urged the council to fight Wal-Mart. "Throw the bums out," Hercules resident Steve Kirby said at the podium of Wal-Mart. "Wal-Mart will never understand what we want." Another resident, Anita Roger-Fields, expressed concern for small businesses in the city, saying they could be driven out of business by the discount store. "[Wal-Mart is] the worst thing that could happen to our community. They want to crush the competition." The vote is the latest twist in a battle between the city and the discount-store chain, which wants to build a store near the city's historic waterfront. The city contends Wal-Mart's plan to build a discount store does not fit with its plans to develop the waterfront into a pedestrianoriented village with high-end shops and homes. "I'm elated. This is the result we wanted. The fact that it was unanimous is wonderful. Our City Council really came through," said Brenda Smith Johnson, an information technology vice president with JP Morgan Chase in San Francisco who moved to Hercules in 1992. "I know this is going to be a hard fight but we're up to it." Some residents were infuriated that Wal-Mart had warned that if the City Council voted for eminent domain, the move would cost the city millions. "I don't like to be threatened and they threatened my community," Bob Steiner, a certified public accountant and magician who lives in Hercules, said after the vote. Only five people spoke in favor of Wal-Mart. "The city has no guarantees that anybody is going to develop the property if they take it away from Wal-Mart," said Hercules resident Andre Wilson. The vote allows the city to begin proceedings to acquire Wal-Mart's property by force to achieve its redevelopment goals. Following the vote, Wal-Mart spokesman Kevin Loscotoff said Wal-Mart will evaluate the situation and decide what to do next. The city was once a company town, home to a dynamite plant that during World War I was the nation's leading producer of TNT, and some turn-of-the-century homes that used to house 15 company officials have been restored. The city plans to continue developing land along the waterfront to fit its vision. "Why should we have to sell ourselves short when we have this great waterfront," Hercules resident Valerie Wilgus said following the vote. Some residents have said they would prefer grocery stores such as Whole Foods, Trader Joe's or Andronico's, and specialty shops like those in Berkeley's swank Fourth Street district. The vote comes after Wal-Mart rejected a city offer to buy its property earlier this year. Officials from the nation's largest retailer have said they are determined to open a store on the company's 17 acres overlooking San Pablo Bay. In a letter to the city on Tuesday, Wal-Mart attorneys argued that eminent domain was unnecessary because the company had tailored its project to meet the community's desires, downsizing the proposed store and garden center from 167,000 square feet to roughly 100,000 square feet and designing the shopping center to have "a very attractive, village-like appearance." But critics countered that Wal-Mart's latest plan was still more than 50 percent larger than a store plan approved for the site before the retail giant bought the property. The city was the first in the state to adopt a redevelopment code that prescribes the design of streets, building dimensions and some architectural requirements, such as front porches. A key part of the plan called for a waterfront village with high-density housing and shops, a shoreline park, a train station, bus service and even a ferry stop. Carla T. Main, The “Blight” Excuse Wall Street Journal, June 23, 2007 In Brandon, Ore. there lives a one-armed man named Scott Cook who owns incomeproducing timberland. The state revoked his license to drive a truck on account of his having only one arm. Then the government decided it wasn't quite through with him: Now his land is being taken by the town by eminent domain, so his neighbor's golf resort can be expanded. The town likes the resort because it supplies jobs. Mr. Cook feels certain he will never get what his land is worth. He is outraged that his town would take land from one man to give to another. This is called an "economic development" taking, and two years ago—June 23, 2005—the nation was up in arms over this sort of thing. On that day the Supreme Court decided Kelo v. New London, and said that it is constitutional for the government to take your property and give it to someone else if doing so will rake in greater taxes for your town. Americans were instantly united in bipartisan fury. The U.S. Congress swiftly passed a resolution condemning Kelo, and the House and Senate introduced a slew of bills, to curb what so many perceived as the power of eminent domain run amok. More than a hundred bills were introduced in state legislatures to accomplish the same end, and two states passed moratoriums on economic development takings. Pundits spilled ink declaring that the Founding Fathers were spinning in their graves. Spittle flew as politicians grabbed the nearest mike, rushing to condemn Kelo as the unquestioned death knell of American property rights. But how is it we still have someone like the soon-to-be-timberless Mr. Cook? Well, a year went by and the moratoriums were lifted. Congress never did pass any of the bills. Reform was left to the states. Some states, such as Oregon (hence Mr. Cook's bad luck), California, New York and New Jersey passed no meaningful reforms. The latter three are among the most active in these kinds of takings. 16 Some 28 states have passed substantive eminent domain reform since Kelo. Many enacted laws that prohibited private-to-private transfers for purposes of economic development. Sounds grand, right? But there's a loophole: blight. Armed with a blight exception, private property in nearly all of the loophole states may still be condemned and ultimately used for economic development. Put another way, once a finding of blight is made, it's anchors away to build whatever the city or a private developer fancies. This leaves property owners vulnerable to unholy alliances between municipalities and developers, with condemnation processes that can lack transparency and due process. In 1954, Supreme Court Justice William O. Douglas unleashed municipalities with the ruling in Berman v. Parker: The liberal court at its apex unanimously agreed with the notion that the elimination of blight is a "public use" under the takings clause of the Constitution. But what is blight? A half-century of experience has demonstrated only that it is in the eye of the beholder, or perhaps more to the point, in the eye of the power holder. Blight standards are notoriously subjective; it just isn't that hard to find when one goes looking for it. And Congress conveniently passed statutes that rewarded municipalities with federal dough for slum clearance. Bingo! Cities found ever more blight to remove, often and not coincidentally in neighborhoods inhabited by blacks and Latinos. Now, even in the backlash against Kelo, eliminating blight as a ground for eminent domain has proven to be close to impossible. The importance of this problem must not be underestimated if we are to understand why takings for economic development have been so hard to stop. Even when common sense would dictate that a project is economic in purpose, it can still be pursued under an urban renewal plan, i.e., to eliminate "blight." In our post-Kelo world, the vocabulary of economic development takings may have changed, but in many states the substance will not, especially as towns learn to teach to the test. Only Utah and Florida passed statutes that eliminated the blight loophole—stating plainly, no economic development takings, ever. The relief in Utah was short-lived. On March 20, 2007, Utah reversed course. Gov. Jon Huntsman signed a bill that restores blight to the table and allows the taking of private property for private development so long as 80% of one's neighbors concur—a democratic scenario one homeowner called "mob rule." Florida's law was passed under the white-hot intensity of the Riviera Beach controversy, a massive project that gained national media attention right after Kelo. This development was the brainchild of former Mayor Michael Brown, who wanted to "save" his mostly black city by ejecting some 1,000 homeowners from their modest seaside bungalows that sit on valuable land not far from Palm Beach. Then a great condo and yacht marina complex could be built on this formerly "blighted" land. The post-Kelo media wave, with support from then Republican Gov. Jeb Bush, helped push Florida's reform bill through and oust the Riviera Beach council, thus killing the project. It remains to be seen how long condo and yacht club developers, big box retailers and the lawmakers they lobby will wait in the wings before obtaining changes in Florida's law. Fellow legislators wonder too. Ohio conducted a year-long, post-Kelo dog-and-pony show of hearings by an eminent domain task force. It issued a lengthy report—but the legislature has passed no laws. One member of the task force, unable to envision a world without eminent domain bulldozers, commented to me about Florida's law: "I don't know how they plan to renovate their barrios down there." 17 At the other end of the spectrum from Utah and Florida there is New Jersey, which has seemingly never met an eminent domain project it didn't like. Events in the Garden State are an object lesson in how post-Kelo politics can devolve. New Jersey Public Advocate Ronald Chen, appointed by Gov. John Corzine, has championed the cause of basic reforms such as giving homeowners notice before condemning their property, improving compensation, and putting the burden on powerful developers to justify a taking by showing that the property is blighted. As a result, Mr. Chen has found himself mired in the down and dirty muck one finds at the intersection of real estate and money in New Jersey politics. State senators have publicly excoriated him in a legislative hearing for something as ordinary as daring to file amicus briefs in eminent domain cases. Meanwhile, change has come at an excruciatingly slow pace. Reform bills have been introduced, but none has passed. Working class octogenarians in Long Branch continue their fight to keep their small oceanfront homes—now valuable—from the grasp of condo builders; trailer park residents in Lodi have to litigate to hold on in a town that wants to upgrade its residents. In Paulsboro, the taking of empty warehouses and vacant land was challenged; the New Jersey Supreme Court held it does not pass muster to say a property is blighted simply because it is "not fully productive." The decision was hailed, though it did not invalidate the redevelopment law that spawns such takings. Still, it's a faint light in a very dark tunnel, and similar to a decision by Ohio's Supreme Court, Gamble v. Norwood, in which a working class neighborhood was slated for urban renewal, not because it was deteriorated, but because it was "deteriorating." The court struck the term down as unconstitutionally vague. In the summer of 2005, even as impassioned speeches to protect private property rights were made to the media on state house steps around the country, resistance was brought to bear inside by interest groups. The result is a national landscape that continues to include barely fettered economic development takings under the blight umbrella. With each Kelo anniversary, the politics will become more partisan as we forget our initial outrage. While the reforms can improve due process, such as those Mr. Chen recommends, many have aimed at narrowing -- but not eliminating -- blight exceptions. We need to take care. Developers will always look for eminent domain bargains, and towns for ways to raise revenue or rid themselves of undesirable populations. It is not hard to imagine a time when they will set their sights on the surest bets -- the poor and minorities -- resetting eminent domain on its most pernicious historical path. 13. In the first decision by a state’s highest court after Kelo, the Ohio Supreme Court adopted a restrictive definition of public use. The Court’s interpretation of the Ohio Constitution came in the case of City of Norwood v. Horney, 110 Ohio 3d 353, 853 N.E.2d 1115 (2006), and is described in the following article: Ian Urbina, Ohio Court Rejects Taking of Homes for Project N.Y. Times, July 27, 2006 The Ohio Supreme Court ruled unanimously yesterday that a Cincinnati suburb cannot take private property by eminent domain for a $125 million redevelopment project. The property rights case was the first of its kind to reach a state's highest court since the United States Supreme 18 Court ruled last year that municipalities could seize property for private development that public officials argue would benefit the community. The Ohio decision rejected that view, and is part of a broader backlash. Since the ruling last year, 28 state legislatures have passed new protections against the use of eminent domain. ''This is the final word in Ohio, and it says something that I think all Americans feel,'' said Dana Berliner, a lawyer with the Institute for Justice, a public-interest law firm in Arlington, Va., who argued on behalf of the homeowners before the Ohio court. ''Ownership of a home is a basic right, regardless of what the U.S. Supreme Court may have decided.'' Since the Ohio case was argued based on the state's Constitution, yesterday's decision cannot be appealed to the United States Supreme Court, which decides matters involving federal law. The United States Supreme Court decision last year made it clear that state constitutions could set different standards for property rights. ''The Ohio decision takes the loophole that was left by the U.S. Supreme Court decision and drives a Mack truck right through it,'' said Richard A. Epstein, a law professor at the University of Chicago. Mr. Epstein said the decision was especially surprising coming from the Ohio Supreme Court, which he said had rarely reached unanimous decisions and had often sided with developers. ''But this decision indicates that the justices were entirely distrustful of planning officials and developers working under nebulous criteria.'' The Ohio decision involves the city of Norwood, which moved in 2002 to seize about 70 houses for a project to build offices, shops and restaurants in a neighborhood widely viewed to be deteriorating. Virtually all the property owners sold their land voluntarily, often at prices greatly above their audited value, state officials said. All but three of the houses at the site have been bulldozed. ''We're just grateful that this is still a constitutional republic,'' said Joy Gamble, one of the plaintiffs in the lawsuit against the state. ''We raised our children in that home, we lived there for 35 years, and we planned to live out our retirement there.'' Mrs. Gamble said that after being evicted in February 2005, she and her husband, Carl, moved in with their daughter across the Ohio River in Independence, Ky. ''We were nervous because we knew that the same developer who built the mall across from us with help from the city and eminent domain was the one who wanted our land,'' said Mrs. Gamble, whose house is one of the three still standing on the contested site. ''But in the end, the city and developer took it away and the courts gave it back, which makes you feel like there is real justice.'' In a 5-to-4 decision last year in a Connecticut case, Kelo v. City of New London, the United States Supreme Court ruled that economic development is an appropriate use of the government's power of eminent domain. That decision gave New London the authority to condemn houses in an aging neighborhood to make way for private development. The legal debate over eminent domain has not been whether governments could condemn private property to build a public amenity like a park or a highway. That power was established by the Fifth Amendment, provided that property owners are given ''just compensation.'' The conflict has been over government attempts to take private homes or businesses for redevelopment projects that at least partly benefit private entities. Two months after the ruling in June 2005, Justice John Paul Stevens, who wrote the majority opinion, said he was bound by the law and legal precedent. But in responding to criticism, he called the outcome ''unwise,'' and said that had he been a legislator he would have opposed it. Ms. Berliner of the Institute for Justice said the Ohio decision was a reaction to the growing use of eminent domain by developers and local officials. Since the Kelo decision, more 19 than 5,700 properties nationwide have been threatened with seizure or have been seized through eminent domain, a threefold increase from the numbers before that decision, she said. The Ohio decision was a blow to Norwood officials, who hoped to gain $2 million a year in tax revenue through the seven-acre project. ''The city is running one hell of a deficit,'' said Mayor Thomas Williams, who predicted that the city would run out of money for its operating budget in October. ''We're just trying to generate enough income to keep our doors open.'' The developer, Jeffrey R. Anderson Real Estate, could not be reached for comment on whether the project would go forward. The 58-page Ohio decision said that while economic factors may be considered in determining whether governments can take private property, the economic benefit to the government and community cannot be the only justification used for seizure. ''For the individual property owner, the appropriation is not simply the seizure of a house,'' Justice Maureen O'Connor wrote. ''It is the taking of a home, the place where ancestors toiled, where families were raised, where memories were made.'' The decision said that justifying the seizure by claiming that the area is deteriorating was unconstitutional because the term is too vague. 14. For the property owners involved in the litigation, the final outcome of the Kelo case was ironic, though perhaps not entirely unhappy. The post-mortem is described in the following articles: Avi Salzman, Homeowners Settle, But Their Fighting Spirit Lives On N.Y. Times, July 9, 2006 Over the last few years, as its residents fought a battle against the city to keep their homes, the Fort Trumbull neighborhood of New London looked more and more like a war-torn village, with acres of vacant lots interrupted intermittently by debris and a few scattered houses. Fort Trumbull was at the center of a national debate over eminent domain last year after the United States Supreme Court ruled that the city could take residents' homes and transfer them to a private developer to put up new housing, offices and a hotel. Of the seven property owners who sued the city, the final two agreed on June 30 to settle, ending the battle. If Fort Trumbull were a war-torn village, what propped it up was the guerilla activism and gallows humor of its resistance movement. During the conflict, messengers on bicycles handed out stickers deriding the city, and homeowners painted huge billboards on the sides of homes with slogans like ''Say No to Eminent Domain Assault.'' Bill Von Winkle, who lived in one of the 12 apartments he owned in the neighborhood, said he settled, on June 5, because he was offered more money. He wouldn't say how much, but to illustrate his point, he put on a pair of sunglasses with holographic dollar signs and said, ''They finally saw it my way.'' Two of his five remaining tenants, some of whom moved in even though they knew eviction was looming, were getting ready to leave. They were due out Sunday, Mr. Von Winkle said. Efrain Caraballo, who works at the Mohegan Sun casino and moved to his one-bedroom apartment at 33 Smith Street in 2004 shortly after graduating from high school, said he would 20 miss the neighborhood. ''It's kind of sad to leave here,'' he said. ''This is the first apartment I ever had.'' Lauren Canario, who also lived at 33 Smith Street, said she had moved to Fort Trumbull from Las Vegas after hearing about the Supreme Court ruling. Ms. Canario, an electronics technician, said she wanted to move to New London to support the property owners financially— by paying rent—and by fighting on their behalf. Last year, she was arrested for creating a public disturbance at a City Council meeting. In a grassy area near Mr. Von Winkle's house, Ms. Canario set up a series of cement blocks with the property owners' handprints pressed into them. Susette Kelo, the lead plaintiff in the Supreme Court case, kept her house cozy throughout the ordeal, placing metal rocking chairs on the porch and storing moccasins in a basket at the foot of the stairs. Ms. Kelo, a nurse, was one of the last holdouts and negotiated a settlement in which the state will pay to move her house. She can keep living on her property for about another year. Pasquale Cristofaro, who owned a house at 53 Goshen Street, also agreed to settle with the city on June 30 and will get a chance to buy property in the new development. His son, Michael, said the national movement to restrict eminent domain showed that the property owners had prevailed. Legislatures throughout the country have voted to limit condemnation. ''We lost the battle,'' he said, ''but we're winning the war.'' Patrick McGeehan, Pfizer to Leave City That Won Land-Use Case N.Y. Times, Nov. 13, 2009 From the edge of the Thames River in New London, Conn., Michael Cristofaro surveyed the empty acres where his parents’ neighborhood had stood, before it became the crux of an epic battle over eminent domain. “Look what they did,” Mr. Cristofaro said on Thursday. “They stole our home for economic development. It was all for Pfizer, and now they get up and walk away.” That sentiment has been echoing around New London since Monday, when Pfizer, the giant drug company, announced it would leave the city just eight years after its arrival led to a debate about urban redevelopment that rumbled through the United States Supreme Court, and reset the boundaries for governments to seize private land for commercial use. Pfizer said it would pull 1,400 jobs out of New London within two years and move most of them a few miles away to a campus it owns in Groton, Conn., as a cost-cutting measure. It would leave behind the city’s biggest office complex and an adjacent swath of barren land that was cleared of dozens of homes to make room for a hotel, stores and condominiums that were never built. The announcement stirred up resentment and bitterness among some local residents. They see Pfizer as a corporate carpetbagger that took public money, in the form of big tax breaks, and now wants to run. “I’m not surprised that they’re gone,” said Susette Kelo, who moved to Groton from New London after the city took her home near Pfizer’s property. “They didn’t get what they wanted: their development, their big plan.” Ms. Kelo lived in a small pink house in the Fort Trumbull section that was square in the sights of city and state officials who wanted to revitalize the area. The city had created the New London Development Corporation to buy up the nine-acre neighborhood and find a developer to replace it with an 21 “urban village” that would draw shoppers and tourists to the area. Economic development officials in Connecticut used that plan—and a package of financial incentives—to lure Pfizer to build a headquarters for its research division on 26 acres nearby. With an agreement that it would pay just one-fifth of its property taxes for the first 10 years, Pfizer spent $294 million on a 750,000-square-foot complex that opened in 2001. By then, Ms. Kelo, the Cristofaros and several neighbors had sued the city to stop it from using its power of eminent domain to take their property. The lawsuit, Kelo v. New London, wound up at the Supreme Court in 2005 as one of the most scrutinized property-rights cases in years. In a 5-to-4 decision, the high court ruled that it was permissible to take private property and turn it over to developers as part of a plan to bolster the local economy. Conservative justices, including Clarence Thomas, dissented. Justice Thomas called New London’s plan “a costly urban-renewal project whose stated purpose is a vague promise of new jobs and increased tax revenue, but which is also suspiciously agreeable to the Pfizer Corporation.” The decision was widely criticized, and spurred lawmakers across the country to adopt statutes to prevent similar uses of eminent domain. Scott G. Bullock, senior attorney at the Institute for Justice, a libertarian group in Arlington, Va., said that 43 states had moved to protect private-property rights since the Kelo decision. New York and New Jersey are among the seven that have not, he said. Mr. Bullock, who represented the landowners in New London, said Pfizer’s announcement “really shows the folly of these plans that use massive corporate welfare and abuse eminent domain for private development.” “They oftentimes fail to live up to expectations,” he added. For its part, Pfizer said it had no stake in the outcome of the Kelo case nor any interest in the development of the land that was acquired by eminent domain, according to a statement provided by a spokeswoman, Liz Power. After Pfizer completed its $67 billion acquisition of Wyeth, another drug giant, in October, Ms. Power said, “We had a lot of real estate that we had to make strategic decisions about.” She said Pfizer would try to sell or lease its buildings in New London and would “continue to pay our taxes to the city as scheduled.” The complex is currently assessed at $220 million, said Robert M. Pero, a city councilman who is scheduled to become mayor next month. The company pays tax on 20 percent of that value and the state pays an additional 40 percent, Mr. Pero said. That arrangement is scheduled to end in 2011, around the time Pfizer, which is currently the city’s biggest taxpayer, expects to complete its withdrawal. “Basically, our economy lost a thousand jobs, but we still have a building,” Mr. Pero said. Then again, he added, “I don’t know who’s going to be looking for a building like that in this economy.” Some residents said they expected Pfizer to seek a revaluation of its buildings if they wind up vacant in two years; Ms. Power declined to comment. Mr. Pero said that he was offended that Pfizer did not notify city officials about the decision before Monday or give them a chance to argue against it or even fully understand it. But he said he did not regret the decisions he and other elected officials had made to bring Pfizer to New London for what they had hoped would be a long and fruitful stay. “I’m sure that there are people that are waiting out there to say, ‘I told you so,’ ” Mr. Pero said. “I don’t know that even today you can say, ‘I told you so.’ ” But Mr. Cristofaro and Ms. Kelo both said just that. Ms. Kelo, a nurse who works in New London and Norwich, Conn., said she was still bitter about the loss of her house, which she sold for $1 to Avner Gregory, a preservationist. Mr. Gregory dismantled the house and moved it across town. It now stands as a bright-pink symbol of the divisive dispute that drew so much attention to New London. “In all honesty, I’m not happy about what happened to me,” Ms. 22 Kelo said. But, she added, “With 43 states changing their laws, in that sense I feel we did some good for people across the country.” 15. In the years since Kelo was decided, questions about the proper exercise of the power of eminent domain remain much in the news. The following articles provide a sampling of the current public use controversies: Charles Bagli, Court Upholds Columbia Campus Expansion Plan N.Y. Times, June. 24, 2010 Columbia University won a major court victory for its $6.3 billion plan to build a satellite campus in Harlem on Thursday, when New York’s highest court ruled that the state could seize private property for the project. In a unanimous decision, the Court of Appeals overturned a lower court ruling that barred the state from using its power of eminent domain to take private property in the 17-acre expansion zone west of Broadway without the property owner’s consent. The ruling held that the courts must give deference to the state’s determination that the area was “blighted” and that condemnation on behalf of a university served a public purpose, two requirements under the law. Lee Bollinger, the president of Columbia University, said he was grateful for the state’s hard work in the case. “This is an extremely important moment in the history of Columbia,” he said. “It’s only fair to say that the opportunity to build a new campus comes along very rarely.” The university hopes to build a series of buildings for science, business and the arts over the course of several decades on the site near the Hudson River, where the streets are lined with warehouses, factories and auto repair shops. Columbia has already acquired the bulk of the land it needs, but the owners of four warehouses and two gas stations refused to sell and sued to stop the taking of their property. There are also seven tenements in the area, which are not subject to condemnation, but Columbia hopes to move the tenants to comparable apartments elsewhere. Normal Siegal, who represented the losing property owners, said he was still reviewing the decision. “We’re extremely disappointed,” he said. Mr. Siegel had hoped that the lower court decision would serve as a roadmap for others hoping to oppose the state’s use of eminent-domain powers. Nicholas Sprayregen, the owner of the four warehouses who had refused to sell to Columbia, could not be reached for comment. The ruling cited a decision in a similar eminent-domain case last year involving the Atlantic Yards development in Brooklyn, where the state was condemning property on behalf of a developer who planned to build a basketball arena for the Nets and up to 6,000 apartments. “We ruled for Atlantic yards, and if we could rule in favor of a basketball arena, surely we could rule for a nonprofit university,” the court said Thursday in its decision, which was written by Judge Carmen Beauchamp Ciparick. In a statement, the Empire State Development Corporation, the agency that would take the land on behalf of Columbia, said the ruling “confirms that the project complies with New York State law in all respects and that the acquisition of the holdout properties is essential to realizing the vision for the Manhattanville campus as it was approved by the state.” “The expansion of one of New York’s oldest educational institutions will enhance the vitality of both the university and its neighboring west Harlem community, while meeting the long-term needs of its residents,” the agency said. 23 In a concurring opinion, Judge Robert S. Smith agreed that the state had the power to decide what constituted blight, but he wrote that the court should not have brought up the issue of what constitutes a “civic purpose,” because it opens the door to any purported “school,” even a tennis school, to have land assembled for it through eminent domain. [The New York Court of Appeals’s decision is: Kaur v. New York State Urban Development Corp., 15 N.Y.3d 235, 933 N.E.2d 721 (2010).] Saul Elbein, Judge Upholds Eminent Domain for Pipeline in Texas N.Y. Times, Aug. 23, 2012 The Canadian energy company TransCanada can take over land owned by a Texas farmer to build its Keystone XL pipeline, a county judge ruled on Wednesday night. In a 15-word ruling sent from his iPhone, Judge Bill Harris of Lamar County Court at Law upheld TransCanada’s condemnation of a 50-foot strip of land across Julia Trigg Crawford’s pasture here. The pipeline is being built to carry oil to Texas refineries from Canada. Ms. Crawford plans to appeal the ruling. “We may have lost this one battle here in Paris, Texas, but we are far from done,” she said in a statement. “I will continue to proudly stand up for my own personal rights, the property rights of my family, and those of other Texans fighting to protect their land.” The case has shed light on a loophole in Texas’s oil and gas regulation — one that critics say has given pipeline companies carte blanche to seize private land. Activists across the political spectrum have rallied behind Ms. Crawford’s cause, from conservative rural landowners and Tea Party organizations to environmental groups. At issue was whether TransCanada is a common carrier — a company with pipeline open to any oil company willing to pay published rates. In Texas, a common carrier has the power to condemn land with little oversight. The problem, Ms. Crawford’s supporters say, is that to earn the designation, an oil company need only claim the status itself on a one-page form submitted to the Texas Railroad Commission, which regulates pipelines. That process has already been challenged successfully in the State Supreme Court. “No notice is given to affected parties,” Justice Don R. Willett wrote in that case, Texas Rice Land Partners v. Denbury Green. “No hearing is held, no evidence is presented, no investigation is conducted.” In the Denbury case, the court unanimously refused the pipeline company’s condemnation claim. “Private property is constitutionally protected,” Justice Willett wrote, “and a private enterprise cannot acquire condemnation power merely by checking boxes on a one-page form.” The court recommended a set of uniform standards for common carriers, and a body to enforce it. But because no such body exists, Ms. Crawford’s case ended up in Judge Harris’s small courtroom. The arguments were technical. TransCanada argued that it derived its power of eminent domain from the Railroad Commission. Wendi Hammond, Ms. Crawford’s lawyer, asserted that based on a 2008 letter, the Railroad Commission said TransCanada’s operations “appear to be interstate and thereby under federal control.” “When our own state agency says they don’t have jurisdiction,” Ms. Hammond said, “and a statute requires that a pipeline be subject to the agency’s jurisdiction, the court should be ruling in favor of the citizen and denying the corporation’s request.” TransCanada welcomed the judge’s decision. “This ruling reaffirms that TransCanada has — and continues — to follow all state and federal laws and regulations as we move forward 24 with the construction of the Gulf Coast Project,” said Grady Semmens, a TransCanada spokesman. In court, Ms. Hammond’s argument seemed to exasperate a TransCanada lawyer, James Freeman. He argued that under Ms. Hammond’s interpretation, “you wouldn’t be able to move interstate oil in Texas pipelines at all.” Ms. Hammond disagreed. “We’re saying TransCanada is welcome to carry whatever they want,” she said. “They just can’t seize Ms. Crawford’s land to do it.” Ms. Hammond was new to the case, having represented Ms. Crawford for just 11 days. Previously, Ms. Crawford’s counsel had argued that TransCanada could not be a common carrier because it carried diluted bitumen, not crude oil, because the Keystone pipeline had not yet been granted a federal permit, and because the pipeline company had not negotiated in good faith, among other things. “That’s how this case has been all along,” Mr. Freeman said. Opposing counsel “makes these claims that have no basis in law or fact, and then by the time I get around to answering it, the argument has changed.” Packing the courtroom were around 50 supporters of Ms. Crawford. To some, the case showed why regulatory reform was needed. Debra Medina, a Republican former candidate for governor, said she drove seven hours to be at the hearing. “This is a clear example of where we have a problem in our law,” Ms. Medina said, “where companies who have not proven that they are a common carrier are allowed to take property using eminent-domain — before they ever demonstrate that they meet the criteria for that use.” Christopher Rhoads, Battle of the Beach Wall St. Journal, May 24, 2013 With debris cleared, beaches replenished and boardwalks repaired, many New Jersey shore towns will be putting up open-for-business signs this holiday weekend, just seven months after the devastation of Superstorm Sandy. The Jersey shore is back for another summer. But Thomas Anzalone of Long Branch, N.J. is not reassured. For those parts of the shore still fighting to recover from the disaster, he thinks that the real battle for survival has yet to begin. On a recent afternoon, the 57-year-old accountant was fixing the storm-damaged roof of the waterfront bungalow that he shares with his father. He fears that developers will take over what Sandy left behind and sees an ominous precedent in a 1987 fire that destroyed a Long Branch pier. The town invoked eminent domain—the power to appropriate private property for the public good—to replace a fire-damaged neighborhood with a new luxury complex of shops and condos. "What Sandy has done to many towns, a fire did to Long Branch," says Mr. Anzalone. "Eminent domain came for us, and it will come for them." Despite upbeat public messages, local officials along the 126-mile-long Jersey shore privately say that the aftermath of one of the worst storms ever to hit the U.S. may require a host of far-reaching solutions to preserve the long-term viability of their towns. These include sensitive measures like merging services with other towns and even merging towns themselves. Eventually, shore communities may also use the power of eminent domain, a politically explosive issue across the nation and nowhere more so than in Mr. Anzalone's town. After the 1987 fire in Long Branch, local officials declared that the surrounding neighborhood had become blighted, a designation allowing them to seize dozens of waterfront homes—including those of longtime and low-income residents who did not wish to sell—for an upscale project that they hoped would signal the city's revival. The centerpiece of the 25 development, called Pier Village, opened in 2005 amid protests and lawsuits. Today, the $400 million complex, which sits on 16 acres of oceanfront property, includes a boutique hotel and a members-only beach club called Le Club. "What happened in Long Branch is what I would call socio-economic cleansing," says Peter Dickson, a Princeton, N.J., lawyer who successfully argued a 2007 case before the New Jersey Supreme Court that slowed the use of eminent domain in the state. Should some of the towns not find a path to recovery, he adds, "this could come back with a vengeance." In a March meeting on recovery efforts hosted by New Jersey state officials, a resident of Seaside Heights, about 30 miles south of Long Branch, said she was worried that she could lose her damaged home to "major developers who will take over our neighborhoods." At a February meeting in Sea Bright, just up the shore from Long Branch, the town's mayor acknowledged, "People fear a heartless government coming in and taking away their land. They fear a plastic look and that the downtown will wind up looking like Pier Village." The power to take private property for the common good, typically for things like roads, schools and bridges, dates back to biblical times. The Fifth Amendment of the U.S. Constitution bestows the right on the federal government but also requires just compensation. State constitutions typically extend the power to local governments. Since the urban decline of the 1960s, courts have expanded the definition of "public use" to mean "public benefit," allowing developers who promised higher tax revenue and jobs to seize property considered blighted. The practice took off during the real-estate boom of the 2000s, as developers flush with cash, working with investment-hungry town governments, turned so-called underutilized properties into big-box retail stores and in many cases upscale residential-commercial developments. The activity prompted growing complaints of abuse. Concerns came to a head following the 2005 U.S. Supreme Court case of Kelo v. City of New London, in which the justices allowed the taking of property from low-income residents for a condo-retail project in Connecticut. The case triggered a backlash. Nine state supreme courts and 44 state legislatures subsequently strengthened criteria for allowing eminent domain, according to the Institute for Justice, a public-interest law firm focused on property rights. "It is hard to think of a more fundamental American principle than the sanctity of the home and private property," says Robert McNamara, an institute attorney. "Frequently the word blight has been a cover for government officials giving property to someone they like better—and that's why it's a dangerous practice." Despite the restrictions imposed by state courts and legislatures, eminent domain continues to be invoked around the country. In National City, Calif., south of San Diego, a developer is seeking to take a large area designated by the city as blighted, including a youth athletic center, to build condominiums. Last fall, Denver officials authorized the use of eminent domain for redevelopment in the city's historic Five Points district. The developer behind the Barclays Center, the new home of the Brooklyn Nets basketball team, was able to seize properties under eminent domain to get the structure built. Even opponents agree that, when used properly, eminent domain can be an effective tool. "Eminent domain is like a knife," says Vince Lepore, a Long Branch activist who fought against Pier Village. "It has its uses, but when used carelessly, it can hurt." Superstorm Sandy has already brought the issue to prominence again in New Jersey as the state tries to strengthen the shore against future disasters. Earlier this month the state supreme court heard a case involving a couple who, before the storm, won a $375,000 judgment from a 26 lower court as compensation for their town's building a dune on their property. The town, Harvey Cedars, had paid the couple just $300 for an easement, seized through eminent domain. The action, they argued, had hurt the value of their property. More towns since Sandy have wanted to build dunes, but they have been slowed by the case, fearful of lawsuits and of having to spend millions of dollars to waterfront homeowners. At a March town hall gathering on the matter, Gov. Chris Christie won applause when he blasted such "selfish" people for standing in the way of what he called the "greater good" of improved dune protection. Development lawyers expect to hear similar arguments from towns recovering from Sandy. With 565 municipalities, New Jersey has one of the highest numbers of towns per capita in the nation. Many of them have their own boards, police departments and other services, which contributes to some of the country's highest property taxes. Some towns now are reckoning with a reduction of 10% or more in the value of their taxable property from Sandy, and at least one, Mantaloking, with more than a 30% decline, according to the latest tax assessments. "These clobbered towns may get some interim relief from Congress," says William Ward, a Florham Park, N.J.-based lawyer who specializes in eminent domain cases. "But the long-term issue is going to stay: They have lost a significant portion of their tax rate base but still have fixed costs for police, fire and schools." That means finding ways to attract developers to rebuild. Tom Neff, director of local government services in the Department of Community Affairs, a New Jersey state agency, says he does not foresee instances of eminent domain in the near term. However, "five years from now, if an entire swath of a community becomes blighted and not rebuilt and there are people not paying their taxes—well, time will tell." About 20 miles up the coast from Long Branch, largely blue-collar Union Beach appears to be a leading candidate. Abandoned homes dot one neighborhood where Sandy swept more than a dozen houses out to sea, leaving behind driveways leading nowhere. The town, which has mostly primary residences (unlike wealthier summer communities to the south), has torn down 167 condemned houses since the storm and has at least another 57 to go, according to the town administrator. In the long run, officials say, neighborhoods where occupied houses are interspersed with vacant lots will not be viable, and entire areas will need to be rebuilt. Paul Smith, Union Beach's mayor, says that the priority for the moment is to get people to come back. The problem is getting the money they need to rebuild. "A lot of people here live paycheck to paycheck," says Mr. Smith, who works in shipping for a fragrance company. "That is the scary part—people won't be able to rebuild." Patricia Wood, a 60-year-old homemaker, still hasn't moved back into her residence of 34 years in Union Beach that she shares with her husband, a driver for a phone company. The flooded home was recently elevated by 13 feet to comply with new regulations, a $35,000 cost covered by a federal loan. She has no idea where she will get the additional $25,000 needed for remaining repairs. Some neighbors have just disappeared, abandoning their damaged homes, she says. With exceptions like a hardware store and a clothing store, most of the businesses in Sea Bright remain boarded up. One recent evening, almost the only source of light in the town's commercial district was Harry's Lobster House, which has been serving lobster bisque since 1933. A single diner ate in the main room. "It feels like the end of the world," said Lou Jacoubs, chef and owner of Harry's, flipping a steak on his industrial stove, which somehow survived 5 feet of flooding in the restaurant's kitchen. Mr. Jacoubs confirmed rumors that a real-estate investment company, Besen & Associates, had made him an offer. The firm has since withdrawn 27 the offer, but Mr. Jacoubs says that he is still looking to sell. Besen & Associates says that it made offers on many businesses in areas affected by the storm. Today, a town in New Jersey can designate a neighborhood as an "area in need of redevelopment," the current vernacular for blighted, giving officials certain revitalization tools. These include measures like tax exemptions and abatements, a waiver on competitive bidding for developers and—in areas where residents don't want to sell—eminent domain. A bill working its way through the New Jersey legislature would provide two tracks for towns considering redevelopment measures: one allowing the use of eminent domain but requiring stricter scrutiny and a more demanding approval process; and the other forbidding eminent domain but requiring less oversight. Local officials seeking the revitalization tools that accompany a blight designation, but without frightening residents about the possibility of using eminent domain, could opt for the second track. For now, the weakened real-estate market has put the brakes on eminent-domain takings by developers. "The power to do this is still there, but the market isn't," says Mr. Ward, the lawyer. When the market comes back, so will the blight takings, he adds. Should that unfold, such actions could recall what happened in Long Branch with Pier Village. Long Branch was once a thriving summer resort of sprawling farms and open vistas, popular in the late 19th and early 20th centuries with U.S. presidents and film stars. In the 1960s, urban decay set in from failed public housing projects and demographic shifts. The devastating 1987 fire destroyed a long-standing pier, a local landmark that held an amusement park, and accelerated the decline. Drugs and gangs proliferated. City officials came up with a master plan in the mid-1990s, designating much of the waterfront an "area in need of redevelopment." In 2000 the city awarded the contract to a developer. Residents, many of them elderly and living on retirement savings, soon realized their homes were to be destroyed. Some of the locals caught in the cross hairs lived in a middle-class enclave of well-kept bungalows and cottages that had been in the same families for generations. Some sellers received payments considered well below market value, but they lacked resources to sue. Many moved away. Others banded together and tried to fight in the courts. Bruce MacCloud says that armed police officers forcibly removed him from his threestory home of 25 years in Long Branch in 2002 just days before Thanksgiving. A builder, Mr. MacCloud says that he had spent years restoring the shingled, 100-year-old Victorian home, a few hundred feet from the ocean. "What happened in Long Branch to achieve Pier Village is an atrocity," says the 53-year-old Mr. MacCloud, who now lives in Tom's River in a ranch-style home a couple of miles from the water. The strain contributed to his divorce from his wife, who received custody of their two children, he says. The town offered him just $189,000 for the house in compensation, he says, which was increased to $220,000 after a lengthy court battle. "I paid off my home, restored it, started a family there, and then I lost it all," says Mr. MacCloud. "I know this was not for the good of the people." The condo development in Long Branch moved ahead, with hundreds of units, many priced above $500,000. Shops and restaurants followed. Plopped on a shoreline noted for its diversity—from the honky-tonk boardwalk scene to stately mansions—Pier Village and the connected development stand out for their uniformity: street after street of identical four-story condos in tan. The development hasn't made the waterfront a year-round community, as hoped, but the area is busy in the summer months. Work recently began on the last phase of the project, a 28 68-room hotel. A spokesman for the developer says that all 283 for-sale residences in Beachfront North, a part of the redevelopment area, have been sold. The Pier Village complex weathered Sandy well because of its up-to-date building materials, according to David Barry, the president of Hoboken-based Ironstate Development Co., which built the complex. The Long Branch mayor who spearheaded the strategy has since been re-elected many times, Mr. Barry points out, and the sale of beach passes in Long Branch has increased. Eminent domain "serves a very useful purpose," says Mr. Barry. "These badly damaged towns will need to figure out a way forward. If they don't want a patchwork recovery, they may find such tools necessary." Shaila Dewan, A City Invokes Seizure Laws to Save Homes N.Y. Times, July 29, 2013 The power of eminent domain has traditionally worked against homeowners, who can be forced to sell their property to make way for a new highway or shopping mall. But now the working-class city of Richmond, Calif., hopes to use the same legal tool to help people stay right where they are. Scarcely touched by the nation’s housing recovery and tired of waiting for federal help, Richmond is about to become the first city in the nation to try eminent domain as a way to stop foreclosures. The results will be closely watched by both Wall Street banks, which have vigorously opposed the use of eminent domain to buy mortgages and reduce homeowner debt, and a host of cities across the country that are considering emulating Richmond. The banks have warned that such a move will bring down a hail of lawsuits and all but halt mortgage lending in any city with the temerity to try it. But local officials, frustrated at the lack of large-scale relief from the Obama administration, relatively free of the influence that Wall Street wields in Washington, and faced with fraying neighborhoods and a depleted middle class, are beginning to shrug off those threats. “We’re not willing to back down on this,” said Gayle McLaughlin, the former schoolteacher who is serving her second term as Richmond’s mayor. “They can put forward as much pressure as they would like but I’m very committed to this program and I’m very committed to the wellbeing of our neighborhoods.” Despite rising home prices in many parts of the country, including California, roughly half of all homeowners with mortgages in Richmond are underwater, meaning they owe more — in some cases three or four times as much more — than their home is currently worth. On Monday, the city sent a round of letters to the owners and servicers of the loans, offering to buy 626 underwater loans. In some cases, the homeowner is already behind on the payments. Others are considered to be at risk of default, mainly because home values have fallen so much that the homeowner has little incentive to keep paying. Many cities, particularly those where minority residents were steered into predatory loans, face a situation similar to that in Richmond, which is largely black and Hispanic. About two dozen other local and state governments, including Newark, Seattle and a handful of cities in California, are looking at the eminent domain strategy, according to a count by Robert Hockett, a Cornell University law professor and one of the plan’s chief proponents. Irvington, N.J., passed a resolution supporting its use in July. North Las Vegas will consider an eminent domain proposal in August, and El Monte, Calif., is poised to act after hearing out the opposition this week. 29 But the cities face an uphill battle. Some have already backed off, and those that proceed will be challenged in court. After San Bernardino County dropped the idea earlier this year, a network of housing groups and unions began working to win community support and develop nonprofit alternatives to Mortgage Resolution Partners, the firm that is managing the Richmond program. “Our local electeds can’t do this alone, they need the backup support from their constituents,” said Amy Schur, a campaign director for the national Home Defenders League. “That’s what’s been the game changer in this effort.” Richmond is offering to buy both current and delinquent loans. To defend against the charge that irresponsible homeowners who used their homes as A.T.M.’s are being helped at the expense of investors, the first pool of 626 loans does not include any homes with large second mortgages, said Steven M. Gluckstern, the chairman of Mortgage Resolution Partners. The city is offering to buy the loans at what it considers the fair market value. In a hypothetical example, a home mortgaged for $400,000 is now worth $200,000. The city plans to buy the loan for $160,000, or about 80 percent of the value of the home, a discount that factors in the risk of default. Then, the city would write down the debt to $190,000 and allow the homeowner to refinance at the new amount, probably through a government program. The $30,000 difference goes to the city, the investors who put up the money to buy the loan, closing costs and M.R.P. The homeowner would go from owing twice what the home is worth to having $10,000 in equity. All of the loans in question are tied up in what are called private label securities, meaning they were bundled and sold to private investors. Such loans are generally the most unfavorable to borrowers and the most likely to default, Mr. Gluckstern said. But they are also the most difficult to modify because they are controlled by loan servicers and trustees for the investors, not the investors themselves. If Richmond’s purchase offer is declined, the city intends to use eminent domain to condemn and buy the loans. The banks and the real estate industry have argued that such a move would be unprecedented and unconstitutional. But Mr. Hockett says that all types of property, not just land and buildings, are subject to eminent domain if the government can show it is needed to promote the public good, in this case fighting blight and keeping communities intact. Railroad stocks, private bus companies, sports teams and even some mortgages have been subject to eminent domain. Opponents, including the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, the American Bankers Association, the National Association of Realtors and some big investors have mounted a concerted opposition campaign on multiple levels, including flying lobbyists to California city halls and pressuring Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and the Federal Housing Administration to use their control of the mortgage industry to ban the practice. Tim Cameron, the head of Sifma’s Asset Management Group, said any city using eminent domain would make borrowing more expensive for everyone in the community and divert profits from the investors who now own the loan to M.R.P. and the investors financing the new program. “Eminent domain is used for roads and schools and bridges that benefit an entire community, not something that cherry-picks who the winners are and who the losers are,” he said. Representative John Campbell, Republican of California, has introduced a bill that would prohibit Fannie, Freddie and the F.H.A. from making, guaranteeing or insuring a mortgage in any community that has used eminent domain in this way. Eminent domain supporters say such limits would constitute a throwback to the illegal practice called redlining, when banks refused to lend 30 in minority communities. Opponents have also employed hardball tactics. In North Las Vegas, a mass mailer paid for by real estate brokers warned that M.R.P. had “hatched a plan to make millions of dollars by foreclosing on homeowners who are current on their payments.” In a letter to the Justice Department, Lt. Gov. Gavin Newsom of California complained that the opposition was violating antitrust laws and that one unnamed hedge fund had threatened an investor in the project. But not all mortgage investors oppose the plan. Some have long argued that writing down homeowner debt makes sense in many cases. “This is not the first choice, but it’s rapidly becoming the only choice on how to fix this mess,” said William Frey, an investor advocate. Mr. Frey said that the big banks were terrified that if eminent domain strategies became widespread, they would engulf not only primary mortgages but some $450 billion in second liens and home equity loans that are on the banks’ balance sheets. “It has nothing to do with morality or anything like that, it has to do with second liens.” Many of the communities considering eminent domain were targeted by lenders who steered minority families eligible for conventional mortgages into loans with higher interest rates and ballooning payments. Robert and Patricia Castillo bought a three-bedroom, one-bathroom home in Richmond because their son, who is severely autistic, would anger landlords with his destructive impulses. They paid $420,000 for a home that is now worth $125,000, Mr. Castillo, a mechanic, said. They have watched as their daughter’s playmates on the block have, one by one, lost their homes. But they are reluctant to walk away from the house in part for the sake of their son. “We’re in a bad situation,” Mr. Castillo, 44, said. “Not only me and my family, but the whole of Richmond.” 16. If you are interested in additional reading on the concept of “public use, please consider Professor Rubenfeld’s provocative interpretation of the “public use” clause. Jed Rubenfeld, Usings, 102 Yale L.J. 1077 (1993). If you want even more on the Kelo litigation itself, there are now two books on the topic: CARLA MAIN, BULLDOZED: “KELO,” EMINENT DOMAIN AND THE AMERICAN LUST FOR LAND (ENCOUNTER 2007) and JEFF BENEDICT, LITTLE PINK HOUSE: A TRUE STORY OF DEFIANCE AND COURAGE (GRAND CENTRAL 2009). KELO v. CITY OF NEW LONDON Supreme Court of the United States 545 U.S. 469 (2005) JUSTICE STEVENS delivered the opinion of the Court. In 2000, the city of New London approved a development plan that, in the words of the Supreme Court of Connecticut, was "projected to create in excess of 1,000 jobs, to increase tax and other revenues, and to revitalize an economically distressed city, including its downtown and waterfront areas." 268 Conn. 1, 5, 843 A.2d 500, 507 (2004). In assembling the land needed for this project, the city's development agent has purchased property from willing sellers and proposes to use the power of eminent domain to acquire the remainder of the property from unwilling owners in exchange for just compensation. The question presented is whether the city's proposed disposition of this property qualifies as a "public use" within the meaning of the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment to the Constitution. I 31 The city of New London (hereinafter City) sits at the junction of the Thames River and the Long Island Sound in southeastern Connecticut. Decades of economic decline led a state agency in 1990 to designate the City a "distressed municipality." In 1996, the Federal Government closed the Naval Undersea Warfare Center, which had been located in the Fort Trumbull area of the City and had employed over 1,500 people. In 1998, the City's unemployment rate was nearly double that of the State, and its population of just under 24,000 residents was at its lowest since 1920. These conditions prompted state and local officials to target New London, and particularly its Fort Trumbull area, for economic revitalization. To this end, respondent New London Development Corporation (NLDC), a private nonprofit entity established some years earlier to assist the City in planning economic development, was reactivated. In January 1998, the State authorized a $5.35 million bond issue to support the NLDC's planning activities and a $10 million bond issue toward the creation of a Fort Trumbull State Park. In February, the pharmaceutical company Pfizer Inc. announced that it would build a $300 million research facility on a site immediately adjacent to Fort Trumbull; local planners hoped that Pfizer would draw new business to the area, thereby serving as a catalyst to the area's rejuvenation. After receiving initial approval from the city council, the NLDC continued its planning activities and held a series of neighborhood meetings to educate the public about the process. In May, the city council authorized the NLDC to formally submit its plans to the relevant state agencies for review. Upon obtaining state-level approval, the NLDC finalized an integrated development plan focused on 90 acres of the Fort Trumbull area. The Fort Trumbull area is situated on a peninsula that juts into the Thames River. The area comprises approximately 115 privately owned properties, as well as the 32 acres of land formerly occupied by the naval facility (Trumbull State Park now occupies 18 of those 32 acres). The development plan encompasses seven parcels. Parcel 1 is designated for a waterfront conference hotel at the center of a "small urban village" that will include restaurants and shopping. This parcel will also have marinas for both recreational and commercial uses. A pedestrian "riverwalk" will originate here and continue down the coast, connecting the waterfront areas of the development. Parcel 2 will be the site of approximately 80 new residences organized into an urban neighborhood and linked by public walkway to the remainder of the development, including the state park. This parcel also includes space reserved for a new U. S. Coast Guard Museum. Parcel 3, which is located immediately north of the Pfizer facility, will contain at least 90,000 square feet of research and development office space. Parcel 4A is a 2.4acre site that will be used either to support the adjacent state park, by providing parking or retail services for visitors, or to support the nearby marina. Parcel 4B will include a renovated marina, as well as the final stretch of the riverwalk. Parcels 5, 6, and 7 will provide land for office and retail space, parking, and water-dependent commercial uses. The NLDC intended the development plan to capitalize on the arrival of the Pfizer facility and the new commerce it was expected to attract. In addition to creating jobs, generating tax revenue, and helping to "build momentum for the revitalization of downtown New London," the plan was also designed to make the City more attractive and to create leisure and recreational opportunities on the waterfront and in the park. 32 The city council approved the plan in January 2000, and designated the NLDC as its development agent in charge of implementation. See Conn. Gen. Stat. § 8-188 (2005). The city council also authorized the NLDC to purchase property or to acquire property by exercising eminent domain in the City's name. § 8-193. The NLDC successfully negotiated the purchase of most of the real estate in the 90-acre area, but its negotiations with petitioners failed. As a consequence, in November 2000, the NLDC initiated the condemnation proceedings that gave rise to this case. II Petitioner Susette Kelo has lived in the Fort Trumbull area since 1997. She has made extensive improvements to her house, which she prizes for its water view. Petitioner Wilhelmina Dery was born in her Fort Trumbull house in 1918 and has lived there her entire life. Her husband Charles (also a petitioner) has lived in the house since they married some 60 years ago. In all, the nine petitioners own 15 properties in Fort Trumbull—4 in parcel 3 of the development plan and 11 in parcel 4A. Ten of the parcels are occupied by the owner or a family member; the other five are held as investment properties. There is no allegation that any of these properties is blighted or otherwise in poor condition; rather, they were condemned only because they happen to be located in the development area. In December 2000, petitioners brought this action in the New London Superior Court. They claimed, among other things, that the taking of their properties would violate the "public use" restriction in the Fifth Amendment. After a 7-day bench trial, the Superior Court granted a permanent restraining order prohibiting the taking of the properties located in parcel 4A (park or marina support). It, however, denied petitioners relief as to the properties located in parcel 3 (office space).1 After the Superior Court ruled, both sides took appeals to the Supreme Court of Connecticut. That court held, over a dissent, that all of the City's proposed takings were valid. It began by upholding the lower court's determination that the takings were authorized by chapter 132, the State's municipal development statute. See Conn. Gen. Stat. § 8-186 et seq. (2005). That statute expresses a legislative determination that the taking of land, even developed land, as part of an economic development project is a "public use" and in the "public interest." 268 Conn., at 18-28, 843 A. 2d, at 515-521. Next, relying on cases such as Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (1984), and Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 (1954), the court held that such economic development qualified as a valid public use under both the Federal and State Constitutions. 268 Conn., at 40, 843 A. 2d, at 527. 1 While this litigation was pending before the Superior Court, the NLDC announced that it would lease some of the parcels to private developers in exchange for their agreement to develop the land according to the terms of the development plan. Specifically, the NLDC was negotiating a 99-year ground lease with Corcoran Jennison, a developer selected from a group of applicants. The negotiations contemplated a nominal rent of $1 per year, but no agreement had yet been signed. See 268 Conn. 1, 9, 61, 843 A.2d 500, 509-510, 540 (2004). 33 Finally, adhering to its precedents, the court went on to determine, first, whether the takings of the particular properties at issue were "reasonably necessary" to achieving the City's intended public use, id., at 82-84, 843 A. 2d, at 552-553, and, second, whether the takings were for "reasonably foreseeable needs," id., at 93-94, 843 A. 2d, at 558-559. The court upheld the trial court's factual findings as to parcel 3, but reversed the trial court as to parcel 4A, agreeing with the City that the intended use of this land was sufficiently definite and had been given "reasonable attention" during the planning process. Id., at 120-121, 843 A. 2d, at 574. The three dissenting justices would have imposed a "heightened" standard of judicial review for takings justified by economic development. Although they agreed that the plan was intended to serve a valid public use, they would have found all the takings unconstitutional because the City had failed to adduce "clear and convincing evidence" that the economic benefits of the plan would in fact come to pass. Id., at 144, 146, 843 A. 2d, at 587, 588 (Zarella, J., joined by Sullivan, C. J., and Katz, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). We granted certiorari to determine whether a city's decision to take property for the purpose of economic development satisfies the "public use" requirement of the Fifth Amendment. III Two polar propositions are perfectly clear. On the one hand, it has long been accepted that the sovereign may not take the property of A for the sole purpose of transferring it to another private party B, even though A is paid just compensation. On the other hand, it is equally clear that a State may transfer property from one private party to another if future "use by the public" is the purpose of the taking; the condemnation of land for a railroad with common-carrier duties is a familiar example. Neither of these propositions, however, determines the disposition of this case. As for the first proposition, the City would no doubt be forbidden from taking petitioners' land for the purpose of conferring a private benefit on a particular private party. See Midkiff, 467 U.S., at 245, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 ("A purely private taking could not withstand the scrutiny of the public use requirement; it would serve no legitimate purpose of government and would thus be void"); Missouri Pacific R. Co. v. Nebraska, 164 U.S. 403, 41 L. Ed. 489, 17 S. Ct. 130 (1896).2 Nor would the City be allowed to take property under the mere pretext of a public purpose, when its actual purpose was to bestow a private benefit. The takings before us, 2 See also Calder v. Bull, 3 U.S. 386, 3 Dall. 386, 1 L. Ed. 648 (1798) ("An act of the Legislature (for I cannot call it a law) contrary to the great first principles of the social compact, cannot be considered a rightful exercise of legislative authority. . . . A few instances will suffice to explain what I mean. . . [A] law that takes property from A. and gives it to B: It is against all reason and justice, for a people to entrust a Legislature with such powers; and, therefore, it cannot be presumed that they have done it. The genius, the nature, and the spirit, of our State Governments, amount to a prohibition of such acts of legislation; and the general principles of law and reason forbid them" (emphasis deleted)). 34 however, would be executed pursuant to a "carefully considered" development plan. 268 Conn., at 54, 843 A. 2d, at 536. The trial judge and all the members of the Supreme Court of Connecticut agreed that there was no evidence of an illegitimate purpose in this case.3 Therefore, as was true of the statute challenged in Midkiff, 467 U.S., at 245, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321, the City's development plan was not adopted "to benefit a particular class of identifiable individuals." On the other hand, this is not a case in which the City is planning to open the condemned land—at least not in its entirety—to use by the general public. Nor will the private lessees of the land in any sense be required to operate like common carriers, making their services available to all comers. But although such a projected use would be sufficient to satisfy the public use requirement, this "Court long ago rejected any literal requirement that condemned property be put into use for the general public." Id., at 244, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321. Indeed, while many state courts in the mid-19th century endorsed "use by the public" as the proper definition of public use, that narrow view steadily eroded over time. Not only was the "use by the public" test difficult to administer (e.g., what proportion of the public need have access to the property? at what price?),4 but it proved to be impractical given the diverse and always evolving needs of society.5 Accordingly, when this Court began applying the Fifth Amendment to the States at the 3 See 268 Conn., at 159, 843 A. 2d, at 595 (Zarella, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part) ("The record clearly demonstrates that the development plan was not intended to serve the interests of Pfizer, Inc., or any other private entity, but rather, to revitalize the local economy by creating temporary and permanent jobs, generating a significant increase in tax revenue, encouraging spin-off economic activities and maximizing public access to the waterfront"). And while the City intends to transfer certain of the parcels to a private developer in a long-term lease--which developer, in turn, is expected to lease the office space and so forth to other private tenants--the identities of those private parties were not known when the plan was adopted. It is, of course, difficult to accuse the government of having taken A's property to benefit the private interests of B when the identity of B was unknown. 4 See, e.g., Dayton Gold & Silver Mining Co. v. Seawell, 11 Nev. 394, 410, 1876 WL 4573, *11 (1876) ("If public occupation and enjoyment of the object for which land is to be condemned furnishes the only and true test for the right of eminent domain, then the legislature would certainly have the constitutional authority to condemn the lands of any private citizen for the purpose of building hotels and theaters. Why not? A hotel is used by the public as much as a railroad. The public have the same right, upon payment of a fixed compensation, to seek rest and refreshment at a public inn as they have to travel upon a railroad"). 5 From upholding the Mill Acts (which authorized manufacturers dependent on powerproducing dams to flood upstream lands in exchange for just compensation), to approving takings necessary for the economic development of the West through mining and irrigation, many state courts either circumvented the "use by the public" test when necessary or abandoned it completely. See Nichols, The Meaning of Public Use in the Law of Eminent Domain, 20 B.U.L. Rev. 615, 619-624 (1940) (tracing this development and collecting cases). For example, in rejecting the "use by the public" test as overly restrictive, the Nevada Supreme Court stressed that "[m]ining is the greatest of the industrial pursuits in this state. All other interests are subservient to it. Our mountains are almost barren of timber, and our valleys could never be made profitable for agricultural purposes except for the fact of a home market having been 35 close of the 19th century, it embraced the broader and more natural interpretation of public use as "public purpose." See, e.g., Fallbrook Irrigation Dist. v. Bradley, 164 U.S. 112, 158-164, 41 L. Ed. 369, 17 S. Ct. 56 (1896). Thus, in a case upholding a mining company's use of an aerial bucket line to transport ore over property it did not own, Justice Holmes' opinion for the Court stressed "the inadequacy of use by the general public as a universal test." Strickley v. Highland Boy Gold Mining Co., 200 U.S. 527, 531, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301 (1906).6 We have repeatedly and consistently rejected that narrow test ever since.7 The disposition of this case therefore turns on the question whether the City's development plan serves a "public purpose." Without exception, our cases have defined that concept broadly, reflecting our longstanding policy of deference to legislative judgments in this field. In Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 (1954), this Court upheld a redevelopment plan targeting a blighted area of Washington, D. C., in which most of the housing for the area's 5,000 inhabitants was beyond repair. Under the plan, the area would be condemned and part of it utilized for the construction of streets, schools, and other public facilities. The remainder of the land would be leased or sold to private parties for the purpose of redevelopment, including the construction of low-cost housing. The owner of a department store located in the area challenged the condemnation, pointing out that his store was not itself blighted and arguing that the creation of a "better balanced, more attractive community" was not a valid public use. Id., at 31, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. Writing for a unanimous Court, Justice Douglas refused to evaluate this claim in isolation, deferring instead to the legislative and agency judgment that the area "must be planned as a whole" for the plan to be successful. Id., at 34, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. The Court explained that "community redevelopment programs need not, by force of the Constitution, be on a piecemeal basis—lot by lot, building by building." Id., at 35, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. The public use underlying the taking was unequivocally affirmed: created by the mining developments in different sections of the state. The mining and milling interests give employment to many men, and the benefits derived from this business are distributed as much, and sometimes more, among the laboring classes than with the owners of the mines and mills. . . . The present prosperity of the state is entirely due to the mining developments already made, and the entire people of the state are directly interested in having the future developments unobstructed by the obstinate action of any individual or individuals." Dayton Gold & Silver Mining Co., 11 Nev., at 409-410, 1876 WL, at *11. 6 See also Clark v. Nash, 198 U.S. 361, 49 L. Ed. 1085, 25 S. Ct. 676 (1905) (upholding a statute that authorized the owner of arid land to widen a ditch on his neighbor's property so as to permit a nearby stream to irrigate his land). 7 See, e.g., Mt. Vernon-Woodberry Cotton Duck Co. v. Alabama Interstate Power Co., 240 U.S. 30, 32, 60 L. Ed. 507, 36 S. Ct. 234 (1916) ("The inadequacy of use by the general public as a universal test is established"); Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co., 467 U.S. 986, 1014-1015, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862 (1984) ("This Court, however, has rejected the notion that a use is a public use only if the property taken is put to use for the general public"). 36 "We do not sit to determine whether a particular housing project is or is not desirable. The concept of the public welfare is broad and inclusive. . . . The values it represents are spiritual as well as physical, aesthetic as well as monetary. It is within the power of the legislature to determine that the community should be beautiful as well as healthy, spacious as well as clean, well-balanced as well as carefully patrolled. In the present case, the Congress and its authorized agencies have made determinations that take into account a wide variety of values. It is not for us to reappraise them. If those who govern the District of Columbia decide that the Nation's Capital should be beautiful as well as sanitary, there is nothing in the Fifth Amendment that stands in the way." Id., at 33, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. In Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (1984), the Court considered a Hawaii statute whereby fee title was taken from lessors and transferred to lessees (for just compensation) in order to reduce the concentration of land ownership. We unanimously upheld the statute and rejected the Ninth Circuit's view that it was "a naked attempt on the part of the state of Hawaii to take the property of A and transfer it to B solely for B's private use and benefit." Id., at 235, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (internal quotation marks omitted). Reaffirming Berman's deferential approach to legislative judgments in this field, we concluded that the State's purpose of eliminating the "social and economic evils of a land oligopoly" qualified as a valid public use. 467 U.S., at 241-242, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321. Our opinion also rejected the contention that the mere fact that the State immediately transferred the properties to private individuals upon condemnation somehow diminished the public character of the taking. "[I]t is only the taking's purpose, and not its mechanics," we explained, that matters in determining public use. Id., at 244, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321. In that same Term we decided another public use case that arose in a purely economic context. In Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co., 467 U.S. 986, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862 (1984), the Court dealt with provisions of the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act under which the Environmental Protection Agency could consider the data (including trade secrets) submitted by a prior pesticide applicant in evaluating a subsequent application, so long as the second applicant paid just compensation for the data. We acknowledged that the "most direct beneficiaries" of these provisions were the subsequent applicants, id., at 1014, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862, but we nevertheless upheld the statute under Berman and Midkiff. We found sufficient Congress' belief that sparing applicants the cost of time-consuming research eliminated a significant barrier to entry in the pesticide market and thereby enhanced competition. 467 U.S., at 1015, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862. Viewed as a whole, our jurisprudence has recognized that the needs of society have varied between different parts of the Nation, just as they have evolved over time in response to changed circumstances. Our earliest cases in particular embodied a strong theme of federalism, emphasizing the "great respect" that we owe to state legislatures and state courts in discerning local public needs. See Hairston v. Danville & Western R. Co., 208 U.S. 598, 606-607, 52 L. Ed. 637, 28 S. Ct. 331 (1908) (noting that these needs were likely to vary depending on a State's "resources, the capacity of the soil, the relative importance of industries to the general public 37 welfare, and the long-established methods and habits of the people").8 For more than a century, our public use jurisprudence has wisely eschewed rigid formulas and intrusive scrutiny in favor of affording legislatures broad latitude in determining what public needs justify the use of the takings power. IV Those who govern the City were not confronted with the need to remove blight in the Fort Trumbull area, but their determination that the area was sufficiently distressed to justify a program of economic rejuvenation is entitled to our deference. The City has carefully formulated an economic development plan that it believes will provide appreciable benefits to the community, including—but by no means limited to—new jobs and increased tax revenue. As with other exercises in urban planning and development,9 the City is endeavoring to coordinate a variety of commercial, residential, and recreational uses of land, with the hope that they will form a whole greater than the sum of its parts. To effectuate this plan, the City has invoked a state statute that specifically authorizes the use of eminent domain to promote economic development. Given the comprehensive character of the plan, the thorough deliberation that preceded its adoption, and the limited scope of our review, it is appropriate for us, as it was in Berman, to resolve the challenges of the individual owners, not on a piecemeal basis, but rather in light of the entire plan. Because that plan unquestionably serves a public purpose, the takings challenged here satisfy the public use requirement of the Fifth Amendment. To avoid this result, petitioners urge us to adopt a new bright-line rule that economic development does not qualify as a public use. Putting aside the unpersuasive suggestion that the City's plan will provide only purely economic benefits, neither precedent nor logic supports petitioners' proposal. Promoting economic development is a traditional and long accepted function of government. There is, moreover, no principled way of distinguishing economic development from the other public purposes that we have recognized. In our cases upholding takings that facilitated agriculture and mining, for example, we emphasized the importance of those industries to the welfare of the States in question, see, e.g., Strickley, 200 U.S. 527, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301; in Berman, we endorsed the purpose of transforming a blighted area into 8 See also Clark, 198 U.S., at 367-368, 49 L. Ed. 1085, 25 S. Ct. 676; Strickley v. Highland Boy Gold Mining Co., 200 U.S. 527, 531, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301 (1906) ("In the opinion of the legislature and the Supreme Court of Utah the public welfare of that State demands that aerial lines between the mines upon its mountain sides and railways in the valleys below should not be made impossible by the refusal of a private owner to sell the right to cross his land. The Constitution of the United States does not require us to say that they are wrong"); O'Neill v. Leamer, 239 U.S. 244, 253, 60 L. Ed. 249, 36 S. Ct. 54 (1915) ("States may take account of their special exigencies, and when the extent of their arid or wet lands is such that a plan for irrigation or reclamation according to districts may fairly be regarded as one which promotes the public interest, there is nothing in the Federal Constitution which denies to them the right to formulate this policy or to exercise the power of eminent domain in carrying it into effect. With the local situation the state court is peculiarly familiar and its judgment is entitled to the highest respect"). 9 Cf. Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 71 L. Ed. 303, 47 S. Ct. 114, 4 Ohio Law Abs. 816 (1926). 38 a "well-balanced" community through redevelopment, 348 U.S., at 33, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98;10 in Midkiff, we upheld the interest in breaking up a land oligopoly that "created artificial deterrents to the normal functioning of the State's residential land market," 467 U.S., at 242, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321; and in Monsanto, we accepted Congress' purpose of eliminating a "significant barrier to entry in the pesticide market," 467 U.S., at 1014-1015, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862. It would be incongruous to hold that the City's interest in the economic benefits to be derived from the development of the Fort Trumbull area has less of a public character than any of those other interests. Clearly, there is no basis for exempting economic development from our traditionally broad understanding of public purpose. Petitioners contend that using eminent domain for economic development impermissibly blurs the boundary between public and private takings. Again, our cases foreclose this objection. Quite simply, the government's pursuit of a public purpose will often benefit individual private parties. For example, in Midkiff, the forced transfer of property conferred a direct and significant benefit on those lessees who were previously unable to purchase their homes. In Monsanto, we recognized that the "most direct beneficiaries" of the data-sharing provisions were the subsequent pesticide applicants, but benefiting them in this way was necessary to promoting competition in the pesticide market. 467 U.S., at 1014, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862.11 The owner of the department store in Berman objected to "taking from one businessman for the benefit of another businessman," 348 U.S., at 33, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98, referring to the fact that under the redevelopment plan land would be leased or sold to private developers for redevelopment.12 Our rejection of that contention has particular relevance to the instant case: 10 It is a misreading of Berman to suggest that the only public use upheld in that case was the initial removal of blight. The public use described in Berman extended beyond that to encompass the purpose of developing that area to create conditions that would prevent a reversion to blight in the future. See 348 U.S., at 34-35, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 ("It was not enough, [the experts] believed, to remove existing buildings that were insanitary or unsightly. It was important to redesign the whole area so as to eliminate the conditions that cause slums . . . . The entire area needed redesigning so that a balanced, integrated plan could be developed for the region, including not only new homes, but also schools, churches, parks, streets, and shopping centers. In this way it was hoped that the cycle of decay of the area could be controlled and the birth of future slums prevented"). Had the public use in Berman been defined more narrowly, it would have been difficult to justify the taking of the plaintiff's nonblighted department store. 11 Any number of cases illustrate that the achievement of a public good often coincides with the immediate benefiting of private parties. See, e.g., National Railroad Passenger Corporation v. Boston & Maine Corp., 503 U.S. 407, 422, 118 L. Ed. 2d 52, 112 S. Ct. 1394 (1992) (public purpose of "facilitating Amtrak's rail service" served by taking rail track from one private company and transferring it to another private company); Brown v. Legal Foundation of Wash., 538 U.S. 216, 155 L. Ed. 2d 376, 123 S. Ct. 1406 (2003) (provision of legal services to the poor is a valid public purpose). It is worth noting that in Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (1984), Monsanto, and Boston & Maine Corp., the property in question retained the same use even after the change of ownership. 12 Notably, as in the instant case, the private developers in Berman were required by contract to use the property to carry out the redevelopment plan. See 348 U.S., at 30, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. 39 "The public end may be as well or better served through an agency of private enterprise than through a department of government—or so the Congress might conclude. We cannot say that public ownership is the sole method of promoting the public purposes of community redevelopment projects." Id., at 34, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98.13 It is further argued that without a bright-line rule nothing would stop a city from transferring citizen A's property to citizen B for the sole reason that citizen B will put the property to a more productive use and thus pay more taxes. Such a one-to-one transfer of property, executed outside the confines of an integrated development plan, is not presented in this case. While such an unusual exercise of government power would certainly raise a suspicion that a private purpose was afoot,14 the hypothetical cases posited by petitioners can be confronted if and when they arise.15 They do not warrant the crafting of an artificial restriction on the concept of public use.16 13 Nor do our cases support Justice O'Connor's novel theory that the government may only take property and transfer it to private parties when the initial taking eliminates some "harmful property use." There was nothing "harmful" about the non-blighted department store at issue in Berman, 348 U.S. 26, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98; nothing "harmful" about the lands at issue in the mining and agriculture cases, see, e.g., Strickley, 200 U.S. 527, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301; and certainly nothing "harmful" about the trade secrets owned by the pesticide manufacturers in Monsanto, 467 U.S. 986, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862. In each case, the public purpose we upheld depended on a private party's future use of the concededly non-harmful property that was taken. By focusing on a property's future use, as opposed to its past use, our cases are faithful to the text of the Takings Clause. See U.S. Const., Amdt. 5. ("[N]or shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation"). Justice O'Connor's intimation that a "public purpose" may not be achieved by the action of private parties, confuses the purpose of a taking with its mechanics, a mistake we warned of in Midkiff, 467 U.S., at 244, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321. See also Berman, 348 U.S., at 33-34, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 ("The public end may be as well or better served through an agency of private enterprise than through a department of government"). 14 Courts have viewed such aberrations with a skeptical eye. See, e.g., 99 Cents Only Stores v. Lancaster Redevelopment Agency, 237 F. Supp. 2d 1123 (CD Cal. 2001); cf. Cincinnati v. Vester, 281 U.S. 439, 448, 74 L. Ed. 950, 50 S. Ct. 360 (1930) (taking invalid under state eminent domain statute for lack of a reasoned explanation). These types of takings may also implicate other constitutional guarantees. See Village of Willowbrook v. Olech, 528 U.S. 562, 145 L. Ed. 2d 1060, 120 S. Ct. 1073 (2000) (per curiam). 15 Cf. Panhandle Oil Co. v. Mississippi ex rel. Knox, 277 U.S. 218, 223, 72 L. Ed. 857, 48 S. Ct. 451 (1928) (Holmes, J., dissenting) ("The power to tax is not the power to destroy while this Court sits"). 16 A parade of horribles is especially unpersuasive in this context, since the Takings Clause largely "operates as a conditional limitation, permitting the government to do what it wants so long as it pays the charge." Eastern Enterprises v. Apfel, 524 U.S. 498, 545, 141 L. Ed. 2d 451, 118 S. Ct. 2131 (1998) (Kennedy, J., concurring in judgment and dissenting in part). Speaking of the takings power, Justice Iredell observed that "[i]t is not sufficient to urge, that the power may be abused, for, such is the nature of all power, —such is the tendency of every human institution: and, it might as fairly be said, that the power of taxation, which is only circumscribed 40 Alternatively, petitioners maintain that for takings of this kind we should require a "reasonable certainty" that the expected public benefits will actually accrue. Such a rule, however, would represent an even greater departure from our precedent. "When the legislature's purpose is legitimate and its means are not irrational, our cases make clear that empirical debates over the wisdom of takings—no less than debates over the wisdom of other kinds of socioeconomic legislation—are not to be carried out in the federal courts." Midkiff, 467 U.S., at 242, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321.17 Indeed, earlier this Term we explained why similar practical concerns (among others) undermined the use of the "substantially advances" formula in our regulatory takings doctrine. See Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, ___, 161 L. Ed. 2d 876, 125 S. Ct. 2074 (2005) (noting that this formula "would empower—and might often require—courts to substitute their predictive judgments for those of elected legislatures and expert agencies"). The disadvantages of a heightened form of review are especially pronounced in this type of case. Orderly implementation of a comprehensive redevelopment plan obviously requires that the legal rights of all interested parties be established before new construction can be commenced. A constitutional rule that required postponement of the judicial approval of every condemnation until the likelihood of success of the plan had been assured would unquestionably impose a significant impediment to the successful consummation of many such plans. Just as we decline to second-guess the City's considered judgments about the efficacy of its development plan, we also decline to second-guess the City's determinations as to what lands it needs to acquire in order to effectuate the project. "It is not for the courts to oversee the choice of the boundary line nor to sit in review on the size of a particular project area. Once the question of the public purpose has been decided, the amount and character of land to be taken for the project and the need for a particular tract to complete the integrated plan rests in the discretion of the legislative branch." Berman, 348 U.S., at 35-36, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. In affirming the City's authority to take petitioners' properties, we do not minimize the hardship that condemnations may entail, notwithstanding the payment of just compensation. We by the discretion of the Body, in which it is vested, ought not to be granted, because the Legislature, disregarding its true objects, might, for visionary and useless projects, impose a tax to the amount of nineteen shillings in the pound. We must be content to limit power where we can, and where we cannot, consistently with its use, we must be content to repose a salutory confidence." Calder, 3 Dall., at 400, 1 L. Ed. 648 (opinion concurring in result). 17 See also Boston & Maine Corp., 503 U.S., at 422-423, 118 L. Ed. 2d 52, 112 S. Ct. 1394 ("[W]e need not make a specific factual determination whether the condemnation will accomplish its objectives"); Monsanto, 467 U.S., at 1015, n. 18, 81 L. Ed. 2d 815, 104 S. Ct. 2862 ("Monsanto argues that EPA and, by implication, Congress, misapprehended the true 'barriers to entry' in the pesticide industry and that the challenged provisions of the law create, rather than reduce, barriers to entry. . . . Such economic arguments are better directed to Congress. The proper inquiry before this Court is not whether the provisions in fact will accomplish their stated objectives. Our review is limited to determining that the purpose is legitimate and that Congress rationally could have believed that the provisions would promote that objective"). 41 emphasize that nothing in our opinion precludes any State from placing further restrictions on its exercise of the takings power. Indeed, many States already impose "public use" requirements that are stricter than the federal baseline. Some of these requirements have been established as a matter of state constitutional law,18 while others are expressed in state eminent domain statutes that carefully limit the grounds upon which takings may be exercised.19 As the submissions of the parties and their amici make clear, the necessity and wisdom of using eminent domain to promote economic development are certainly matters of legitimate public debate. This Court's authority, however, extends only to determining whether the City's proposed condemnations are for a "public use" within the meaning of the Fifth Amendment to the Federal Constitution. Because over a century of our case law interpreting that provision dictates an affirmative answer to that question, we may not grant petitioners the relief that they seek. The judgment of the Supreme Court of Connecticut is affirmed. JUSTICE KENNEDY, concurring. I join the opinion for the Court and add these further observations. This Court has declared that a taking should be upheld as consistent with the Public Use Clause, U.S. Const., Amdt. 5, as long as it is "rationally related to a conceivable public purpose." Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 241, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (1984); see also Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 (1954). This deferential standard of review echoes the rational-basis test used to review economic regulation under the Due Process and Equal Protection Clauses, see, e.g., FCC v. Beach Communications, Inc., 508 U.S. 307, 313-314, 124 L. Ed. 2d 211, 113 S. Ct. 2096 (1993); Williamson v. Lee Optical of Okla., Inc., 348 U.S. 483, 99 L. Ed. 563, 75 S. Ct. 461 (1955). The determination that a rational-basis standard of review is appropriate does not, however, alter the fact that transfers intended to confer benefits on particular, favored private entities, and with only incidental or pretextual public benefits, are forbidden by the Public Use Clause. A court applying rational-basis review under the Public Use Clause should strike down a taking that, by a clear showing, is intended to favor a particular private party, with only incidental or pretextual public benefits, just as a court applying rational-basis review under the Equal Protection Clause must strike down a government classification that is clearly intended to injure a particular class of private parties, with only incidental or pretextual public justifications. See Cleburne v. Cleburne Living Center, Inc., 473 U.S. 432, 446-447, 450, 87 L. Ed. 2d 313, 105 S. Ct. 3249 (1985); Department of Agriculture v. Moreno, 413 U.S. 528, 533-536, 37 L. Ed. 2d 782, 93 S. Ct. 2821 (1973). As the trial court in this case was correct to observe: "Where the purpose [of a taking] is economic development and that development is to be carried out by 18 See, e.g., County of Wayne v. Hathcock, 471 Mich. 445, 684 N.W.2d 765 (2004). Under California law, for instance, a city may only take land for economic development purposes in blighted areas. Cal. Health & Safety Code Ann. §§ 33030-33037 (West 1999). See, e.g., Redevelopment Agency of Chula Vista v. Rados Bros., 95 Cal. App. 4th 309, 115 Cal. Rptr. 2d 234 (2002). 19 42 private parties or private parties will be benefited, the court must decide if the stated public purpose—economic advantage to a city sorely in need of it—is only incidental to the benefits that will be confined on private parties of a development plan." A court confronted with a plausible accusation of impermissible favoritism to private parties should treat the objection as a serious one and review the record to see if it has merit, though with the presumption that the government's actions were reasonable and intended to serve a public purpose. Here, the trial court conducted a careful and extensive inquiry into "whether, in fact, the development plan is of primary benefit to . . . the developer [i.e., Corcoran Jennison], and private businesses which may eventually locate in the plan area [e.g., Pfizer], and in that regard, only of incidental benefit to the city." The trial court considered testimony from government officials and corporate officers; documentary evidence of communications between these parties; respondents' awareness of New London's depressed economic condition and evidence corroborating the validity of this concern; the substantial commitment of public funds by the State to the development project before most of the private beneficiaries were known; evidence that respondents reviewed a variety of development plans and chose a private developer from a group of applicants rather than picking out a particular transferee beforehand; and the fact that the other private beneficiaries of the project are still unknown because the office space proposed to be built has not yet been rented. The trial court concluded, based on these findings, that benefiting Pfizer was not "the primary motivation or effect of this development plan"; instead, "the primary motivation for [respondents] was to take advantage of Pfizer's presence." Likewise, the trial court concluded that "[t]here is nothing in the record to indicate that . . . [respondents] were motivated by a desire to aid [other] particular private entities." Even the dissenting justices on the Connecticut Supreme Court agreed that respondents' development plan was intended to revitalize the local economy, not to serve the interests of Pfizer, Corcoran Jennison, or any other private party. 268 Conn. 1, 159, 843 A.2d 500, 595 (2004) (Zarella, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). This case, then, survives the meaningful rational basis review that in my view is required under the Public Use Clause. Petitioners and their amici argue that any taking justified by the promotion of economic development must be treated by the courts as per se invalid, or at least presumptively invalid. Petitioners overstate the need for such a rule, however, by making the incorrect assumption that review under Berman and Midkiff imposes no meaningful judicial limits on the government's power to condemn any property it likes. A broad per se rule or a strong presumption of invalidity, furthermore, would prohibit a large number of government takings that have the purpose and expected effect of conferring substantial benefits on the public at large and so do not offend the Public Use Clause. My agreement with the Court that a presumption of invalidity is not warranted for economic development takings in general, or for the particular takings at issue in this case, does not foreclose the possibility that a more stringent standard of review than that announced in Berman and Midkiff might be appropriate for a more narrowly drawn category of takings. There may be private transfers in which the risk of undetected impermissible favoritism of private parties is so acute that a presumption (rebuttable or otherwise) of invalidity is warranted under 43 the Public Use Clause. Cf. Eastern Enterprises v. Apfel, 524 U.S. 498, 549-550, 141 L. Ed. 2d 451, 118 S. Ct. 2131 (1998) (Kennedy, J., concurring in judgment and dissenting in part) (heightened scrutiny for retroactive legislation under the Due Process Clause). This demanding level of scrutiny, however, is not required simply because the purpose of the taking is economic development. This is not the occasion for conjecture as to what sort of cases might justify a more demanding standard, but it is appropriate to underscore aspects of the instant case that convince me no departure from Berman and Midkiff is appropriate here. This taking occurred in the context of a comprehensive development plan meant to address a serious city-wide depression, and the projected economic benefits of the project cannot be characterized as de minimis. The identities of most of the private beneficiaries were unknown at the time the city formulated its plans. The city complied with elaborate procedural requirements that facilitate review of the record and inquiry into the city's purposes. In sum, while there may be categories of cases in which the transfers are so suspicious, or the procedures employed so prone to abuse, or the purported benefits are so trivial or implausible, that courts should presume an impermissible private purpose, no such circumstances are present in this case. For the foregoing reasons, I join in the Court's opinion. JUSTICE O'CONNOR, with whom the CHIEF JUSTICE, JUSTICE SCALIA, and JUSTICE THOMAS join, dissenting. Over two centuries ago, just after the Bill of Rights was ratified, Justice Chase wrote: "An Act of the Legislature (for I cannot call it a law) contrary to the great first principles of the social compact, cannot be considered a rightful exercise of legislative authority . . . . A few instances will suffice to explain what I mean. . . . [A] law that takes property from A. and gives it to B: It is against all reason and justice, for a people to entrust a Legislature with such powers; and, therefore, it cannot be presumed that they have done it." Calder v. Bull, 3 U.S. 386, 3 Dallas 386, 1 L. Ed. 648 (1798) (emphasis deleted). Today the Court abandons this long-held, basic limitation on government power. Under the banner of economic development, all private property is now vulnerable to being taken and transferred to another private owner, so long as it might be upgraded—i.e., given to an owner who will use it in a way that the legislature deems more beneficial to the public—in the process. To reason, as the Court does, that the incidental public benefits resulting from the subsequent ordinary use of private property render economic development takings "for public use" is to wash out any distinction between private and public use of property--and thereby effectively to delete the words "for public use" from the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment. Accordingly I respectfully dissent. I 44 Petitioners are nine resident or investment owners of 15 homes in the Fort Trumbull neighborhood of New London, Connecticut. Petitioner Wilhelmina Dery, for example, lives in a house on Walbach Street that has been in her family for over 100 years. She was born in the house in 1918; her husband, petitioner Charles Dery, moved into the house when they married in 1946. Their son lives next door with his family in the house he received as a wedding gift, and joins his parents in this suit. Two petitioners keep rental properties in the neighborhood. In February 1998, Pfizer Inc., the pharmaceuticals manufacturer, announced that it would build a global research facility near the Fort Trumbull neighborhood. Two months later, New London's city council gave initial approval for the New London Development Corporation (NLDC) to prepare the development plan at issue here. The NLDC is a private, nonprofit corporation whose mission is to assist the city council in economic development planning. It is not elected by popular vote, and its directors and employees are privately appointed. Consistent with its mandate, the NLDC generated an ambitious plan for redeveloping 90 acres of Fort Trumbull in order to "complement the facility that Pfizer was planning to build, create jobs, increase tax and other revenues, encourage public access to and use of the city's waterfront, and eventually 'build momentum' for the revitalization of the rest of the city." Petitioners own properties in two of the plan's seven parcels—Parcel 3 and Parcel 4A. Under the plan, Parcel 3 is slated for the construction of research and office space as a market develops for such space. It will also retain the existing Italian Dramatic Club (a private cultural organization) though the homes of three plaintiffs in that parcel are to be demolished. Parcel 4A is slated, mysteriously, for "'park support.'" At oral argument, counsel for respondents conceded the vagueness of this proposed use, and offered that the parcel might eventually be used for parking. To save their homes, petitioners sued New London and the NLDC, to whom New London has delegated eminent domain power. Petitioners maintain that the Fifth Amendment prohibits the NLDC from condemning their properties for the sake of an economic development plan. Petitioners are not holdouts; they do not seek increased compensation, and none is opposed to new development in the area. Theirs is an objection in principle: They claim that the NLDC's proposed use for their confiscated property is not a "public" one for purposes of the Fifth Amendment. While the government may take their homes to build a road or a railroad or to eliminate a property use that harms the public, say petitioners, it cannot take their property for the private use of other owners simply because the new owners may make more productive use of the property. II The Fifth Amendment to the Constitution, made applicable to the States by the Fourteenth Amendment, provides that "private property [shall not] be taken for public use, without just compensation." When interpreting the Constitution, we begin with the unremarkable presumption that every word in the document has independent meaning, "that no word was unnecessarily used, or needlessly added." Wright v. United States, 302 U.S. 583, 588, 82 L. Ed. 439, 58 S. Ct. 395, 86 Ct. Cl. 764 (1938). In keeping with that presumption, we have read the Fifth Amendment's language to impose two distinct conditions on the exercise of eminent 45 domain: "the Taking must be for a 'public use' and 'just compensation' must be paid to the owner." Brown v. Legal Foundation of Wash., 538 U.S. 216, 231-232, 155 L. Ed. 2d 376, 123 S. Ct. 1406 (2003). These two limitations serve to protect "the security of Property," which Alexander Hamilton described to the Philadelphia Convention as one of the "great obj[ects] of Gov[ernment]." 1 Records of the Federal Convention of 1787, p 302 (M. Farrand ed. 1911). Together they ensure stable property ownership by providing safeguards against excessive, unpredictable, or unfair use of the government's eminent domain power--particularly against those owners who, for whatever reasons, may be unable to protect themselves in the political process against the majority's will. While the Takings Clause presupposes that government can take private property without the owner's consent, the just compensation requirement spreads the cost of condemnations and thus "prevents the public from loading upon one individual more than his just share of the burdens of government." Monongahela Nav. Co. v. United States, 148 U.S. 312, 325, 37 L. Ed. 463, 13 S. Ct. 622 (1893); see also Armstrong v. United States, 364 U.S. 40, 49, 4 L. Ed. 2d 1554, 80 S. Ct. 1563 (1960). The public use requirement, in turn, imposes a more basic limitation, circumscribing the very scope of the eminent domain power: Government may compel an individual to forfeit her property for the public's use, but not for the benefit of another private person. This requirement promotes fairness as well as security. Cf. Tahoe-Sierra Preservation Council, Inc. v. Tahoe Regional Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 336, 152 L. Ed. 2d 517, 122 S. Ct. 1465 (2002) ("The concepts of 'fairness and justice' . . . underlie the Takings Clause"). Where is the line between "public" and "private" property use? We give considerable deference to legislatures' determinations about what governmental activities will advantage the public. But were the political branches the sole arbiters of the public-private distinction, the Public Use Clause would amount to little more than hortatory fluff. An external, judicial check on how the public use requirement is interpreted, however limited, is necessary if this constraint on government power is to retain any meaning. See Cincinnati v. Vester, 281 U.S. 439, 446, 74 L. Ed. 950, 50 S. Ct. 360 (1930) ("It is well established that . . . the question [of] what is a public use is a judicial one"). *** This case returns us for the first time in over 20 years to the hard question of when a purportedly "public purpose" taking meets the public use requirement. It presents an issue of first impression: Are economic development takings constitutional? I would hold that they are not. We are guided by two precedents about the taking of real property by eminent domain. *** In [Berman and Midkiff], we emphasized the importance of deferring to legislative judgments about public purpose. Because courts are ill equipped to evaluate the efficacy of proposed legislative initiatives, we rejected as unworkable the idea of courts' "'deciding on what 46 is and is not a governmental function and . . . invalidating legislation on the basis of their view on that question at the moment of decision, a practice which has proved impracticable in other fields.'" [Midkiff,] at 240-241, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (quoting United States ex rel. TVA v. Welch, 327 U.S. 546, 552, 90 L. Ed. 843, 66 S. Ct. 715 (1946)); see Berman, supra, at 32, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 ("[T]he legislature, not the judiciary, is the main guardian of the public needs to be served by social legislation"); see also Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 161 L. Ed. 2d 876, 125 S. Ct. 2074 (2005). Likewise, we recognized our inability to evaluate whether, in a given case, eminent domain is a necessary means by which to pursue the legislature's ends. Midkiff, supra, at 242, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321; Berman, supra, at 33, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. Yet for all the emphasis on deference, Berman and Midkiff hewed to a bedrock principle without which our public use jurisprudence would collapse: "A purely private taking could not withstand the scrutiny of the public use requirement; it would serve no legitimate purpose of government and would thus be void." Midkiff, 467 U.S., at 245, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321; id., at 241, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 ("[T]he Court's cases have repeatedly stated that 'one person's property may not be taken for the benefit of another private person without a justifying public purpose, even though compensation be paid'" (quoting Thompson v. Consolidated Gas Util. Corp., 300 U.S. 55, 80, 81 L. Ed. 510, 57 S. Ct. 364 (1937))); see also Missouri Pacific R. Co. v. Nebraska, 164 U.S. 403, 417, 41 L. Ed. 489, 17 S. Ct. 130 (1896). To protect that principle, those decisions reserved "a role for courts to play in reviewing a legislature's judgment of what constitutes a public use . . . [though] the Court in Berman made clear that it is 'an extremely narrow' one." Midkiff, supra, at 240, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (quoting Berman, supra, at 32, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98). The Court's holdings in Berman and Midkiff were true to the principle underlying the Public Use Clause. In both those cases, the extraordinary, pre-condemnation use of the targeted property inflicted affirmative harm on society—in Berman through blight resulting from extreme poverty and in Midkiff through oligopoly resulting from extreme wealth. And in both cases, the relevant legislative body had found that eliminating the existing property use was necessary to remedy the harm. Berman, supra, at 28-29, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98; Midkiff, supra, at 232, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321. Thus a public purpose was realized when the harmful use was eliminated. Because each taking directly achieved a public benefit, it did not matter that the property was turned over to private use. Here, in contrast, New London does not claim that Susette Kelo's and Wilhelmina Dery's well-maintained homes are the source of any social harm. Indeed, it could not so claim without adopting the absurd argument that any single-family home that might be razed to make way for an apartment building, or any church that might be replaced with a retail store, or any small business that might be more lucrative if it were instead part of a national franchise, is inherently harmful to society and thus within the government's power to condemn. In moving away from our decisions sanctioning the condemnation of harmful property use, the Court today significantly expands the meaning of public use. It holds that the sovereign may take private property currently put to ordinary private use, and give it over for new, ordinary private use, so long as the new use is predicted to generate some secondary benefit for the public—such as increased tax revenue, more jobs, maybe even esthetic pleasure. But nearly any 47 lawful use of real private property can be said to generate some incidental benefit to the public. Thus, if predicted (or even guaranteed) positive side effects are enough to render transfer from one private party to another constitutional, then the words "for public use" do not realistically exclude any takings, and thus do not exert any constraint on the eminent domain power. There is a sense in which this troubling result follows from errant language in Berman and Midkiff. In discussing whether takings within a blighted neighborhood were for a public use, Berman began by observing: "We deal, in other words, with what traditionally has been known as the police power." 348 U.S., at 32, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. From there it declared that "[o]nce the object is within the authority of Congress, the right to realize it through the exercise of eminent domain is clear." Id., at 33, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. Following up, we said in Midkiff that "[t]he 'public use' requirement is coterminous with the scope of a sovereign's police powers." 467 U.S., at 240, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321. This language was unnecessary to the specific holdings of those decisions. Berman and Midkiff simply did not put such language to the constitutional test, because the takings in those cases were within the police power but also for "public use" for the reasons I have described. The case before us now demonstrates why, when deciding if a taking's purpose is constitutional, the police power and "public use" cannot always be equated. The Court protests that it does not sanction the bare transfer from A to B for B's benefit. It suggests two limitations on what can be taken after today's decision. First, it maintains a role for courts in ferreting out takings whose sole purpose is to bestow a benefit on the private transferee—without detailing how courts are to conduct that complicated inquiry. For his part, Justice Kennedy suggests that courts may divine illicit purpose by a careful review of the record and the process by which a legislature arrived at the decision to take—without specifying what courts should look for in a case with different facts, how they will know if they have found it, and what to do if they do not. Whatever the details of Justice Kennedy's as-yet-undisclosed test, it is difficult to envision anyone but the "stupid staff[er]" failing it. See Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1025-1026, n. 12, 120 L. Ed. 2d 798, 112 S. Ct. 2886 (1992). The trouble with economic development takings is that private benefit and incidental public benefit are, by definition, merged and mutually reinforcing. In this case, for example, any boon for Pfizer or the plan's developer is difficult to disaggregate from the promised public gains in taxes and jobs. Even if there were a practical way to isolate the motives behind a given taking, the gesture toward a purpose test is theoretically flawed. If it is true that incidental public benefits from new private use are enough to ensure the "public purpose" in a taking, why should it matter, as far as the Fifth Amendment is concerned, what inspired the taking in the first place? How much the government does or does not desire to benefit a favored private party has no bearing on whether an economic development taking will or will not generate secondary benefit for the public. And whatever the reason for a given condemnation, the effect is the same from the constitutional perspective—private property is forcibly relinquished to new private ownership. A second proposed limitation is implicit in the Court's opinion. The logic of today's decision is that eminent domain may only be used to upgrade—not downgrade—property. At best this makes the Public Use Clause redundant with the Due Process Clause, which already 48 prohibits irrational government action. See Lingle, 544 U.S. 528, 161 L. Ed. 2d 876, 125 S. Ct. 2074. The Court rightfully admits, however, that the judiciary cannot get bogged down in predictive judgments about whether the public will actually be better off after a property transfer. In any event, this constraint has no realistic import. For who among us can say she already makes the most productive or attractive possible use of her property? The specter of condemnation hangs over all property. Nothing is to prevent the State from replacing any Motel 6 with a Ritz-Carlton, any home with a shopping mall, or any farm with a factory. Cf. Bugryn v. Bristol, 63 Conn. App. 98, 774 A.2d 1042 (2001) (taking the homes and farm of four owners in their 70's and 80's and giving it to an "industrial park"); 99 Cents Only Stores v. Lancaster Redevelopment Agency, 237 F. Supp. 2d 1123 (CD Cal. 2001) (attempted taking of 99 Cents store to replace with a Costco); Poletown Neighborhood Council v. Detroit, 410 Mich. 616, 304 N.W.2d 455 (1981) (taking a working-class, immigrant community in Detroit and giving it to a General Motors assembly plant), overruled by County of Wayne v. Hathcock, 471 Mich. 445, 684 N.W.2d 765 (2004); Brief for Becket Fund for Religious Liberty as Amicus Curiae 4-11 (describing takings of religious institutions' properties); Institute for Justice, D. Berliner, Public Power, Private Gain: A Five-Year, State-by-State Report Examining the Abuse of Eminent Domain (2003) (collecting accounts of economic development takings). The Court also puts special emphasis on facts peculiar to this case: The NLDC's plan is the product of a relatively careful deliberative process; it proposes to use eminent domain for a multipart, integrated plan rather than for isolated property transfer; it promises an array of incidental benefits (even esthetic ones), not just increased tax revenue; it comes on the heels of a legislative determination that New London is a depressed municipality. Justice Kennedy, too, takes great comfort in these facts. But none has legal significance to blunt the force of today's holding. If legislative prognostications about the secondary public benefits of a new use can legitimate a taking, there is nothing in the Court's rule or in Justice Kennedy's gloss on that rule to prohibit property transfers generated with less care, that are less comprehensive, that happen to result from less elaborate process, whose only projected advantage is the incidence of higher taxes, or that hope to transform an already prosperous city into an even more prosperous one. Finally, in a coda, the Court suggests that property owners should turn to the States, who may or may not choose to impose appropriate limits on economic development takings. This is an abdication of our responsibility. States play many important functions in our system of dual sovereignty, but compensating for our refusal to enforce properly the Federal Constitution (and a provision meant to curtail state action, no less) is not among them. *** It was possible after Berman and Midkiff to imagine unconstitutional transfers from A to B. Those decisions endorsed government intervention when private property use had veered to such an extreme that the public was suffering as a consequence. Today nearly all real property is susceptible to condemnation on the Court's theory. In the prescient words of a dissenter from the infamous decision in Poletown, "[n]ow that we have authorized local legislative bodies to decide that a different commercial or industrial use of property will produce greater public benefits than its present use, no homeowner's, merchant's or manufacturer's property, however productive or valuable to its owner, is immune from condemnation for the benefit of other private interests that 49 will put it to a 'higher' use." 410 Mich., at 644-645, 304 N. W. 2d, at 464 (opinion of Fitzgerald, J.). This is why economic development takings "seriously jeopardiz[e] the security of all private property ownership." Id., at 645, 304 N. W. 2d, at 465 (Ryan, J., dissenting). Any property may now be taken for the benefit of another private party, but the fallout from this decision will not be random. The beneficiaries are likely to be those citizens with disproportionate influence and power in the political process, including large corporations and development firms. As for the victims, the government now has license to transfer property from those with fewer resources to those with more. The Founders cannot have intended this perverse result. "[T]hat alone is a just government," wrote James Madison, "which impartially secures to every man, whatever is his own." For the National Gazette, Property, (Mar. 27, 1792), reprinted in 14 Papers of James Madison 266 (R. Rutland et al. eds. 1983). I would hold that the takings in both Parcel 3 and Parcel 4A are unconstitutional, reverse the judgment of the Supreme Court of Connecticut, and remand for further proceedings. JUSTICE THOMAS, dissenting. Long ago, William Blackstone wrote that "the law of the land . . . postpone[s] even public necessity to the sacred and inviolable rights of private property." 1 Commentaries on the Laws of England 134-135 (1765) (hereinafter Blackstone). The Framers embodied that principle in the Constitution, allowing the government to take property not for "public necessity," but instead for "public use." Amdt. 5. Defying this understanding, the Court replaces the Public Use Clause with a "'[P]ublic [P]urpose'" Clause (or perhaps the "Diverse and Always Evolving Needs of Society" Clause (capitalization added)), a restriction that is satisfied, the Court instructs, so long as the purpose is "legitimate" and the means "not irrational." This deferential shift in phraseology enables the Court to hold, against all common sense, that a costly urban-renewal project whose stated purpose is a vague promise of new jobs and increased tax revenue, but which is also suspiciously agreeable to the Pfizer Corporation, is for a "public use." I cannot agree. If such "economic development" takings are for a "public use," any taking is, and the Court has erased the Public Use Clause from our Constitution, as Justice O'Connor powerfully argues in dissent. I do not believe that this Court can eliminate liberties expressly enumerated in the Constitution and therefore join her dissenting opinion. Regrettably, however, the Court's error runs deeper than this. Today's decision is simply the latest in a string of our cases construing the Public Use Clause to be a virtual nullity, without the slightest nod to its original meaning. In my view, the Public Use Clause, originally understood, is a meaningful limit on the government's eminent domain power. Our cases have strayed from the Clause's original meaning, and I would reconsider them. I The Fifth Amendment provides: "No person shall be held to answer for a capital, or otherwise infamous crime, unless on a presentment or indictment of a Grand Jury, except in cases arising in the land or naval 50 forces, or in the Militia, when in actual service in time of War or public danger; nor shall any person be subject for the same offence to be twice put in jeopardy of life or limb, nor shall be compelled in any criminal case to be a witness against himself, nor be deprived of life, liberty, or property, without due process of law; nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation." (Emphasis added.) It is the last of these liberties, the Takings Clause, that is at issue in this case. In my view, it is "imperative that the Court maintain absolute fidelity to" the Clause's express limit on the power of the government over the individual, no less than with every other liberty expressly enumerated in the Fifth Amendment or the Bill of Rights more generally. Shepard v. United States, 544 U.S. 13, 28, 161 L. Ed. 2d 205, 125 S. Ct. 1254 (2005) (Thomas, J., concurring in part and concurring in judgment) (internal quotation marks omitted). Though one component of the protection provided by the Takings Clause is that the government can take private property only if it provides "just compensation" for the taking, the Takings Clause also prohibits the government from taking property except "for public use." Were it otherwise, the Takings Clause would either be meaningless or empty. If the Public Use Clause served no function other than to state that the government may take property through its eminent domain power—for public or private uses—then it would be surplusage. See ante, at 496, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 462 (O'Connor, J., dissenting); see also Marbury v. Madison, 5 U.S. 137, 1 Cranch 137, 174, 2 L. Ed. 60 (1803) ("It cannot be presumed that any clause in the constitution is intended to be without effect"); Myers v. United States, 272 U.S. 52, 151, 71 L. Ed. 160, 47 S. Ct. 21 (1926). Alternatively, the Clause could distinguish those takings that require compensation from those that do not. That interpretation, however, "would permit private property to be taken or appropriated for private use without any compensation whatever." Cole v. La Grange, 113 U.S. 1, 8, 28 L. Ed. 896, 5 S. Ct. 416 (1885) (interpreting same language in the Missouri Public Use Clause). In other words, the Clause would require the government to compensate for takings done "for public use," leaving it free to take property for purely private uses without the payment of compensation. This would contradict a bedrock principle well established by the time of the founding: that all takings required the payment of compensation. 1 Blackstone 135; 2 J. Kent, Commentaries on American Law 275 (1827) (hereinafter Kent); For the National Property Gazette, (Mar. 27, 1792), in 14 Papers of James Madison 266, 267 (R. Rutland et al. eds. 1983) (arguing that no property "shall be taken directly even for public use without indemnification to the owner").20 The Public Use Clause, like the Just Compensation Clause, is therefore an express limit on the government's power of eminent domain. The most natural reading of the Clause is that it allows the government to take property only if the government owns, or the public has a legal right to use, the property, as opposed to taking it for any public purpose or necessity whatsoever. At the time of the founding, 20 Some state constitutions at the time of the founding lacked just compensation clauses and took property even without providing compensation. See Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1056-1057, 120 L. Ed. 2d 798, 112 S. Ct. 2886 (1992) (Blackmun, J., dissenting). The Framers of the Fifth Amendment apparently disagreed, for they expressly prohibited uncompensated takings, and the Fifth Amendment was not incorporated against the States until much later. See id., at 1028, n. 15, 120 L. Ed. 2d 798, 112 S. Ct. 2886. 51 dictionaries primarily defined the noun "use" as "[t]he act of employing any thing to any purpose." 2 S. Johnson, A Dictionary of the English Language 2194 (4th ed. 1773) (hereinafter Johnson). The term "use," moreover, "is from the Latin utor, which means 'to use, make use of, avail one's self of, employ, apply, enjoy, etc." J. Lewis, Law of Eminent Domain § 165, p 224, n 4 (1888) (hereinafter Lewis). When the government takes property and gives it to a private individual, and the public has no right to use the property, it strains language to say that the public is "employing" the property, regardless of the incidental benefits that might accrue to the public from the private use. The term "public use," then, means that either the government or its citizens as a whole must actually "employ" the taken property. See id., at 223 (reviewing founding-era dictionaries). Ganted, another sense of the word "use" was broader in meaning, extending to "[c]onvenience" or "help," or "[q]ualities that make a thing proper for any purpose." 2 Johnson 2194. Nevertheless, read in context, the term "public use" possesses the narrower meaning. Elsewhere, the Constitution twice employs the word "use," both times in its narrower sense. Claeys, Public-Use Limitations and Natural Property Rights, 2004 Mich. St. L. Rev. 877, 897 (hereinafter Public Use Limitations). Article I, § 10 provides that "the net Produce of all Duties and Imposts, laid by any State on Imports or Exports, shall be for the Use of the Treasury of the United States," meaning the Treasury itself will control the taxes, not use it to any beneficial end. And Article I, § 8 grants Congress power "[t]o raise and support Armies, but no Appropriation of Money to that Use shall be for a longer Term than two Years." Here again, "use" means "employed to raise and support Armies," not anything directed to achieving any military end. The same word in the Public Use Clause should be interpreted to have the same meaning. Tellingly, the phrase "public use" contrasts with the very different phrase "general Welfare" used elsewhere in the Constitution. See ibid. ("Congress shall have Power To . . . provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States"); preamble (Constitution established "to promote the general Welfare"). The Framers would have used some such broader term if they had meant the Public Use Clause to have a similarly sweeping scope. Other founding-era documents made the contrast between these two usages still more explicit. See Sales, Classical Republicanism and the Fifth Amendment's "Public Use" Requirement, 49 Duke L. J. 339, 367368 (1999) (hereinafter Sales) (noting contrast between, on the one hand, the term "public use" used by 6 of the first 13 States and, on the other, the terms "public exigencies" employed in the Massachusetts Bill of Rights and the Northwest Ordinance, and the term "public necessity" used in the Vermont Constitution of 1786). The Constitution's text, in short, suggests that the Takings Clause authorizes the taking of property only if the public has a right to employ it, not if the public realizes any conceivable benefit from the taking. The Constitution's common-law background reinforces this understanding. The common law provided an express method of eliminating uses of land that adversely impacted the public welfare: nuisance law. Blackstone and Kent, for instance, both carefully distinguished the law of nuisance from the power of eminent domain. Compare 1 Blackstone 135 (noting government's power to take private property with compensation) with 3 id., at 216 (noting action to remedy "public . . . nuisances, which affect the public, and are an annoyance to all the king's subjects"); see also 2 Kent 274-276 (distinguishing the two). Blackstone rejected the idea that private property could be taken solely for purposes of any public benefit. "So great . . . is the regard of the law for private property," he explained, "that it will not authorize the least violation of it; no, 52 not even for the general good of the whole community." 1 Blackstone 135. He continued: "If a new road . . . were to be made through the grounds of a private person, it might perhaps be extensively beneficial to the public; but the law permits no man, or set of men, to do this without the consent of the owner of the land." Ibid. Only "by giving [the landowner] full indemnification" could the government take property, and even then "[t]he public [was] now considered as an individual, treating with an individual for an exchange." Ibid. When the public took property, in other words, it took it as an individual buying property from another typically would: for one's own use. The Public Use Clause, in short, embodied the Framers' understanding that property is a natural, fundamental right, prohibiting the government from "tak[ing] property from A. and giv[ing] it to B." Calder v. Bull, 3 Dall. 386, 388, 1 L. Ed. 648 (1798); see also Wilkinson v. Leland, 27 U.S. 627, 2 Pet. 627, 658, 7 L. Ed. 542 (1829); Vanhorne's Lessee v. Dorrance, 2 U.S. 304, 2 Dallas 304, 1 L. Ed. 391 (CC Pa. 1795). The public purpose interpretation of the Public Use Clause also unnecessarily duplicates a similar inquiry required by the Necessary and Proper Clause. The Takings Clause is a prohibition, not a grant of power: The Constitution does not expressly grant the Federal Government the power to take property for any public purpose whatsoever. Instead, the Government may take property only when necessary and proper to the exercise of an expressly enumerated power. See Kohl v. United States, 91 U.S. 367, 371-372, 23 L. Ed. 449 (1876) (noting Federal Government's power under the Necessary and Proper Clause to take property "needed for forts, armories, and arsenals, for navy-yards and light-houses, for custom-houses, post-offices, and court-houses, and for other public uses"). For a law to be within the Necessary and Proper Clause, as I have elsewhere explained, it must bear an "obvious, simple, and direct relation" to an exercise of Congress' enumerated powers, Sabri v. United States, 541 U.S. 600, 613, 158 L. Ed. 2d 891, 124 S. Ct. 1941 (2004) (Thomas, J., concurring in judgment), and it must not "subvert basic principles of" constitutional design, Gonzales v. Raich, ante, at 65, 162 L. Ed. 2d 1, 125 S. Ct. 2195 (Thomas, J., dissenting). In other words, a taking is permissible under the Necessary and Proper Clause only if it serves a valid public purpose. Interpreting the Public Use Clause likewise to limit the government to take property only for sufficiently public purposes replicates this inquiry. If this is all the Clause means, it is, once again, surplusage. The Clause is thus most naturally read to concern whether the property is used by the public or the government, not whether the purpose of the taking is legitimately public. II Early American eminent domain practice largely bears out this understanding of the Public Use Clause. This practice concerns state limits on eminent domain power, not the Fifth Amendment, since it was not until the late 19th century that the Federal Government began to use the power of eminent domain, and since the Takings Clause did not even arguably limit state power until after the passage of the Fourteenth Amendment. See Note, The Public Use Limitation on Eminent Domain: An Advance Requiem, 58 Yale L. J. 567, 599-600, and nn. 3-4 (1949); Barron ex rel. Tiernan v. Mayor of Baltimore, 32 U.S. 243, 7 Pet. 243, 250-251, 8 L. Ed. 672 (1833) (holding the Takings Clause inapplicable to the States of its own force). Nevertheless, several early state constitutions at the time of the founding likewise limited the power of eminent domain to "public uses." See Sales 367-369, and n. 137 (emphasis deleted). 53 Their practices therefore shed light on the original meaning of the same words contained in the Public Use Clause. States employed the eminent domain power to provide quintessentially public goods, such as public roads, toll roads, ferries, canals, railroads, and public parks. Lewis §§ 166, 168171, 175, at 227-228, 234-241, 243. Though use of the eminent domain power was sparse at the time of the founding, many States did have so-called Mill Acts, which authorized the owners of grist mills operated by water power to flood upstream lands with the payment of compensation to the upstream landowner. See, e.g., id., § 178, at 245-246; Head v. Amoskeag Mfg. Co., 113 U.S. 9, 16-19, 28 L. Ed. 889, 5 S. Ct. 441, and n. (1885). Those early grist mills "were regulated by law and compelled to serve the public for a stipulated toll and in regular order," and therefore were actually used by the public. Lewis § 178, at 246, and n. 3; see also Head, supra, at 18-19, 28 L. Ed. 889, 5 S. Ct. 441. They were common carriers—quasi-public entities. These were "public uses" in the fullest sense of the word, because the public could legally use and benefit from them equally. See Public Use Limitations 903 (common-carrier status traditionally afforded to "private beneficiaries of a state franchise or another form of state monopoly, or to companies that operated in conditions of natural monopoly"). To be sure, some early state legislatures tested the limits of their state-law eminent domain power. Some States enacted statutes allowing the taking of property for the purpose of building private roads. See Lewis § 167, at 230. These statutes were mixed; some required the private landowner to keep the road open to the public, and others did not. See id., § 167, at 230234. Later in the 19th century, moreover, the Mill Acts were employed to grant rights to private manufacturing plants, in addition to grist mills that had common-carrier duties. See, e.g., M. Horwitz, The Transformation of American Law 1780-1860, pp. 51-52 (1977). These early uses of the eminent domain power are often cited as evidence for the broad "public purpose" interpretation of the Public Use Clause, see, e.g., ante, at 479-480, n 8, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 450-451 (majority opinion); but in fact the constitutionality of these exercises of eminent domain power under state public use restrictions was a hotly contested question in state courts throughout the 19th and into the 20th century. Some courts construed those clauses to authorize takings for public purposes, but others adhered to the natural meaning of "public use."21 As noted above, the earliest Mill Acts were applied to entities with duties to remain open 21 Compare ante, at 479, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 450-451, and n. 8 (majority opinion) (noting that some state courts upheld the validity of applying the Mill Acts to private purposes and arguing that the "'use by the public' test" "eroded over time"), with, e.g., Ryerson v. Brown, 35 Mich. 333, 338-339 (1877) (holding it "essential" to the constitutionality of a Mill Act "that the statute should require the use to be public in fact; in other words, that it should contain provisions entitling the public to accommodations"); Gaylord v. Sanitary Dist. of Chicago, 204 Ill. 576, 581-584, 68 N. E. 522, 524 (1903) (same); Tyler v. Beacher, 44 Vt. 648, 652-656 (1871) (same); Sadler v. Langham, 34 Ala. 311, 332-334 (1859) (striking down taking for purely private road and grist mill); Varner v. Martin, 21 W. Va. 534, 546-548, 556-557, 566-567 (1883) (grist mill and private road had to be open to public for them to constitute public use); Harding v. Goodlett, 3 Yer. 41, 53 (Tenn. 1832); Jacobs v. Clearview Water Supply Co., 220 Pa. 388, 393-395, 69 A. 870, 872 (1908) (endorsing actual public use standard); Minnesota Canal & Power Co. v. 54 to the public, and their later extension is not deeply probative of whether that subsequent practice is consistent with the original meaning of the Public Use Clause. See McIntyre v. Ohio Elections Comm'n, 514 U.S. 334, 370, 131 L. Ed. 2d 426, 115 S. Ct. 1511 (1995) (Thomas, J., concurring in judgment). At the time of the founding, "[b]usiness corporations were only beginning to upset the old corporate model, in which the raison d'etre of chartered associations was their service to the public," Horwitz, supra, at 49-50, so it was natural to those who framed the first Public Use Clauses to think of mills as inherently public entities. The disagreement among state courts, and state legislatures' attempts to circumvent public use limits on their eminent domain power, cannot obscure that the Public Use Clause is most naturally read to authorize takings for public use only if the government or the public actually uses the taken property. III Our current Public Use Clause jurisprudence, as the Court notes, has rejected this natural reading of the Clause. The Court adopted its modern reading blindly, with little discussion of the Clause's history and original meaning, in two distinct lines of cases: first, in cases adopting the "public purpose" interpretation of the Clause, and second, in cases deferring to legislatures' judgments regarding what constitutes a valid public purpose. Those questionable cases converged in the boundlessly broad and deferential conception of "public use" adopted by this Court in Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 (1954), and Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (1984), cases that take center stage in the Court's opinion. The weakness of those two lines of cases, and consequently Berman and Midkiff, fatally undermines the doctrinal foundations of the Court's decision. Today's questionable application of these cases is further proof that the "public purpose" standard is not susceptible of principled application. This Court's reliance by rote on this standard is ill advised and should be reconsidered. A As the Court notes, the "public purpose" interpretation of the Public Use Clause stems from Fallbrook Irrigation Dist. v. Bradley, 164 U.S. 112, 161-162, 41 L. Ed. 369, 17 S. Ct. 56 (1896). The issue in Bradley was whether a condemnation for purposes of constructing an irrigation ditch was for a public use. 164 U.S., at 161, 41 L. Ed. 369, 17 S. Ct. 56. This was a public use, Justice Peckham declared for the Court, because "[t]o irrigate and thus to bring into possible cultivation these large masses of otherwise worthless lands would seem to be a public purpose and a matter of public interest, not confined to landowners, or even to any one section of the State." Ibid. That broad statement was dictum, for the law under review also provided that "[a]ll landowners in the district have the right to a proportionate share of the water." Id., at 162, 41 L. Ed. 369, 17 S. Ct. 56. Thus, the "public" did have the right to use the irrigation ditch because all similarly situated members of the public—those who owned lands irrigated by the ditch—had a right to use it. The Court cited no authority for its dictum, and did not discuss Koochiching Co., 97 Minn. 429, 449-451, 107 N. W. 405, 413 (1906) (same); Chesapeake Stone Co. v. Moreland, 126 Ky. 656, 663-667, 104 S. W. 762, 765, 31 Ky. L. Rptr. 1075 (Ct. App. 1907) (same); Note, Public Use in Eminent Domain, 21 N. Y. U. L. Q. Rev. 285, 286, and n 11 (1946) (calling the actual public use standard the "majority view" and citing other cases). 55 either the Public Use Clause's original meaning or the numerous authorities that had adopted the "actual use" test (though it at least acknowledged the conflict of authority in state courts, see id., at 158, 41 L. Ed. 369, 17 S. Ct. 56; supra, at 513-514, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 473, and n 2). Instead, the Court reasoned that "[t]he use must be regarded as a public use, or else it would seem to follow that no general scheme of irrigation can be formed or carried into effect." Bradley, supra, at 160-161, 41 L. Ed. 369, 17 S. Ct. 56. This is no statement of constitutional principle: Whatever the utility of irrigation districts or the merits of the Court's view that another rule would be "impractical given the diverse and always evolving needs of society," ante, at 479, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 451, the Constitution does not embody those policy preferences any more than it "enact[s] Mr. Herbert Spencer's Social Statics," Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 75, 49 L. Ed. 937, 25 S. Ct. 539 (1905) (Holmes, J., dissenting); but see id., at 58-62, 49 L. Ed. 937, 25 S. Ct. 539 (Peckham, J., for the Court). This Court's cases followed Bradley's test with little analysis. In Clark v. Nash, 198 U.S. 361, 49 L. Ed. 1085, 25 S. Ct. 676 (1905) (Peckham, J., for the Court), this Court relied on little more than a citation to Bradley in upholding another condemnation for the purpose of laying an irrigation ditch. 198 U.S., at 369-370, 49 L. Ed. 1085, 25 S. Ct. 676. As in Bradley, use of the "public purpose" test was unnecessary to the result the Court reached. The government condemned the irrigation ditch for the purpose of ensuring access to water in which "[o]ther land owners adjoining the defendant in error . . . might share," 198 U.S., at 370, 49 L. Ed. 1085, 25 S. Ct. 676, and therefore Clark also involved a condemnation for the purpose of ensuring access to a resource to which similarly situated members of the public had a legal right of access. Likewise, in Strickley v. Highland Boy Gold Mining Co., 200 U.S. 527, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301 (1906), the Court upheld a condemnation establishing an aerial right-of-way for a bucket line operated by a mining company, relying on little more than Clark, see Strickley, supra, at 531, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301. This case, too, could have been disposed of on the narrower ground that "the plaintiff [was] a carrier for itself and others," 200 U.S., at 531-532, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301, and therefore that the bucket line was legally open to the public. Instead, the Court unnecessarily rested its decision on the "inadequacy of use by the general public as a universal test." Id., at 531, 50 L. Ed. 581, 26 S. Ct. 301. This Court's cases quickly incorporated the public purpose standard set forth in Clark and Strickley by barren citation. See, e.g., Rindge Co. v. County of Los Angeles, 262 U.S. 700, 707, 67 L. Ed. 1186, 43 S. Ct. 689 (1923); Block v. Hirsh, 256 U.S. 135, 155, 65 L. Ed. 865, 41 S. Ct. 458 (1921); Mt. Vernon-Woodberry Cotton Duck Co. v. Alabama Interstate Power Co., 240 U.S. 30, 32, 60 L. Ed. 507, 36 S. Ct. 234 (1916); O'Neill v. Leamer, 239 U.S. 244, 253, 60 L. Ed. 249, 36 S. Ct. 54 (1915). B A second line of this Court's cases also deviated from the Public Use Clause's original meaning by allowing legislatures to define the scope of valid "public uses." United States v. Gettysburg Electric R. Co., 160 U.S. 668, 40 L. Ed. 576, 16 S. Ct. 427 (1896), involved the question whether Congress' decision to condemn certain private land for the purpose of building battlefield memorials at Gettysburg, Pennsylvania, was for a public use. Id., at 679-680, 40 L. Ed. 576, 16 S. Ct. 427. Since the Federal Government was to use the lands in question, there is no doubt that it was a public use under any reasonable standard. Nonetheless, the Court, speaking through Justice Peckham, declared that "when the legislature has declared the use or 56 purpose to be a public one, its judgment will be respected by the courts, unless the use be palpably without reasonable foundation." Id., at 680, 40 L. Ed. 576, 16 S. Ct. 427. As it had with the "public purpose" dictum in Bradley, the Court quickly incorporated this dictum into its Public Use Clause cases with little discussion. See, e.g., United States ex rel. TVA v. Welch, 327 U.S. 546, 552, 90 L. Ed. 843, 66 S. Ct. 715 (1946); Old Dominion Land Co. v. United States, 269 U.S. 55, 66, 70 L. Ed. 162, 46 S. Ct. 39 (1925). There is no justification, however, for affording almost insurmountable deference to legislative conclusions that a use serves a "public use." To begin with, a court owes no deference to a legislature's judgment concerning the quintessentially legal question of whether the government owns, or the public has a legal right to use, the taken property. Even under the "public purpose" interpretation, moreover, it is most implausible that the Framers intended to defer to legislatures as to what satisfies the Public Use Clause, uniquely among all the express provisions of the Bill of Rights. We would not defer to a legislature's determination of the various circumstances that establish, for example, when a search of a home would be reasonable, see, e.g., Payton v. New York, 445 U.S. 573, 589-590, 63 L. Ed. 2d 639, 100 S. Ct. 1371 (1980), or when a convicted double-murderer may be shackled during a sentencing proceeding without on-the-record findings, see Deck v. Missouri, 544 U.S. 622, 161 L. Ed. 2d 953, 125 S. Ct. 2007 (2005), or when state law creates a property interest protected by the Due Process Clause, see, e.g., Castle Rock v. Gonzales, post, at 756-758, 162 L. Ed. 2d 658, 125 S. Ct. 2796; Board of Regents of State Colleges v. Roth, 408 U.S. 564, 576, 33 L. Ed. 2d 548, 92 S. Ct. 2701 (1972); Goldberg v. Kelly, 397 U.S. 254, 262-263, 25 L. Ed. 2d 287, 90 S. Ct. 1011 (1970). Still worse, it is backwards to adopt a searching standard of constitutional review for nontraditional property interests, such as welfare benefits, see, e.g., Goldberg, supra, while deferring to the legislature's determination as to what constitutes a public use when it exercises the power of eminent domain, and thereby invades individuals' traditional rights in real property. The Court has elsewhere recognized "the overriding respect for the sanctity of the home that has been embedded in our traditions since the origins of the Republic," Payton, supra, at 601, 63 L. Ed. 2d 639, 100 S. Ct. 1371, when the issue is only whether the government may search a home. Yet today the Court tells us that we are not to "second-guess the City's considered judgments," ante, at 488, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 457, when the issue is, instead, whether the government may take the infinitely more intrusive step of tearing down petitioners' homes. Something has gone seriously awry with this Court's interpretation of the Constitution. Though citizens are safe from the government in their homes, the homes themselves are not. Once one accepts, as the Court at least nominally does, that the Public Use Clause is a limit on the eminent domain power of the Federal Government and the States, there is no justification for the almost complete deference it grants to legislatures as to what satisfies it. C These two misguided lines of precedent converged in Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98 (1954), and Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229, 81 L. Ed. 2d 186, 104 S. Ct. 2321 (1984). Relying on those lines of cases, the Court in Berman and Midkiff upheld condemnations for the purposes of slum clearance and land redistribution, respectively. "Subject to specific constitutional limitations," Berman proclaimed, "when the 57 legislature has spoken, the public interest has been declared in terms well-nigh conclusive. In such cases the legislature, not the judiciary, is the main guardian of the public needs to be served by social legislation." 348 U.S., at 32, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. That reasoning was question begging, since the question to be decided was whether the "specific constitutional limitation" of the Public Use Clause prevented the taking of the appellant's (concededly "nonblighted") department store. Id., at 31, 34, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. Berman also appeared to reason that any exercise by Congress of an enumerated power (in this case, its plenary power over the District of Columbia) was per se a "public use" under the Fifth Amendment. Id., at 33, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. But the very point of the Public Use Clause is to limit that power. More fundamentally, Berman and Midkiff erred by equating the eminent domain power with the police power of States. Traditional uses of that regulatory power, such as the power to abate a nuisance, required no compensation whatsoever, see Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623, 668-669, 31 L. Ed. 205, 8 S. Ct. 273 (1887), in sharp contrast to the takings power, which has always required compensation. The question whether the State can take property using the power of eminent domain is therefore distinct from the question whether it can regulate property pursuant to the police power. In Berman, for example, if the slums at issue were truly "blighted," then state nuisance law, not the power of eminent domain, would provide the appropriate remedy. To construe the Public Use Clause to overlap with the States' police power conflates these two categories. The "public purpose" test applied by Berman and Midkiff also cannot be applied in principled manner. "When we depart from the natural import of the term 'public use,' and substitute for the simple idea of a public possession and occupation, that of public utility, public interest, common benefit, general advantage or convenience . . . we are afloat without any certain principle to guide us." Bloodgood v. Mohawk & Hudson R. Co., 18 Wend. 9, 60-61 (NY 1837) (opinion of Tracy, Sen.). Once one permits takings for public purposes in addition to public uses, no coherent principle limits what could constitute a valid public use-at least, none beyond Justice O'Connor's (entirely proper) appeal to the text of the Constitution itself. I share the Court's skepticism about a public use standard that requires courts to second-guess the policy wisdom of public works projects. The "public purpose" standard this Court has adopted, however, demands the use of such judgment, for the Court concedes that the Public Use Clause would forbid a purely private taking. It is difficult to imagine how a court could find that a taking was purely private except by determining that the taking did not, in fact, rationally advance the public interest. The Court is therefore wrong to criticize the "actual use" test as "difficult to administer." Ante, at 479, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 451. It is far easier to analyze whether the government owns or the public has a legal right to use the taken property than to ask whether the taking has a "purely private purpose"—unless the Court means to eliminate public use scrutiny of takings entirely. Obliterating a provision of the Constitution, of course, guarantees that it will not be misapplied. For all these reasons, I would revisit our Public Use Clause cases and consider returning to the original meaning of the Public Use Clause: that the government may take property only if it actually uses or gives the public a legal right to use the property. IV 58 The consequences of today's decision are not difficult to predict, and promise to be harmful. So-called "urban renewal" programs provide some compensation for the properties they take, but no compensation is possible for the subjective value of these lands to the individuals displaced and the indignity inflicted by uprooting them from their homes. Allowing the government to take property solely for public purposes is bad enough, but extending the concept of public purpose to encompass any economically beneficial goal guarantees that these losses will fall disproportionately on poor communities. Those communities are not only systematically less likely to put their lands to the highest and best social use, but are also the least politically powerful. If ever there were justification for intrusive judicial review of constitutional provisions that protect "discrete and insular minorities," United States v. Carolene Products Co., 304 U.S. 144, 152, n. 4, 82 L. Ed. 1234, 58 S. Ct. 778 (1938), surely that principle would apply with great force to the powerless groups and individuals the Public Use Clause protects. The deferential standard this Court has adopted for the Public Use Clause is therefore deeply perverse. It encourages "those citizens with disproportionate influence and power in the political process, including large corporations and development firms," to victimize the weak. Ante, at 505, 162 L. Ed. 2d, at 468 (O'Connor, J., dissenting). Those incentives have made the legacy of this Court's "public purpose" test an unhappy one. In the 1950's, no doubt emboldened in part by the expansive understanding of "public use" this Court adopted in Berman, cities "rushed to draw plans" for downtown development. B. Frieden & L. Sagalyn, Downtown, Inc. How America Rebuilds Cities 17 (1989). "Of all the families displaced by urban renewal from 1949 through 1963, 63 percent of those whose race was known were nonwhite, and of these families, 56 percent of nonwhites and 38 percent of whites had incomes low enough to qualify for public housing, which, however, was seldom available to them." Id., at 28. Public works projects in the 1950's and 1960's destroyed predominantly minority communities in St. Paul, Minnesota, and Baltimore, Maryland. Id., at 28-29. In 1981, urban planners in Detroit, Michigan, uprooted the largely "lower-income and elderly" Poletown neighborhood for the benefit of the General Motors Corporation. J. Wylie, Poletown: Community Betrayed 58 (1989). Urban renewal projects have long been associated with the displacement of blacks; "[i]n cities across the country, urban renewal came to be known as 'Negro removal.'" Pritchett, The "Public Menace" of Blight: Urban Renewal and the Private Uses of Eminent Domain, 21 Yale L. & Pol'y Rev. 1, 47 (2003). Over 97 percent of the individuals forcibly removed from their homes by the "slum-clearance" project upheld by this Court in Berman were black. 348 U.S., at 30, 99 L. Ed. 27, 75 S. Ct. 98. Regrettably, the predictable consequence of the Court's decision will be to exacerbate these effects. *** The Court relies almost exclusively on this Court's prior cases to derive today's farreaching, and dangerous, result. But the principles this Court should employ to dispose of this case are found in the Public Use Clause itself, not in Justice Peckham's high opinion of reclamation laws. When faced with a clash of constitutional principle and a line of unreasoned cases wholly divorced from the text, history, and structure of our founding document, we should not hesitate to resolve the tension in favor of the Constitution's original meaning. For the reasons I have given, and for the reasons given in Justice O'Connor's dissent, the conflict of principle 59 raised by this boundless use of the eminent domain power should be resolved in petitioners' favor. I would reverse the judgment of the Connecticut Supreme Court. 60