D&L SCOTT 2 1 TEL 44(0)1738 A U L D H O U S E W Y N D P E R T H P H 1 1 R G 442956 FAX 44(0)1738 440275 6 September 2010 International Accounting Standards Board 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH United Kingdom Dear Sirs I write to provide comments on the Exposure Draft ED/2010/3, “Defined Benefit Plans, Proposed amendments to IAS 19”. Personal background I have been a professional trustee of occupational pension schemes in the UK for 23 years. I am current chairman of the industry-wide Railways Pension Scheme and a former DTI-appointed trustee of the Mineworkers’ Pension Scheme. I am generally opposed to the proposed amendments to IAS 19 and in particular the change from using an expected return on plan assets to applying a net interest discount rate on the net defined liabilities. Overall response to the exposure draft Not only can I not see reasons for change at this time but I would go further and say that such changes as are proposed will further distance the artificial financial accounting reporting from the reality of the legal and commercial relationships that have been developed between fiduciaries of defined benefit pension schemes and their sponsoring business employers. I live today in a world of scheme-specific pensions regulation, not one attempting uniform, one-size-fits-all which is, frankly, not fit for purpose. The logic, if indeed IASB members have any, appears to be that by invoking the relative idea of a “high quality corporate bond” this infers something objective and relevant that is somehow better than using a scheme-specific “estimate” of the scheme’s expected returns, which have been reported on by actuaries and others qualified to do so. Financial reporting includes many, many instances where judgment and/or estimates must be used. Corporate bonds are a relatively recent phenomenon, but even so it has been apparent in recent years that the mis-classification of some bonds as being of a high quality, based on rating agencies’ opinions, has been only in relative terms to other bonds, has been subject to market manipulation, varying levels of liquidity and, consequently, varying levels of volatility, with such mark-to-market accounting often bearing no stable relationship to the underlying quality, recoverability or expected cash yield of the said bonds. The proposed change in financial reporting also does not seem to grasp that many defined benefit schemes can and do achieve their expected returns over reasonable funding periods, although of course never in any one particular year, nor should that be expected. While the proposed change may be said by you to target a perceived abuse by those preparers of financial statements who Derek Scott BAcc (Hons) CA Linda M. Scott BAcc CA are considered consistently to overstate their expected returns, it would do so at the expense to those many schemes and their hard-working fiduciaries who properly attempt to reflect the expected investment return characteristics and the agreed terms of the defined benefits payment contract entered into with the employers and their employees, current and former. I believe you would do better to concentrate both the preparers of financial statements and their auditors on whether the expected returns chosen by particular companies are consistent with two levels of evidence: backward-looking in terms of historical achievements, and forward-looking in terms of prudent estimates of what should be achievable from the balance sheet date, notwithstanding general uncertainty and liquidity-based volatility in the investment markets. OTHER COMMENTS Accounting for investments within defined benefit schemes is an area that many users of financial statements seem to find difficult to understand. I would hope that, over time, users have improved their understanding of IFRS and IAS 19, in particular, and are better placed to interpret financial statements prepared in accordance with IAS 19. Given there is no single, theoretically correct answer on how to account for defined benefit plans, however, it is my view that the understandability of defined benefit plan accounting and the objectivity derived through the relevance and consistency (rather than an objectivity derived through attempted and misplaced uniformity) of accounting over time should be the prominent considerations. My greatest objection is to your proposal to eliminate the existing IAS 19 concept of the expected return on plan assets. No clear rationale is given as to why your proposed approach is suddenly more correct than the existing approach, and the disadvantages, the so-called “unintended consequences”, of making the change would appear to outweigh any advantages. Indeed, based on my reading of the IASB’s vast and extensive literature on these proposals and also after participating in the one-sided IASB webinar presentation run by some of your staff, your principal reasoning would seem to me to be to stamp out a perceived abuse by some, presumably in a minority, preparers of financial statements who intentionally overstate the expected rate of return on assets to flatter profit. While I would accept this abuse must exist to an extent, the present disclosure requirements of IAS 19 if properly applied should provide users of financial statements with the opportunity to challenge entities, even if their auditors fail to do so first, where they consider that excessive expected rates of investment return have been assumed. A net approach to measure market-derived interest rate costs is also inconsistent and downright inefficient compared with what many defined benefit schemes’ actually do with their investment strategies. Defined benefit schemes invest in assets that their fiduciaries expect to deliver sufficient quality and higher returns in order to reduce the long-term cost of the schemes which are otherwise funded inefficiently (not to mention issues of tax relief and public affordability) by employer and employee contributions. In many cases, the mark-to-market performance of these assets will not reflect anything like the more stable patterns of income and other cash flows from planned realisations to fund scheme liabilities as they fall due. These income and other cash flows can be budgeted. Market volatility, despite claims by some to the contrary, cannot even be modelled for any reasonable length of future time. That is in the realms of pseudoscience. In the context of the IFRS framework, I am informed that an appropriate distinction between profit or loss and other comprehensive income has yet to be determined. It therefore seems inappropriate to alter the presentation of elements of defined benefit cost between profit or loss and other comprehensive income until that distinction has been properly refined and agreed as part of the IASB’s ongoing work on performance reporting. I wonder from time to time why accounting standard setters do not appear to see it as being within their remit to consider the wider public interest. Accounting standards, however, should be neutral. In this case, even the IASB should acknowledge that the proposed changes are likely to further discourage the provision of higher retirement benefits by employers to employees. On your conscience be it. My responses to some of the specific questions raised in the Exposure Draft are below, although these should be viewed in the context of my overall questioning of the need to make further, partial changes to IAS 19 at this time. 1. I agree with the proposal that an entity should recognise all changes in the present value of the defined benefit obligation and in the fair or intrinsic value (which is not necessarily the same as market value) of plan assets when they occur. 2. I am content with a proposal that entities recognise unvested past service cost in the period when the related plan amendment occurs. 3. The components of defined benefit cost as defined in current version of IAS 19 are in my view appropriate. 4. I agree that any service cost component of defined benefit cost should exclude changes in the defined benefit obligation resulting from changes in demographic assumptions. 5. As previously stressed, I strongly disagree with the proposals for determining the finance cost component of defined benefit cost and consider it more appropriate to retain the existing components of expected return on assets and interest on liabilities at this time. 6. As previously explained, I believe the expected return on assets (as determined in accordance with the existing IAS 19) should remain a component of profit or loss. I am surprised to see the IASB proposal to prescribe the captions within which individual components of defined benefit cost should be presented. Generally and elsewhere in IFRS, income statement classification is usually not so prescribed. 7. I see no need to alter the accounting requirements for settlements and curtailments. Questions 8 to 12 The body of standards developed by the IASB has resulted in ridiculously lengthy financial reports that are not widely read and consequently poorly understood by investors, even by some so-called analysts. Financial reports should not be required to disclose what appears to be every piece of information from an aggregated wish list of what each user of financial reports say they would like to have. The IASB seriously needs to reconsider how it canvasses the views of users. Inevitably a user will state that he or she requires more, rather than less, information. It does not follow that significant numbers of users will actually use such information. Taken as a whole, the financial statements become far, far, too long, difficult to understand. Important information must be lost within less important information. I would urge the IASB to re-initiate concerted attempts to reduce the disclosure burden in financial statements, to make financial statements more readable and understandable. I believe any new disclosure requirements for defined benefit schemes should be developed with this in mind. At the same time, standards of auditing need to be stepped up to address perceptions of abuse in the use of expected rates of return which have no credibility by considering both backward-looking and forward-looking evidence. 14. I agree that in many situations a defined benefit multi-employer plan does not have a consistent and reliable basis for allocating the plan obligation, plan asset and cost to the individual entities participating in the plan, and it may be appropriate for individual entities to account for such a plan as a defined contribution plan. Last man standing obligations need to be understood, however, and if the allocation of obligations is not made at least the disclosures should explain the ultimate underwriter(s) within multi-employer plans. 15. I believe that any changes should be applied retrospectively. 16. For the reasons explained above, I totally disagree with the IASB’s assessment of the benefits of the proposals. While I do agree it is appropriate to eliminate some of the options in IAS 19, as with other IFRS, I do not believe that further fundamental changes are required or have been theoretically justified at this time. 17. Where I would personally take further issue is with the use of "fair value" within accounting standards. Fair values, which are typically equated to "efficient market" values, are used to justify mark-to-market accounting. IASB seems to assume that markets are "efficient" and can therefore be used to obtain "fair values" as if that is a sign of their objectivity, of their strength even as a basis of financial reporting. But if the assets I hold as a fiduciary are indeed "fairly valued" then I should probably have sold them or be selling them as they have achieved what they are most likely to achieve. I should of course to be "really efficient" then reinvest the proceeds in "undervalued" assets for future income and profit. But accounting standard setters seem blind to recognise such possibilities within their treatment of long-term monetary investments. (They seem to allow for it in the capitalisation of acquisition prices, including goodwill, for future income streams expected from subsidiaries or associate company investments, and also with other fixed assets.) I also think pension scheme fiduciaries and scheme sponsors who believe the asset allocation is the paramount consideration are playing unwittingly into the hands of accounting standard setters like IASB. Standard setters demonstrate a poor understanding of the operation of liquid markets, of the pro-cyclical nature of their measurement bias, and the real components of long-term investment returns. But such a one-dimensional analysis of a pension scheme's financial position in financial reporting by companies (and by fiduciary trustees) leads inevitably to mark-to-market measurement, placing uniformity of market prices above relevance and objectivity. By focussing mainly/exclusively on the balance sheet structure at a point in time, rather than the cash flows and realisable income generation over time, the financial reporting of pensions obligations which results is, in my view, of limited credibility and limited overall usefulness. Finally, I also think what results fails any reasonable interpretation of "a true and fair view". But of course the accounting standard setters seem to have fixed the "true and fair view" nowadays to mean something entirely different, something which merely conforms ("is in accordance") with UK or EU Accounting Standards. That approach seems to me designed to suit the professional firms who profit from auditing and related services, and who are able to limit their professional liability to an expensive form of compliance-type reporting which avoids them having to apply more in the way of judgment and forward-looking skills, at precisely the time when those judgments and skills are needed by users of financial statements. Yours faithfully Derek Scott