January 10, 2015 Dear Hunters, Recent changes to Wildlife Allocation Policy have ignited an uproar in the hunting community. I cannot tell you how excited I am about this ‐ to see hunters energized over this issue gives me great hope. It is long overdue. The policy has been flawed for decades and it’s time to get it right. I am a passionate hunter myself, born and raised with it like I am sure many of you were. My folks bought a hunting resort in 1975 in the Vanderhoof area, though for my father it was just a hobby. When I was old enough I became an outfitter and operated the resort for almost 15 years until a horse crushed my leg while on a moose retrieval and put me out of commission. I’ve since recovered from the broken leg, and I haven’t by any means given up on hunting, but I can’t outfit anymore. A sadness weighs in my heart over this because I love hunting (particularly moose hunting – oh the sweet sound of bulls grunting in the fog) and guiding gave me the opportunity to share my passion with others. In 2011 the BC Liberals introduced “the Matrix” as the solution to Wildlife Allocation. The formula was so complex and convoluted it was hard to wade through the bureaucratic lingo. Myself, I lost about 40% of my business with the Matrix. I poured my soul into the subject to find out what had happened and discovered how awful the policy was for everyone, not just me – plain and simple the Matrix was a terrible idea. I tried talking to my MLA and to bureaucrats to enact change, but I quickly discovered that because I wasn’t a member of the outfitters association GOABC I really had no influence. I tried to help create a sportsman’s organization which could better represent both outfitters and resident hunters because I strongly disagreed with the GOABC position on the subject and didn’t feel very welcome in the BCWF as an outfitter. I went to Victoria to speak with government about the issue but came away so disheartened by the lack of regard for hunters that as I was on the ferry back to the mainland I called the BC Conservative Party and asked what I could do to help stop the BC Liberals. This was my start in politics, which eventually led to me become leader of the BC Conservative Party in April 2014. Upon returning home, I wrote a report titled the Balance Allocation Plan: Solving the Wildlife Allocation Crisis in British Columbia. I called for a whole new approach to wildlife allocation which I called 70/20 +10. The concept was that residents were guaranteed 70%, outfitters 20%, and the remaining 10% was determined based on local circumstances and not decided in Victoria. Because outfitters stood to lose the most in my plan I also advocated for remedies to help alleviate losses. The Balanced Allocation Plan is mostly redundant now that the Matrix no longer exists, which was much of what I was criticizing in the report. However, the concept of 70/20 +10 still has merit. Some hunters have questioned my current motives as leader of the BC Conservative Party in criticizing the BC Liberals because I was an outfitter before I was a politician. I wrote the Balanced Allocation Plan long before I became leader of the BC Conservative Party, and you can judge my motives from its contents. My motive in criticizing the BC Liberals is because the policy is wrong, wrong, wrong. It lacks the elements I was seeking when I wrote the Balanced Allocation plan – a balanced approach that respected resident hunter priority and outfitter businesses, a policy that had regional flexibility and was not dictated by lobbyists with influence in Victoria. I have since come to the conclusion that the Balanced Allocation Plan does not go far enough, that allocation should have an additional aspect I call Targeted Allocation whereby residents and outfitters set reasonable and biologically possible targets for actual wildlife tags they would like allocated in an area, and then government takes measures to better manage wildlife in those regions to achieve those targets. This concept is intended to achieve real results, and not philosophical arguments what percentage either user group should receive. I still cringe when I think of GOABC claims that resident priority only meant 51%. I can also tell you I’ve heard hunters say outfitters should only get 5%. Both are wrong in my opinion, these are the extremes and we should all avoid them. The truth is resident hunters and outfitters need each other. For too long the two groups have been at odds, but the reality is one cannot survive without the other. I believe the worst possible thing hunters could do is to destroy the outfitting industry, the results would be catastrophic to their political influence in an era where hunting is under constant attack from the anti‐hunting lobby in Victoria. Likewise, it would be equally catastrophic for outfitters to reduce resident hunting opportunity which would reduce the number of hunters in BC ‐ an important factor in maintaining our political influence. We must work together to keep both sides strong and vibrant, we need a balanced approach to Wildlife Allocation. I invite you to contact me to talk about Wildlife Allocation, it is a subject I believe in passionately and hope that the energy and enthusiasm which has recently exploded give this issue the attention it deserves in the public media. If you share my views I invite you to join with me and the BC Conservative Party. We will champion this cause, but we need your support. Good hunting, and I truly hope to share a campfire with you one day. Your friend, Dan Brooks BC Conservative Leader The Balanced Allocation Plan Solving the Wildlife Allocation Crisis in British Columbia Daniel Brooks March 2012 Contents About the Author vii Executive Summary ix A Brief History of Allocation The Outsteader Era The Neofitter Era 1 1 2 The New Allocation Policy 4 Two Approaches to Allocation The Human Approach: Managerial Tools The Mathematical Approach: The Matrix 5 5 7 An Unbalanced Equation Problems with the Fluctuating Matrix Amendments to the policy 7 8 14 Pragmatic Examination of the Matrix 14 The Balanced Allocation Plan: Rebalancing the Equation 18 The Mathematical Formula: Fixed Range of Allocation Flexibility The Math Behind 70/20+10 20 20 The Human Formula: Managerial Tools Inevitable Loss: Remedies 24 24 Conclusion 26 Appendix A: Trumpy Report “Harvest Allocation Policy Review” 29 iii List of Tables Table 1: Maximum possible allocation loss (%) for residents and outfitters. 10 Table 2: Changes in allocation caused by implementation of the Matrix. 14 Table 3: Actual changes to moose quota in two areas: Pre-Matrix, amended Matrix, unamended Matrix. 17 Table 4: Capture and maximum loss rates for various minimum share values and ranges of flexibility. 21 Table 5: Resident allocations that are forcibly reduced compared to pre-Matrix allocations. 22 Table 6: Outfitter allocations that are forcibly reduced compared to pre-Matrix allocations. 22 v About the Author Daniel Brooks is a second-generation outfitter whose family has guided in British Columbia since 1975. He began guiding in 1994 and took over Crystal Lake Resort from his father in 1999. He is a licensed outfitter, trapper, and resident hunter. He has been involved extensively in land-use planning through the Land and Resource Management Plan (LRMP) and the Public Advisory Group (PAG). He founded and has chaired the Upper Nechako Wilderness Council (UNWC) since 2005, a coalition of tourism operators in Vanderhoof dedicated to tourism resource planning and marketing. He has a BA (Hon.) in Classical Studies from the University of Waterloo. vii Executive Summary The implementation of the new wildlife allocation policy has created a crisis in the outfitting industry. The complex history of outfitting has led to inconsistent allocations across British Columbia. Forcing a one-size-fits-all policy on this diverse industry is proving catastrophic. The lack of flexibility in the new matrix calculations and the removal of managerial tools have unbalanced the equation of allocation and turned it into a rigid mathematical formula—a formula that is fundamentally flawed. There is no single mathematical model that can be unilaterally applied. The policy must be replaced. The Balanced Allocation Plan described herein addresses the problems with the existing allocation policy. Its core proposal is a Fixed Range of Allocation Flexibility between 70–80% for residents and 20–30% for outfitters for all species province wide (notated as 70/20+10). Within that range of flexibility, regional managers will be able to adjust allocation based on transparent managerial tools. Unfortunately, outfitter losses are inevitable. We can’t go back to the previous allocation policy, but the new one is also untenable. Regional managers will require the authority and tools necessary to address these immediate losses. For resident hunters, the biggest concern is hunting opportunity and the perception that outfitters are depriving them of it. The reality is that allocation policy is the wrong tool for improving hunting opportunity. Because residents already enjoy a greater share of the allocation, any such gains will always be marginal and at the expense of outfitters. The key to increasing resident hunter opportunity is increasing the Annual Allowable Harvest (AAH). The Balanced Allocation Plan addresses all the reasons government rightly decided to review allocation policy in the first place and frees us to focus on the real issue of better wildlife management and growing the AAH. ix A Brief History of Allocation Allocation is the process that divides available wildlife harvest between outfitters (quota) and resident hunters (LEH—Limited Entry Hunting). Technically, this allocation process has existed since the first LEH and quota systems were implemented, though it is doubtful that any initial consideration was actually given to dividing percentages of wildlife between the two user groups; it is more likely that allocation was based on whether a population could sustain levels of harvest requested by hunters or outfitters. Each region in BC has a different allocation history, and within each region, each territory has a different allocation story. The history of allocation across the province is incredibly diverse; this is the main reason why allocation policy has not been an easy matter to resolve. In general, though, outfitting in BC has passed through two different eras of progress, which are labelled here as the Outsteader Era and the Neofitter Era. Each region in BC has a different allocation story The Outsteader Era Much like the early homesteaders that colonized and expanded the farmland of BC, outfitting was once a type of homesteading that went through a similar process of expansion. During this Outsteader Era, starting as early as the 1880s and continuing until the 1970s, an outfitter would explore a potential hunting area, apply to government for tenure on the land, develop and improve the area for outfitting, and then raise their family on this land. Incredible works of infrastructure were built to accommodate these outfitting businesses, including lodges and cabins, roads and bridges, airstrips and docks, fences and corrals, and trail networks and corridors. These accomplishments are all that more incredible when you consider the remote and rugged situation of the outfitters that built them. Today, many of the wilderness lodges and resorts were built during this Outsteader Era by the initiative of these early outfitters. Over time, some of these lodges have been sold, separated from their hunting quota, and turned into different tourism businesses, but they exist in the first place because of the outfitting industry. Because of this, many outfitters feel strongly that outfitting is the father of tourism in BC, and their contribution to the tourism industry is often taken for granted. This is relevant to the matter at hand because it demonstrates how government, through the allocation of areas and quota to outfitters, was able to promote and grow the outfitting industry that created the backbone for modern tourism in BC, which is Like homesteaders, early outfitters would explore a potential hunting area, apply to government for tenure, then develop and improve the area for outfitting. This process of allocation promoted strong growth in the outfitting industry. 1 Allocations were decided on an outfitter-by-outfitter basis in a one-on-one process between outfitter and regional manager. currently the largest industry in the province. It also explains why the previous allocation policy existed as it did. A potential outfitter would approach the government, tell them they wanted to start an outfitting business, draw the boundary on a map, tell them how much quota they needed to support their business, and they were issued a certificate and given a license. This may perhaps be oversimplifying the process somewhat, but the point is that allocations were decided on an outfitter-by-outfitter basis in a one-on-one process between them and the government representative (the regional manager), driven by the business needs of the outfitter. There was no formal allocation policy. Regional managers had great leeway in making these decisions, and there was a certain amount of arbitrariness in the process. Regional managers did, however, rely on a number of guidelines and tools when making these decisions, including: ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ The unfortunate result was an opaque process and inconsistent allocations. Inflating allocation based on success factors Shifting vacant area allocations Shifting unused quota from one outfitter to another Remote area multipliers & hunting pressure factors Business model needs Historical precedent These methods of arriving at territory boundaries and quotas led to tremendous growth in the outfitting industry and the eventual triumph of tourism in BC. As the land base across the province began to fill with outfitting territories, however, the number of new territories dwindled, and the Outsteader Era came to a close. By the 1980s, the allocation decisions made in this era (the status quo) were simply adopted as policy. This resulted in an opaque and inconsistent process. The Neofitter Era Today, the outfitting industry is largely composed of second- and third-generation outfitters. 2 Beginning in the 1980s, accelerating in the 1990s, and continuing until today, a new generation of outfitters evolved. The Outsteader Era was the epoch of the family outfitting business, but the Neofitter Era was the next generation of outfitters that either inherited their outfitting territories from the blood, sweat, and tears of their parents or purchased their territories as a business. Today, the outfitting industry comprises a mixture of second- and third-generation families and corporate businesses. During this era, the rise and triumph of the forestry industry in BC had a dramatic impact on the outfitting industry. Many outfitting businesses that had built and invested heavily in outfitting infrastructure were swept aside by the logging hegemony. The dramatic increase in forestry road construction penetrated wilderness areas sacrosanct to outfitters. There were two main problems created for the outfitting industry during this time: the loss of operating land base, and the increasing conflict with resident hunters. Most outfitting businesses had been originally created in remote areas of BC, far away from roads and trains and towns. As the forest industry swallowed up an increasingly larger portion of the province, the remote areas available to outfitters to hunt were reduced further and further. Because of the loss of workable land, some outfitters were unable to maintain their businesses and sold their quota to neighbouring outfitters and their lodges to new tourism businesses. In other circumstances, outfitters vehemently insisted consideration be given them in land-use planning, and efforts were made to control access on forest roads to protect outfitter livelihoods. And in still other cases, outfitters adapted to the new reality and joined the resident hunters on the roads to compete for wildlife harvest directly. The expansion of the logging industry was the nemesis of outfitters, as they continually lost the operating land base necessary to maintain their businesses. This remains the case today, particularly after dramatic increases in harvest levels and road construction in reaction to the mountain pine beetle. With the increase in road construction came the increase in conflict with resident hunters. Prior to this time, outfitters enjoyed relative isolation where few if any resident hunters dared to tread. But the roads brought resident hunters, and to outfitting families and businesses that had built their livelihoods on their isolation from hunters, these roads were a threat. Outfitters and resident hunters very quickly came into direct conflict as roads pushed further and further into hunting territories previously inaccessible. Given their investment in the land base, outfitters were protective of their infrastructure and fought to protect their livelihoods and infrastructure investments. At the same time, resident hunters fought to gain access to what they viewed as miniature outfitting kingdoms. This conflict continues even today, and the focus of this conflict is access management. However, the conflict over access to land also creates a conflict over access to animals— the two being inseparably connected. Resident hunters resented what they felt were outfitters controlling public lands, and that resentment spilled over against non-resident hunters for harvesting animals that many resident hunters felt belonged to them. And this is the principal argument in the conflict between outfitters and resident hunters over allocation. The growth of the forestry industry posed a problem as it allowed access to wilderness areas sacrosanct to outfitters. Outfitters are understandably protective of their investments in infrastructure. Resident hunters resent the perceived control over public land by outfitters and begrudge any quota taken from them. 3 The New Allocation Policy The previous allocation policy was fraught with inconsistencies and difficulties. There were legitimate reasons to review the policy. The review of the allocation policy began in late 2003, early 2004. Most outfitters believe that the review was a direct result of the lobbying by anti-outfitter forces in the BC Wildlife Federation (BCWF). However, it is also clear that the hodge podge of status quo allocation from the Outsteader Era was fraught with inconsistencies and difficulties; there was a legitimate need to review the policy. Reasons given for the review according to the Ministry website were the need for: ▶▶ “a consistent and transparent approach for making allocation decisions across the province” ▶▶ “a decision-making process that was more objective, databased, and amicable” ▶▶ “allocation outcomes that are more achievable, efficient, and reflective of stakeholders’ interests” The review process quickly resembled a negotiation, with government acting as mediator between resident hunter and outfitter organizations. 4 The government stated that its “decisions had been made through long, and sometimes heated, negotiations amongst staff and stakeholders.” It isn’t difficult to see from these reasons that resident hunter and outfitter conflict, or “heated negotiations,” was a primary reason to review the policy. But conversely it isn’t difficult to see that the status quo wasn’t “consistent and transparent” and needed to be reviewed. The review of the allocation policy involved four primary stakeholders: the BCWF—who purported to represent the resident hunters; Guide Outfitter Association of BC (GOABC)—claiming to represent outfitters; BC Trappers Association (BCTA)— representing trappers; and of course the government. The review quickly took on the role of a negotiation, with government acting as mediator between the BCWF and GOABC. Opinions of this negotiation are controversial at best and conspiratorial at worst. But whatever the process was, a new policy was created in 2007. Implementation was to take place over the next allocation period from 2007–2011 with full implementation in 2012. It became immediately apparent with even just partial implementation that the outfitting industry was going to be seriously and negatively affected. Under pressure from GOABC, government contracted with Chris Trumpy to review the policy and provide recommendations. Trumpy’s report, released in 2011, contained eleven recommendations that resulted in further amendments to the policy. (Trumpy’s report is discussed in detail in the appendix.) The policy with amendments was implemented in early 2012. Currently, given the crisis created by the policy, a one-year quota has been issued for 2012 while government seeks to address outfitter concerns. Two Approaches to Allocation The allocation review resulted in a dramatically different policy from what had existed previously. The previous allocation was based on what can be called the human approach: i.e., managerial tools that look at each circumstance and allow for individualized solutions. The new allocation policy removes the human factor altogether and is based on what can be called the mathematical approach: i.e., the Matrix. The pendulum has swung, and whereas too much emphasis on the human approach resulted in arbitrary and inconsistent allocations, too much emphasis on the mathematical approach results in an allocation that is too rigid and unresponsive to regional differences. Just as too much emphasis on the “human approach” made the previous policy arbitrary and inconsistent, the exclusive focus on the “mathematical approach” results in the current policy (the Matrix) being too rigid and unresponsive to regional differences. The Human Approach: Managerial Tools The human formula was controlled for the most part by the regional manager who balanced the needs of resident hunters and outfitters to arrive at what he felt was the best policy for both sides. The importance of this human formula is greatly diminished under the new policy. Not a single one of the previous managerial tools continues to exist in its original form, and some cease to exist entirely. Inflating allocation based on success factors—Regional managers very often would give an area a larger allocation than the Annual Allowable Harvest (AAH) would support based on outfitter and resident hunter success rate in a given species. This made it easier to reach the AAH targets. These were applied to both outfitters and residents. This allowed outfitters to take greater numbers of hunters. The assumption was that only a percentage of hunters would be successful, and the resulting harvest would be closer to what the regional manager expected. It is important to note that this was never expressly documented as part of an outfitter’s certificate or license prior to the new policy, because success was calculated regionally. Many outfitters built businesses on harvesting 100% while others harvested much less. Under the new policy, administrative guidelines now allow a guide to harvest 30% of a 5-year quota in one year. This allows an outfitter to take approximately 50% more hunters in one year than they have quota without exceeding their harvest. If they harvested greater than 20% of their 5 year quota in one year, they Inflating allocations based on success rates made it easier to reach AAH targets. Administrative guidelines allow an outfitter to harvest 30% of a 5-year quota in a single year, allowing an outfitter to sell more hunts while at the same time managing a clearly understood and sustainable quota. 5 The practice of shifting allocations from vacant areas allowed outfitters to maintain their businesses, with minimal impact on resident hunters. This practice is done away with under the new policy. Allowing the shifting of allocation between outfitters was another way to help outfitters grow their businesses. This practice is now a temporary measure. Taking into account an area’s remoteness and hunting pressure is another valuable practice removed under the new policy. Regional managers no longer have the discretion to tweak individual allocations. The new policy has almost completely removed the human component of wildlife allocation. 6 would have to reduce their harvest later in the 5 year allocation period to adjust for it. Shifting vacant area allocations—Quota from vacant territories was assigned to adjacent outfitters, even though they had no claim to those areas. In some regions, certain areas were deliberately left vacant to allow resident hunters opportunity to hunt without competition from an outfitter. This was done with the expectation that outfitters in these regions would receive the allocation from the vacant area. This practice ceases to exist entirely under the new policy, and all allocation from vacant areas is given to resident hunters. Under the new policy, the allocation is area based, meaning your allocation is determined by the size of your territory and cannot include vacant areas. Shifting unused quota from one outfitter to another—This was done on a one-on-one basis where an outfitter could approach the regional manager and make a case for increasing their quota because another outfitter was not using theirs. These decisions were driven by business needs, and often led to large areas with small quota and small areas with large quota. The new policy does away with this practice and all allocations are based on area. However, quota may be shifted to another outfitter on a temporary basis with the agreement of both outfitters and the regional manager. Remote area multipliers & hunting pressure factors—In remote areas of the province, where resident hunting pressure was small or non-existent, regional managers could allocate larger percentages of the harvest to outfitters who, due to their infrastructure and hunting methods, could more easily access these game animals. These practices cease to exist under the new policy. Business model needs—Outfitters who built or expanded their hunting territories could approach the regional manager and request greater quotas so they could grow their businesses. Regional managers had the discretion to make agreements, formal or otherwise, to increase an outfitter’s quota to meet his ascribed business needs. This practice ceases to exist under the new policy. Historical precedent—Most allocations were inherited from the Outsteader Era. Managers in many cases took a hands-off approach and did not change allocations unless there were biological reasons to do so. Under the new allocation policy, the human approach has been almost entirely removed, and the mathematical approach has replaced it—the Matrix. The Mathematical Approach: The Matrix The Matrix introduced the concept of fluctuating allocations based on two key principles: utilization—the number of animals actually harvested; and importance—resident hunting demand/ outfitter hunt values. If residents or outfitters have greater utilization or importance than the other, the allocation then changes to reflect the degree of difference from the baseline of a 75/25 split. Residents and outfitters have certain guaranteed minimums: ▶▶ R esidents are guaranteed 60% for allocated sheep, goat, and grizzly bear hunts; 98% for allocated antlerless hunts; and 70% for all other species. ▶▶ Outfitters are guaranteed 20% for sheep, goat, and grizzly; and 10% for all other species (except antlerless). The Matrix introduces fluctuating allocations based on two key principles: “utilization” and “importance.” The baseline of the Matrix is a 75/25 split between residents and hunters respectively, with certain guaranteed minimums. The Matrix can be broken down into the following formula: Allocation = 75% + (2 × (RI-OI)) + (2 × (RU-OU)) ▶▶ R I = Resident Importance—A number from 1 to 10 (10 being the most important) based on the number of successful LEH applicants who purchased a species license. ▶▶ OI = Outfitter Importance—Also a number from 1 to 10 (10 being the most important) based on the total economic contribution of an allocated species in a region, calculated using the number of hunters and the hunt price. ▶▶ RU = Resident Utilization—A number from 1 to 4 representing the actual harvest compared to allocation (4 being 75–100% of actual harvest). ▶▶ OU = Outfitter Utilization—Also a number from 1 to 4 representing the actual harvest compared to allocation (4 being 75–100% of actual harvest). An Unbalanced Equation The allocation process has perhaps never been “balanced” per se. In the past, it was too easily manipulated by regional managers. Simply replacing them with a mathematical matrix does not balance the allocation process either. On the contrary, the process has now become encumbered with the inflexible rules of algebra. And so the allocation has gone from being too flexible to being too inflexible. Whereas on the one hand residents previously felt cheated by the outfitter influence on the allocation process, now The allocation process has gone from being too flexible to being too inflexible. A more balanced approach is called for. 7 outfitters feel cheated by the mathematical inflexibility of the new policy. And so the conflict between outfitters and resident hunters continues with increased ferocity and without resolution. The Matrix also makes the Environmental Appeal Board irrelevant to the allocation process. If an outfitter has a problem with their allocation, on what grounds can they appeal? The fundamental laws of mathematics are not at issue, and the Board doesn’t have the authority to change the policy itself. Problems with the Fluctuating Matrix The Matrix is fundamentally flawed and is an unfair tool to allocate wildlife harvest. Whoever developed the allocation matrix deserves credit for an elegant idea, but the Matrix is fundamentally flawed, and by its very mathematical nature it is an unfair tool to allocate wildlife harvest. The mathematical flaw begins with the baseline. The baseline from which to begin the allocation calculation is 75/25. For each point of difference between the RI and OI or RU and OU the Matrix moves by 2 percentage points. Example 1: RI = 8, OI = 7, RU = 4, and OU = 2. The difference between RI and OI is 1, and the difference between RU and OU is 2, for a total of 3. This moves the Matrix 3 × 2% = +6% from the baseline. 75% + 6% = 81% for an allocation of 81% to residents and 19% to outfitters. Example 2 (the inverse of example 1): RI = 7, OI = 8, RU = 2, and OU = 4. The difference between RI and OI is -1, and the difference between RU and OU is -2, for a total of -3. This moves the Matrix -3 × 2% = -6% from the baseline. 75% - 6% = 69% for an allocation of 69% to residents and 31% to outfitters. Because of the baseline, outfitter allocation will always be three times more volatile than resident allocation. While this appears to be a fair calculation, it is actually heavily weighted against the outfitters. In terms of real effects, a 2% change in the Matrix for residents only means a 2.67% change in allocation because they start with the larger baseline assumption of 75%. But to outfitters, starting at 25%, a 2% change in the Matrix means an 8% change in allocation. In fact, the outfitter allocation will always be three times more volatile than the resident allocation. Example: There are 100 tags to be allotted. The allocation is determined to be 81/19, a +6% move off the baseline of 75/25. Residents receive 81 tags and outfitters receive 19 tags. To resi- 8 dent hunters, going from 75 tags to 81 tags is an 8% increase. To an outfitter, going from 25 tags to 19 tags is a 24% loss. While real hunting opportunities for residents will only ever see a marginal increase or decrease, outfitters face extreme volatility. It is impossible to rectify this problem in the Matrix unless the baseline is moved to 50/50. So long as outfitters have the smaller share, the Matrix will always produce an unfair allocation to outfitters. All things being considered, moving the Matrix to a 50/50 baseline is out of the question, so the Matrix is permanently flawed by where it begins. The next obvious flaw in the Matrix is the inequality of the minimum share values. Real hunting opportunities for residents will only ever see a marginal change, whereas outfitters face extreme volatility. Another flaw in the Matrix is the inequality of the minimum share values. ▶▶ R esidents are guaranteed 60% for allocated sheep, goat, and grizzly bear hunts; 98% for allocated antlerless hunts; and 70% for all other species . ▶▶ Outfitters are guaranteed 20% for sheep, goat, and grizzly; and 10% for all other species (except antlerless). The most astonishing part of the minimum shares is the 98% antlerless for residents. In this case, the minimum share value will always be enacted, because the OI and OU would have to be at the maximum matrix deviation of 24% (resulting in a 99/1 allocation) in order for residents to get more than the 98% minimum shares. This is clearly not a fair allocation process for outfitters. It should be noted that there are only two regions of BC which have antlerless on allocation: Region 7A cow moose, and Region 7B antlerless elk. Why this minimum share value exists at such a level is not explained in the policy, but clearly fairness to outfitters was not considered. Minimum shares have an additional negative effect on the Matrix. In the process of calculating importance, each of the 36 allocated species in BC is assigned a number from 1 to 10 based on their percentile within the total guided hunt value. The two antlerless categories both score an 8 for importance, even though they cannot possibly benefit from these scores because the minimum share value will always be assigned. Therefore, including the antlerless in the Matrix deflates the importance values of the remaining species, hurting outfitters a second time. In the most recent allocation, minimum share values were invoked to protect resident hunter allocations five times and only once for outfitters (and the one for outfitters only applied because of the temporary “10 percent rule” amendment). Including the antlerless in the Matrix deflates the importance values of the remaining species, hurting outfitters a second time. 9 Why should one species be guaranteed more than another? The Matrix is clearly not balanced when deviation from the baseline can only go 5% one way but 15% the other. Giving different minimum shares to different species makes it even more difficult to view the Matrix as fair. Why should one species be guaranteed more than another? Again, this is not explained in the policy but appears to have been a negotiated point. Combining minimum share values with the unequal Matrix baseline causes even larger problems to emerge. The maximum deviation off the baseline shifts unequally. In the case of sheep, goat, and grizzly, the most residents can gain off the baseline is 5%, going from 75% to 80%, because the outfitter minimum is 20%. But at the same time they can lose 15%, going from 75% to 60%, because their minimum for sheep goat and grizzly is 60%. The inverse applies to outfitters for the other species; they can only gain 5% for moose, elk, and caribou, but can lose 15%. The math is clearly not balanced when deviation from the baseline can only go 5% one way but 15% the other. This may appear to be some sort of equal trade off, with one Table 1: Maximum possible allocation loss (%) for residents and outfitters. Resident Min Share Sheep, Goat, Grizzly 60 Moose, Elk, Caribou 70 Outfitter Min Share 20 10 Resident Max % Loss 25 22 Outfitter Max % Loss 50 67 species possibly going up 5% and down 15% and the other going up 15% and down 5%, but the problem for outfitters is that not all species are available to all outfitters. If an outfitter doesn’t have sheep, goat, or grizzly (which many outfitters don’t) then the trade-off is not fair to them. This sort of trade-off only serves outfitters with sheep, goat, and grizzly allocations. This results in preferential treatment of some outfitters over others rather than a clear and transparent rationale that is fair to all outfitters alike. Using relative importance as a variable in the Matrix formula creates class distinctions among outfitters and diminishes the importance of local species to local outfitters. Relative importance for outfitters is calculated by taking the hunt value for a particular species and multiplying it by the average number of hunters per year. The result is the total hunt value per species per region. Each allocated species for each region is then ranked from 1 to 10 based on what percentile the total hunt value for each species in each region falls into. The end result of this process is a relative importance number used to rank outfitters. 10 Example 1 (taken directly from the Matrix): Bull Moose in region 7A—Hunt Value = $8300, Average # hunters = 493.25, Hunt Value = $8300 × 493.25 = $4,093,975. This falls into the top 10% of hunt values and is therefore given a relative importance of 10. Example 2 (taken directly from the Matrix): Bull Moose in region 4—Hunt Value = $7000, Average # hunters = 58.5, Hunt Value = $7000 × 58.5 = $409,500. This falls into the 60–70 percentile of hunt values and is therefore given a relative importance of 7. This method of calculating importance ignores some key components. First, outfitters have defined boundaries. If those boundaries do not include a species ranked at a 10, there is nothing the outfitter can do to change that. Second, each species on allocation to an outfitter is most important to that outfitter: i.e., if an outfitter only has moose quota, then moose have an importance of 10 to that outfitter. Because outfitters cannot guide anywhere except their defined territory boundaries, placing the importance of one outfitter in one region as greater or less than another outfitter in another region is unfair. Even if the calculation were done on a regional basis, it would still result in unfair outcomes since, within regions, not all species are available to all outfitters. The result is that many species with high rankings are unavailable to most other outfitters, and in some cases entire regions don’t have a single species ranked greater than a 6. Why should these outfitters be penalized? To them, those species are of critical importance to the success of their businesses. If all outfitters could guide in all areas of BC, then using this method of calculating relative importance might be tenable, but this is not the case (nor should it be). In addition, fluctuating the Matrix based on importance gives distinct Matrix advantages to those outfitters in BC who rank higher, thus creating a vicious cycle of loss. Because the hunt value is calculated using the average number of hunters, and the average number of hunters is determined by the possible allocation to an outfitter, those outfitters with higher relative importance will continue to receive higher numbers of hunters than those with lower rankings. The result is that lower ranked outfitters receive less allocation, so they cannot take as many hunters as they did previously. Their total hunt value will continue to decrease and they can never recover importance rankings: the vicious cycle of loss. On the other hand, outfitters with greater rankings will continue to receive higher relative importance rankings because they If an outfitter only has moose quota, then moose have an importance of 10 to that outfitter. Because outfitters cannot guide anywhere except their defined territory boundaries, this method of calculating “importance” is unfair. 11 Ultimately, this system ranks outfitters, not regions or species, and thus creates class distinctions. The result of categorized importance rankings is class distinctions between have and have-not outfitters. “Utilization” penalizes one outfitter for the lack of performance of another, and it promotes dubious wildlife management practices. “Utilization” creates a “use it or lose it” philosophy and encourages harvesting without regard to biology and wildlife management. 12 maintain or improve their hunter numbers, which increases their percentage of allocation, which increases hunter numbers, and thereby increases relative importance for species those outfitters have. The end results of all this ranking from region to region and species to species is not that regions or species are ranked so much as each outfitter is ranked, and this creates class distinctions. Essentially outfitters are ranked on their economic contribution, and those with lower rankings are deemed less important than those with higher rankings. This method is extremely unfair to the individual outfitter and marginalizes outfitters ranked lower. Telling one business they cannot sell as much as another business because the other business contributes more economically moves the market towards monopolization. It shifts available product from lower ranked businesses to higher ranked ones. The result of categorized importance rankings is an unequal distribution of product, wealth, and influence, creating class distinctions between have and have-not outfitters. Such disparity is appalling and not in the best interest of the outfitting industry as a whole. Using utilization to calculate allocation is also fraught with problems. Utilization is another variable that penalizes one outfitter for the lack of performance of another, and it promotes dubious wildlife management practices for both residents and outfitters. Utilization is calculated based on the number of animals harvested in a region. For residents, the lack of utilization is muted because of the number of hunters; if one fails to perform, the loss in utilization is marginal. But for outfitters, of which there are fewer, and one outfitter has many tags, if an outfitter fails to harvest their quota, all outfitters in the region could see a Matrix loss and a resulting loss in quota allocation. The utilization of one outfitter affects the entire region, and other outfitters are punished by circumstances beyond their control. The concept behind utilization is to transfer allocation from either residents or outfitters to the other because they aren’t using it and the other group possibly could. This creates a “use it or lose it” philosophy and encourages harvesting without regard to biology and wildlife management. Utilization puts pressure on outfitters and residents alike to harvest at unsustainable levels simply to maintain future opportunity. Such a utilization policy reduces the incentive for outfitters and residents to make harvest decisions based on ecological responsibility. It encourages outfitting businesses to put their immediate financial well-being ahead of ecological viability, and it also encourages resident hunters to put their immediate hunting opportunities ahead of longer term ecological considerations. This is particularly true of species like goat and grizzly bear where the harvest of females is possible but not preferable from an ecological stand point. Both resident hunters and outfitters will be under greater pressure to harvest females to maintain utilization in the Matrix rather than face the possibility of opportunity or business losses resulting from under-utilization. This is also true of quality game management. Under a utilization regime, there is no incentive to allow animals to reach a greater age class—quite the opposite. Mitigating this problem would require a much larger financial commitment from government in the area of wildlife management. As the incentive to hunters for ecological conservation decreases through utilization, the responsibility for government to more closely manage wildlife increases. While in the past many outfitters and resident hunters would refrain from harvesting if they perceived a problem with populations or quality, outfitters and resident hunters are now penalized for such a failure to harvest. In order to prevent the ecological problems associated with “use it or lose it,” the responsibility falls on government to exercise greater diligence in wildlife management through more frequent inventories and increased regulation. The majority of sportsmen and outfitters strongly support responsible and sustainable wildlife management, but utilization undermines these principles and encourages a culture of killing, not a culture of conservation. Utilization is strongly tied to economics. If outfitters cannot sell hunts due to an economic downturn, utilization naturally decreases. The outfitter is then penalized with a loss of allocation, which means they no longer have a product to sell when the economy finally rebounds. But utilization also produces volatile results in the Matrix. Assuming outfitters don’t use their entire allocation, they would lose allocation, and the resulting allocation would be closer to the actual harvest rate. But when harvest rates and allocation come closer together, utilization goes up, and the allocation would increase in the next allocation period. This creates a bounce and spike effect where utilization never actually stabilizes at a consistent harvest level. This volatility is problematic. Utilization also ignores infrastructure issues. Harvesting more animals generally requires more infrastructure (more hunters requires more cabins, ATVs, boats, and guides). If the outfitter doesn’t have the cash to invest in new infrastructure, the increased allocation will go under-utilized. The overall effects of using a fluctuating matrix based on utilization and importance and bounded by minimum shares is industry volatility, business uncertainty, and barriers to investment and industry growth. It creates a great deal of instability in the Because “utilization” reduces the incentive for hunters to harvest responsibly, the government’s role in wildlife management must increase. The principle of “utilization” encourages a culture of killing, not a culture of conservation. “Utilization” also creates a bounce and spike effect in allocations and never stabilizes at a consistent harvest level, creating problematic volatility for outfitters. 13 The Matrix is inflexible from a managerial point of view and extremely volatile from a mathematical point of view, rendering the policy untenable. outfitting industry. So while the Matrix is inflexible from a managerial point of view, it is also extremely volatile from a mathematical point of view. The idea may have been well intentioned and good, but it is so profoundly flawed that its failure is inevitable. For outfitters, resident hunters, and the wildlife affected by these policies, it is far better to admit failure and begin again than to attempt to force a flawed policy to work. The fluctuating matrix must be eliminated and replaced. Amendments to the policy There have been several amendments made to try to mitigate and address deficiencies in this policy. These amendments include: ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ 20% hardship rule (2007–2011) 30% hardship rule (2012 only) 10% cap on change to outfitters matrix allocation Thinhorn sheep removed from matrix Dampening utilization from 1–10 to 1–4 Quota variance principle None of these amendments succeed to address the fundamental problems with the Matrix itself and the removal of managerial tools. Pragmatic Examination of the Matrix The current allocation policy has created a crisis in the outfitting industry, as the following table shows. Table 2: Changes in allocation caused by implementation of the Matrix. Region 1 1 1 2 3 3 3 3 14 Species Grizzly Bear Elk (bull) Elk (archery) Elk (bull) Grizzly Bear Moose (bull) Goat Bighorn Sheep Outfitter Allocation Pre-Matrix Matrix 53 31 10 17 50 17 20 19 10 25 5 11 26 29 30 23 % Change -42 70 -66 -5 150 120 12 -23 Region 4 4 4 4 5 5 5 5 6North 6North 6North 6North 6North 6South 6South 6South 7A 7A 7A 7B 7B 7B 7B 7B 7B 8 8 8 8 Species Grizzly Bear Moose (bull) Goat Bighorn Sheep Grizzly Bear Caribou (bull) Moose (bull) Goat Moose (bull) Caribou (bull) Goat Thinhorn Sheep (dall) Grizzly Bear Moose (bull) Goat Grizzly Bear Grizzly Bear Moose (bull) Moose (cow) Grizzly Bear Thinhorn Sheep Elk (antlerless) Elk (either sex) Bison Goat Grizzly Bear Moose (bull) Goat Bighorn Sheep Outfitter Allocation Pre-Matrix Matrix 30 27 29 19 26 31 25 33 38 21 20 29 22 23 43 27 na 30 47 25 37 35 40 21 % Change -10 -34 19 32 -45 45 5 -37 na -47 -5 -48 50 19 25 50 50 15 22 50 23 10 na 20 25 na 19 39 35 -34 32 16 -38 -30 53 -91 -46 na -80 na 15 -8 na 0 -36 -17 33 25 29 31 35 23 2 27 na 2 22 23 23 25 19 25 29 As you can see, the volatility is significant. For outfitters, 20 of 36 species are reduced (15 of those are reduced by more than 20%). Only 1 remains static, leaving a gain in 12 species, 7 of which are more than 20%. These data, however, don’t capture additional losses created by the removal of the managerial tools, which can only be determined on an outfitter-by-outfitter basis. Let’s examine Region 4, for example. The Matrix shows a 19% increase in goat allocation and a 32% increase in big horn sheep allocation. However, after taking into consideration the loss of The Matrix does not capture additional losses created by the removal of the managerial tools. The full extent of the damage can only be determined on an outfitter-byoutfitter basis. 15 This example shows how while the Matrix shows the allocation for a particular outfitter increasing, the removal of managerial tools results in a dramatic decrease in quota. 16 managerial tools, here are the actual numbers. The goat allocation actually went from 502 to 264, a 47% loss. The sheep allocation likewise went from 147 to 68, a 54% loss. Moose and grizzly also suffered greater losses than the Matrix alone predicted. Moose went from 342 to 199, a 42% loss instead of the 34% the Matrix calculated. Grizzly allocation went from 184 to 42, a 77% loss, a far cry from the 10% loss calculated by the Matrix. Clearly the Matrix alone does not tell the whole story, and managerial tools are a significant part of the process. The removal of managerial tools does not affect all outfitters within a region equally. Some are affected positively, whereas others negatively. Understanding how the Matrix and loss of managerial tools affects allocation is best described by an example. The following describes an outfitter from region 7A. Prior to 2007, the allocation was 85/15 for the region. Outfitters and residents both had access to immature bulls in a general open season (GOS). Resident allocation included a 50% inflation due to success factors and outfitters had a 65% success factor inflation. In this example, one outfitter had two territories. The allocation for these territories had been set many decades earlier based primarily on business needs. The outfitter had one territory (Area A) with 10 bull moose tags and 4 cow moose tags on a territory about 80,000 ha. He had also recently purchased a second territory (Area B) about 160,000 ha with 8 bull moose and 2 cow moose tags. Between the two areas, the outfitter was harvesting an average of 17 bulls per year (including immature on GOS), and 3 cows, with the majority coming from Area A because of the infrastructure. In 2007, the new allocation policy was partially implemented. Allocations were changed to an area-based calculation, outfitters were no longer allowed to harvest immature bulls under GOS (residents retained the immature GOS), and a new allocation of 82/18 from the Matrix was implemented. This allocation kept the success factor inflations. See Table 3 for the changes to the outfitter’s actual quota. Area A saw a decrease in bull moose quota of about 14% and a decrease of 25% in cow moose. Area B saw an increase of 115% for bulls and 67% for cows. The primary reason for the large change was the shift to area-based allocation, because Area A was half the size of Area B but had the larger quota. It should also be remembered that the GOS for immature bulls was lost during this time as well, which accounted for 2 or 3 bulls harvested each year as well. Cow quota would have been reduced much further (to 2%) except a 20% hardship rule was temporarily enacted to prevent the total collapse of antlerless quota for this outfitter. The change in allocation was problematic, although it appears to be beneficial overall. Area A had the majority of infrastructure, while Area B had the majority of quota. The loss of allocation and immature bull GOS for Area A was a problem for this outfitter, and while the allocation increase for Area B was welcomed, the outfitter was never able to capitalize on this, lacking the ability to invest more money into infrastructure in that area. The end result was under-utilization: the outfitter harvested 100% of the quota in Area A, while only harvesting about 60% of the quota in Area B. This under-utilization later contributed to a regional utilization of 3 on the Matrix. Table 3: Actual changes to moose quota in two areas: Pre-Matrix, amended Matrix, unamended Matrix. Area A Pre-2007 Bulls Allocation % 15 Quota 10 Cows Allocation % 22 Quota 4 2007–11 18 8.6 2 3* 2012–16 20 6.4 2 0.2 Area B Pre-2007 15 8 22 3 2007–11 18 17.2 2 5* 2012–16 20 12.6 2 0.4 * The quota did not drop as much as it should have because of a temporary hardship rule. In 2012, the Matrix produced an allocation of 77/23 (outfitters lost 2% because of under-utilization). The 10% rule amendment, however, meant the allocation could only increase by 10% of 18% = 1.8%. So, rounded up, the allocation was actually set to 80/20. Inflation due to success factors was also taken out of the equation. With the expiration of the 20% “hardship rule,” the minimum shares allocation of 98/2 was applied to the antlerless cows. The following table demonstrates the flow of quota over the three time periods. Apart from the catastrophic loss of cow allocation, from the point of view of the Matrix, the allocation for these two areas steadily climbed from 15% to 18% to 20%, and will continue to climb to 23% once the 10% rule expires. However, this clearly does not coincide with the actual changes in quota. Area A saw a steady decrease for each time period while Area B had a sharp jump and then a sharp drop. So the Matrix is not the sole problem; the loss of managerial tools has a huge impact. This example also helps explain why there is such a wide variety of circumstances across the province, within each region and from outfitter to outfitter. Between the two areas, this outfitter technically had a total of 18 bulls before 2007, and he had a total of 19 bulls after 2012, which appears to be a small increase. The intervening 5 years be- The Matrix is not the sole problem, nor does it tell the whole story. The loss of managerial tools is an essential part of the crisis. 17 Quota changes due to the loss of managerial tools does not affect outfitters equally. Some few experience increases, but most suffer serious losses. This new allocation policy fails to respond to the individual circumstances of outfitters, and the amendments designed to alleviate hardships in fact increased them. tween 2007 and 2012 should not be ignored here, though. This outfitter was planning on a larger quota and had begun to make more infrastructure investments to utilize that quota, which came to a screaming halt in 2012 once he realized this was now impossible. Keep in mind, if this had been two separate outfitters, one would be in crisis and the other panicking to find a way to use the new quota. The quota change due to the loss of managerial tools by no means affected outfitters equally, with very few experiencing increases and most suffering losses. This new allocation policy fails completely to respond to the individual circumstances of outfitters, and the amendments (such as the 10% rule) designed to alleviate hardships across the province in fact increased them in region 7A. In fact, in 2012 (now delayed to 2013), every outfitter in Region 7A saw a 30% loss in allocation when compared to the 2007–2011 time period, and this loss would have only been about 20% had the 10% hardship rule not been implemented. Many similar examples like this exist across the province. A few outfitters are experiencing marginal gains while others suffer catastrophic losses. As a direct result of the Matrix, outfitters lose allocation for 20 out of 36 species, or 56%. It is difficult to tell how many lose as a direct result of the loss of managerial tools, because this can only be assessed for outfitters one at a time; however, the losses are anecdotally very high. Many outfitters are losing huge percentages of allocation because of the move to area-based allocation, loss of vacant area allocations, and the removal of success factor inflation all being done at the same time. The Balanced Allocation Plan: Rebalancing the Equation The existing allocation policy will decimate the outfitting industry, but reverting to the previous policy fails to acknowledge its deficiencies. We need to balance the opaque but flexible human component with the transparent but rigid mathematical component. 18 Allocation needs to be calculated differently. The existing allocation process will decimate the outfitting industry, but reverting to the previous policy fails to acknowledge its deficiencies. The old policy created an inconsistent allocation situation due to the overly liberal use of managerial tools, but the new allocation has created a structured formula based on dubious variables with no managerial flexibility. The way forward is to balance the equation: we need to balance the opaque but flexible human component with the transparent but rigid mathematical component. The Balanced Allocation Plan proposes the following: The allocation would be set provincially for all species at 70% minimum for resident hunters and 20% minimum for outfitters, creating a 10% range of flexibility between 70–80% for residents and 20–30% for outfitters (notated as 70/20+10). Within this range of flexibility, regional managers have the discretion to make additional allocations to outfitters based on managerial tools and considerations, including: ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ The answer is the mathematical baseline (70/20+10) consistent across all species and the reinstatement of important managerial tools. Previous allocations Business needs Remote area multipliers Vacant area allocation Hunting pressure factors Harvest levels Economic considerations Allocations would continue to be based on habitat area. Administrative guidelines allowing a 30% harvest of a 5 year allocation within 1 year would remain as the replacement for success rate inflation for outfitters. All species under GOS for residents would be GOS for outfitters as well. Since any new plan will result in loss somewhere, the Balanced Allocation Plan gives the regional managers the authority and tools necessary to address outfitter losses caused by implementation by doing the following: Area-based and administrative guidelines are retained. GOS is equal for outfitters and residents. Regional managers are given authority and tools to mitigate outfitter losses due to implementation. ▶▶ Assess impact of the policy on each individual outfitter ▶▶ Set the initial allocation for each individual outfitter within the range of flexibility after considering the impacts on the outfitter and their historical allocations. ▶▶ W here there is deemed to be a hardship to the outfitter, the regional manager may: ▷▷ Amalgamate the outfitter’s territory with an adjacent vacant area. ▷▷ Facilitate the changing of several outfitter territory boundaries to incorporate allocating vacant areas equally across each region. ▷▷ Facilitate the purchase of smaller areas to amalgamate with another outfitter’s territory. ▷▷ Offer other solutions deemed necessary to minimize impact to outfitters. ▶▶ Make changes to wildlife management unit boundaries and hunting regulations where these are considered an obstacle to implementation and minimizing impacts on outfitters. 19 The Mathematical Formula: Fixed Range of Allocation Flexibility 70/20+10 means a 70% minimum share for resident hunters, 20% minimum share for outfitters, and a 10% range of flexibility, allocated by regional managers. The allocation would be set provincially for all species at 70% minimum for resident hunters and 20% minimum for outfitters, creating a 10% range of flexibility between 70–80% for residents and 20–30% for outfitters. This range was carefully calculated, as described later in this submission. This new formula would replace the fluctuating matrix. Regional managers would be responsible for allocating the remaining 10% as appropriate. Preferential treatment for certain species is removed. This method is simple, clear, and easy to understand. Eliminating the Matrix eliminates the total mathematical control over allocation, but the new method doesn’t return total control back to regional managers, either. The fixed range of allocation flexibility is the balance between the two approaches. The Math Behind 70/20+10 It is desirable to provide a range within which a human manager can operate, while providing a degree of stability and structure that allows participants to reasonably predict outcomes. “Capture rate” represents the number of allocated species whose allocation would not be forcibly reduced by the Balanced Allocation Plan. “Maximum % loss” represents the absolute most an outfitter could possibly lose in an allocation period under the Balanced Allocation Plan. 20 The goal of the Balanced Allocation Plan is to find the balance between the opaque but flexible system that existed before the Matrix, and the transparent but rigid system that the Matrix introduced. In order to balance these, it is desirable to provide a range within which a human manager can operate, while providing a degree of stability and structure that allows the participants to reasonably predict outcomes. To determine the optimal range of flexibility, we need to examine the concepts of “capture rate” and “maximum % loss.” Capture rate is calculated by comparing previous allocation numbers (pre-Matrix and Matrix) to the maximum possible share under the Balanced Allocation Plan. The capture rate represents the number of allocated species whose allocation would not be forcibly reduced by the Balanced Allocation Plan (the higher the rate the better). Maximum % loss represents the most an outfitter could possibly lose per allocation period under the Balanced Allocation Plan (the lower the number the better). From a mathematical perspective, there is no optimal tradeoff between maximum % loss and capture rate. This must be determined intuitively. Intuition, however, should be informed by hard data, which is presented and discussed below. Table 4 examines a reasonable range of possible splits and ranges of flexibility. The first 4 rows of each table list the capture rates for residents and outfitters for the pre-Matrix and Matrix time periods. Taking the average between resident and outfitter capture rates allows one to determine the optimal split—the one that captures the most for both residents and outfitters. The maximum % loss is also included for each split. One immediately sees that the optimal split for each table falls at the 70% point for resident allocation. What is left to be determined is the ideal range of flexibility: 5, 10, or 15%. The maximum % loss ranges from 17% to 50%. Clearly, a 50% loss is unacceptable from a business perspective, but the narrow range of flexibility (5%) for a maximum loss of 17% is clearly insufficient Table 4: Capture and maximum loss rates for various minimum share values and ranges of flexibility. 60/30+10 Resident Pre-Matrix 44 Capture % Matrix 22 Outfitter Pre-Matrix 78 Capture % Matrix 100 Pre-Matrix Avg. 61 Matrix Avg. 61 Total Avg. 61 % Max Outfitter Loss 25 65/25+10 67 56 67 100 67 78 72.5 29 70/20+10 81 75 64 81 72.5 78 75.25 33 75/15+10 89 89 47 58 68 73.5 70.75 40 80/10+10 97 92 28 25 62.5 58.5 60.5 50 60/25+15 R-Capture Pre-Matrix 67 Rate (%) Matrix 56 O-Capture Pre-Matrix 78 Rate (%) Matrix 100 Pre-Matrix Avg. 72.5 Matrix Avg. 78 Total Avg. 75.25 % Max Outfitter Loss 38 65/20+15 81 75 67 100 74 87.5 80.75 43 70/15+15 89 89 64 81 76.5 85 80.75 50 75/10+15 97 92 47 58 72 75 73.5 60 80/5+15 100 92 28 25 64 58.5 61.25 75 60/35+5 R-Capture Pre-Matrix 36 Rate (%) Matrix 6 O-Capture Pre-Matrix 78 Rate (%) Matrix 100 Pre-Matrix Avg. 57 Matrix Avg. 53 Total Avg. 55 % Max Outfitter Loss 13 65/30+5 44 22 67 100 55.5 61 58.25 14 70/25+5 67 56 64 81 65.5 68.5 67 17 75/20+5 81 75 47 58 64 66.5 65.25 20 80/15+5 89 89 28 25 58.5 57 57.75 25 21 A 10% range of flexibility and a maximum percent loss of 33% is a reasonable balance between the various extremes. to make allocation decisions by regional managers meaningful and effective. This leaves us with a 10% range of flexibility and a maximum % loss of 33%, which is a reasonable balance given that the maximum % loss under the pre-Matrix policy was essentially 0% and the maximum % loss under the Matrix is a catastrophic 67% (see Table 1). It is critically important to understand the difference between the Matrix and the Balanced Allocation Plan. The reimplementation of managerial tools means that allocations don’t always have to change because the math says so. There is a certain leeway. So while the maximum loss is 33%, it is in no way an expected loss, and such a loss would be accompanied with a justifiable rationale from the regional manager. This is how the 70/20+10 split put forward by the Balanced Allocation Plan was determined. Coincidentally, that range of flexibility matches with the maximum minimum share values for residents of 70% and outfitters of 20% that was determined through negotiation. Now that the optimum range for both residents and outfitters has been established, let’s examine exactly what species in what regions are not captured by the range of flexibility introduced by the Balanced Allocation Plan. Table 5: Resident allocations that are forcibly reduced compared to preMatrix allocations. Region 1 3 3 6South 7A 7B 8 Species Elk (bull) Grizzly bear Moose (bull) Moose (bull) Moose (bull) Elk (anterless) Moose (bull) % Allocation Loss 10 10 15 1 5 10 1 Table 6: Outfitter allocations that are forcibly reduced compared to preMatrix allocations. Region 1 1 5 5 22 Species Grizzly bear Elk (archery) Grizzly bear Goat % Allocation Loss 23 20 8 13 Region 6North 6North 6North 6North 6South 7A 7B 8 8 Species Caribou (bull) Goat Thinhorn Sheep (Dall) Grizzly bear Grizzly bear Grizzly bear Grizzly bear Goat Bighorn sheep % Allocation Loss 17 7 10 20 20 20 20 9 5 When comparing the Balanced Allocation Plan to the pre-Matrix allocations, 13 species are forcibly reduced for outfitters and 7 for residents. This is a clear improvement over the Matrix policy which forcibly reduced the allocations for 20 species for outfitters and 12 for residents. It should be noted that the Balanced Allocation Plan does not prescribe allocations like the Matrix does. Regional managers have discretionary authority within the range of flexibility. There are 10 additional outfitter species and 11 resident species that could conceivably be reduced by regional managers under the Balanced Allocation Plan if they deemed it appropriate. Regional managers have discretionary authority to adjust allocations within the range of flexibility. Number of Species Affected by the Balanced Allocation Plan Outfitters 13 Species Static or Improved 10 Species Flexible Allocation 13 Species Forcibly Reduced Residents 18 Species Static or Improved 11 Species Flexible Allocation 7 Species Forcibly Reduced 23 The Human Formula: Managerial Tools The 10% window would be managed by the regional manager using the managerial tools already available to them including: ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ ▶▶ Regional managers will have access to many tools and can consider many factors when determining allocations. These decisions would be accompanied by a clear rationale and would be constrained by the fixed 10% range of flexibility. Previous allocations Business needs Remote area multipliers Vacant area allocation Hunting pressure factors Harvest levels Other economic factors Issues of “utilization” (harvest levels) and “relative importance” (economic factors) still exist, but they are only part of what a regional manager would consider when making decisions, and these variables would only have influence over the narrow 10% window of flexibility. Under the new model, regional managers can look at individual guide harvest levels and the importance of each species to each guide in order to set allocations. In addition, the new model is not limited to those factors alone: regional managers may consider other factors that are relevant or specific to their region. Under the new method, regional managers would have the discretion to choose what the best allocation for residents and outfitters is within this range of flexibility. Regional managers would be expected to provide a clear and transparent rationale for why they set the allocation where they did, and they could make changes within their regions from outfitter to outfitter if necessary. But all these decisions would be constrained by the fixed 10% range of flexibility, and residents and outfitters would still have access to the Environmental Appeal Board if a manager’s rationale was erroneous or inappropriate. This is the balance between the human and the mathematical approaches. Inevitable Loss: Remedies There is no “impact neutral” way to proceed. Losses are inevitable. 24 Neither the Balanced Allocation Plan, the Matrix, nor any other solution can be impact neutral. There must be changes to correct the deficiencies of the past, but these changes do not necessarily mean there must be absolute losses to outfitters. There are ways to mitigate the impacts. There are some good ideas coming out of the previous policy that should be retained because they create a stronger industry and better ecological management: administrative guidelines and area-based allocations, to name the two most prominent. But these cannot be implemented without some loss to the outfitting industry, since outfitters lose the inflation based on success factors, and their quota changes to reflect their actual habitat. There are ways to minimize these losses, however, and the Balanced Allocation Plan extends to regional managers the authority to examine and address the negative effects of these changes. Possible remedies include: There are, however, ways to minimize these losses. ▶▶ S etting the initial allocation for each individual outfitter within the range of flexibility after considering the impacts on the outfitter and their historical allocations. This gives the regional managers the ability to ensure a fair share to each outfitter based on their historical share if negatively impacted. This alone may solve the impact problems for many outfitters, but if the outfitter share was greater than the 30%, additional remedies will be needed. For some outfitters, the most recent allocation policy was a boon and they made business plans on those new numbers. This should also be taken into consideration by the regional manager when making his decisions. However, it is entirely possible that a regional manager deems an outfitter’s allocation to be unjustified, and he could conceivably reduce allocations within the range of flexibility. Regional managers would be required to provide a clear, written rationale for such a decision. If outfitters felt the decision was unjustified or erroneous in some way, they would have recourse to the Environmental Appeal Board. Regional managers could conceivably reduce allocations within the range of flexibility, if warranted. ▶▶ W here there is deemed to be a hardship to the outfitter, the regional manager may: ▷▷ Amalgamate the outfitter’s territory with an adjacent vacant area. ▷▷ Facilitate the changing of several outfitter territory boundaries to incorporate allocating vacant areas equally across each region. ▷▷ Facilitate the purchase of smaller areas to amalgamate with another outfitter’s territory. There exists many vacant areas throughout BC, and it makes rational sense to amalgamate adjacent vacant areas with affected outfitters in order to offset losses. However, the actual vacant area may not be immediately adjacent to an affected outfitter. In this case the regional manager would act as a facilitator to bring outfitters together to discuss possible territory boundary changes There exists many vacant areas throughout BC, and it makes sense to be able to amalgamate adjacent vacant areas with affected outfitters in order to offset losses. 25 Regional managers will need to work with outfitters on a consensus basis. to allow these vacant areas to be divided up equally among all outfitters. In conjunction with this, there may exist opportunities to amalgamate smaller territories into larger ones, if outfitters are willing to sell their territories. The regional manager would not have authority to force the changes upon an unwilling outfitter, and so he will need to work on a consensus basis with outfitters to find solutions. This will be a complicated process, but if all parties act in good faith, a consensus-based solution is the best way to mitigate losses. ▶▶ M ake changes to wildlife management unit boundaries and hunting regulations where these are considered an obstacle to implementation and minimizing impacts on outfitters. It may very well be that it is not territorial boundaries that are the obstacle to implementation but WMU boundaries. The regional manager should examine changes to these boundaries and regulations as a potential option. Conclusion The fixed range of allocation flexibility, coupled with managerial tools, removes most of the uncertainty and volatility from the allocation process. We can promote greater tourism opportunity through outfitting and greater outfitting through tourism. 26 There can be no doubt that if the current allocation policy (the Matrix) remains in place, the future of outfitting will begin a longterm decline. The policy will result in massive quota losses to outfitters across the province, a reduction in the number of viable outfitters, a withdrawal of investment from BC, and the end of the family outfitter, to name a few. The Balanced Allocation Plan aims to redirect this course. It is imperative to repair the damage done by the new policy by immediately implementing the Balanced Allocation Plan. The fixed range of allocation flexibility, coupled with managerial tools, removes most of the uncertainty and volatility from the allocation process. The Balanced Allocation Plan addresses most of the negative effects of the current policy and allows for a viable industry to thrive. In the past, the Outsteading era led to tremendous growth in outfitting, but the industry has stagnated and perhaps even contracted somewhat with the Neofitter era. Most of the provincial tourism machine has divorced itself from outfitting, in spite of the close historical connection between the two. With concerted effort and bold action, there is the potential to remarry the two and promote greater tourism opportunity through outfitting and greater outfitting through tourism. Outfitters are hopeful that the future of outfitting will lead us into an era of prosperity, but that can only be made possible with bold leadership and new ideas. For resident hunters, the real issue has always been hunting opportunity and the fear that outfitters are reducing this opportunity. Any honest examination of the allocation process, whether pre-Matrix, Matrix, or Balanced Allocation Plan, must conclude that real hunting opportunity is not controlled by the allocation process so much as by the Annual Allowable Harvest (AAH). The hunting industry is unique among natural resource industries, such as mining and logging, in that businesses (outfitters) compete directly with residents. Fortunately it is also unique in that it is a resource that renews quickly (10-year cycles, as opposed to 100 years for logging, for example) and so with proper management can be increased. Allocation policy is the wrong tool for increasing resident hunter opportunities. Gains due to allocation are always limited by the AAH, and gains will always be marginal because residents already enjoy a much larger share of the allocation. However, if you can increase the AAH, this will always result in increased opportunity for resident hunters, and that opportunity always grows at a greater rate than for outfitters, again because residents enjoy a larger portion of allocation. Imagine, if you will, a species allocated at 70/30 with 100 animals to allocate under the AAH. Residents get 70, and outfitters get 30. Residents could potentially improve their allocation by a small amount from 70 to 80, but this would be at the expense of outfitters. But consider that if government focused effort and resources on improving the game population and succeeded in increasing the AAH for that species from 100 to 200, resident don’t go from 70 to 80, but from 70 to 140. And that means real new opportunity for resident hunters. The government rightly decided that the old allocation policy needed to be changed. They wanted a policy that was “consistent and transparent,” “objective and data-based,” and, most importantly, “reflective of stakeholders’ interests.” The Matrix might satisfy the first two objectives, but it clearly fails to meet the third. The Balanced Allocation Plan addresses all these needs, and its implementation would make it possible to begin making real improvement to resident hunting opportunity through increasing the AAH. The argument needs to move from how to divide the pie to how to make the pie bigger. There are already more species to hunt in BC than any other single jurisdiction in North America. It’s tough to improve on that sort of hunting opportunity, so the focus needs to be on better wildlife management and growing wildlife populations to improve the AAH. Any honest examination of the allocation process must conclude that real hunting opportunity is not controlled by the allocation process so much as by the Annual Allowable Harvest (AAH). Allocation policy is the wrong tool for increasing resident hunter opportunities. The old allocation policy needed to be changed, but change is possible without putting outfitters out of business. The argument needs to move from how to divide the pie to how to make the pie bigger. 27 Appendix A: Trumpy Report “Harvest Allocation Policy Review” Overall, the Trumpy Report “Harvest Allocation Policy Review” is quite critical of the policy. It identifies several specific impacts of implementing the policy (pp. 19–20): ▶▶ O verall the number of animals guides have access to will fall, in some cases dramatically, but there are a few cases where guides will have small increases ▶▶ The value of guide outfitting territories will fall where there is a reduction in the number of animals available. ▶▶ Some guide outfitters will fail. ▶▶ The incentive to “use or lose” allocation share will result in behaviours inconsistent with good wildlife stewardship. ▶▶ Successful guides will be negatively affected when other guides in their region fail to harvest animals. Like the Balanced Allocation Plan, the Trumpy Report identifies the historical and present problems with the allocation policy as being in the past, too inconsistent, but in the present, too inflexible. Although the new policy is transparent and consistent, it is too inflexible to deal with the diversity of circumstances that exist throughout the province. (p. 4) Trumpy identifies the challenges inherent in the discretion of regional managers: When government regulation provides regulators with little discretion there are inevitably unfair results. Where regulators have too much discretion the result is that decisions are described as inconsistent. (p. 16) Prefacing his recommendations, Trumpy offers this opinion: The Harvest Allocation Policy is intended to bring consistency, fairness, equity and transparency to a system which was inconsistent, inequitable and not very transparent. In doing so it has failed to be fair because it does not take into account temporary circumstances, access differences, or the impact of individual guide behaviour on other guides. (p. 20) 29 The Balanced Allocation Plan identifies the same problems in the policy that Trumpy does but goes one step further to examine the mathematical flaws that Trumpy failed to recognize. But more importantly, the Balanced Allocation Plan encompasses the core recommendations of the Trumpy Report, though the Balanced Allocation Plan was not written with the intention of accommodating Trumpy. Of the eleven recommendations from Trumpy, seven fall within the Balanced Allocation Plan, three are neutral and don’t affect the Balanced Allocation Plan either way, and one is contrary. Below I have examined the recommendations from Trumpy and how the Balanced Allocation Plan affects these recommendations: Recommendation from Trumpy that are encompassed by the Balanced Allocation Plan Recommendation 1—The split between resident and guided hunters should not be set by species at the regional level using the new allocation model. While the model should inform the decision, the Ministry should also consider actual splits using data available for the last 10 years and circumstances unique to each region. A base level of guided hunter split should be available to every guide but regional managers should have some discretion to allocate individual guide share above the base level up to a regional split determined by the Ministry What Trumpy is essentially calling for here is the return of powers to the regional manager to determine allocations from a baseline. While not exactly what the Balanced Allocation Plan proposes, this does fall within the Balanced Allocation Plan concept of a 70/20+10 split, where the baseline is 70/20 and the regional managers determine where within this range the allocation falls based on whatever factors they find relevant. Recommendation 3—Allocation within a region to individual guides should consider access, level of resident hunter activity and be determined by the regional manager. The reasons for variances from the base level of regional splits should be disclosed. Again, this is returning discretional powers to the regional manager, which is central to the Balanced Allocation Plan, allowing the regional managers a 10% window of flexibility. 30 Recommendation 5—All of the allocation in areas where there are no guide territories should be allocated to resident hunters. This is consistent with an area based allocation, which the Balanced Allocation Plan advocates. Recommendation 6—Species of GOS for residents should not be on quota for guides. This is also called for directly by the Balanced Allocation Plan. Recommendation 8—Regional managers should have access to a wide range of tools to support the industry achievement of its split, at both the regional and individual guide level. Tools dropped in the new policy should be reconsidered and new options explored provided they are consistent with good wildlife stewardship. Here is another recommendation which returns discretionary powers to the regional manager, as is also advocated by the Balanced Allocation Plan. Recommendation 10—The Ministry needs to clarify its policy for vacant guide territories to provide certainty for the industry. Fractional sales which provide marginal additions to strengthen existing operations should proceed. The Balanced Allocation Plan advocates using vacant areas to offset losses to outfitters in the implementation process. Recommendation 11—The Ministry should consider facilitating the consolidation of guide territories in regions where small territories are the norm to encourage more viable operations. The Balanced Allocation Plan advocates the regional manager acting as a non-binding facilitator to amalgamate smaller territories as part of the implementation process. 31 Recommendation from Trumpy that are neutral in regards to the Balanced Allocation Plan Recommendation 2—The splits should be set, beginning in 2012, for a minimum of 10 years. The Balanced Allocation Plan does not expressly call for this. Whether this recommendation is implemented or not does not affect the core concept of the Balanced Allocation Plan. It should be noted here though that a 10 year allocation as opposed to a 5 year allocation limits the degree of flexibility regional managers have to respond to changing circumstances. On the other hand, it provides for longer term security for outfitters. Recommendation 4—Individual guides with smal­ler allocations (less than 5 animals over a 5 year period) should be permitted to harvest all their allocation in a single year provided there is no impact on population sustainability. This works within the Balanced Allocation Plan, but is not necessary for Balanced Allocation Plan to work. I believe government has already implemented this recommendation. Recommendation 9—Guides not utilizing their allocation should be encouraged or required to transfer it to guides in adjacent territories provided there are no negative impacts on population sustainability. This recommendation is made irrelevant with the Balanced Allocation Plan, because utilization no longer exists as a controlling factor in the process. However, a temporary transferal of allocation from outfitter to outfitter is certainly one tool that could be used by regional managers if they felt it necessary, though this concept is problematic with an area based allocation. It would have to be temporary to work with express agreement between both outfitters or else the policy would run the risk of falling into previous allocation problems of unfairness. Recommendation from Trumpy that are contrary to the Balanced Allocation Plan Recommendation 7—If a guide in a region fail to use their allocation over a two or three year period then it should be made available on a temporary basis to 32 residents through a one or two year increase in LEH authorizations where such actions have no impact on population sustainability. There would be no possibility for reduction to guide split until the end of the 10 year period. This is anathema to the Balanced Allocation Plan, and in particular administrative guidelines. Administrative guidelines allow for outfitters to harvest 30% of a 5 year allocation in 1 year, so an outfitter could technically harvest 5% in year 1, 5% in year 2, and then 30% in years 3–5 and still meet their allocation. This would not be possible if regional managers were constantly shifting allocations from outfitters to residents based on underutilization, as would happen in this example in the first two years. Allocation must be fixed, and how and when a regional manager changes allocation must be determined in a predictable fashion. If underutilization were a consistent concern of the regional manager, the proper time to correct that is in conjunction with all the other consideration at the end of each allocation period, not in the interim. The core idea of returning power to the regional managers with variance from a base level as brought forward by Trumpy in his recommendations is addressed in the Balanced Allocation Plan. The Balanced Allocation Plan improves this concept greatly by establishing mathematically where the baseline should be for residents and outfitters, and how much flexibility should be given to regional managers. Financial Impact Beyond the recommendations from Trumpy, what is obviously missing from his report is a more concrete assessment of the financial impact on outfitters. This would take a very thorough examination of the industry, outfitter by outfitter, because while the matrix changes can easily be calculated and given a value, the impact of the loss of managerial tools is not so easily calculated as it affects outfitters in the same region very differently. Trumpy readily admits that “At the individual guide level the impact of this revenue reduction combined with the elimination of tools used by regional managers could prove catastrophic” (p. 17). There is a void in available financial data here which will require joint effort from industry and government to fill by properly assessing the affect policy on an individual basis. If and when these numbers are forthcoming, the real effects on the industry could then be accurately assessed. In the meantime, using Trumpy’s vague estimate 33 that the “impact on the industry is more than a 10% decline in revenues” (p. 17) (the actual math calculation is 13–19%) must also be considered with statements like “The gross industry impact probably understates the impact for a number of individual guides who will likely fail in the coming years if the new policy is fully implemented in 2012” (p. 19). These losses are indeterminate without better information. 34