International Management Forum (IMF) Distance Course Future Battlefields: Transfer Pricing and Intangibles 9 August 2012 Course Editors: Steef Huibregtse, Rudolf Sinx, Vladimir Zivkovic, Joel Wilpitz, Raheem Farishta Lesson 1: Introduction Authors: Steef Huibregtse, Vladimir Zivkovic, Louan Verdoner, Joel Wilpitz (TPA Amsterdam) Lesson 2: Transfer Pricing Labels of intangibles, identification of intangibles, ownership of intangibles Authors: Steef Huibregtse (TPA Amsterdam), Lukasz Kubicki (TPA Switzerland) Lesson 3: Valuation of Intangibles Authors: Steven van Wijk, Sjoerd de Jong (TPA Amsterdam), Steven Carey (TPA Asia) Lesson 4: Business models: Intangible Property configurations Authors: Steef Huibregtse (TPA Amsterdam), Steven Carey (TPA Asia), Elizabeth King (Beecher Consulting LLC) Lesson 5: Intellectual Property Law and Transfer Pricing Authors: Eric Master, Dorus van der Burgt (Witlox Van den Boomen) Lesson 6: Accounting definitions of IP and transfer pricing Authors: Steven van Wijk (TPA Amsterdam), Lukasz Kubicki (TPA Switzerland), Alon Wexler, Ryan Abrams (Richter Consulting Inc) Lesson 7: Corporate Income Tax Aspects of IP and Transfer Pricing Authors: Rudolf Sinx, Louan Verdoner, Raheem Farishta (TPA Amsterdam) 1 Table of Contents 1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 7 1.1 Introduction .............................................................................................................................. 8 1.2 The evolution of the MNE and the importance of intangibles ................................................. 9 1.3 OECD Definition of Intangible Property .................................................................................. 11 1.3.1 Chapter VI of the July 2010 OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines ..................................................... 11 1.3.2 Discussion Draft of the Proposed Revisions to Chapter VI of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines (6 June 2012) ................................................................................................................................................ 12 1.4 How do emerging jurisdictions (i.e. BRICS) deal with intangibles .......................................... 14 1.5 Transfer Pricing & Intangibles: four functional variables ....................................................... 15 1.5.1 Label.............................................................................................................................................. 17 1.5.2 Identification ................................................................................................................................. 18 1.5.3 Ownership ..................................................................................................................................... 19 1.5.4 Valuation....................................................................................................................................... 20 1.6 Locating IP in tax advantaged jurisdictions ............................................................................ 22 1.7 Transfer Pricing Risks (1): Court Cases on Intangibles ............................................................ 24 1.7.1 DHL................................................................................................................................................ 24 1.7.2 Maruti-Suzuki ................................................................................................................................ 25 1.7.3 Veritas ........................................................................................................................................... 27 1.7.4 GlaxoSmithKline ............................................................................................................................ 28 1.8 Transfer Pricing Risks (2): Corporate Reputation at Risk Through SEC Disclosure of Intercompany Transactions ............................................................................................................... 28 1.9 Introduction to lessons 2-7 ..................................................................................................... 30 Lesson 2: Transfer Pricing Labels of intangibles, identification of intangibles, ownership of intangibles .... 30 Lesson 3: Valuation of intangibles ................................................................................................................ 30 Lesson 4: Business models: IP configurations ............................................................................................... 30 Lesson 5: Intellectual Property Law and Transfer Pricing ............................................................................. 31 Lesson 6: Accounting Definitions of Intellectual Property and Transfer Pricing ........................................... 31 Lesson 7: Corporate Income Tax Aspects of IP and Transfer Pricing............................................................. 31 1.10 Questions ................................................................................................................................ 31 1.11 Answers .................................................................................................................................. 32 1.12 Literature ................................................................................................................................ 33 2 Transfer Pricing Labels of intangibles, identification of intangibles, ownership of intangibles 35 2.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 36 2 2.2 2.2.1 Legal perspective .......................................................................................................................... 36 2.2.2 Accounting perspective ................................................................................................................. 38 2.2.3 Tax perspective ............................................................................................................................. 38 2.2.3.1 Trade intangibles ....................................................................................................................................... 39 2.2.3.2 Marketing intangibles ............................................................................................................................... 39 2.2.3.3 Article 12 of the OECD Model Tax Convention ......................................................................................... 40 2.2.4 Local Tax Perspective .................................................................................................................... 40 2.2.5 Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................... 41 2.2.6 Alternative labelling ...................................................................................................................... 43 2.3 3 Definition of intangibles ......................................................................................................... 36 Labelling of intangibles........................................................................................................... 44 2.3.1 Legal ownership ............................................................................................................................ 45 2.3.2 Economic ownership ..................................................................................................................... 45 2.3.3 Nominal Ownership: ..................................................................................................................... 46 2.3.4 Process Ownership: ....................................................................................................................... 46 2.3.5 Entitlement to Intangibles related returns:................................................................................... 46 2.3.6 Special Case: Subcontracting ........................................................................................................ 47 2.3.7 Special Case: Cost contribution arrangement ............................................................................... 48 2.4 Questions ................................................................................................................................ 49 2.5 Answers .................................................................................................................................. 50 Valuation of intangibles....................................................................................................... 51 3.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 52 3.2 When and Why Intangible Assets are Valuable ..................................................................... 53 3.3 Companies with highly valued intangibles ............................................................................. 55 3.3.1 3.3.1.1 3.3.2 Microsoft Corporation................................................................................................................... 55 Market value of Microsoft ........................................................................................................................ 56 Veritas v Commissioner ................................................................................................................. 57 3.4 Why and when are intangibles valued? ................................................................................. 58 3.5 Price, Value and Cost .............................................................................................................. 61 3.6 Generally Accepted Valuation Approaches ............................................................................ 62 3.6.1 The Cost Approach Valuation Methods ........................................................................................ 62 3.6.2 Market Approach Valuation Methods .......................................................................................... 64 3.6.3 Income Approach Valuation Methods .......................................................................................... 67 3.6.3.1 Example of the Income Approach, the Discounted Future Benefits Method ........................................... 70 3.6.3.2 Example of the Income Approach, Capitalized Royalty Income Method for Trademark Valuation .......... 70 3 3.6.4 Valuation Synthesis and Conclusion Procedures ........................................................................... 71 3.6.5 Intangible RUL Considerations ...................................................................................................... 71 3.6.6 The Valuation of Intangibles for Tax Purposes ............................................................................. 72 3.6.7 Discussion Draft on Intangibles, OECD Chapter VI ........................................................................ 74 3.6.8 Summary ....................................................................................................................................... 75 3.7 Determining the Discount Rate and Capitalization Rate ........................................................ 77 3.8 Business Restructuring and Valuation, Chapter IX, OECD ...................................................... 78 3.8.1 Generating a functional and factual analysis ............................................................................... 79 3.8.2 Economic analysis ......................................................................................................................... 80 3.8.2.1 Transfers with economic value in isolation ............................................................................................... 80 3.8.2.2 Transfers that require a renegotiation or termination of existing contracts ............................................ 81 3.8.3 3.9 Determine arm's length treatment ............................................................................................... 83 Questions ................................................................................................................................ 85 3.10 Answers .................................................................................................................................. 85 4 Business models: Intangible Property configurations............................................................ 86 4.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 87 4.2 Overview of business models from a commercial perspective: .............................................. 87 4.2.1 Licensing-in model ........................................................................................................................ 87 4.2.2 In house development model ........................................................................................................ 88 4.2.3 Contract R&D model ..................................................................................................................... 89 4.2.4 Cost sharing model ....................................................................................................................... 90 4.3 Transfer pricing and general corporate tax considerations of each model............................ 91 4.3.1 Licensing in.................................................................................................................................... 91 4.3.2 In-house development .................................................................................................................. 91 4.3.3 Contract R&D ................................................................................................................................ 92 4.3.4 Cost sharing .................................................................................................................................. 92 4.4 Model implementation – high level guidance on implementing each of the above models, including: ........................................................................................................................................... 93 4.4.1 5 Legal framework for managing IP ................................................................................................ 93 4.5 Case Study .............................................................................................................................. 94 4.6 Questions with model answers............................................................................................... 96 4.7 Multiple choice questions ....................................................................................................... 97 4.8 Answers to open and multiple choice questions .................................................................... 97 4.9 Literature ................................................................................................................................ 99 Intellectual Property law and Transfer Pricing .................................................................... 100 4 5.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 101 5.2 Brief History of IP .................................................................................................................. 101 5.3 Future of IP ........................................................................................................................... 102 5.4 Appearance of IP .................................................................................................................. 103 5.4.1 Copyright and rights related to copyright. .................................................................................. 103 5.4.2 Industrial property. ..................................................................................................................... 103 5.4.3 Copyright..................................................................................................................................... 104 5.4.4 Patent ......................................................................................................................................... 106 5.4.5 Design ......................................................................................................................................... 107 5.4.6 Trade mark .................................................................................................................................. 109 5.4.7 Short summary of other Intellectual Property rights: ................................................................. 111 5.5 Neighbouring rights ................................................................................................................................ 111 5.4.7.2 Plant breeders’ rights or plant variety rights .......................................................................................... 111 5.4.7.3 Database rights ....................................................................................................................................... 112 5.4.7.4 Trade name ............................................................................................................................................. 112 IP exploitation ....................................................................................................................... 112 5.5.1 IP-rights for own use ................................................................................................................... 113 5.5.2 IP-rights granted to third parties ................................................................................................ 113 5.5.3 Transfer of IP-rights .................................................................................................................... 114 5.6 IP management .................................................................................................................... 114 5.6.1 Action against infringement ....................................................................................................... 114 5.6.2 Prolonging and expanding IP-rights............................................................................................ 115 5.6.3 Positioning of IP-rights ................................................................................................................ 116 5.7 6 5.4.7.1 IP transfer ............................................................................................................................. 116 5.7.1 Transfer by deed ......................................................................................................................... 116 5.7.2 Reasons for transfer .................................................................................................................... 116 5.7.3 Risks assessment and valuation issues ....................................................................................... 117 5.8 Questions .............................................................................................................................. 118 5.9 Answers ................................................................................................................................ 119 Accounting definitions of IP and transfer pricing ................................................................ 120 6.1 Introduction – Intangibles .................................................................................................... 121 6.2 Recognition of Intangibles .................................................................................................... 122 6.2.1 Intangibles acquired externally ................................................................................................... 123 6.2.2 Intangibles generated internally ................................................................................................. 125 6.2.3 Intangibles acquired as part of business combination ................................................................ 128 5 7 6.3 Goodwill ................................................................................................................................ 131 6.4 Subsequent measurement .................................................................................................... 133 6.5 Questions .............................................................................................................................. 134 6.6 Answers ................................................................................................................................ 135 6.7 Literature .............................................................................................................................. 135 Corporate Income Tax Aspects of IP and Transfer Pricing .................................................... 136 7.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 137 7.2 Initial Intangible Asset Value ................................................................................................ 137 7.3 Amortization/Decrease in Value of Intangible Assets .......................................................... 138 7.3.1 Methods of Amortization ............................................................................................................ 139 7.4 R&D Tax Credit ..................................................................................................................... 139 7.5 Innovation Box/Other Incentives .......................................................................................... 141 7.6 Replacement Reserve ........................................................................................................... 143 7.7 Withholding Tax on Royalty Payments................................................................................. 144 7.8 Capital Gains Tax .................................................................................................................. 144 7.9 Business Restructuring and Related Taxes ........................................................................... 145 7.10 VAT ....................................................................................................................................... 146 7.11 Purchase Price Allocation ..................................................................................................... 147 7.12 Beneficial/Economic/Legal Ownership ................................................................................. 148 7.12.1 Beneficial Ownership .................................................................................................................. 148 7.12.2 Legal Ownership ......................................................................................................................... 149 7.12.3 Economic Ownership................................................................................................................... 149 7.12.4 Differences between Economic and Legal Ownership ................................................................ 150 7.12.5 Centralized vs. Distributed Ownership ........................................................................................ 152 7.13 Conclusion............................................................................................................................. 152 7.14 Questions .............................................................................................................................. 152 7.15 Answers ................................................................................................................................ 153 6 1 Introduction Authors: Steef Huibregtse/Vladimir Zivkovic/Louan Verdoner/Joel Wilpitz 7 1.1 Introduction Today, intangible property (IP) 1 generally represents between 40 and 80 percent of ‘valueadd’ of multinational enterprises (MNEs), making it a key component of a MNE’s valuechain. Intangible property includes business rights associated with commercial activities, including marketing activities. Intangible property will not always be shown on the balance sheet of a company, and often intangible property attracts a considerable risk, e.g. contract or product liability. There are numerous legal, accounting and tax related definitions of IP. However, most of these are typically purpose specific. In the context of transfer pricing, the four main questions relating to intangibles include: • How to label different types of intangibles? • How to recognize or identify intangibles? • What ownership types of intangibles can exist? • How to determine the arm’s length value of intangibles? The OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines, July 2010 (Chapter VI and VIII) is the leading reference document which provides guidance on the treatment of intangible property in the context of transfer pricing. The two categories of intangibles the OECD has identified in the Transfer Pricing Guidelines, July 2010 include: • Commercial intangibles: e.g. patents, know-how, designs and models that are used for the production of a good or the provision of a service; • Marketing intangibles: e.g. trademarks and trade names which enhance the commercial exploitation of a product or service, customer list, distribution channels, and unique names, symbols, or pictures that have an important promotional value. Given that transfer pricing issues pertaining to intangibles are a key area of concern to governments and taxpayers, the OECD found that updating Chapter VI and VIII has become an increasingly important issue in the evolution of new business realities and subsequent adaptations to the transfer pricing regulations. In addition to offering guidance on intangibles in the general sense, Working Party No. 6 of the OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs (Working Party) is focusing on four main areas pertaining to intangibles: goodwill, brands, ownership, and synergies. The Working Party has passed the halfway mark of their proposed four-year rewriting project, i.e. target publication date before end of 2013. 1 In the context of Lesson 1, the terms “intangible property,” “IP,” and “intangibles” are used interchangeably. 8 On June 6, 2012, the OECD released a discussion draft “Revision of the Special Considerations for Intangibles in Chapter VI of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines and Related Provisions,” (Discussion Draft) 2. This draft is the result of a series of meetings with the public and has been influenced by the discussions that have taken place. The OECD has requested comments from the public regarding the Discussion Draft by 14 September, 2012. The Discussion Draft contains a variety of considerable changes that, if implemented, could have major impacts on transfer pricing considerations for intangibles. The contents of the Discussion Draft provide valuable guidance on particular topics relating to intangibles. However, at the same time the Discussion Draft raises more questions due to specific changes that are presented in the new wording. There are far-reaching implications on how the Working Party decides to define intangibles and word the guidelines surrounding them. If the OECD aligns with a strict definition of intangibles, this could cause alienation of the BRIC countries (Brazil, Russia, India, and China). These countries typically favour a wider definition of intangibles because they have not traditionally been active in the protection of IP through patents, trademarks, registrations or copyrights. The BRIC countries potentially could threaten to become active members of the UN Charter on Transfer Pricing instead of OECD members. The difference in regulations between the two bodies has the potential to cause double taxation for MNEs operating in both BRIC countries and OECD-member countries, i.e. introducing two sets of transfer pricing standards. With the dynamic nature of intangibles and transfer pricing, it is clear that this is an increasingly important area of transfer pricing, and one which will gain increasing attention from tax authorities and MNEs across the world for years to come. 1.2 The evolution of the MNE and the importance of intangibles Today’s typical MNE is a reflection of the evolution of the global economy over the last few decades. Rapid technological innovation has vastly contributed towards the integration of the global economy and has had important implications for the everyday operations of MNEs across the world. Whereas firms competed only with players in their local markets, today MNEs compete with companies from all over the globe. Sometimes this competition extends across industries as 2 The OECD discussion draft is an interim draft. The OECD has invited public comments on this draft by the 14 September 2012. 9 well, as firms have started diversifying their operations and entering into various industry or market segments. This increased competition has led firms to significantly reduce the timeframes for decision-making and execution across various segments of the value chain, to compete more on costs, as well as to invest more into market research and product innovation and development. In other words, a shorter product life cycle has forced internationally operating companies to maximize the efficiency and cost benefits of their global production and supply chain footprint. Practical issues which are addressed by MNEs on a daily basis include questions on how to operate more efficiently, how to cut costs and how to create a sustainable competitive advantage in today’s global marketplace. During this period, the value and importance of intangibles has come to the forefront of the value chain of many MNEs operating in a wide array of industries. Product and process related intangibles have become important ways to differentiate one’s offering in the marketplace. As such, intangibles such as patents, know-how, designs, models, trademarks and trade names, all of which enhance the potential for commercial exploitation of a product or service, as well as customer lists and distribution channels are all important factors contributing to the value- add of an MNE in the marketplace. A modern example of the value that can be added with intangibles is the Apple iPod. The following image provides evidence as to how the “Apple” brand creates value and how the know-how, design and channel of distribution that is at Apple’s disposal adds a considerable amount of value to this product. The real value of the iPod does not reside in its parts or even in putting those parts together, but in the know-how, design, brand and channel of distribution of the iPod. That is the reason why Apple receives $80 for each iPod it sells, which is by far the largest piece of value added in the entire supply chain. 10 Source: Varian, Hal R, The New York Times, June 28, 2007. An IPod Has Global Value. Ask the (Many) Countries That Makes It. 1.3 OECD Definition of Intangible Property 1.3.1 Chapter VI of the July 2010 OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines The July 2010, OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises and Tax Administrations (“OECD Guidelines”) provide a standard reference for intangibles and how to apply transfer pricing methods to intangibles. In the context of transfer pricing, intangibles are typically examined in four components. The four functional variables are the label, identification, ownership and value of a given intangible and are the basis of evaluating an intangible in the realm of transfer pricing. Chapter VI of the OECD Guidelines provides two categories of intangibles: • Commercial intangibles e.g. patents, know-how, designs and models that are used for the production of a good or the provision of a service. • Marketing intangibles e.g. trademarks and trade names which enhance the commercial exploitation of a product or service, customer list, distribution channels, and unique names, symbols, or pictures that have an important promotional value. 11 Rather than relying strictly on the categories provided by the OECD Guidelines, it is worthwhile to develop a characterization of intangibles that reflects practical labels based on how the intangible adds value to the business. There are a variety of labels that can be applied to an intangible. The labels are typically process related, product related, market related or a combination of the different labels. When identifying an intangible, the initial step is typically the available legal and accounting information. Because of the unique nature of intangibles and the process of generating and developing intangibles, they are often not present in legal agreements or balance sheets. In order to asses internally created IP, it is typically necessary to conduct a thorough functional analysis of the MNE and evaluate where intangibles exist in the company’s value chain. The next aspect of an intangible that is evaluated according to the OECD Guidelines is the ownership of the intangible. The two types of ownership that are addressed are economic ownership and legal ownership. Legal ownership is centred on contracts or agreements that lead to an entity being designated as the holder of legal rights to use, exploit, or prevent others from using an intangible. An economic owner has the rights to claim or receive income that can be attributed to an asset that is owned. Finally, in addressing the value that is assigned to an intangible, the OECD emphasizes that the arm’s length principle should still be maintained for determining the value or price of any transaction between related parties involving intangibles. The OECD recognizes the difficulty of accurately valuing an intangible because of the inherently unique nature of intangibles. It is still recommended to search for comparables in order to determine a fair market value of a given transaction. 1.3.2 Discussion Draft of the Proposed Revisions to Chapter VI of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines (6 June 2012) In Paragraph 5 of the Discussion Draft, the OECD writes, “the word “intangible” is intended to address something which is not a physical asset or a financial asset, and which is capable of being owned or controlled for use in commercial activities.” The OECD chooses to not provide any particular categories of labels of intangibles in the Discussion Draft. “No attempt is made in these Guidelines to delineate various classes or categories of intangibles.” 3 This is a considerably different stance than in Chapter VI of the OECD Guidelines, 2010. Source: Par. 13 OECD Discussion Draft, 6 June, 2012 12 The OECD also addresses the issue of identifying intangibles by introducing a list of factors that should be considered. These factors are: • “Intangibles that are important to consider for transfer pricing purposes are not always recognised as intangible assets for accounting purposes.” 4 • Having legal or contractual mechanisms to protect an intangible does not affect the importance of the intangible in the context of transfer pricing.5 • “Transferability is not a necessary condition for an item to be characterised as an intangible for transfer pricing purposes.” 6 • The importance of separating intangibles from market specific conditions or other variables that are not transferrable or capable of being owned.7 • Not all intangibles require or justify remuneration or add value in all situations or circumstances. 8 These considerations provide the foundation for a modified perspective on what intangibles are relevant to transfer pricing and how to handle the intangibles that are still considered to be significant in the context of transfer pricing. Paragraph 29 of the Discussion Draft described the concept of “entitlement to intangible related returns.” (i) The terms and conditions of legal arrangements including relevant registrations, licence agreements, and other relevant contracts; (ii) whether the functions performed, the assets used, the risks assumed, and the costs incurred by members of the MNE group in developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting intangibles are in alignment with the allocation of entitlement to intangible related returns in the relevant registrations and contracts; and (iii) whether services rendered, in connection with developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting intangibles, by other members of the MNE group to the Source: 5 Par. 6 OECD Discussion Draft, June 6, 2012 5 Par. 7 OECD Discussion Draft, June 6, 2012 6 Par. 7 OECD Discussion Draft, June 6, 2012 7 Par. 8 OECD Discussion Draft, June 6, 2012 8 Par. 9 OECD Discussion Draft, June 6, 2012 13 member or members of the MNE group entitled to intangible related returns under the relevant registrations and contracts, are compensated on an arm’s length basis under the relevant circumstances. 9 This concept outlines the requirements to be entitled to claim returns that are a result of an intangible. In order for an entity to have the rights to these returns, they must hold the set of legal rights, contracts or other agreements to the intangible while performing and controlling the functions related to developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting the intangible. The party claiming entitlement to the returns must also assume the risks that correspond to the functions associated with the intangible. In this context the Discussion Draft is aligned with the “control over risks” concept found in paragraph 9.23 10. When these factors are aligned an entity within an MNE is entitled to intangible related returns. Section D of the Discussion Draft provides new guidance regarding the valuation of intangibles. It is still required to apply the arm’s length principle to any transactions that take place between related parties involving an intangible. The first step of assessing the value of the intangibles is also expected to utilize market based comparables in order to achieve a suitable arm’s length valuation of the intangible. Readers of the Discussion Draft should keep in mind that the contents are likely to be modified and have not been enacted by members of the OECD. It is clear that the OECD has taken into account feedback from practitioners and is continuing to work towards guidelines that are beneficial for tax authorities and taxpayers alike. With this Discussion Draft, there are sizeable changes that will have a profound impact on issues relating to transfer pricing and intangibles. 1.4 How do emerging jurisdictions (i.e. BRICS) deal with intangibles 11 As emerging countries like India, Brazil and China develop more complex tax legislation and advanced regulations on transfer pricing, the challenges of handling transfer pricing risk in these countries also increases. 9 Source: Par. 29 OECD Discussion Draft, 6 June, 2012 10 Source: Par 9.23 Chapter XI July 2010 OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines 11 Contributions from Dr. Jian Li of TPA Asia and Mr. Vishnu Bagri of ACCRETIVE Business Consulting 14 As China continues to develop its tax laws and legislation, there are likely to be more transfer pricing controversies in China in the coming years. Some current issues include the number of local tax authorities that collect taxes and the overlay of the State Administration of Taxation (SAT), the difficult legal framework for the protection of intellectual property rights in general, and the speed with which the Chinese economy is creating value for Chinese businesses and the country as a whole. As the number of consumable products that bear the label “Made in China” has increased over the past decade, it is clear that there is a very strong incentive for the SAT to capitalize on the large potential tax revenue. The SAT is looking closely at how intangibles of MNEs are being used in the context of transfer pricing in China. An additional country with emerging transfer pricing challenges is India. There have been considerable changes to this tax jurisdiction among which is an evolving view of how intangibles should be dealt with as well as an increase in scrutiny of intra-company transactions in general. The term intangible property has been broadened by Indian tax authorities to include the following intangible assets: marketing, technology related (process patents, technical documentation etc.), artistic related, data processing related, engineering related, customer related, human capital related (trained work force, agreements, union contracts, etc.) location related (leasehold interest, water rights, etc.), contract related, goodwill related, methods, programs, systems, procedures, campaigns, surveys, studies, forecasts, estimates, customer lists or technical data, anything which derives value from intellectual content rather than physical attributes. These and other changes have given rise to a more advanced tax system that will certainly increase the challenges of transfer pricing that takes place in India. 1.5 Transfer Pricing & Intangibles: four functional variables In addressing intangibles, a distinction between the following four functional variables can be made: 1. Label: What is the label of the intangible? Example: a patent. 2. Identification: How do you identify an intangible? Example: a logo on a sports shoe. 3. Owner: Who owns the intangible? Example: a company who has registered the trade name. 4. Valuation: What is the value? Example: when a transfer of intangibles occurs the value needs to be determined. 15 The following types of professionals, however, might have a different view on handling each of the four functional variables described above. • • • • • • IP lawyers; Accountants; Tax/transfer pricing professionals; IP management professionals; Bankruptcy consultants; Anti-trust lawyers. As a result, a total of 24 different ways to approach and discuss the topic of intangibles can be created. The following IPR Matrix (see www.iprplaza.com 12) provides a summary of the four functional variables according to the various disciplines of professionals involved. 12 IPR Plaza is a multidisciplinary portal that provides free-of-charge qualitative and quantitative information on intangibles. IPR Plaza is empowered by different leading IP advisory firms and delivers up-to-date guidance on intangibles from IP Law, Accounting, IP Management, Antitrust, and Tax/Transfer Pricing perspectives. The first block filters information from public sources, while the second block allows users to go back to the original definition of an intangible. The third block provides quantitative information on intangibles, which can be applied by doing your own valuations, and provides a practical quickscan on how to manage intangibles. 16 Source: www.iprplaza.com 1.5.1 Label From a tax or transfer pricing perspective, intellectual property has a broader perspective and more often than not, it is difficult to label intangibles since not all valuable intangible assets are legally protected and registered or recorded on balance sheets. OECD Guidelines do not provide any specific definition of intangibles; however, list different kinds of intangibles: • Rights to use industrial assets such as patents, trademarks, trade names, designs or models; • Literary and artistic property rights; and • Intellectual property, such as know-how and trade secrets. In order to better understand intangibles from a tax and transfer pricing perspective the OECD Guidelines (2010) categorizes different types of intangibles into commercial intangibles and marketing intangibles. 17 Commercial Intangibles: include patents, know-how, designs, and models that are used for the production of a good or the provision of a service, as well as intangible rights that are themselves business assets transferred to customers or used in the operation of business (e.g. computer software). Marketing Intangibles: include trademarks and trade names that aid in the commercial exploitation of a product or service, customer lists, distribution channels, and unique names, symbols, or pictures that have an important promotional value for the product concerned. Commercial intangibles other than marketing intangibles are considered as trade intangibles. In the Discussion Draft, the OECD chose to not include or focus on any categories relating to the labelling of intangibles. 1.5.2 Identification From a tax or transfer pricing perspective, the identification of intangibles is a critical step in determining ownership, and in turn, determining which party is eligible to receive income from that IP. Intangibles can either be remunerated, i.e. royalty payments, or used free of charge by other group companies (often in good faith). In case of free of charge access to the intangible, no agreement will be in place, which makes it difficult to determine the existence of such intangible assets. In the Discussion Draft, there are new factors used to identify and categorize intangibles. The factors prescribed by the OECD assist in the process of identifying intangibles and will have a notable impact on how intangibles are identified in the context of transfer pricing. The OECD introduces the idea of economically significant intangibles and delineates the fact that not all intangibles contribute to the creation of economic returns. It is also stressed that there must be a thorough functional analysis and justification for the aggregation of various intangibles, and that “it is not sufficient to suggest that vaguely specified or undifferentiated intangibles have an effect on arm’s length prices or other conditions.” 13 There are also procedures that are used by tax and transfer pricing specialists to further identify intangibles. The procedures are: • 13 Interviews with relevant officers involved with the development, usage or management of IP. For example, the responsible person for research & development in an MNE will be Source: Par. 12 OECD Discussion Draft, 6 June, 2012 18 • • able to provide indications of protected/unprotected patents or not yet finalized R&D projects, which may ultimately result in a registered patent. An industry analysis investigating relevant industry IP could provide details about existing IP within the multinational, particularly in cases where it has not been registered, protected, or capitalized in the balance sheet. A functional analysis can identify IP according to its functional characteristics (protectable or not, published or not, registered or not, willingness from customer to pay a premium or not, multiyear positive contribution of cash flow of multinational). 1.5.3 Ownership The process of determining the owner of an intangible can become difficult when one entity is the legal owner and another is the economic owner. The legal owner refers to the entity that is considered the owner under intellectual property law, while the economic owner refers to the entity that has the right to the income attributable to the ownership of the asset, such as royalties. Another way to determine ownership is looking at the degree of centralization. Centralized ownership can have the following attributes: a single company in the group that owns the intangibles legally and economically and has license agreements with other group entities, a situation which can create opportunities for tax planning. A distributed or joined ownership, on the other hand, has the following attributes: a number of group companies that share ownership of intangibles on a pre-determined basis, always involves some form of shared economic ownership, usually takes the form of a R&D cost contribution or cost-sharing R&D arrangement. In addition, the OECD Guidelines offer two standards about the ownership of intangibles: Legal ownership is typically assigned according to the legal title and legal protection of the intellectual property. Thus, the intellectual property can be legally protected in the country it is registered, such as patents and trademark. For patents and trademarks, the owner can protect their intellectual property by registering them; however, for embedded intangibles like know- how, it may be harder to use a legal system to protect it. Legal ownership offers the owner the protections and the rights to utilize the IP to generate further benefits and prevent others from using the intangible. Economic ownership refers to a situation when the intangible is not legally protected or it is difficult to identify the legal owner of the intangible so economic ownership is then considered. Economic ownership can be determined by analysing the relative contributions to the intangibles by each party. 19 Though legal ownership is usually the starting point of defining ownership, there are cases where ownership lies elsewhere, such as with the licensee. The following circumstances describe instances when the ownership does not lie with the legal owner but with the economic owner. • The license is issued exclusively, • The license is issued for an indefinite period or at least a period that concurs with the expected economic life of the intangible, • The licensor has no economic interest in the intangible, for instance when the royalties are not dependent on turnover, and • The licensee is allowed to transfer the license without the licensor’s permission. In the Discussion Draft, the OECD has introduced a new concept of “entitlement to intangibles related returns.” This concept requires an entity that is claiming the right to returns that stem from an intangible to poses the legal agreements and contracts that are related to an intangible, exercise control over the risks borne and costs incurred while performing the functions related to developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting an intangible. If the functions, risks and legal agreements are aligned, the entity is entitled to the returns related to intangibles. 1.5.4 Valuation Tax and transfer pricing professionals are mainly concerned with the valuation of intangible assets in the intra-group context. In assessing the appropriate value for any IP transferred between related parties, professionals refer to the "fair market value", a concept that is defined by the OECD Guidelines 14. Fair market value is the estimated amount for which an asset could be exchanged in arm's length transactions as if the two parties were unrelated. The challenge is that intangibles are not priced by standard pricing mechanisms in the open marketplace, so the perspectives of both the transferor of the property and the transferee must be taken into account in order to determine a proper price for the IP. The three methods that are used by tax and transfer pricing professionals when determining the value of IP are: the cost method, the market method, and the income method. The general guidance for applying the arm's length principle, as outlined in Chapter 1 of the OECD Guidelines, pertains equally to the determination of transfer pricing between related 14 Source: OECD Guidelines, paragraph 1.42 ‘Evaluation of separate and combined transactions’, “(...) in order to arrive at the most precise approximation of fair market value, the arm's length principle should be applied on a transaction-by transaction basis (...)” 20 parties for IP related transactions. This principle can however be difficult to apply to controlled transactions involving intangible property because such property has a special character complicating the search for comparables and in some cases making it difficult to accurately determine the value at the time of the transaction. Arm's length pricing for IP-related transactions should take into account, for the purposes of comparability, the perspective of the transferor of the property and the transferee. From the perspective of the transferor, the arm's length principle would examine the pricing at which a comparable independent enterprise would be willing to transfer the property. From the perspective of the transferee, the transferee will generally be prepared to pay for the IP if the benefit it reasonably expects to secure from the use of the intangibles is satisfactory having regard to other options realistically available. According to paragraph 9.80 of the OECD Guidelines, “an essential part of the analysis of a business restructuring is to identify the significant intangible assets that were transferred (if any), whether independent parties would have remunerated their transfer, and what their arm’s length value is.” In the Discussion Draft on intangibles, assigning value to intangibles is addressed in section D. The OECD chose to focus on transactional value, factors for addressing valuation, methods of assessing value and valuation techniques. The factors that are related to assessing the value of the intangibles for comparability include: • exclusivity • extent and duration of legal protection • geographic scope • useful life • stage of development • rights to enhancements, revisions, and updates; • expectation of future benefit In the context of valuation, the Discussion Draft provides some freedom in circumstances when reliable comparables are not available to apply the appropriate valuation technique to accurately price an intangible. “It should be emphasised that the characterisation of the transaction as the provision of products or services or the transfer of intangibles or a combination of both does not necessarily dictate the use of a particular transfer pricing method.” 15 The Discussion Draft presents explanations and examples of various valuation 15 Source: Par. 75 OECD Discussion Draft, 6 June, 2012 21 methods, but emphasizes that seeking a comparable transaction to evaluate the tested party is the first step that should be taken in determining the value of an intangible for an intercompany transaction. 1.6 Locating IP in tax advantaged jurisdictions Because a high percentage of value-add within an MNE is created by intangibles, there is a considerable incentive for MNEs to reduce their tax burdens by shifting IP related functions to tax jurisdictions with lower tax considerations. In response to this, the OECD and its member countries have taken specific steps to address this view. The first issue that tax authorities have begun to evaluate is the effective place of management. When evaluating the functions and risks that are assumed by companies, tax authorities have focused on the alignment of risk and assets with effective management. This is a shift of focus from the previous standard of purely legal agreements. The criterion that is applied to these types of companies is the level of decision making and management power that the foreign controlled company has. In the Laerstate BV court case, brought before the UK Tribunal in 2009, the evaluation of the management functions of the company proved to be the most important component of the Tribunal’s decision. 16 The Tribunal wrote, “An objective way of testing whether this is the case is to ask whether the directors have the absolute minimum amount of information that a person would need to have in order to be able to make a decision at all on whether to agree to follow the shareholders wishes or to decide not to sign.” As companies have increased their distribution of risks and functions related to IP, there has also been an increase in the number of cases and regulations that deal directly with this issue. One set of rules that was designed to focus on limiting the practice of tax avoiding is the Controlled Foreign Corporation (“CFC”) law that was introduced by major industrial countries. For example under UK tax law a CFC is defined as a company, which is a resident outside the UK, while being controlled for 50 percent or more by a UK company. There are tax incentives that are associated with this ruling. One of the tax incentives for a CFC is the fact that it is subject to a lower level of taxation, roughly three quarters of the corresponding UK corporate income tax. 16 Source: Laerstate BV v. HMRC (2009) UKFTT 2009 (TC). 22 As the number of companies that are handling IP and functions related to it has increased, the OECD and tax authorities around the world have also placed a greater focus on the substance of the company that is responsible for the IP. In order to be entitled to economic returns that are related to intangibles, the company typically must meet a certain number of specific requirements. These requirements are generally: • payroll requirements/number of full time equivalents; • minimum capital requirements; • minimum revenue thresholds; • minimum amount of investment/spending; • reporting requirements; • requirements in relation to activities/number of activities; and • other requirements. These requirements are a good point of evaluation to determine the alignment of managerial functions, risk assumed and legal agreements between the parties involved. Tax authorities are most interested in the concepts of “substance” and “control over risk.” In order to determine if the risk that is transferred is aligned with the legal, managerial and accounting systems, tax authorities evaluate the structure of the company and where the actual control of risks takes place. The OECD Guidelines make it clear that the entity designated as the owner of the IP must be in control of the management functions related to the IP and that it has the financial capability to assume the risk of decisions that are associated with investment in IP. If these essential components are not established, tax authorities will likely raise questions over the commercial substance of the agreement between the two parties. ‘‘Control’’ in this context is elaborated on in paragraph 9.23 of the OECD Guidelines where it is defined as, ‘‘… the capacity to make decisions to take on the risk (decision to put the capital at risk) and decisions on whether and how to manage the risk, internally or using an external provider. This would require the company to have people– employees or directors – who have the authority to, and effectively do, perform these control functions.” Chapter 9 further explains that not all of the functions must be performed by employees or directors, but that managers must be able to evaluate the performance of the outsourced functions on a day-to-day basis and have the ability to make decisions regarding that performance. The OECD, as outlined in the Discussion Draft, now states that the functions that relate to the development, enhancement, maintenance and protection of an intangible 23 and the entity controlling these functions, as well as exercising control over risks relating to those functions should be the entity which is entitled to intangible related returns. 1.7 Transfer Pricing Risks (1): Court Cases on Intangibles In recent years, tax authorities around the world have challenged taxpayers on various issues in relation to intercompany transactions involving intangibles. This has resulted in a sizeable increase of transfer pricing court cases on intangibles. Some of the key court cases and trends relating to transfer pricing and intangibles include: • USA: DHL, Veritas and Glaxo court cases • Europe: Various court cases pending • Asia: Maruti-Suzuki, various valuation of intangibles which are being transferred to tax favourable hubs such as Singapore The remainder of this chapter presents a summary of the facts, key arguments and decisions pertaining to four landmark court cases dealing with intangibles from a transfer pricing perspective: DHL, Veritas, Maruti-Suzuki and GlaxoSmithKline. 1.7.1 DHL 17 The DHL case positioned around a split of a trademark value between a US headquarter office, called DHL and its Hong Kong subsidiary, called DHLI, which needed the trademark for handling a courier business outside the US. DHLI bore the publicity cost of the network outside the US. DHLI had obtained a license under the trademark in its territory. On July 9, 1990, DHL and DHLI executed an agreement, granting DHLI an option to purchase the DHL trademark for $ 20 million, based on an internal valuation exercise and confirmed by an external valuation firm. The U.S. Tax Court of First Instance provided a step-by-step reasoning of its valuation method. First, the U.S. Tax Court attained a $ 300 million value for unbooked intangibles, based on a third party consortium payment for DHLI’s excess value. Second, the U.S. Tax Court determined that one half thereof was attributable to the trademark. Third, the U.S. Tax Court determined that two-thirds of the value of the trademark, i.e. $ 100 million, was attributable to the non-US rights to the trademark. Fourth, the U.S. Tax Court discounted the non-US rights by 50% to take account of marketability constraints possibly connected 17 Source: DHL Corp, 76 CCHTCM 1122, 89 AFTR 2d 2002-1978, 285 F3d 1210, 2002-1 USTC. 24 with DHL’s ownership of the foreign trademark rights. As a result the U.S. Tax Court concluded that domestic and foreign trademark rights amounted to $ 50 million each. The next point to decide concerned the imputation of royalty payments from DHLI to DHL, being the legal owner of the trademark. The U.S. Tax Court held that such imputation was justified with reference to the legal ownership of the trademark by DHL. Therefore it allocated $ 50 million in addition to DHL to account for imputed royalty payments. The Tax Court imputed substantial understatement penalties for unpaid royalties and a gross valuation misstatement penalty for the amount allocated to DHL in respect of the sale of the trademark itself. The Court of Appeal affirmed the valuation by the U.S. Tax Court of the trademark at the amount of $ 100 million, based on a $ 50 million figure for the domestic rights and a $ 50 million figure for the foreign rights. However the 9th Circuit Court of Appeals principally reversed the full allocation of both amounts to DHL only. Instead it allocated the $ 50 million value of the foreign trademark rights to DHLI, based upon the old IRS regulations section 482 developer-assistor regulations as DHLI had incurred major expenditures to develop the trademark outside the US. With respect to the imputed royalty payments the Court of Appeal rejected the imputed royalty payments following a similar reasoning concerning the developer-assister doctrine. The party that incurred the costs and risks of developing the intangible should not be required to pay a royalty to use the intangible. The penalties were rejected in total. The first one, because no imputation of royalty payments was justified and the second one because DHL showed good faith by obtaining a comfort letter from its external appraisal firm. 1.7.2 Maruti-Suzuki 18 Maruti, an Indian company engaged in the manufacture and sale of automobiles, entered into a license agreement with Japanese-based competitor Suzuki for the manufacture and sale of cars. On the strength of this license agreement Maruti was allowed to use the Suzuki trademark in combination with the Maruti trademark thus reinforcing the local market position for the relevant cars. In effect Maruti used the Suzuki trademark/logo in 18 Source: Maruti Suzuki India Ltd. v. Additional Commissioner of Income Tax Transfer Pricing Officer New Delhi, W.P. (C) 6876/2008 High Court of Delhi at New Delhi, 2010. 25 combination with the Maruti trademark/logo on the front side whereas it continued to use the mark ‘Maruti’ along with the word ‘Suzuki’ on the rear side of the cars. According to the Transfer Pricing Officer (“TPO”) the trademark ‘Suzuki’ had piggybacked on the trademark “Maruti” without payment of any compensation. In addition the TPO came to the conclusion that the trademark “Maruti” had acquired the value of a super brand whereas the trademark “Suzuki” was a relatively weak brand in the Indian market. The TPO concluded that the promotion of the co-branded trademark “Maruti-Suzuki” had resulted in impairment of the “Maruti” trademark. Ultimately Maruti, according to the TPO, incurred major expenditures on account of marketing/promotion in excess of standard norms and should have been rewarded for the development of the resulting marketing intangible. The High Court decided in favour of Maruti. The Court made the following considerations: • There is no justification for any payment from Suzuki to Maruti on account of use and application of the Maruti trademark or logo to the benefit of Suzuki. The Court cannot agree that Maruti had become a “superbrand.” Maruki faced intensified competition from major foreign passenger car manufacturers and felt the need therefore to reinforce its position by in-licencing the technical know-how, trademark and logo of Suzuki in order to uphold its customer base. • If an independent domestic entity uses a foreign trademark or logo, no payment is necessary unless it is agreed; • If an associated domestic entity uses trademarks or logos on its products no payment to the foreign owner should be made in case the use of the foreign trademark or logo concerned is discretionary for the domestic entity. However the income from such international transactions must be determined at arm’s length. • If the domestic entity is mandatorily required to use the foreign trademark or logo on its products, appropriate payment should be made by the foreign entity to the domestic entity on account of the benefit it derives from the marketing intangibles relating to the respective products. • In the case described in the foregoing paragraph, the arm’s length price with respect to the international transaction between the two entities should be determined taking into consideration the value of the marketing intangibles obtained by the foreign entity on account of its compulsory use of the trademark or logo by the domestic entity. • Compensation of promotional, advertising and/or general marketing expenses by the foreign company is required only if and insofar the corresponding expenses exceed the expenses which a similarly situated and comparable independent domestic entity would have incurred. 26 1.7.3 Veritas19 Veritas Software Corporation (“Veritas Software”), a US entity, entered into a cost sharing agreement (“CSA”) with its wholly owned subsidiary Veritas Ireland to enable the latter to use its pre-existing intangible assets. The CSA was part of a comprehensive set of transactions entailing the transfer of all sales agreements with its European-based subsidiaries to Veritas Ireland. In addition Veritas Software and Veritas Ireland entered into a research and development agreement and a technology license agreement. On the verge of the technology license agreement Veritas Software granted Veritas Ireland the right to use certain covered intangibles as well as certain trademarks, trade names and service marks. Veritas Software charged Veritas Ireland a buy-in payment of US $118 million on the strength of the then prevailing US Cost-Sharing Regulations calculated, applying the Comparable Uncontrolled Transaction method pursuant to US 482, section 4-a Regulations. The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) disputed the methodology and calculation implemented by Veritas Software using the income valuation method analysis resulting in a US$ 2.5 billion (round figure) present value for US corporate taxation purposes. The reasoning of the IRS boiled down to the following components: • • • • The intangible assets, derived from research and development in the US, were unique in providing perpetual useful life characteristics. Synergetic effect with other assets was basic in ascertaining value of the shared assets. The buy-in transaction was considered to be akin to a sale of assets. Approach of the IRS was package-related and applied a multiplier in order to reach a profitability profile. The Court found that the akin to a sale doctrine misconceives the fact that the intangible assets should be characterized as short-lived and could therefore not be considered as perpetual life assets. The Court also asserted that in such cases, future intangibles were included in the calculation base. The Court estimated the average lifetime of the pertaining intangible assets to be four (4) years. In addition it found that the IRS used the wrong “beta’’ and equity risk premium. 19 Source: Veritas Software Corp. 133 TC 297, Dec. 58.016 (2009). 27 Finally, the Court concluded that the IRS departed from unrealistic growth rates. The Court therefore ruled in favour of Veritas. 1.7.4 GlaxoSmithKline 20 This major case centred around the question whether the drug called ‘Zantac’, derived its primary value from marketing efforts in the US instead of from research and development performed by its UK headquarters. The IRS asserted that GlaxoSmithKline (“Glaxo”) US took full responsibility for the marketing of the drug on the US market. Glaxo US should have invoiced Glaxo UK a marketing services fee. Further, the IRS converted the transfer price to a contract manufacturing mark-up and lowered the royalty percentage from the license agreement concluded between Glaxo US and Glaxo UK. Glaxo US applied the resale price method whereas the IRS applied the residual profit split method to arrive to their respective profit allocation. In its deficiency note the IRS claimed that Glaxo US was the economic owner of the US marketing intangible since Glaxo US was considered to be the developer of said intangible which was tantamount to a royalty-free license under the intangible and the trademark from Glaxo US to Glaxo UK. The case was ultimately settled in 2006 at US$3.1 billion and as such there is no verdict of the Court and ensuing transfer pricing jurisprudence. As marketing and its connected expenditures are more than once at the centre of discussion with respect to their (embedded) intangible characteristics it is unfortunate that the Court was not in a position to enunciate proper guidelines. However, the case will remain to play a leading role in upcoming disputes about the core issue whether the critical success factor of a drug is to be attached to research, development or design achievements or to comprehensive strategic marketing decisions at the domestic level. 1.8 Transfer Pricing Risks (2): Corporate Reputation at Risk Through SEC Disclosure of Intercompany Transactions In recent years governments around the world have increased documentation and disclosure requirements related to transfer pricing. As of Fiscal Year (FY) 2010, the United States Internal Revenue Service (IRS) introduced Schedule UTP, which requires the disclosure of detailed information on uncertain tax positions, including transfer pricing 20 Source: GlaxoSmithKline Holdings (Americas) Inc., TC Nos 5750-04 and 6959-05, 2006. 28 positions. In September 2011, the first group of US taxpayers filing Form 1120, 1120-F, 1120-L, or 1120-PC were required to disclose their uncertain tax positions on Schedule UTP when the taxpayer or a related party had (1) one or more uncertain tax positions as part of their 2010 ASC 740/FIN 48 analyses and (2) total assets equal to or in excess of $100 million. The total asset threshold will be reduced to $50 million in FY 2012 and to $10 million starting with FY 2014. In the United States, the IRS has also increased penalties for failure to accurately file related-party disclosure forms (Forms 5471 and 5472). According to an article in the February 2012 BNA Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report titled “SEC Comment Letters Show Inquiries into Firms’ Transfer Pricing Activities” 21, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) investigated seven U.S. public companies regarding transfer pricing disclosures made within their financial statements or other related government filings. These seven companies include Amazon.com, Inc.; China United Insurance Service, Inc.; Google, Inc.; Honda Motor Co., Ltd.; Pitney Bowes, Inc.; Red Hat, Inc.; and VASCO Data Security International, Inc. In the case of Amazon.com, the corporation had a $1.5 USD billion tax increase related to transfer pricing. The SEC rejected the China United Insurance Services original IPO request due to the fact that it failed to fully disclose the relationship between its management and one of its Chinese affiliates in the registration papers. The Google case involved a SEC inquiry about the proper disclosure of its 2006 Advance Pricing Agreement (APA) in the company’s financial statements. Honda Motors was scrutinized about a $7.7 USD billion provision for a transfer pricing dispute dating back from 2001-2006. Additionally, some other well-known corporations have also recently made the headlines for their transfer pricing practices. According to the 2011 Boston Scientific Annual Report, the IRS proposed a $581 USD million tax liability in connection with the transfer pricing of technology license agreements between domestic and foreign subsidiaries of Guidant Corporation. The September 2011 10Q for Cardinal Health reported that the IRS had proposed additional taxes of $849 USD million for transfer pricing arrangements between foreign and domestic subsidiaries, including the transfer of intellectual property, based on an audit of fiscal years 2001 through 2010. Stryker Corporation, in its 2011 SEC filings, mentioned IRS proposed adjustments on the company’s 2006 and 2007 income tax returns due to tax positions taken on its cost sharing arrangements with entities operating in Ireland. 21 Bloomberg BNA, Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report, “SEC Comment Letters Show Inquiries into Firms’ Transfer Pricing Activities”, Volume 20 Number 20, February 23, 2012. 29 As seen from the examples above, transfer pricing has become one of the key topics that US tax authorities have scrutinized in recent investigations. In testimony to Congress earlier this year, IRS Commissioner Douglas Shulman stated that Section 482, allocation of income including transfer pricing, was one of the top three IRS Code sections disclosed by taxpayers on their 2010 Schedule UTP and that 19% of all issues disclosed were transfer pricing issues. Furthermore, the proposed 2013 IRS budget specifically noted the goal to enhance oversight of complex financial situations, including transfer pricing and uncertain tax positions. These current situations have forced taxpayers to review their transfer pricing transactions in more detail, in order to prevent their corporate reputation from being harmed by such public disclosures, which can be perceived as negative in the eyes of the general public. 1.9 Introduction to lessons 2-7 Lesson 2: Transfer Pricing Labels of intangibles, identification of intangibles, ownership of intangibles This Lesson evaluates the labels that are applied to intangibles in the context of transfer pricing by utilizing four functional variables. The definitions of intangibles are evaluated from a legal, tax, and accounting perspective. The lesson then examines methods for applying labels to intangibles and how to properly identify the rightful owners and which entity is entitled to the returns related to an intangible. Lesson 3: Valuation of intangibles Lesson 3 provides the reader a clear picture of the various aspects of assessing the value of an intangible for transfer pricing purposes. This is accomplished through providing relevant background information, introducing components of valuation methods and applying these ideas to real world examples of highly valued companies that utilize intangibles in their business models. After introducing these concepts, practical methods of assessing value are examined. Lesson 4: Business models: IP configurations Lesson 4 describes how and where intangibles are located in the value chain of multinational enterprises. This is accomplished through evaluating these business models from a general business/commercial perspective as well as from a transfer pricing perspective. The reader then is presented with case studies and questions to evaluate different practical examples. 30 Lesson 5: Intellectual Property Law and Transfer Pricing Lesson 5 examines the legal system surrounding intellectual property (IP) rights. The lesson provides a brief history of IP rights in the legal context, discusses the future of IP rights, and looks at the different types of legally recognized IP rights. The lesson also further explores on the legal aspects of IP exploitation, IP management, and IP transfer. How to protect intangibles through IP law, corporate law, contract law and labour law is also examined. Lesson 6: Accounting Definitions of Intellectual Property and Transfer Pricing Lesson 6 provides a high level overview of the accounting standards relating to intangible assets. The lesson focuses on the recognition and measurement of intangibles according to accounting principles. The lesson also examines the differences in the valuation of IP according to IFRS, US GAAP, and Canadian GAAP. Lesson 7: Corporate Income Tax Aspects of IP and Transfer Pricing This Lesson outlines the corporate income tax aspects related to intangibles and transfer pricing. The lesson touches on many tax aspects including amortization, tax credits, capital gains tax, value-added tax, and more. This is done by providing several examples from different countries to highlight how intangible property is taxed around the world. 1.10 Questions 1. Which court case resulted in a tax valuation of domestic and foreign trademarks in the amount of $100 Million: A. DHL Ltd. B. GlaxoSmithKline C. Maruti-Suzuki D. Veritas Software Corporation 2. Which of the following is not a functional variable of intangibles: A. Ownership B. Identification C. Label D. Value E. All of the above are functional variables 31 3. Which of the following is not a factor related to comparability in valuation according to the Discussion Draft: A. Exclusivity B. Stage of Development C. Geographic Scope D. Amount of innovation E. All of the above are factors relating to comparability in valuation according to the Discussion Draft. 4. True or False: India has a more narrow definition of intangibles than what is outlined in the OECD Guidelines Chapter VI and the Discussion Draft: A. True B. False 5. The term “control over risk” is explained in which paragraph of the OECD Guidelines: A. Paragraph 4.15 B. Paragraph 9.23 C. Paragraph 6.39 D. Paragraph 3.78 6. Which of the following is a company with recent SEC disclosures on “Uncertain Tax Positions”: A. Microsoft Corporation B. Lockheed Martin C. Pitney Bowes Ltd. D. Toyota Motor Corporation 1.11 Answers 1. A. 2. E. 3. D. 4. B. 32 5. B. 6. C. 1.12 Literature Mandatory Reading: • 6 June 2012 Discussion Draft of the Proposed Revisions to Chapter 6 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines • Chapter VI OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines July, 2010 Optional Reading: • TPA’s Press Release regarding Discussion Draft of the Proposed Revisions to Chapter 6 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines • Public Comments found on the OECD website regarding intangibles: http://www.oecd.org/document/5/0,3746,en_2649_33753_46030661_1_1_1_1,00. html • IP companies and substance: no-fly zones? Steef Huibregtse, Mark Peeters, Louan Verdoner and Steven Carey. http://www.tpa-global.com/PDF/Publications/TPAIPcompanies.pdf • Bloomberg BNA, Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report, “SEC Comment Letters Show Inquiries into Firms’ Transfer Pricing Activities”, Volume 20 Number 20, February 23, 2012 33 34 2 Transfer Pricing Labels of intangibles, identification of intangibles, ownership of intangibles Authors: Steef Huibregtse/Lukasz Kubicki 35 2.1 Introduction When interacting with intangibles in a transfer pricing context, it is best to evaluate the intangible with four functional variables. These functional variables are: • The label associated with an intangible; • The Identification of an intangible; • The owner of an intangible; and • The value of an intangible. These labels provide a clear method for understanding the various aspects that are important to the intangible and allow for the creation of an effective transfer pricing solution. This lesson will examine the functional variables in order to provide a better understanding of the methods to evaluate an intangible. 2.2 Definition of intangibles There are many definitions of intangibles for legal, accounting, and tax/transfer pricingrelated purposes. In practice, MNEs have to deal with all of these definitions when for example protecting its intellectual property, recognizing intangibles on a balance sheet or determining tax consequences of intra group licensing policies. Below we will discuss in more detail existing definitions and their origin. 2.2.1 Legal perspective 22 IP law focuses on the protection of the intellectual property and the pursuit of infringement of the owner’s intellectual property. In order to proper protect any owner’s intellectual property, IP law offer different definitions of different kind of intellectual property. We will use IP law in the U.S. and international conventions as examples to illustrate how intellectual property can be defined. Patent: In order to qualify for a patentable invention, the invention should have three characteristics: 1) Novelty; which means that the subject matter is new taking into account the publicly available state of the art; 2) non-obviousness, the invention has to be nonobvious to a person skilled in the art; and 3) utility, meaning that the invention should be capable to being applicable in the field of industry (including agriculture). 22 For more information about U.S. IP Law, please visit http://www.uspto.gov/. For more information about European IP Law, please visit http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/internal_market/businesses/intellectual_property/index_en.htm 36 Copyrights: Under U.S. law, the author of a work is automatically the owner of the copyright in the work. If an employee creates a work as part of his employment, the employer is considered to be the "author" for copyright purposes. Under U.S. copyright law, software is considered to be a “literary work” and is protected by the copyright law. Trademarks: A trademark includes any word, name, symbol, device, or any combination, used, or intended to be used, in commerce to identify and distinguish the goods of one manufacturer or seller from goods manufactured or sold by others, and to indicate the source of the goods. Trade Secrets: Trade secret is protected by contract law. Trade secret law protects any secret process, technique or information which gives the owner a competitive advantage. If the owner of a trade secret fears that his trade secret is being used by a competitor or by an employee or customer in an improper manner, he can bring suit to enforce his rights under the applicable contracts and, under appropriate circumstances, obtain an injunction preventing use of the trade secret and requiring that all matters pertaining to the trade secret be returned to the owner. Industrial design: An industrial design is the ornamental or aesthetic aspect of an article. The design may consist of three-dimensional features, such as the shape or surface of an article, or of two-dimensional features, such as patterns, lines or colour. Industrial designs are applied to a wide variety of products of industry and handicraft: from technical and medical instruments to watches, jewellery, and other luxury items; from housewares and electrical appliances to vehicles and architectural structures; from textile designs to leisure goods. To be protected under most national laws, an industrial design must be new and/or original. Novelty or originality is determined with respect to the existing design corpus. An industrial design is primarily of an aesthetic nature, and does not protect any technical features of the article to which it is applied. Geographical indications: A geographical indication (GI) is a sign used on goods that have a specific geographical origin and possess qualities, reputation or characteristics that are essentially attributable to that origin. An appellation of origin (AO) is a special kind of GI. GIs are protected in accordance with international treaties and national laws under a wide range of concepts, including laws specifically for the protection of GIs or AOs, trademark laws in the form of collective marks or certification marks, laws against unfair competition, consumer protection laws, or specific laws or decrees that recognize individual GIs. 37 2.2.2 Accounting perspective According to IAS 38 intangible assets are “identifiable nonmonetary assets without physical substance.” 23 An asset is a resource that is controlled by the entity as a result of past events (for example, purchase or self-creation) and from which future economic benefits (inflows of cash or other assets) are expected. Additionally, IAS 38 states that “requires an entity to recognize an intangible asset if, and only if, specified criteria are met.” 24 Thus, the three critical attributes of an intangible asset are: • Identification, • control (power to obtain benefits from the asset), • future economic benefits (such as revenues or reduced future costs). IAS 38 provides practical guidelines and standards of how to handle intangible assets from an accounting perspective. The areas that IAS 38 focuses on are the process of recognition and measurement, specific guidance on internally generated intangible assets, measurement after recognition, the useful life of an intangible and how to evaluate intangible assets with finite and indefinite useful lives. This standard provides clarity on how to view intangible assets in the discipline of accounting. 2.2.3 Tax perspective OECD model tax convention provides principles of international taxation and transfer pricing. Article 9 of the model convention defines the arm’s length principle which is further elaborated in the OECD TP Guidelines which in turn, are followed by most of the OECD countries. The commentary to the OECD model tax convention provides examples of the intangible assets. Accordingly the intangible asset is a “property such as patents, procedures and similar property”. Also the OECD model tax convention provides the definition of know-how which is described as “undivulged information of an industrial, commercial or scientific nature arising from previous experience, which has practical application in the operation of an enterprise and from the disclosure of which an economic benefit can be derived”. The OECD Model tax convention further deals with the intangible assets in Chapter 12. Although it does not define intangibles directly, it defines term royalties as “consideration for the use of, or the right to use, any copyright or literary, artistic or scientific work including 23 Source: IAS 38, (IASB April 2009) 24 Source: IAS 38, (IASB April 2009) 38 cinematograph films, any patents, trade mark, design or model, plan secret formula, or process, or for information concerning industrial, commercial or scientific experience”. According to the OECD TP Guidelines an intangible is defined as the asset “that is used in commercial activities such as the production of a good or the provision of a service, as well as an intangible right that is itself a business asset transferred to customers or used in the operation of business.“ Also, according to the OECD TP Guidelines, the term "intangible property" includes rights to use industrial assets such as patents, trademarks, trade names, designs or models. It also includes literary and artistic property rights, and intellectual property such as know-how and trade secrets. These intangibles are assets that may have considerable value even though they may have no book value in the company's balance sheet. There also may be considerable risks associated with them (e.g., contract or product liability and environmental damages). OECD identifies two main categories of intangibles i.e. trade and marketing intangibles. These categories are further discussed below. 2.2.3.1 Trade intangibles Trade intangibles often are created through risky and costly research and development (R&D) activities, and the developer generally tries to recover the expenditures on these activities and obtain a return thereon through product sales, service contracts, or licence agreements. The developer may perform the research activity in its own name, i.e. with the intention of having legal and economic ownership of any resulting trade intangible, on behalf of one or more other group members under an arrangement of contract research where the beneficiary or beneficiaries have legal and economic ownership of the intangible, or on behalf of itself and one or more other group members under an arrangement in which the members involved are engaged in a joint activity and have economic ownership of the intangible. Reciprocal licensing (cross-licensing) is not uncommon, and there may be other more complicated arrangements as well. 2.2.3.2 Marketing intangibles Marketing intangibles include trademarks and trade names that aid in the commercial exploitation of a product or service, customer lists, distribution channels, and unique names, symbols, or pictures that have an important promotional value for the product concerned. Some marketing intangibles (e.g., trademarks) may be protected by the law of the country concerned and used only with the owner's permission for the relevant product or services. The value of marketing intangibles depends upon many factors, including the reputation and credibility of the trade name or the trademark fostered by the quality of the goods and 39 services provided under the name or the mark in the past, the degree of quality control and ongoing R & D, distribution and availability of the goods or services being marketed, the extent and success of the promotional expenditures incurred in order to familiarize potential customers with the goods or services (in particular advertising and marketing expenditures incurred in order to develop a network of supporting relationships with distributors, agents, or other facilitating agencies), the value of the market to which the marketing intangibles will provide access, and the nature of any right created in the intangible under the law. 2.2.3.3 Article 12 of the OECD Model Tax Convention Article 12 of the OECD Model Tax Convention defines intangibles in terms of royalty payments. The term “royalties” as used in Article 12 refers to any payment received as a consideration for the use of, or the right to use any copyright of literary, artistic, or scientific work. The royalty definition applies to payments whether or not they are publicly registered. Additionally, the definition covers both payments made under a license and compensation for infringing upon a copyright. 2.2.4 Local Tax Perspective Below we provide examples of intangibles’ definitions as provided in the local legislation of European countries. Under Section 266.II.A of the German Commercial Code (Handelsgesetzbuch), "intangibles" are identified as concessions, industrial property and similar rights, the licenses referring to such rights, goodwill, and advance payments. Section 5 of the 1983 Administrative Guidelines lists industrial property and similar rights, design protection rights, copyrights, business secrets, and other rights and benefits not legally protected. The US Income Tax Regulations section 1.482-4(b), the final section 482 regulations[fn. 1] define an intangible as an asset with substantial value “independent of the services of any individual,” and as comprising any of the following six categories: • Patents, inventions, formulae, processes, designs, patterns or know-how, • Copyrights and literary, musical or artistic compositions, • Trademarks, trade names or brand names, • Franchises, licenses or contracts, • Methods, programs, systems, procedures, campaigns, surveys, studies, forecasts, estimates, customer lists or technical data and 40 • Other “similar” items. An item is considered “similar” if it derives its value not from “physical attributes”, but from its “intellectual content or other intangible properties.” 2.2.5 Conclusion Based on our comparison of the definitions of intangibles referred above, one could conclude that although there are some common features in these definitions, there are still many inconsistencies which make dealing with the intangibles by MNEs very difficult. To address this issue, the OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs decided to commence a new project examining the transfer pricing aspects of intangibles, to be carried out by Working Party No. 6 on the Taxation of Multinational Enterprises. Conclusion: There are different IP definitions for different purposes, which leads to a variety of issues. The following is an excerpt from the recently released Discussion Draft of the proposed revisions to chapter 6 of the OECD guidelines25: In these Guidelines, the word “intangible” is intended to address something which is not a physical asset or a financial asset, and which is capable of being owned or controlled for use in commercial activities. Rather than focusing on accounting or legal definitions, the thrust of a transfer pricing analysis in a matter involving intangibles should be the determination of the conditions that would be agreed upon between independent parties for a comparable transaction. Intangibles that are important to consider for transfer pricing purposes are not always recognized as intangible assets for accounting purposes. For example, costs associated with developing intangibles internally through expenditures such as research and development and advertising are sometimes expensed rather than capitalized for accounting purposes and the intangibles resulting from such expenditures therefore are not always reflected on the balance sheet. Such intangibles may nevertheless carry significant economic value and may need to be considered for transfer pricing purposes. Furthermore, the enhancement to value that may arise from the complementary nature of a collection of intangibles when exploited together is not always reflected on the balance sheet. Accordingly, whether an item should be considered to be an intangible for transfer pricing purposes under Article 9 25 Source: Discussion Draft on Proposed Revisions to chapter 6 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines Paragraphs 5-11 (6 June 2012, OECD) 41 of the OECD Model Tax Convention can be informed by its characterization for accounting purposes, but will not be determined by such characterization only. Furthermore, the determination that an item should be regarded as an intangible for transfer pricing purposes does not determine or follow from its characterization for general tax purposes, as, for example, an expense or an amortizable asset. The availability and extent of legal, contractual, or other forms of protection may affect the value of an item and the returns that should be attributed to it. The existence of such protection is not, however, a necessary condition for an item to be characterized as an intangible for transfer pricing purposes. Similarly, while some intangibles may be identified separately and transferred on a segregated basis, other intangibles may be transferred only in combination with other business assets. Therefore, separate transferability is not a necessary condition for an item to be characterized as an intangible for transfer pricing purposes. It is important to distinguish intangibles from market conditions or other circumstances that are not capable of being owned, controlled or transferred by a single enterprise. For example, features of a local market, such as the level of disposable income of households in that market or the size or relative competitiveness of the market, may affect the determination of an arm’s length price for a particular transaction and should be taken into account in a comparability analysis. They are not, however, intangibles for purposes of Chapter VI. The identification of an item as an intangible is separate and distinct from the determination of the value of the item or the return attributable to the item under the facts and circumstances of a given case. Depending on the industry sector and other facts specific to a particular case, intangibles can account for either a large or small part of the MNE’s value creation. It should be emphasized that not all intangibles deserve separate compensation in all circumstances, and not all intangibles give rise to premium returns in all circumstances. For example, consider a situation in which an enterprise performs a service using nonunique know-how, where other comparable service providers have comparable know-how. In that case, even though know-how constitutes an intangible, it may be determined under the facts and circumstances that the know-how does not justify allocating a premium return to the enterprise, over and above normal returns to the functions it performs. See TPG 1.39. Care should be taken in determining whether or when an intangible exists and whether an intangible has been used or transferred. For example, not all research and development expenditures produce or enhance an intangible and not all marketing activities result in the creation or enhancement of an intangible. 42 In a transfer pricing analysis of a matter involving the use or transfer of intangibles, it is important to identify the relevant intangibles with some specificity. The functional analysis should identify the economically significant intangibles at issue, the manner in which they contribute to the creation of value in the transactions under review, and the manner in which they interact with other intangibles, with tangible assets and with business operations to create value. While it may be appropriate to aggregate intangibles for purposes of determining arm’s length conditions for the use or transfer of the intangibles in certain cases, it is not sufficient to suggest that vaguely specified or undifferentiated intangibles have an effect on arm’s length prices or other conditions. A thorough functional analysis, including an analysis of the importance of identified economically significant intangibles in the MNE’s global business, should support the determination of arm’s length conditions.” The work will focus on the following aspects: • The development of a framework for analysis of intangible-related transfer pricing issues; • Definitional aspects; • Specific categories of transactions involving intangibles, such as research and development activities, differentiation between intangible transfers and services, marketing intangibles, other intangibles and business attributes; • How to identify and characterise an intangible transfer; • Situations where an enterprise would at arm’s length have a right to share in the return from an intangible that it does not own; • Valuation issues. The intention is to release a discussion draft for public comment by the end of 2013. 2.2.6 Alternative labelling In practice, it is difficult to allocate an intangible asset either as a trade or marketing intangible. Often the intangibles are combination of both (so called hybrid intangibles). Therefore an alternative view may be required to distinguish between various intangible assets. To characterize intangibles in a practical, overarching way, the following labels may be used: • Product-related Intangibles: those intangibles that are embedded in a particular product, such as product design or patent. • Process-related Intangibles: those intangibles that are related to unique or valuable know-how used in specific business processes, such as manufacturing know-how or procedures. 43 • Market-related Intangibles: intangibles that are linked to a way that a company/product name is positioned and recognized in the market, such as company name and logo. • Hybrids: intangibles that do not fit clearly within one of the above categories and exhibit characteristics of more than one group, such as franchise or license. Product related intangibles • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • Patent Invention Pattern Methods Copyright Design / Model Formulae/Recipes Software Literary, musical, or artistic composition / film Technical data / documentation Prescription drug files Library Natural resources Database Permit Regulatory license e.g. from central bank Trade secrets Process related intangibles • • • • • • • • • • • • • • Know-how Software Method Procedure System Supplier relationships Procedural manuals Technical data / documentation Training manuals Managerial skills and core competencies Airport gates and slots Financial instruments Embedded work force Supply chain intelligence Market and Marketing intangibles • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • Logo Trade mark Trade name Brand Campaign Survey Customer list Import quota Customer relationships Distribution network & agreements Retail shelf space Subscription lists Publications/thought leadership Reputation Book of business Hybrids • • • • Franchise Permit / right / license (air, water, land, drilling, emission, broadcasting) Domain name Unique location Source: TPA’s contribution to OECD on scheduled update of Chapters VI of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines 2.3 Labelling of intangibles The process of determining the owner of an intangible can become difficult when one entity is the legal owner and another is the economic owner. The legal owner refers to the entity that is considered the owner under IP law, while the economic owner refers to the entity that has the right to the income attributable to the ownership of the asset, such as royalties. Another way to determine ownership is looking at the degree of centralization. Centralized ownership can have the following attributes: a single company in the group that owns the intangibles legally and economically and has license agreements with other group entities, a situation which can create opportunities for tax planning. A distributed or joined ownership, on the other hand, has the following attributes: a number of group companies that share ownership of intangibles on a pre-determined basis, always involves some form of shared economic ownership, usually takes the form of an R&D cost contribution or costsharing R&D arrangement. In addition, the OECD guidelines offer two standards about the ownership of intangibles: 44 2.3.1 Legal ownership Legal ownership is defined according to the legal title and legal protection of the intellectual property. Thus, the intellectual property can be legally protected in the country it is registered, such as patents and trademark. From a transfer pricing perspective, the legal owner of the intellectual property is considered as the owner of the IP. For patent and trademark, the owner can protect their intellectual property by registering them; however, for embedded intangibles like know- how, it is usually hard to use legal system to protect it. Legal ownership offers the owner the protections and the rights to utilize the IP to generate further benefits. In the context of IP law, ownership is defined and based on the types and the circumstances of the intellectual property laws in place. Patents, trademark and copyrights are defined differently in Europe, the U.S., and Asia. Below is a quick comparison of the ownership terms of the different law systems in the United States and Europe. 2.3.2 Economic ownership Economic ownership refers to a situation when the intangible is not legally protected or it is difficult to identify the legal owner of the intangible so economic ownership is then considered. Economic ownership can be determined by analysing the relative contributions to the intangibles by each party. Though legal ownership is usually the starting point of defining ownership, there are cases where ownership lies elsewhere, such as with the licensee. The following circumstances describe instances when the ownership does not lie with the legal owner but with the economic owner. • The license is issued exclusively, • For an indefinite period or at least a period that concurs with the expected economic life of the intangible, • The licensor has no economic interest in the intangible, for instance when the royalties are not dependent on turnover, and • The licensee is allowed to transfer the license without the licensor’s permission. The developer may perform the research activity in its own name, i.e. with the intention of having legal and economic ownership of any resulting trade intangible, on behalf of one or more other group members under an arrangement of contract research where the beneficiary or beneficiaries have legal and economic ownership of the intangible, or on behalf of itself and one or more other group members under an arrangement in which the 45 members involved are engaged in a joint activity and have economic ownership of the intangible. The most common structures used in transfer pricing to manage legal and economic ownership of intangibles include contact R&D services and cost contribution arrangements. 2.3.3 Nominal Ownership: An additional level of ownership is what can be described as nominal ownership. This type of ownership is strictly in name only and is very limited in functions performed, assets involved and risks assumed. A hypothetical example of nominal ownership could be described as follows: Company A operates in Country B and holds the legal title of a particular trade name intangible. Company C operates in Country D. Company A has agreed to license the use of the trade name to Company C for a nominal percentage of gross third party sales by Company C. Company C performs functions, employs assets and assumes risks related to developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting the rights while Company A merely holds the legal title to the intellectual property. In this example, Company A would be strictly nominal owners of the intellectual property. 2.3.4 Process Ownership: Process ownership refers to the owner who is responsible for the functions that are related to an intangible. The OECD in the June 6th, 2012 Discussion Draft on the Proposed Revisions to Chapter 6 of the OECD Guidelines states that there are certain functions directly linked to intangibles. The functions provided by the OECD are development, enhancement, maintenance, and protection of intangibles. These four functions must be under the control of the process owner. The functions do not have to be directly performed by the process owner, but they must be under the supervision or control of the entity that is the process owner. The OECD also writes about four different risks that are assumed by the process owner. These risks are developmental, obsolescent, protection and product liability risk. 2.3.5 Entitlement to Intangibles related returns: In the recently published Discussion Draft from the OECD regarding the proposed changes to Chapter 6 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines, the idea of entitlement to intangibles related returns has been introduced. This principal of entitlement is threshold that must be reached in order for an entity to have a claim on residual returns that are related to an intangible. Paragraph 29 of the Discussion Draft explains that there are three factors that should be considered in order to determine if an entity is entitled to the intangible related returns. The first factor to be evaluated is the legal agreements, contracts, licenses registrations related to the intangible. In order to have entitlement to the returns, the entity 46 must have some legal claim to the intangible. The second component of entitlement to the intangible related returns is “the functions performed, the assets used, the risks assumed, and the costs incurred by members of the MNE group in developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting intangibles are in alignment with the allocation of entitlement to intangible related returns in the relevant registrations and contracts.” 26 The last factor is the compensation of other members of the MNE group who rendered services in connection with developing, enhancing, maintain and protecting intangibles. It is required that the entity claiming entitlement to the returns compensates the MNE group members on an arm’s length basis. The following diagram summarizes the requirements to surpass the threshold in order to be entitled to the intangible related returns. 2.3.6 Special Case: Subcontracting Contract R&D services are often put in place to minimize local ownership of valuable intangibles created by the R&D activities. This construction is useful when the group wishes to conduct R&D activities in various locations worldwide and at the same time retain centralized legal ownership and management of the group’s intangibles. The providers of 26 Source: Discussion Draft on Proposed Revisions to chapter 6 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines (6 June 2010, OECD) 47 the R&D services usually do not bear significant risks related to their operations and are often remunerated on cost plus basis where total costs are covered plus small profit margin. Paragraph 41 of the Discussion Draft also explains the requirement that “it is expected that, in a situation where contractual entitlements and functions are in alignment, the party or parties claiming contractual entitlement to intangible related returns will exercise control over the performance of those functions and the associated risks, will bear the necessary costs required to support the performance of the function, and will provide arm’s length compensation to any associated enterprise physically performing a relevant function.” 27 There is also additional guidance provided in paragraphs 9.23 through paragraph 9.28 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines. These two sections from the OECD provide clarity that in order to receive the returns related to an intangible, an entity must have some control and responsibility in the functions that are employed and simply bearing financial risk and costs does not entitle a company to the returns. 2.3.7 Special Case: Cost contribution arrangement A CCA is a framework agreed among business enterprises to share the costs and risks of developing, producing or obtaining assets, services, or rights, and to determine the nature and extent of the interests of each participant in those assets, services, or rights. A CCA is a contractual arrangement rather than necessarily a distinct juridical entity or permanent establishment of all the participants. In a CCA, each participant’s proportionate share of the overall contributions to the arrangement will be consistent with the participant’s proportionate share of the overall expected benefits to be received under the arrangement, bearing in mind that transfer pricing is not an exact science. Further, each participant in a CCA would be entitled to exploit its interest in the CCA separately as an effective owner thereof and not as a licensee, and so without paying a royalty or other consideration to any party for that interest. Conversely, any other party would be required to provide a participant proper consideration (e.g. a royalty), for exploiting some or all of that participant’s interest. The end result of a CCA is the existence of one legal owner and multiple economic owners who are entitled to various portions of the returns related to the intangible or some level of remuneration for various activities and assets employed as a result of the intangible. 27 Source: Discussion Draft on Proposed Revisions to chapter 6 of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines (6 June 2010, OECD) 48 2.4 Questions 1. Which of the following is not a requirement for an invention to qualify for a patent: E. Novelty F. Non-obviousness G. Utility H. Business plan I. All are needed 2. Which of the following is not a risk associated with the functions related to an intangible: F. The risk of obsolescence(the intangible becoming obsolete) G. Developmental risk, (i.e. exceeding a budget, poor performance of those involved in developing) H. Stakeholders that are unsatisfied with the developed intangible I. Product Liability Risks 3. Which of the following is not a factor to determine if an entity is entitled to intangibles related returns: F. The Functions, assets and risks assumed relating to Developing, Enhancing, Maintaining and Protecting an intangible G. The location of the company in relation to the intangible H. The compensation to other group companies at an arm’s length basis I. The legal holdings, agreements and contracts of the entity in question 4. What are the three critical attributes of an intangible asset: C. Identification, control (power to obtain benefits from the asset), and trademark D. Identification, control (power to obtain benefits from the asset), and legal registration of intangible E. future economic benefits (such as revenues or reduced future costs), control (power to obtain benefits from the asset), and legal registration of intangibles F. Identification, control (power to obtain benefits from the asset), and future economic benefits (such as revenues or reduced future costs) 49 2.5 Answers 1. D. 2. C. 3. B. 4. D. 50 3 Valuation of intangibles Authors: Steven van Wijk/Sjoerd de Jong/Steven Carey 51 3.1 Introduction The importance of MNEs in the world economy is reflected in the production and transfer of intangible assets. Intangible assets are nonphysical assets that allow an enterprise to earn profits above the profits the enterprise would have earned with only its physical assets. However, intangible assets are difficult to value for several reasons: • They are seldom traded on external markets; • They are often transferred in bundles with tangible assets and; • They are sometimes even difficult to detect. Because of these difficulties professionals try to track intangibles by certain proxies such as royalties, license fees and dividends. UNCTAD’s yearly-published World Investment Report (World Investment Prospects Survey 2009-2011) and much research on MNEs provide empirical analysis about MNEs’ intangible production and trade. For example more than 75 per cent of all private R&D expenditures worldwide are accounted for by MNEs. Additionally, most royalty licenses and management fees are intra-firm payments, flowing from foreign affiliates to their parent companies. The ratio of R&D investments has exceeded physical investments by large MNEs in the 1980s. Values of patents and trademarks mostly have risen over the second half of the last century. The phenomena behind these statistics are subject to much research in various disciplines, namely economics, organizational theory, history and politics. Theoretical and empirical evidence lead to two findings: • The development of intangible assets plays a major role for enterprises in their building of competitive advantages; • Second, the existence of intangible assets helps to explain the determination of the boundaries of an enterprise. Due to the boost in the value of intangibles, the issue of how to value something which cannot be seen becomes more important. Several internal and external drivers exist to value intangible assets: • financing securitization and collateralization; • management information and planning; • transfer pricing and structuring for sale and licensing; and • tax planning and compliance. 52 Probably the most controversial issue in the context of intangible valuation is the application of an appropriate valuation method. Three basic methods are commonly mentioned to determine the value of intangible assets, namely: • The market approach; • The income approach; and • The cost approach. Given the increasing number of intangibles and the magnitude of their values, a ‘fair’ valuation of these transfers is, not surprisingly, crucial for both tax authorities and taxpayers. Since the tax liability can vary significantly depending on the value assigned to the transfers, it is clear that taxpayers and tax authorities have opposing objectives. The differences in transfer pricing policies illustrate one point where all transfer pricing specialists agree: The valuation of intangible assets for transfer pricing purposes is a difficult and controversial issue. The main discussions stem from the following: 3.2 • The nature of MNEs as integrated businesses that derive synergies from being part of a wider group means that comparing intra-group transactions with a market reference of independent transactions is not logical. • Most intangibles are unique assets and comparable transactions rarely exist. This creates obvious challenges in both the selection of an appropriate transfer pricing methodology and in the identification of external price references and application of the arm’s length principle. When and Why Intangible Assets are Valuable In Chapter 1 it is pointed out the important role intangibles play in the context of globalization. A closer look at the academic literature, financial markets and firm’s behaviour reveals an increasing awareness of the importance of intangibles on a national and international level. However, intangibles are harder to measure, quantify and manage than their tangible counterparts. In the majority of cases intangibles are not recorded in the balance sheets and thus do not contribute to the book value of a company. This being said, the question arises whether with respect to these types of assets the main requirements imposed by transfer pricing provisions can be fulfilled, which is comparing one institutional situation of a transfer with a second or even a third one, i.e. finding comparables. The existence and ownership of an intangible does not automatically imply that the intangible possesses a marketable economic value. To find out whether an existing intangible has a sustainable and measurable economic market value, several measures have been developed. A general starting point is to ask if an independent party is willing to pay to 53 acquire either the intangible itself or rights to exploit it. If so, there will be - at least theoretically - a market to transfer the intangible. If the answer is negative, the intangible might have some positive economic value to the owner, but this does not necessarily translate into a positive economic value for the intangible. The reason why some intangibles have positive economic values in the sense that a third party would offer a positive price to buy or exploit them lies in the future. An intangible’s value heavily depends on the investor’s expectation to earn a higher profit by employing the intangible than compared to a situation in which he only relies on the physical and monetary assets of the enterprise. This implies that the intangible is expected, on the one hand, to generate a measurable increase in income or decrease in costs, and on the other hand to enhance the combined value of the other assets with which it is associated. The market value of intangibles has three major determinants, which are: • Market demand; • Existence or absence of close substitutes; and • The economic environment in which the intangible is embedded. Addressing market demand, as an example in the pharmaceutical industry, Bayer undertook long lasting and expensive R&D activities that resulted in the patent for Lipobay, a cholesterol medication. The formula was highly valuable until the medication was suspected to be responsible for the sudden death of several patients. With the pharmaceutical supervisory body’s withdrawal of the approval, demand dropped to zero, and with it the value of the formula. Domain names, in contrast, are intangible with very little sophistication, but if somebody possesses a domain name which is of importance to a company, the company’s demand might generate a high economic value although the degree of sophistication is very low. The second key factor to give an intangible economic value is the existence of close technical or economic substitutes, which affect the uniqueness of the intangible. Uniqueness is often linked to the intangible owner’s ability to realize higher than normal profits by employing the unique intangible. Such scenarios occur when potential rivals are not able to quickly or efficiently imitate the innovators’ intangibles. The so-called above normal profits, however normally provoke market entry of competitors. If in such case the intangibles owner is able to protect the rights to his unique intangibles by law through trademarks or patents or by preventing competitors from market entry through an input or output monopoly, the value of the intangibles rises, because substitutes are not available. If there were, however, close substitutes for the intangible, the intangible’s value would 54 vanish (even despite unambiguous defined property rights), because investors could chose to invest in the - probably cheaper – substitute. In these cases the intangibles profit potential is not higher than that of the economically equivalent substitute. An example for such substitute can be found when we look at the market for attire. If the market for attire only comprised a high-end quality brand like Chanel and a low-end brand like H&M, investors with a preference for high quality products would attribute a positive economic market value to the Chanel brand. If, however, there were Chanel and another competitor in the high quality segment such as Dior, the latter one could be considered as a close substitute and the value of the Chanel brand would partly diminish. Finally, the value of the intangible may vary with the economic environment in which it is embedded. Geographic location and historical and political factors are all relevant here. The knowledge needed for the development of Lipobay mentioned above might have no economic value at this point, but its value might rise if Bayer were able to demonstrate that the utility risk ratio of the intake of the medication is reasonable and hence gets reapproved by the pharmaceutical supervisory body, to use the knowledge to modify the formula and hence patent it under an adjusted patent, or to develop a completely new formula. 3.3 Companies with highly valued intangibles The market value of a company is generally determined by combining the total value of shareholders’ equity and the book value of long-term debt. This combination has been defined previously as the invested capital or business enterprise value for the company. When this value is compared to the balance sheet for different asset categories, a huge gap of value is often identified. Companies with highly valued intangibles represent a broad cross-section of industries. 3.3.1 Microsoft Corporation Microsoft has developed a broad line of systems software and applications software for computers. The system software of the company began with the MS-DOS operating system, which was the most widely used system for IBM-compatible computers. From that base, the company has expanded its product offerings beyond operating software. Applications software produced by the company includes highly acclaimed spreadsheet programs, word, file managers, database management, games, etc. The company also sells a large assortment of books that help customers get the most out of the company’s programs. The company also sells a large assortment of books that help customers get most out of the company’s programs. In addition, the company sells interface products, and other peripheral hardware. Microsoft has interests in every form of information collection and 55 manipulation service or product that exist; all derived from a $ 10,000 investment in the basic code for its original disk operating system. In 1994, revenues for Microsoft exceeded $4.6 billion. By 1998, revenues were $14.5 billion. Operating profits were 47.9% for 1998, better than the profit level achieved by the world’s leading pharmaceutical company. Total assets of the company for the year ending June 1998 were $22.4 billion. Cash ($13.9 billion) represented over 60% of that amount. Fixed assets totalled $1.5 billion, with less than $0.5 billion shown as investment in other longterm assets. The business enterprise value, on an accounting basis, was $15.0 billion. 3.3.1.1 Market value of Microsoft The value of invested capital for Microsoft is calculated below. Equity is valued at the end of June 1998, stock market price times the number of shares outstanding. The debt component is valued at the book value of long-term debt. Together, the equity and debt values indicate that the Microsoft enterprise value is over $535 billion. Microsoft (values in millions) Shares 4,940.0 Price $108.38 Value of Equity $535,372.5 Long-Term Debt Value of Invested Capital ----535,372.5 Using the market value of invested capital and the book value of fixed assets, working capital and other assets allows a calculation for intellectual property and intangible assets as a residual. As shown below, a more accurate accounting for intangible assets and intellectual property is a value of over $523 billion. The huge sales and profit margins enjoyed by Microsoft are not derived from fixed assets. They come from the $523 billion intangible asset base that is not mentioned in the financial reports. Microsoft Invested Capital 100.0% $535,372.5 Net Working Capital 1.9% $ 10,159.0 Fixed Assets 0.3% $ 56 1,505.0 Other Assets 0.0% $ 260.0 Intellectual Property & Intangible Assets 97.8% $523,448.5 The total amount of invested capital is allocated among general asset categories of the company. For Microsoft, an enormous 97.8% of the value of the enterprise is associated with intellectual property and intangible assets. 3.3.2 Veritas v Commissioner 28 In November 1999, Veritas Software Corp. (Veritas US) and its wholly owned foreign subsidiary Veritas Ireland entered into a cost sharing agreement (CSA). Under the terms of the CSA Veritas US granted Veritas Ireland the right to use certain existing intangibles and charged Veritas Ireland a buy-in payment. Veritas alleged that the value of the buy-in payment in question should be US$118 million based on their CUT (comparable uncontrolled transaction) pricing method. The IRS alleged that the buy-in payment in question should be valued at US$ 2.5 billion based on their income-based valuation method that took into account a comparison to comparable 3rd party acquisitions, the useful life of the intangibles and the workforce in place. The US Tax Court supported the CUT pricing method applied by Veritas and rejected the income method applied by the IRS. As a result Veritas US prevailed against the Commissioner. This case laid some of the groundwork for determining when a bottom-up (Veritas) versus a top-down (IRS) approach should be used. The distinction is illustrated below. 28 Source: Veritas Software Corp. 133 TC 297, Dec. 58.016 (2009) 57 3.4 Why and when are intangibles valued? There are many reasons for which a value needs to be determined for intangibles. The following diagram captures some of the key valuation triggers, with further examples of each provided below. 58 Source: TPA Playbook a. Financing collateralization and securitization • Using intangibles as collateral in either cash flow based or asset based debt financing • Sale-and-license-back financing of intangibles. An example of where an intangible valuation has been used in this context was for Thomas cook. In order to fund its pension liabilities the Company was able to transfer some of its brand intangibles into a special purpose vehicle and then lease these intangibles back. This enabled the company to use the intangibles as collateral in loans to provide the lenders with the needed level of security and thereby continue trading. (http://www.accountancyage.com/aa/opinion/2141656/tangible-benefits-intangibles) b. Taxation planning and compliance • The establishment of an intangible- or IP-holding company and the licensing of the intangibles or IP to the taxpayer’s operating companies. • Tax based purchase price allocations (among acquired tangible assets and intangible assets) in a taxable business acquisition. • Amortization deductions for purchased intangibles • Determining the arm’s length price (ALP) for the cross border transfer and use of multinational taxpayer corporation intangibles (in compliance with Section 482). The OECD Discussion Draft of 6 June explores the above and their interaction with other drivers of valuation in detail. c. Regulatory compliance and corporate governance • Estimation of the fair market value of intangible sale, license or any other transfer between a profit and non-profit entity. • Custodial inventory of owned and licensed intangibles • Assessment of adequate insurance coverage for owned and licensed intellectual property. • Defence against infringement, torts, breach of contract and other wrongful acts. • Defence against allegations of dissipation of corporate assets. d. Bankruptcy and reorganization • Collateralization of intangibles for secured creditor financing • Use of intangibles as collateral for debtor-in-possession secured financing. • Fairness opinion on the sale or license of intangibles. 59 • The usage of intangibles in the assessment of the debtor corporation solvency or insolvency with respect to fraudulent transfers and preference actions • Impact of intellectual property on the bankrupt owner plan or reorganization An example in this category is the recent bankruptcy of Nortel Networks Inc. Despite the fact that the business was no longer considered a going concern the liquidators were able to realise a significant recovery on the sale of the patents, thereby paying off creditors (although not shareholders). The patents were purchased by Apple, Microsoft and various other parties. One interesting observation from this is that a value was recognised from the patents in bankruptcy that was not able to be exploited by Nortel while it was in business. e. Financial accounting and fair value reporting • Acquisition purchase accounting allocation among acquired tangible assets and intangible assets. • Impairment testing of goodwill and intellectual property Note that it is relevant to be aware of potential differences in valuations performed for financial accounting purposes and tax/transfer pricing purposes. The OECD in the 2012 Discussion Draft at paragraph 110 notes that “Caution should therefore be exercised in accepting valuations performed for accounting purposes as necessarily reflecting arm’s length prices or values for transfer pricing purposes without a thorough examination of the underlying assumptions. In particular, valuations of intangibles contained in purchase price allocations performed for accounting purposes are not relevant for transfer pricing purposes.” Forensic analysis and dispute resolution • Intangible assets lost profits, royalty rate or other economic damages in infringement claims. • Intangibles, lost profits or other economic damages in breach of contract; license or non-compete and non-disclosure agreement damages claims. Strategic planning and management information • Formation of intangibles joint venture, joint development or joint commercialization agreements • Negotiation of inbound or outbound intangible asset use, development, commercialization or exploitation agreements. • Identification and negotiation of intangible license, spin-off, joint venture and other commercialization opportunities. 60 3.5 Price, Value and Cost The diagram shows the distinction between price and value. Price is the result of demand versus supply directly or via negotiations. Market circumstances like liquidity, efficiency and the level of control acquired, affect the demand versus supply and therefore the price. Valuation methodologies based on price include trading multiples and transaction multiples. Value is buyer specific and based on expected cash flow in general, including the synergies, against risk perception and return requirements over the long term. In other words, companies create value by investing capital they raise from investors to generate future cash flows at rates of return exceeding the cost of capital. The faster a company can increase their revenues and deploy more capital at attractive rates of return, the more value they create. The combination of growth and return on invested capital (ROIC) relative to its cost is what drives value. This is how competitive advantage, the core concept of business strategy, links to the guiding principle of value creation. Cost is an amount that has to be paid or given up in order to get something. In business, cost is usually a monetary valuation of: • Effort, • Material, • Resources, • Time and utilities consumed, • Risks incurred, and • Opportunity forgone in production and delivery of a good or service. 61 All expenses are costs, but not all costs (such as those incurred in acquisition of an incomegenerating asset) are expenses. 3.6 Generally Accepted Valuation Approaches Valuation analysts typically attempt to use all three valuation approaches to value the intangibles. When that is possible, the analyst can develop mutually supportive evidence and a multifaceted perspective regarding the intangible value. However, due to data constraints, it is common in a valuation to rely on only one or two valuation approaches in the intangible valuation process. 3.6.1 The Cost Approach Valuation Methods The cost approach belongs to the category of input indicators of measuring intangible assets as opposed to output indicators. This approach proxies the value of an intangible by the costs of creating and transferring it. The method implies that the intangible’s value is equal to its costs of development and hence is built on the assumption that the higher the development costs, the higher the value of the intangible. It already can be anticipated that this does not always accurately reflect reality when it comes to the valuation of intangibles. Within the cost approach, there are several intangible valuation methods. Each valuation uses a specific definition of cost. The two most common definitions are: • Reproduction cost new and • Replacement cost new. Advantage 1 - The total cost, at current prices, to develop an exact duplicate of the intangible is the reproduction cost. Advantage 2 - The total cost, at current prices, to develop an asset having the same functionality or utility as the intangible is the replacement cost. Functionality in this case, means the ability of the intangible to perform the task for which it was originally designed and is an engineering concept. Utility refers to the ability of the intangible to provide an equal amount of satisfaction and is an economic concept. Some valuation analysts also consider cost avoidance as a cost approach. In this case the historical or prospective costs that have been avoided because of the ownership of intangibles are the quantification for this cost measure. The cost measurement consists out of four cost components: 62 • Direct costs (e.g. materials) • Indirect costs (e.g. engineering and design labour) • The intangible developer’s profit (on the direct cost and indirect cost investment) • An opportunity cost/entrepreneurial incentive (to motivate the development process) Normally, the intangible development material, labour and overhead cost are easy to identify and quantify. The developer’s profit can be estimated using several procedures. The material, labour and overhead costs can be estimated as a percentage of return on the total investment. The entrepreneurial incentive is often valued as the lost profits during the replacement intangible development period. As an example, let’s assume it takes five years to develop a replacement patent. If the developer of the new patent buys an actual patent, the developer can start directly earning income with the actual patent; this can be operating income or license income. If the developer “builds” its own hypothetical replacement patent or new patent, the developer will not earn any income during the development period of five years. The five years development period represents the opportunity cost of developing a new replacement patent, in comparison to purchasing the actual seasoned patent. All four cost components (direct costs, indirect costs, developer’s profit and opportunity cost) should be taken into consideration in the intangible cost approach valuation. In other words there are also economic analyses included in the cost approach. These economic analyses provide indications of both: • The correct levels of opportunity costs (in case there are) • The correct amount of economic uselessness (in case there are) The intangible cost new should be adjusted for losses in value due to: • Physical weakening • Functional uselessness • Economic uselessness Physical weakening is the reduction in value as a result of physical wear and tear. It is unlikely that physical weakening will happen with intangibles. Functional uselessness is the reduction in value as a result of the intangible’s inability to perform the function for which it was originally designed. The technological side of functional uselessness is a reduction in value as a result of improvements in technology that make the intangible less valuable than the ideal replacement for itself. 63 Economic uselessness is a decrease in value due to the effects, event or conditions that are external and out of the control of the intangible owner. The valuation analyst will estimate the amounts of intangible physical weakening, functional uselessness and economic uselessness. A general accepted approach for quantifying intangible replacement cost new is: Reproduction cost new – Curable functional uselessness = Replacement cost new Estimating the intangible value, the following cost approach formula is generally accepted: Replacement cost new – Physical weakening – Economic uselessness – Incurable functional uselessness = Intangible value Example of the cost approach 3.6.2 Market Approach Valuation Methods In the valuation of intangibles, valuation analysts try to apply market approach methods first. The reason is that the market that is the economic environment where arm’s length transactions between unrelated parties occur is considered to provide the best indicator of value. However, the market approach only provides useful valuation evidence when the valued intangible is sufficient comparable with similar intangibles that are transacting in the market. In that case the comparable transactions may indicate the price that can be expected for the intangible in the transaction. The two principal intangible market approach valuation methods are: • The comparable uncontrolled transaction (CUT) and • The comparable profit margin method (CPM) 64 In the CUT, the search is for the arm’s length sales or licenses of benchmark intangible assets. In the CPM method, the search is for companies that provide benchmarks to the valued intangible. In the CUT method, it is more likely that the valuation will rely on CUT license transactions than sale transactions, due to the fact that third party licenses of intangibles are more common than third party sales of intangibles. Nevertheless, for sale as well as license transactions, the systematic process in the CUT method has to be followed in a valuation. Research the appropriate exchange markets to get information about similar sale or license transactions, involving guideline, similar in investment risk and expected return, or comparable, because the intangible is almost comparable with the valued intangible. Comparison attributes can include: • Intangible type • Intangible use • Kind of industry • Date of license or sale • Verifying the transactional information i.e.: • Whether the transactional data are really accurate and • That the sale or license exchange reflect arm’s length market considerations. This verification procedure can also extract additional information about the current market conditions, for the sale or license of the intangible. Selection of the relevant units of comparison, for example income pricing multiples, dollars per unit or any other unit of comparison. Comparing the selected guideline or comparable intangible sale or license transaction with the subject intangible, using the selected elements of comparison. Declare the differences between the sale and license price of each guideline transaction, for every selected element. If such comparison cannot declare the differences in the comparison, the valuation analyst may eliminate the sale or license transaction as a guideline for future valuation considerations. Selecting pricing metrics for the subject intangible from the range of pricing metrics indicated from the guideline or comparable transactions. Pricing multiples in three ranges will be selected; in the low end, midpoint or high end of the range of pricing metrics, indicated by the transactional sale or license data. Summarizing, selection of the subject- 65 specific pricing metrics based on the analyst’s comparison of the owner intangible to the guideline intangible. • Applying the selected subject-specific pricing metrics to the subject intangible financial or operational fundamentals, for example: • Revenue • Income, Number of drawings • Number of lines of code • Reconciling the various value indications provided by the analysis of the guideline sale or license transactions into a single market approach value indication In the CUT method, databases or other sources will be used to search in order to select intangible license CUTs. Besides, the valuation analyst will also confer with the owner management to explore whether the owner has entered into any intangible license agreement (either inbound or outbound). These owner license agreements could relate to either the subject intangible or to comparable intangible. Although the CPM method is also based on a comparative analysis, the analyst is searching for comparable or guideline companies. The objective of the CPM method is to identify guideline companies that are comparative to the owner company in all ways, except the ownership of the subject intangible. The optimal situation should be that the CPM method guideline companies operate in the same industry, having the same types of raw materials and the same type of products or services and customers. In the ideal situation, the owner has an established trademark and the guideline companies only have generic trademarks or the owner owns a subject patent and the guideline companies produce unpatented products. As a result, the owner should have earned a higher profit margin than the selected guideline companies. This profit margin comparison is normally made at the earnings before interest and taxes (or EBIT) level of income. This EBIT margin typically reflects the pre-tax operating income of the comparative companies. The incremental profit margin earned by the owner can then be converted into an intangible implied royalty rate. Typically, all of the excess profit margin is assigned to the intellectual property, depending on the fact whether the intangible is the only reason for the owner’s superior profit margin. The implied royalty rate is the first result, in the search and comparison. The implied royalty rate is then multiplied by the owner revenue in order to estimate the amount of implied royalty income generated from the intangible. This hypothetical royalty is capitalized over 66 the expected useful life of the intangible. The result of this capitalization procedure is an estimate of the intangible value, according to the CPM method. 3.6.3 Income Approach Valuation Methods In this valuation approach, the intangible value is estimated as the present value of the future income from the ownership of the intangible. The present value calculations are based on three principal components: • An estimate of the duration of the projection period, typically measured as the expectation of the intangible’s remaining useful life (RUL). • An estimate of the intangible related income for each period in the projection, typically measured as the owner income. • An estimate of the appropriate capitalization rate, typically measured as the required rate of return on an investment in the intangible. For purposes of the income approach, the RUL relates to the time period over which the owner expects to receive any income related to the intangible: • License • Use or • Forbearance of use. In addition to the term of the RUL, the analyst is also interested in the shape of the RUL curve. That is, the analyst is interested in the annual rate of decay of the future intangible asset income. For purposes of the income approach, different intangible income measures may be relevant. If property applied, these different income measures can be used in the income approach to derive a value indication. Some of the different income measures include: • Gross or net revenues • Gross income (or gross profit) • Net operating income • Net income before tax • Net income after tax • Operating cash flow • Net cash flow • Incremental income 67 • Differential income • Royalty income • Excess earnings income and • Several others (such as incremental income) Because there are different income-measures that may be used in the income approach, it is important for the capitalization rate (either the discount rate or the direct capitalization rate) to be derived on a basis consistent with the income measure used. Regardless of the measure of income considered in the income approach, there are several categories of income based valuation methods that are typically used: Valuation methods that quantify an incremental level of intellectual property income: That is, the owner will expect a greater level of revenue (however measured) by owning the intangible as compared to not owning the intangible. Alternatively, the owner may expect a lower level of costs, such as capital costs, investment costs or operating costs, by owning the intangible as compared to not owning the intangible. Valuation methods that estimate a relief from a hypothetical license royalty payment: That is, these reliefs from royalty (RFR) methods estimate the amount of hypothetical royalty payment that the owner (as licensee) does not have to pay to a third party licensor for the use of the intangible. The owner is “relieved” from having to pay this hypothetical license royalty payment for the use of the intangible. This is because the owner, in fact, owns the intangible. Valuation methods that estimate a residual measure of intangible income: That is, these methods typically start with the overall business enterprise income. Next, the valuation analyst identifies all of the tangible assets and routine intangible assets (other than the particular intangible) that are used in the overall business. These assets are typically called contributory assets. The analyst then determines a fair rate of return on all of the contributory assets. The analyst then subtracts the fair return on the contributory assets from the owner business enterprise total income. This residual (or excess) income is the income that is associated with the intangible. Valuation methods that rely on a profit split: That is, these methods typically also start with the overall business enterprise income. The valuation analyst then allocates this total income between: • The owner tangible assets and routine intangible assets and • The intangible. The profit split percent (e.g., 20% 25 %, etc.) to the intangible is typically based on the valuation analyst’s functional analysis of the business operations. This functional analysis identifies the relative importance of: • The intangible 68 • The contributory assets to the production of the total business income. Valuation methods that quantify comparative income. That is, these methods compare the owner income to a benchmark measure of income (that, presumably, does not benefit from the use of the intangible). Common benchmark income measures include: • The owner income before the intangible development • Industry average income levels • Selected publicly traded company income levels. A common measure of income for these comparative analyses is the EBIT margin. This EBIT income is considered to be a pre-tax measure of operating income. When publicly traded companies are used as the comparative income benchmark, the method is often called the CPM method. All of these income approach valuation methods can be applied using either the direct capitalization procedure or the yield capitalization procedure. In the direct capitalization procedure, the valuation analyst: • Estimates a normalized income measure for one future period (typically one year) and • Divides that measure by an appropriate investment rate of return. The appropriate investment rate of return is called the direct capitalization rate. The direct capitalization rate may be derived for: • A perpetual time period or • A specified finite time period. This decision will depend on the valuation analyst’s estimate of the intangible RUL. Typically, the analyst will conclude that the intellectual property has a finite RUL. In that case, the analyst may use the yield capitalization procedure. Alternatively, the analyst may use the direct capitalization procedure with a limited life direct capitalization rate. Mathematically, the limited life capitalization rate is typically based on a present value of annuity factor (PVAF) for the intangible property RUL. In the yield capitalization procedure, the valuation analyst projects the appropriate income measure for several future time periods. This discrete time period is typically based on the intangible RUL. This income projection is converted into a present value by the use of a present value discount rate. The present value discount rate is the investor’s required rate of return or yield capitalization rate over the expected term of the income projection. 69 The result of either the direct capitalization procedure or the yield capitalization procedure is the income approach value indication for the intangible. 3.6.3.1 Example of the Income Approach, the Discounted Future Benefits Method Estimated Variables in TUSD Item 1. Estimated Benefits 2. Expected Growth Rate 3. Estimated Discount Rate 4. effective Income Tax Results Revenue (income Tax Rate) Estimated After-Tax Benefits /Discount Factor Discounted Benefits Present Value of the Intangible 3.000 3.50% 18% 35% Year 1 € 3.000 € 1.050 € 1.950 0.847457627 € 1.653 Year 2 € 3.105 € 1.087 € 2.018 0.71818443 € 1.449 Year 3 € 3.124 € 1.125 € 2.089 .0608630873 € 1.271 € 4.374 3.6.3.2 Example of the Income Approach, Capitalized Royalty Income Method for Trademark Valuation Item 1. Arm's Length Royalty (Range) 2. Estimated Net Revenue 3. Market-derived Discount Rate 4. Estimated Growth Rate 5. Effective Income Tax Rate Estimated Variables in TUSD Results Estimated Royalty Income p.a. (income Tax Expense) Estimated After-Tax Royalties /Capitalization Rate (3.-4.) Range of Value 70 5% 7% € 12.000 € 12.000 22.50% 22.50% 2.50% 35.00% 2.50% 35.00% € 600.000 € 210.000 € 390.000 20.00% € 840.000 € 294.000 € 546.000 20.00% € 1.950 € 2.730 3.6.4 Valuation Synthesis and Conclusion Procedures In the valuation synthesis and conclusion process, the valuation analyst should consider the following question: does the selected valuation approach(es) and method(s) accomplish the analyst’s assignment? That is, does the selected approach and method actually quantify the desired objective of the analysis such as: • A defined value • A transaction price • A third party license rate • An intercompany transfer price • An economic damages estimate • An intellectual property bundle exchange ratio • An opinion on the intellectual property transaction fairness. The valuation analyst should also consider if the selected valuation approach and method analyses the appropriate intangible asset(s). The valuation analyst should consider if there were sufficient empirical data available to perform the selected valuation approach and method. That is, the valuation synthesis should consider if there were sufficient data available to make the analyst comfortable with the analysis conclusion. And, the valuation analyst should consider if the selected approach and method will be understandable to the intended audience for the intellectual property valuation. 3.6.5 Intangible RUL Considerations The valuation analyst should also consider which approaches and methods deserve the greatest consideration with respect to the intangible RUL. The intangible RUL is an important consideration of each valuation approach. In the income approach, the RUL will affect the projection period for the intangible income subject to either yield capitalization or direct capitalization. In the cost approach, the RUL will affect the total amount of uselessness, if any, from the estimated “cost” measure i.e. the intangible reproduction cost or replacement cost. In the market approach, the RUL will affect the selection, rejection and/or adjustment of the comparable or guideline intangible sale or license transactional data. The following factors typically influence the intangible expected RUL: • Legal factors • Contractual factors 71 • Functional factors • Technological factors • Economic Factors • Analytical Factors Each of these factors is normally considered in the valuation analyst’s RUL estimation. Typically, the life factor that indicates the shortest RUL deserves the primary consideration in the valuation synthesis and conclusion. Ultimately, the experienced valuation analyst will use professional judgment to weight the various valuation approach and method value indications to conclude a fair value based on: • The analyst’s confidence in the quantity and quality of available data • The analyst’s level of due diligence performed on that data • The relevance of the valuation method to the subject intangible life cycle stage and degree of marketability • The degree of variation in the range of value indications Based on the valuation synthesis, the intangible final value conclusion can be either: • Point estimate (which is common for fair market valuations) • A value range (which is common for transaction negotiations or license/sale fairness opinions). 3.6.6 The Valuation of Intangibles for Tax Purposes In an international framework, the prices at which tangible and intangible assets are transferred internally (transfer prices) not only determine the income of each party participating in a particular transfer, but also influence the tax base of the jurisdictions where these parties are located. Theoretically, a properly calculated transfer price should “reasonably” allocate profits resulting from such a transfer among all parties involved. Consequently, each jurisdiction should receive a ‘fair’ proportion of the tax revenues based on these profits. Practically, there are several pitfalls that prevent income and expenditure allocation among MNEs and tax jurisdictions from being easily resolved. The crucial point why transfer pricing appears to be matter of concern for both taxpayers and tax authorities occurs because tax jurisdictions have different corporate income systems and tax rates. Profit maximizing MNEs can and – assuming economically rational behaviour – will take advantage of tax differentials by applying tax planning techniques in which they attempt to shift income from 72 the higher tax jurisdiction to the lower taxed one. As governments of jurisdictions with higher tax rates fear an erosion of their tax base, they react to these techniques by formulating new or reforming already existing tax legislation, attempting to render the usage of tax avoidance activities more difficult. Transfer pricing rules are supposed to provide guidance to MNEs on how the values of transferred items have to be calculated. The principal underpinning of basically all national regulatory policies is the arm’s length standard (ALS). The ALS requires MNEs to value a transaction like independent parties engaged in the same (or very similar) transaction under the same (or very similar) circumstances would have valued such a transaction. Tax authorities recommend that MNEs find either an internal comparable (a product that is traded both inside and outside the multinational enterprise) or an external comparable (two unrelated third parties trading the identical product) as a benchmark against which to measure the transfer price. If no comparable can be found so that a real arm’s length comparison is not possible, MNEs have to hypothesize how independent parties would have valued the transaction (hypothetical arm’s length comparison). Various regulatory policies further provide a range of valuation methods, which taxpayers have to apply when calculating arm’s length values. These methods are usually categorized into two groups: the (traditional) transaction-based methods and the profit- or income-based methods. The transactions-based methods embrace the comparable uncontrolled price method (CUP) and the comparable uncontrolled transaction method (CUT), the resale minus method and the cost plus method. CUP and CUT can be considered as the most direct applications of the ALS since they use product comparables as arm’s length benchmarks. The resale minus and the cost plus method, in contrast, ask for functional arm’s length comparables. These methods focus on either the distributor’s or the manufacturer’s side of a transaction and determine a transfer price by comparing the tested party’s functions with competitors performing the same functions. The comparable profits method (CPM), the transactional net margin method (TNMM) and the profit split method belong to the group of profit-based methods. These methods compare profits of controlled and uncontrolled parties. For the valuation of intra-company intangible asset transfers, the range of applicable transfer pricing methods is limited to the CUT and CUP, the CPM and TNMM and profit split. When the ALS is applied via the use of these methods, several difficulties occur, namely: • How should comparable transactions be identified? • How should comparables or transactions be adjusted, when they are not the same but reasonably similar? 73 • What should be done when comparables do not even exist, which is likely to be the case when it comes to intangible assets? • Which of the provided methods is best to apply? • How should it be documented why a certain method was chosen over an alternative one? 3.6.7 Discussion Draft on Intangibles, OECD Chapter VI The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development on June 6 issued a discussion draft containing proposed revisions to Chapter VI of Transfer Pricing Guidelines, Transfer Pricing Considerations for Intangibles. The 60-page discussion draft is organized into four sections: • Identifying intangibles; • Identification of parties entitled to intangible –related returns; • Transactions involving the use or transfer of intangibles; and • Determining arm’s length conditions or prices in cases involving intangibles. Below we focus on point 4 above to highlight how the discussion draft relates to intangible valuation for tax and transfer pricing purposes. The OECD acknowledges that challenging comparability issues are at stake, but that restraint should be exercised in rejecting potential comparables. Comparability adjustments may be necessary but a different transfer pricing method may also be required if any such adjustments represent a large percentage of the compensation of the intangible. The revised chapter states that it is important to note that • A tested party, even if it is the least complex party, may still be entitled to intangible related returns, • Unrelated parties may also have intangibles at their disposal, and no comparability adjustments may be necessary, and • The specific features of intangibles that may be important are: • Exclusivity, • The extent and duration of legal protection, • Geographic scope, • Useful life, • Stage of development, • Rights to enhancements, revisions and updates, and 74 • Expectation of future benefits. According to the OECD, when selecting a transfer pricing method, tax authorities and taxpayers should not too readily assume that all residual profits are to be allocated to the party entitled to intangible related returns. A functional analysis can also identify other factors that influence value creation for example, risks borne, specific market characteristics, location, business strategies, group synergies, etc. The OECD discusses the use of valuation techniques drawn from financial valuation practice. These techniques may be used either as part of one of the five OECD approved transfer pricing methods, or as a tool that can be applied in identifying the arm’s length price. The OECD expresses concern about valuations performed for accounting purposes, as these “valuation assumptions may sometimes be biased in favour of conservative estimates of the value of assets in a company’s balance sheet”. The OECD mentions that the use of cost plus methods or resale price methods is generally discouraged in the valuation of intangibles. In contrast, the comparable uncontrolled price (CUP) method and the transactional profit method will most likely be useful when valuing intangibles. The OECD provides a description of factors that impact the valuation of intangibles (for example: partially versus fully developed intangibles and the related discount factor; growth rate; accuracy of financial projections; useful life of intangibles and terminal values; tax rates; etcetera.). Finally, the OECD comments on arm’ s-length pricing for transfers of intangibles for which the valuation is extremely uncertain at the time of the transaction (for example, the reliability of projections of anticipated benefits versus price adjustment clauses or renegotiations). Once again, the application of hindsight is explicitly disallowed. The authors note that while the OECD provides valuation guidance, the facts and circumstances (functional analysis) remain of critical importance. 3.6.8 Summary Shortcomings are found in all the identified valuation methods. If the economic benefits generated by the intangibles and the costs of producing them were linked, the resulting values should be similar, regardless of which of the approaches mentioned above is used. Due to the nature of intangibles, however, economic benefits and production costs are not necessarily interrelated so that the three approaches might provide differing results. The uniqueness of intangibles translates into the fact that they are not easily reproducible, and value chains usually cannot be traced. 75 Obviously, first-best solutions for the intangible asset valuation do not exist. The question coming up then is: “Which of the approaches presented above is under current conditions the most appropriate second-best method to calculate a ‘fair’ market value for intangibles? Again and probably not surprisingly the answer is very contentious among specialists. Tax authorities and some business appraisers clearly prefer the market approach because of its arm’s length quality, which is supposed to guarantee the highest degree of objectivity. Other appraisers tend to favour the income approach. They argue that this approach is conceptually superior since it focuses on future variables, which would better correspond with: • The nature of intangibles, i.e. with their uniqueness and their future profit orientation, and • The perspective an investor assumes when buying an intangible. However, combinations of market and income approach are also possible when external transfers exist, which then would unite both aspects. Some professional intangible appraisal offices and consultants developed their individual valuation approaches, partly focusing on brand valuations. Names of alternative valuation models are Value-Dynamics, Balanced Scorecards or the Skandia Navigator approach. These approaches use multistage factors, scoring or index models partly including variations of the aforementioned methods to approach the problem including both quantitative and qualitative measures. However, none of these models, so far, is recognized across the board as uniform, standardized and especially objective enough. Any presented value that was derived by means of one of these methods provokes the question: Which proxies were used with what weight and on what grounds? In fact, no matter, which method is chosen, a substantial degree of uncertainty and subjectivity exist when it comes to the estimation of the variables and the assessment of the methods, relevant proxies, and useful life. Every buyer or licensee has a different set of parameters with regard to how much he/she would pay for an intangible than sellers or licensors have when they calculate their price. Finally even objective analysts judge the described underlying factors of an intangible differently. Because of the unavailability of reliable information and publicly accessible data on intangibles, a market for these assets, such as it exists, will be full of subjectivity, guesswork and sometimes inconsistencies. A nice illustration of this is the valuation of Facebook before initial public offer. 76 3.7 Determining the Discount Rate and Capitalization Rate In discounting available cash flow, an appropriate rate of return must be determined. The rate of return expected by an investor from an investment is related to: • The general level of interest rates; • A premium for perceived financial risk; and • A premium for perceived business risk. The appropriate rate of return for valuing an investment is the cost of capital for that investment. This rate of return is referred to as the discount rate, which is most often determined by using either the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) or the build-up method. Both of these methodologies are variations of the basic summation concept. The summation concept essentially "builds" a discount rate using the various components which comprise the total rate of return required on an investment. These components are: • The total return required on a long-term, risk-free investment; • Equity risk premium; and • Increments for risk differentials of the particular business or investment. For the business or intangibles, these risk differentials result from risk factors that are specific to the business and related to its advantages and disadvantages over other companies on the open market. These factors should include, but are not limited to, the following: • The industry; • The diversification of the licensing of the intellectual property; • The characteristics of the intellectual property; • The financial risks; • The diversification of the operations; • Lack of management depth; • Lack of access to capital markets; • Geographic diversification; • Risk of assets; and • Years in business. Based on the factors listed above, an intangibles’ discount or capitalization rate can greatly vary. An established intangible widely licensed may use an industry rate of return, while an 77 intangible in an emerging technology area with high obsolescence may have a rate of return similar to venture capital. Developing a discount rate applicable to intellectual property is normally a two-step process. First, the valuer must develop the discount rate applicable to the entire business, which includes a company specific risk premium accounting for the company’s unique risk differentials. Next, the valuer must isolate the discount rate applicable to the specific asset being valued, by identifying and quantifying the relative risks of investments in the Company’s various assets and in similar assets measured in the open market. The discount rate applicable to the intellectual property should reflect the rate of return an investor would require for an investment in the asset. For any individual asset, this rate must be determined in the context of the discount rate of the business overall. Conceptually, the discount rate for the business may be viewed as a weighted average of a series of discount rates applicable to the individual assets of the business from the least risky (e.g., cash, receivables) to the most risky (e.g., goodwill). The capitalization rate, the rate used as the divisor in the Direct Capitalization Method, is derived from the discount rate and is determined by subtracting from the discount rate the projected average annual compound growth rate of an earnings stream. The reciprocal of the capitalization rate is the valuation multiple. 3.8 Business Restructuring and Valuation, Chapter IX, OECD Chapter IX of the OECD Guidelines sets out the OECD’s approach to business restructuring and in this context includes a discussion on valuation. Figure 1 outlines a general approach to determining arm's length compensation for a business restructuring, as described in parts 2 – 4 of Chapter IX. We have mapped the key issues identified in Chapter IX against three broad headings that make up a typical transfer pricing analysis. 78 3.8.1 Generating a functional and factual analysis The purpose of the functional and factual analysis is to explore whether “something of value” (9.48) has been moved as part of the restructuring. To do this, a thorough review of the functions, assets and risks before and after the restructuring is required (9.54). Legal rights are stated to be relevant under contract and commercial law (9.54). Where there is a contract in place that has been altered, whether it contains a termination, non-renewal or renegotiation clause (and whether it was respected) should be considered (9.104). Whether that contract was arm's length should also be considered (9.106). The guidance also suggests that contractual arrangements can be inferred or modified to conform with arm's length behaviour (but without using hindsight, 9.56) and with actual conduct (9.55). Such modification of actual contractual rights may prove to be a contentious area in practice. The motives behind the change should be identified. Anticipated business synergies are noted as typical motivation, and it would be good practice for taxpayers to maintain documentation of the assumptions driving expected synergy benefits at the time of restructuring (9.57). It is helpful that the OECD acknowledges that profits may not actually increase for the MNE group after the restructuring, and could even fall, either because the restructuring is aimed more at maintaining competitiveness than increasing it, or because expected synergies do 79 not always materialize in practice (9.58). Lastly, and most challenging, the OECD requires an assessment of realistic alternatives for each party in a restructuring (9.59). This stage asks the taxpayer to identify the next best realistic alternatives to the original or restructured business arrangement. This analysis acts as a prelude to a calculation of potential losses in profit potential, discussed below, and impacts the bargaining power of each party operating at arm's length. The OECD does not require an exhaustive search, rather: “if there is a realistically available option that is clearly more attractive, it should be considered in the analysis of the conditions of the restructuring” (9.64). In practice it is likely that relative bargaining power of the parties, taking into account features such as the uniqueness of the function in the open market, may be perceived as affecting the options available. If, after consideration of the facts, a conclusion can be drawn that nothing of value (in terms of rights and obligations) has been transferred as part of the restructuring, then it has no compensable profit potential (9.67). In this case, and assuming the above information is clearly documented, the further analysis discussed below would not be necessary. 3.8.2 Economic analysis The second phase of analysis evaluates the potential compensation due when it is concluded that valuable rights or obligations have been transferred. Two types of restructuring are considered. First, transfers of something with economic value in isolation i.e. transfers of tangible and intangible assets or an ongoing concern (9.74 – 9.99). Second, where contracts are renegotiated or terminated, for example in restructuring of risk around a group, i.e. converting a fully-fledged operator to limited risk (9.100 – 9.122). Sometimes, restructurings will encompass both types of transfer, in which case both should be considered together (9.101). 3.8.2.1 Transfers with economic value in isolation Where a transfer has economic value in isolation, the challenges appear more straightforward. The guidance focuses attention on what has been transferred, whether specific assets or an ongoing business and then on identification of appropriate pricing and valuation methodologies. Tangible assets are considered not to raise much difficulty (9.75), although transfers of inventory (perhaps as part of a de-risking) present challenges around arriving at an appropriate price for transferred raw materials and finished goods. Market based pricing, resale minus or cost plus methods could be used, depending on the facts and circumstances of the business (9.78). Intangible assets receive particular attention. Sound business reasons for transferring intangible assets within a group are explored (9.83), and restructuring where an intangible asset is transferred and then licensed back is not rejected 80 as non-commercial. However, the OECD does suggest that the two transactions are likely to be negotiated concomitantly, and gives an example that a transfer of an intangible for 100 which is licensed back at 100 a year is unlikely to be consistent with the arm's length principle (9.86). The reference to a transfer of an ongoing concern (defined as a functioning, economically integrated business unit, 9.93) suggests that the valuation of an ongoing concern can be greater than the sum of the separate elements (9.94). It goes on to state that: “Valuation methods that are used in acquisition deals between independent parties may prove useful to valuing the transfer of an ongoing concern between independent parties (9.94)” These methods would include income and market based valuation methods that value the transferred function as a separate business. This type of analysis rewards any goodwill in the transferring business. This could be problematic in a group situation, where both parties are likely to have existing relationships with other parts of the group and with third-parties, and so it can be difficult to identify goodwill for which the recipient would be prepared to pay over and above the value of the assets transferred. 3.8.2.2 Transfers that require a renegotiation or termination of existing contracts Where the restructuring does not involve the transfer of a specific asset or ongoing concern, but a renegotiation or termination of existing contractual arrangements (and where these have, as above, been determined to be rights and obligations with demonstrable value) the analysis is more complicated. A starting point will be to consider changes in profit potential that result from this analysis. However, the guidance (9.65) makes some very significant cautionary statements that the case for compensation under the arm's length principle is not determined by a reduction in profit potential: “An independent enterprise does not necessarily receive compensation when a change in its business arrangements results in a reduction in its profit potential or expected future profits.” It follows, therefore, that: “The arm's length principle does not require compensation for a mere decrease in the expectation of an entity's future profits.” The section goes on to emphasize that what is important in the first instance are the elements captured in the functional and factual analysis. However, given that this hurdle has been met: 81 “... an entity with considerable rights and/ or other assets at the time of the restructuring may have considerable profit potential, which must ultimately be appropriately remunerated in order to justify the sacrifice of such profit potential (9.67)”. The analysis suggested by the OECD attempts to calculate whether an entity is at least as well off as under other realistically available alternatives (9.71). If, after a proposed restructuring that involved de-risking, a distributor was expected to be left worse off (on a risk adjusted basis), this implies that either the post-restructuring is mispriced or additional compensation (by way of exit charge) would be required to remunerate the distributor (9.71). This example highlights the trade-off between the post-restructuring transfer price and any indemnification charge that may be due. In theory, a post-restructuring transfer price can be calculated that reflects properly the relative riskiness of the expected returns (as well as other realistically available alternatives –which in turn impacts the bargaining power of each of the parties)so that the restructuring is a zero sum game, with no separate indemnification charge being payable. This may mean that for de-risking scenarios, finding an appropriate post-restructuring transfer price will negate the need for an indemnification charge. However, Part 3 of the Chapter states a principle that post-restructuring transfer prices should in most cases be identical to newly structured transfer prices (9.123). To the extent that adopting this principle limits the appropriate post-restructuring transfer price to an amount that leaves the de-risked operator worse off than under its next best realistic alternative, an indemnification charge may be required to bridge the gap. The mechanics of calculating a post-restructuring transfer price is an area where the realities of a true third party scenario may be hard to recreate in transfer pricing situations between multinationals. For third parties there would likely be: uncertainty and dispute over profit forecasts; each party would have different information; different approaches to managing risk; and different attitudes towards risk. In multinationals these differences may not be present, or may not be fully understood, and are certainly unlikely to be reflected in financial forecasts that will be used to apply transfer pricing and valuation techniques (such as discounted cash flow), in any analysis of pre and post-restructuring profit potential. Another possible approach for assessing the value of any indemnification charge is to consider information on comparable restructurings. This can assist with identifying whether the terms of a restructuring are arm's length (9.50), as well as likely indemnification. As an example, if a manufacturer is considering outsourcing functions to a low cost country, examination of how such outsourcing transactions are structured at arm's length would be 82 relevant information. Independent parties do not necessarily require explicit compensation from a transferring entity, in particular where that entity also benefits from cost savings from the relocation (9.99). 3.8.3 Determine arm's length treatment This stage pulls together the analysis under the functional and factual analysis and the economic analysis, in order to conclude whether any indemnification payment would be due. In short, the answer depends on whether two parties would have agreed an indemnification payment in comparable circumstances at arm's length. To arrive at an assessment as to whether third parties would have agreed an indemnification payment, the first step is to conclude whether or not something of value (in terms of contractual rights and obligations) has been transferred. The second step (only necessary if the first step is answered in the affirmative) is to use established transfer pricing and valuation techniques to price transfers in isolation and/ or changes in profit potential. The Guidelines note that commercial/ case law could also help in determining how third parties would settle similar contract re-negotiations or terminations at arm's length (9.115). An example from Chapter IX Paragraphs 9.72 and 9.73 include a detailed example highlighting how these calculations may work in practice: 83 Source: July 2010, OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines In case no. 1, the distributor is surrendering a profit potential with significant uncertainties for a relatively low but stable profit. Whether an independent party would be willing to surrender this profit potential would depend on its anticipated return under both scenarios, on its level of risk tolerance and on its options realistically available and on possible compensation for the restructuring itself. In case no. 2, it is unlikely that independent parties in the distributor’s situation would agree to relocate the risks and associated profit potential for no additional compensation if they had the option to do otherwise. Case no. 3 illustrates the fact that the analysis should take account of the profit potential going forward and that, where there is a significant change in the commercial or economic environment, relying on historical data alone will not be sufficient. 84 3.9 Questions 1. Which of the following is not a method for assigning value to an intangible: A. Income Based Method B. Market Based Method C. Cost Based Method D. All of the above are accepted methods 2. True or False: The price of an intangible equals the value of an intangible: A. True B. False 3. Which of the following are not factors of Determining the Discount Rate and Capitalization Rate: A. The general level of interest rates B. A premium for perceived financial risk C. The holder of the patents D. A premium for perceived business risk E. All of the above are factors in determining the discount rate and capitalization rate 4. The present value calculations in the income based method are based on how many principal components: A. 5 B. 2 C. 7 D. 3 3.10 Answers 1. 2. 3. 4. D. B. C. D 85 4 Business models: Intangible Property configurations Authors: Steef Huibregtse/Steven Carey/Elizabeth King 86 4.1 Introduction Once it is identified that a business has a need for Intangible Property (IP”) 29 in order to grow, establish a brand and client base or develop proprietary technology, the next critical question is what is the optimal business model/IP configuration from a commercial, transfer pricing and tax perspective. This chapter explores the four broad IP business models that are typically applied as well as their transfer pricing and tax implications. 4.2 Overview of business models from a commercial perspective: 4.2.1 Licensing-in model The first and simplest model is based on the concept of the IP that is being used being owned by another party (either related or unrelated) and access being provided typically through payment of a royalty or license fee. The model could be applied to any type of IP including brand, technology or know how. This model enables the licensee to benefit from access to IP immediately without the need to incur the cost and the risk of developing it inhouse. From the perspective of the licensor it provides an opportunity to earn a return through a royalty/license fee stream for the cost and risk of developing the IP. Licensor License fee/Royalty Provision of IP Licensee Below is an example of a business model by using a Dutch company as an IP company or intermediary royalty collector for Chinese/Taiwanese multinationals. 29 In the context of Lesson 4, the terms “Intangible Property,” “Intangibles” and “IP” are used interchangeably. 87 Parent Company China/Taiwan License Royalty Dutch Company (IP company) Interest/Royalty Directive License Royalty Company B1, B2, B3... EU Tax treaty License Royalty Company C1, C2, C3... Non-EU In this model, the Dutch company acts as an IP company or intermediary royalty collector to provide license to relevant group companies in EU countries or non EU-countries. According to the EU country Interest/Royalty Directive and extensive tax treaty network with non-EU countries, the royalty paid to the Dutch company is subject to zero or lower Withholding Tax. 4.2.2 In house development model This second model is based on the idea that the entity develops its own IP in-house. This could be over an extended period such as the development of a brand through marketing expenditure or through a more deliberate establishment of an R&D team to develop a specific product such as a pharmaceutical compound, method of production or software code. This model shifts all the risk to the entity performing the development, with potentially significant upside if the development is successful and a sunk cost if unsuccessful. The entity is then free to utilize the IP as they see fit without restriction and would not be incurring royalty/license fee costs going forward. 88 4.2.3 Contract R&D model The third model involves using a third or related party contract R&D provider to undertake the R&D work. The R&D provider acts under contract with the principal and is remunerated based on total costs plus a profit mark-up (or an alternative model such as hourly rates). The principal is responsible for all decisions on what products are to be developed and how resources are allocated. In this model the economic and legal ownership of any IP developed remains with the principal. The benefit of such a model is that the principal is not required to recruit and train an R&D team and as with the above model is not required to incur royalty/license fee costs for IP owned by a third party. The downside is that a cost is incurred for R&D which may prove to be unsuccessful and not lead to creation of any IP. Service Fee Contract R&D entity Licensor (Principal) Provision of contract R&D services License fee/Royalty Provision of IP Licensee Example: Below is an example used in the business model of Chinese/Taiwanese multinationals, it is by using a related contract R&D company (normally based in China/Taiwan) to provide the R&D work. The R&D company will be remunerated based on cost plus mark up. 89 S (IP1) Investment Centre Contract R&D (cost recharge + mark-up) Contract R&D (cost recharge +mark-up) R&D Manufacturing CN/TW CN/TW (IP2 for European products) Investment Centre Principal Company SG/HK Country of origin HQ/Cost Centre Sales of finished goods (cost plus mark up) Stepping stone Matchmaker/ Profit Centre Holding NL Logistics Europe NL Sales of finished goods; Reinbursment of brand advertising Legal title S&M NL S&M C GER S&M Residual IP1: Manufacturing IC Principal Company PC IP2: Principal Company PC/IC IT The manufacturing company (based in China/Taiwan, normally they are also the headquarters of the group) would use the related contract R&D company to provide product related IP. In this case, the manufacturing company is entitled to receive residual profit together with the profit centre. On the other hand, the Principal Company (based in Hong Kong or Singapore, acting as a profit centre) would also use the related contract R&D company to provide product related IP; however, it is more from design or function’s perspective customized for the European market. To this end, the Principal Company is entitled to receive all residual profit. 4.2.4 Cost sharing model Finally, the cost sharing model is based on the idea that various (generally related) parties may be in a position to contribute funding and/or resources to a cost sharing model in respect of the IP development. The resultant IP would be owned respectively by each of the parties in proportion to their contribution. This avoids the need for royalty/license fee payments to access the IP developed and spreads the risk and funding cost across several entities. 90 Provision of resources Cost sharing participants Cost sharing Arrangement Commensurate access to IP 4.3 Transfer pricing and general corporate tax considerations of each model 4.3.1 Licensing in The licensor is typically subject to corporate tax on the royalty/license fee payments received. In some countries this may qualify for concessional or zero tax treatment under certain tax regimes to encourage ownership and development of IP. From the perspective of the licensee the following considerations apply: • There is typically an obligation to withhold tax at a prescribed rate under domestic law. This may be nullified or reduced under certain tax treaties. The tax is withheld on behalf of the licensor and is generally re-charged in some form. • A deduction is generally allowed for the amount of the royalty. For both the licensor and licensee transfer pricing guidelines are a significant consideration. The royalty amount needs to be considered arm’s length and ideally supported by evidence that the IP being licensed is actually used in the business of the licensee and by a benchmarking study supporting the rate charged. In some countries such as India and China such arrangements may also face challenges from a foreign exchange perspective. 4.3.2 In-house development Under this model the expenses incurred in the development of the IP, such as marketing costs to develop brand intangibles, or R&D costs for product IP, are generally a deductible expense. In some cases this can also be accelerated as countries through their tax regimes attempt to encourage further R&D and to encourage taxpayers to take a longer term view of IP development. It is important from a transfer pricing perspective that at some point in time the R&D efforts lead to the development of a valuable intangible which generates premium profitability for 91 the entity. For example, the Chinese authorities have a very clear view of marketing intangibles generated by MNCs through marketing expenditure in China and expect a premium profit to be recognized at some point in return for the deductibility of marketing spend. 4.3.3 Contract R&D The tax implications of contract R&D are relatively straightforward. For the entity performing the contract R&D the remuneration received should lead to an arm’s length mark-up on total costs, which is subject to corporate tax. For the principal in this transaction, the spending on contract R&D should be deductible and expected to produce in due course some IP that enables it to generate a premium return. The payments are not typically subject to withholding tax. In this model it is important that the principal is genuinely controlling the key decision associated the R&D process, including what to develop, prioritization of work and in broad terms how to develop it. If the principal is not seen to be in control of this process the question may arise whether this is genuinely a contract R&D arrangement and therefore which party ultimately owns the IP resulting from such process. 4.3.4 Cost sharing A cost sharing arrangement generally requires an agreement between the parties stipulating contributions and shares of any output, as well as details on buy in payments if applicable. In several countries for an entity to be a part of a cost sharing arrangement the agreement must be lodged with the relevant tax authority. Subject to the above compliance steps, contributions are generally deductible. One attractive feature of a cost sharing arrangement is that the payments are not subject to withholding tax and no mark-up is applicable (in contrast to a royalty or contract R&D structure). To the extent that there is existing IP that is to form part of the arrangement, any new participants will be required to make a buy-in payment based on the value of the existing IP at the date of commencement. 92 4.4 Model implementation – high level guidance on implementing each of the above models, including: 4.4.1 Legal framework for managing IP Although beyond the scope of this course it is important that the portfolio of IP also be addressed from a legal and contractual perspective. Some legal considerations include: • Ensuring that appropriate contracts are in place to create consistency between the legal and economic reality of the business model – although in transfer pricing it is well established that economic reality is leading, it is common for tax authorities to use the legal agreements and contracts as the starting point for any investigation into the ownership of IP. Ensuring that the legal framework is rigid and consistent with how the business operates also helps to avoid various risks such as the creation of a permanent establishment for tax purposes. • Addressing whether certain IP such as trademarks etc. need to be registered and in which jurisdictions. • To the extent that the IP is valuable and unique, should a patent be sought, how is this maintained and what level of protection can it provide? • What to document and benchmark? Regardless of the model selected, as indicated above there is a need to provide the appropriate level of transfer pricing support for the structure in order to withstand scrutiny from tax authorities. Depending on the model this may include: • Benchmarking studies for royalty rates based on one of the available databases of royalty and licensing agreements. • Benchmarking studies for cost plus mark-ups for contract R&D activities typically performed using a database to identify net margins of independent companies performing comparable functions. • Valuation studies for buy in payments under a cost sharing arrangement – refer to separate chapter on valuation methodologies. The table below illustrates how to locate intangibles in value chain 30. 30 Source: TPA Playbook, 2012. 93 Supplier • • • • • • • Profit Center + Investment Center ‘Cost Center” contractors Manufacturing R&D Logistics Packaging “Revenue Center” sales/ services hubs Sales/Marketing Repair & Warranty Call Center Customer • SSC Supplier IP Company / “Investment Center” • IP creation & management Royalty • • • • • ‘Cost Center” contractors Manufacturing R&D Logistics Packaging SSC “Profit Center” • Dashboard/Matchmaker • • • “Revenue Center” sales/ services hubs Customer Sales/Marketing Repair & Warranty Call Center access to residual result no access to residual result The table below is an example of product intangibles 31, which illustrates how R&D activities lead to ownership of intangibles through determining a policy for single versus shared ownership. R&D Cost Centralized Decentralized Centralized Sole owner Cost contribution /cost sharing Decentralized Sole owner + contract R&D Cost Contribution /cost sharing R&D Activities 4.5 Case Study Case Study 1 Overview: 31 Source: TPA Playbook, 2012. 94 Our client is a NYSE listed company that has recently established an IP management company in Singapore. The company in Singapore was granted a tax incentive award by the Singapore Economic Development Board (EDB) for a certain period of time. In particular, in order to qualify for the tax incentive award as an IP management company, the company is required to undertake certain tasks which includes, and is not limited to, the following: • Conduct R&D activities in Singapore; and • Own and manage an intellectual property (IP) portfolio with a value of at least S$100 million and maintain this portfolio until the end of the incentive period. We have been engaged by the client to assist them in determining the value of IP as it is progressively transferred to Singapore. In addition, we have assisted them in designing their IP management policy, by taking into consideration the nature of the IP, the current ownership rights as well as future plans and objectives of the company. Key issues that we dealt with: • Definition and labelling of IP Given the complicated nature of the company’s operations, we first had to understand the nature of IP and in order to determine how to best configure the IP within the client’s business model and value it. Some IP was characterized as process related IP while others were product intangibles. This was done through a detailed analysis of the IP by speaking with several senior people. In some cases, the IP was legally protected through patents. However, in most cases, the IP owned in this company was not legally protected, yet the company believed that they had valuable IP, which could be proxied by significantly higher operating margins. A key aspect of the IP was the fact that the ability to reverse engineer the IP was strongly protected not by patents but by customer contracts and Non-Disclosure Agreements (NDAs). • Valuation of IP The IP owned by the entities is varied. This suggests that the valuation techniques that are used to value the IP need to take into account the varied nature of the IP as well as the data that is available. Situations that we faced were as follows: 1. A new product was being manufactured based on IP that was in existence in the market place for more than 15 years. The new product involved new R&D and parts that enhanced the marketability of the existing IP which was being used competitively. A prototype was built to market this new product to new and existing customers. Given that no revenues had been generated in more than 6 months since the prototype was 95 created, and given that it was a recent R&D project, it was determined that the cost based method was the most appropriate in this case. 2. The company had decided to stop manufacturing a particular product line in Europe due to cost reasons. Rather, due to lower manufacturing costs in China, the company decided that on an going basis the products will be manufactured in China. The Chinese manufacturing entity will continue to sell the products to existing customers in Europe as well as to new customers in Asia. It was determined that the best method in this case was the income based method, where we analysed the revenues that were foregone by the European manufacturer to proxy for the minimum amount that the IP would be valued at. 3. In the third example, we had a technology that was not being commercially marketed in the US very successfully, although it was protected through a patent. Market analysis seems to suggest that selling the product in China would be a more commercially viable option and the company wanted to transfer the Asian rights to this IP to Singapore. In this case, we envision having to value to patent per se which may provide the minimum value that the seller would expect. • Selection of IP business model It should be noted that in all the cases we also helped the company determine what was the most appropriate IP transfer methodology. For example in (a) given that new revenues have yet been recognized by any of the entities as a result of the IP, it was determined that it would be most conservative to enter into a buy-in cost share arrangement between the US and Singapore in relation to the IP. This would enable both parties to reap the benefits arising from the IP. However, in (b), given that the company had made a commercial decision that they would only manufacture the product in Asia on a going forward basis, due to cost reasons, it was determined that a lump sum payment for this IP would be most appropriate. 4.6 Questions with model answers 1. Company ABC, an Italian clothing brand, has through marketing expenditure over several years, developed a recognised global brand. Company ABC understands the market opportunities in the Chinese market and has recently established a Chinese subsidiary in order to market and distribute the product in China. What is the optimal business model from an IP perspective for the company to give the Chinese subsidiary access to its brand, and what are the transfer pricing implications? 2. Company XYZ, a Swiss pharmaceutical MNC, is involved in the development of several drug compounds and in the various testing phases of pharmaceuticals prior to release. Company 96 ZYZ has a US subsidiary that has set up a team to perform some development and testing of the same drugs concurrently with the Swiss team. The group is seeking guidance on how to configure this IP model to manage transfer pricing risk going forward. 4.7 Multiple choice questions 1. Which of the following is not a feature of the licensing in-model: A. Licensor has exclusive ownership of the IP B. Licensee pays a royalty to the licensor for access to IP C. Licensor and licensee jointly fund R&D through a cost sharing arrangement D. Risk of IP development is borne by the licensor 2. Which of the following is not an advantage of a cost sharing arrangement: A. Can be effective means for funding R&D through excess cash in the group B. Ensures that resulting IP is owned and managed exclusively by the licensor C. Eliminates need for withholding tax on royalty payments D. Enables participants to share in the IP commensurately with their contribution. 3. What typically needs to be benchmarked or valued in relation to a licensing-in IP model? A. The value of the buy-in payment for the existing IP B. The mark-up on costs of the contract R&D provider C. The royalty rate to be paid by the licensee to licensor D. Both a and c 4. What is the optimal model from a tax planning perspective? A. The cost sharing model as it eliminates withholding tax B. The licensing in model as it isolates IP ownership in one entity C. In-house development as it may allow for accelerated deductibility D. It depends. 4.8 Answers to open and multiple choice questions Answers to open questions: 97 1. A: On the assumption that the company wishes to retain legal and economic ownership of the brand and other marketing intangibles in Italy, the optimal model is a licensing model whereby the Italian company charges a royalty for the brand and other marketing intangibles to the Chinese company. This royalty needs to be benchmarked and fully supported from a transfer pricing perspective. The company should also note that over time, to the extent that local marketing spend is being incurred in China, the Chinese tax authorities may determine that a local marketing intangible is also being developed, expecting a premium profit from this intangible and perhaps questioning whether a benefit is being received from the payment of the royalty i.e. the risk that the Chinese adaptation of the brand has evolved into a new brand that is economically owned in China. 2. A: The optimal model depends on a number of factors: • Is the group willing to have joint legal/economic ownership of the IP going forward? • How is the R&D being funded? Is there cash in the US subsidiary that could be efficiently used to fund the R&D? • Who is making key decisions on the R&D and drug development and where is this person/team based? Responses to the above questions enable a decision to be made between a contract R&D model, whereby the US entity would act as the contract service provider with all key decisions being made in the Swiss company or a cost sharing model. Under a contract R&D model, the US company receives a cost plus return on total costs of the R&D effort, regardless of the success or failure. The Swiss company owns the outcomes of the R&D process and is entitled to all future royalties etc. resulting from a successful outcome. In contrast, if there is cash available to fund the R&D in the US and the group wishes to have joint ownership going forward, a cost sharing model could be considered. The Swiss and US company would contribute in an agreed proportion to the R&D and testing cost and have proportionate ownership in the resulting IP. Answers to multiple choice questions: 1. C 2. B 3. C 4. D 98 4.9 Literature • TPA Playbook • TPA’s “Transfer Pricing Workshop for Chinese and Taiwanese Multinationals – Inbound Investments into Europe.” 99 5 Intellectual Property Law and Transfer Pricing Authors: Eric Matser/Dorus van der Burgt 100 5.1 Introduction This lesson outlines of the basic legal system of Intellectual Property (“IP”)32 rights. The legal system in respect to Intellectual Property may not be determining in all Transfer Pricing cases, but in any event the significance should be determined wittingly. The objective of this lesson is to cover the following topics: • • • • • • 5.2 a brief history of Intellectual Property (5.2) the future of Intellectual Property (5.3) appearance of Intellectual Property rights (5.4) legal aspects of IP exploitation (5.5) legal aspects of IP management (5.6) legal aspects of IP transfer (5.7) Brief History of IP Intellectual Property law is part of the much broader competitive trading law. The general purpose of competitive trading law is to create or maintain a fair, open and accessible market. Intellectual Property law generally aims to protect, stimulate, encourage and reward amongst others creative achievements, technical inventions, industrial design and distinctive signs. Protection, stimulation encouragement and reward are achieved by granting (exclusive) rights to the creators of any of these efforts. One competitor having an exclusive right has a direct and restrictive influence on competitive trading. The term “Intellectual Property” is relatively new and came into existence in the midst of the 19th century. Towards the end of the 19th century, several (mostly European) countries realized the necessity for an international approach to Intellectual Property Rights. The first international efforts to regulate and harmonise Intellectual Property law (avant la lettre) were the Paris Convention of 1883 on the protection of Industrial Property and the Berne Convection of 1986 on the protection of literary and artistic works. The administrative secretariats established by these two conventions merged in 1893 and adopted the term Intellectual Property as a collective noun for the different rights governed by both conventions. Eventually this organization evolved into the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), located in Geneva, Switzerland. 32 In the context of lesson 5, the terms “intellectual property” and “IP” are used interchangeably. 101 Since the Paris and Berne Convention came into existence, the importance and manifestation of specific Intellectual Property rights has changed. Trademarks have become ever more important. New technologies gave rise to whole new areas of research and accompanying patents, the choice of products available to the public has grown, making design and innovation more important. The introduction of computers and the internet made information readily available in previously unattainable quantities. These changes were met with many attempts by legislators and international organizations to regulate this growing importance. In Europe, The European Committee issued a large amount of Directives and Guidelines to harmonize and regulate Intellectual Property Law. 33 Internationally, the member states of the WIPO concluded 24 treaties to further develop an international consensus on the use and protection of Intellectual Property 34. This contribution focuses on the international aspects of Intellectual Property rights. Although there are a number of treaties and for Europe Directives and Regulations, Intellectual Property law is mostly national law. Within the scope of this contribution, it is not possible to inventory the many differences between national regulations of intellectual property rights. Instead, this contribution only regards the international similarities. 5.3 Future of IP Globalization and more close to home Europeanization of Intellectual Property rights will continue. More and more treaties, including European Directives and Regulations will come, that will further harmonize Intellectual Property law. One of the clear benefits of this development is the gradual disappearance of differences in national law, thus generating equality and predictability of rights for international competitors. Since the midst of the 19th century, Intellectual Property has become a valuable asset to the persons or companies that own or control them. In the wake of this development, focus has shifted from the pure protection and stimulation of creative achievements, technical inventions, industrial design and distinctive signs to the protection of investments (e.g. databases) and other purely economic interests (e.g. geographical indications). Lobbying has had and will continue to have a profound influence on the international development of Intellectual Property rights and law. 33 For example some regulations include Directive 2004/48/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 29 April 2004 on the enforcement of intellectual property rights, The Information Society Directive (2001/29/EC 22 May 2001), and Directive 98/71/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October 1998 on the legal protection of designs 34 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/treaties/en/ 102 Another aspect of globalization is the fact that the internet and modern transportation methods invite companies to not only focus on their traditional regional or national market, but to enter international or even worldwide markets. Where it used to be hard to expand the market for certain, nowadays it’s more of a challenge to limit sales to a specific area. This may cause problems when products – intentionally or unintentionally - enter markets where other competitors - with their own exclusive rights - are already active. The evolution and international importance of Intellectual Property rights will further increase when globalization reaches Asia. Intellectual Property rights are not yet generally regarded as a valuable asset or even an exclusive right that is to be respected. In 2006 Weerawit Weeraworawit of Thailand's Ministry of Commerce said on this matter: "A lot of education is needed among the population at large to convince people that it's better to earn a living from our own creation and innovation than copying from someone else". 35 5.4 Appearance of IP Intellectual property rights are customarily divided into two main areas 36: 5.4.1 Copyright and rights related to copyright. The rights of authors of literary and artistic works such as books and other writings, poems and plays, films, musical compositions, computer programs (software) and artistic works such as drawings, paintings, photographs and sculptures, and architectural designs are protected by copyright. 5.4.2 Industrial property. Industrial property can usefully be divided into two main areas: • One area can be characterized as the protection of distinctive signs, in particular trade marks (which distinguish the goods or services of one undertaking from those of other undertakings) and geographical indications (which identify a good as originating in a place where a given characteristic of the good is essentially attributable to its geographical origin). 35 Source: CNET News, “Asia warms up to intellectual property”, http://news.cnet.com/Asia-warms-up-tointellectual-property/2100-1030_3-6108596.html 36 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/intel1_e.htm 103 The protection of such distinctive signs aims to stimulate and ensure fair competition and to protect consumers, by enabling them to make informed choices between various goods and services. The protection may last indefinitely, provided the sign in question continues to be distinctive. • Other types of industrial property are protected primarily to stimulate innovation, design, and the creation of technology. In this category fall inventions (protected by patents), industrial designs, and trade secrets. The social purpose is to provide protection for the results of investment in the development of new technology, thus giving the incentive and means to finance research and development activities. A functioning intellectual property regime should also facilitate the transfer of technology in the form of foreign direct investment, joint ventures, and licensing. The protection is usually given for a finite term (typically 20 years in the case of patents). This division is not ironclad. Many Intellectual Property rights have elements of both main areas. Inventory and definition of the most well-known Intellectual Property rights In this inventory we will focus on Copyright, Patents, Designs and Trade marks. Although there are many other, important, interesting Intellectual property rights, it is not possible to analyse and describe them all in detail. Towards the end of this inventory, we will briefly summarize some other Intellectual Property rights. The scope of this summary doesn’t allow an in-depth review of other IP-related intangibles such as goodwill, trade secrets, and knowhow. 5.4.3 Copyright Copyright was one of the first Intellectual Property rights to become the topic of an international treaty. The goal of the 1886 Berne Convention 37 was to create a Union for protection of copyright, or as it reads in article 1: “the rights of authors in their literary and artistic works”. The term “works” is not really defined. The Berne Convention merely contains a list of appearances of works that include “every production in the literary, scientific and artistic domain, whatever may be the mode or form of its expression, such as books, pamphlets and other writings; lectures, addresses, sermons and other works of the same nature; dramatic or dramatico-musical works; choreographic works and entertainments in dumb show; 37 Source: http://www.wipo.int/treaties/en/ip/berne/trtdocs_wo001.html#P85_10661. 104 musical compositions with or without words; cinematographic works to which are assimilated works expressed by a process analogous to cinematography; works of drawing, painting, architecture, sculpture, engraving and lithography; photographic works to which are assimilated works expressed by a process analogous to photography; works of applied art; illustrations, maps, plans, sketches and three-dimensional works relative to geography, topography, architecture or science” (Article 2, section 1 of the Berne Convention). The term “author” is not defined in the Berne Convention. This causes significant differences in national copyright regulation. One of the most important problems created by this difference in definition of the term “author” is found when regarding the possibility of copyright of a company or an employer. In some countries, an employer automatically becomes the author of any works created by his employees while performing their – normal – duties38. In other countries the employee is the author 39. In Europe, multiple EC Directives where issued on Copyright or Copyright related topics, mostly regulating specific forms of Copyright, or reacting to changes in modern communication technology 40. In 2001 however, the EC issued the so-called “Copyright Directive” in an effort to harmonize copyright in Europe 41. Whatever the differences are on other issues regarding copyright, a copyright grants essentially the same rights to authors in all states that signed the Berne Convention. Having a copyright means that an author has the exclusive right of authorizing the reproduction of these works, in any manner or form. This gives the author an exclusive right with both a negative and a positive angle. The negative angle is the authors right to forbid anyone to reproduce his works. His right is exclusive. The author can choose to exploit his own works, where none of his competitors are allowed to do so. The positive angle is that the author can authorize others to reproduce his work within limitations or under conditions set by the author. This gives the author total control over his works, even when they are being reproduced by others. Both angles can be profitable. 38 For example: The Netherlands, UK and USA. 39 For example: Italy, France and Germany. 40 For example: the Council Directive of 14 May 1991 on the legal protection of computer programs (91/250/EEC). 41 Directive 2001/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 22 May 2001 on the harmonization of certain aspects of copyright and related rights in the information society. 105 In general copyrights are granted for a minimum period of 50 years after the death of the author. For some specific works – such as films, photographs, and applied art – the period of protection starts at the moment the work was first made available to the public. 5.4.4 Patent Patent law has traditionally been a largely harmonized legal field. The Paris Convention (1883) 42 formulated a minimal level of protection. Further regulation and harmonization was achieved when the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT) was conceived in Washington (1971) 43 , regulating cooperation between national patent agencies. The Strasbourg Conventions of 1963 44 and 1971 defined key concepts of international patent law, paving the way for the 1973 European Patent Convention (EPC) 45 that regulates a uniform granting procedure in Europe. Although many treaties and conventions came to be, it never resulted in an actual international or even European patent, although the PCT refers to a possibility to apply for an “international patent”. This international patent application is in effect nothing more than a bundle of national applications. A patent – in the sense of these treaties and Conventions - is an exclusive right granted to inventors. The Strasbourg Convention of 1963 regulates the conditions that have to be met by an invention in order to qualify for a patent. The Strasbourg Convention defines several criteria, of which these are the most important: • Patents shall be granted for any inventions which are susceptible of industrial application, which are new and which involve an inventive step (article 1); • An invention shall be considered as susceptible of industrial application if it can be made or used in any kind of industry (article 3); • An invention shall be considered to be new if it does not form part of the state of the art (article 4 section 1); and 42 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/treaties/en/ip/paris/trtdocs_wo020.html#P83_6610 43 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/pct/en/texts/articles/atoc.htm 44 Source: Council of Europe, “Convention on the Unification of Certain Points of Substantive Law on Patents for Invention”, http://conventions.coe.int/treaty/EN/treaties/html/047.htm 45 Source: European Patent Office, “The European Patent Convention”, http://www.epo.org/lawpractice/legal-texts/epc.html 106 • An invention shall be considered as involving an inventive step if it is not obvious having regard to the state of the art (article 5). A patent will only be granted after an application. Applications will generally be made by the inventor himself, or his employer. In most of Europe countries, the ownership of an invention made by an employee is granted to the employer by law, if the invention was made in the course of the inventor's normal or specifically assigned employment duties. In some countries it is necessary to expressly stipulate this in an employment agreement. In the USA however, only the inventor himself can apply for a patent. In turn, this inventor can be bound by contract to assign the patent to his employer. A patent grants the holder an exclusive right with a certain negative and possible a positive angle. On the one hand the negative angle of a patent gives the holder a possibility to exclude others from using his invention. On the other hand, the patent may be based upon an earlier patent by another inventor. In that case, the holder of the patent is not allowed to use the earlier patent himself without consent of the holder of the older patent. Only when a patent is not hindered or limited by earlier patents, the positive angle comes into play and the holder can allow others to use the invention. In general patents are granted for a period of 20 years. This minimum period was included in the 1994 Agreement on Trade-Related aspects of Intellectual Property rights (TRIPs) 46. For specific patents, such as patents for medication, it’s possible to get a one-time extension for an additional 5 years. 5.4.5 Design Just like patents, design rights are considered to be Industrial Property rights. Alongside patents, design rights were also covered in the 1883 Paris Convention. International efforts were made in the 1925 The Hague Convention to harmonize and to simplify the deposition of design rights47. This convention wasn’t very appealing for countries like the USA, Japan, and the UK that demand a prior review on substantive grounds before accepting a deposition of a model. The original text of The Hague Convention doesn’t allow a prior review. The ultimate goal of The Hague Convention (global harmonization) could therefore not be reached. Subsequently, The Hague Convention was amended several times and was 46 Source: World Trade Organization, “TRIPS: AGREEMENT ON TRADE-RELATED ASPECTS OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS” http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/t_agm3_e.htm 47 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/hague/en/legal_texts/wo_hal0_.htm 107 ultimately renewed in 1999 in Geneva 48 . This renewal facilitates the participation of countries that demand a prior review. In Europe, national law on design rights varies greatly. Where some countries have specific national laws concerning design rights, other countries simply rely on copyrights for the protection of designs. The EC intervened with the 1998 Design Directive 49 and the 2001 Design Regulation 50, defining design rights and creating the possibility of a Community Design right. For the purposes of the Design Regulation, a design means the appearance of the whole or a part of a product resulting from the features of, in particular, the lines, contours, colours, shape, texture and/or materials of the product itself and/or its ornamentation (article 3 Design Regulation). The Regulation only offers protection to designs that are “new” and have “individual character”. A design is considered “new” if no identical design has been made available to the public. A design has “individual character” if it’s overall impression differs from the overall impressions by earlier designs. Designs that are dictated by their technical function or must-fit criteria are not eligible for protection. A Community Design right gives the holder an exclusive right. The registration of a design shall confer on its holder the exclusive right to use it and to prevent any third party not having his consent from using it. The aforementioned use shall cover, in particular, the making, offering, putting on the market, importing, exporting or using of a product in which the design is incorporated or to which it is applied, or stocking such a product for those purposes (article 12 Design Directive and 19 Design Regulation). Registration of a Community Design gives the holder an exclusive right for duration of five years. This exclusive right can be extended with a maximum of four more periods of five years to a total duration of 25 years. The Design Directive and Design Regulation also created an exclusive right to an unregistered Design. The unregistered Design is modelled after copyright and exists at the 48 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/hague/en/legal_texts/wo_haa_t.htm 49 Source: European Union Law, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:31998L0071:en:HTML 50 Source: European Union Law, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:32002R0006:EN:NOT 108 moment of creation. It lasts for three years but only protects against clear imitation, where a registered Community Design will also give protection against derivative designs. 5.4.6 Trade mark Trade marks are considered to be Industrial property, but not in the same way as Patents and Designs. A trade mark doesn’t necessarily involve an invention or a creative effort. A trade mark is a distinctive sign that identifies goods or services for the public. This allows the industrial efforts of the Trade mark holder to communicate to the public that these products or services are his. As were patents and designs, trade marks were covered in the 1883 Paris Convention. Some general agreements were made on the protection of well-known trade marks, the impossibility to claim trade marks on crests, flags and other emblems of member states and loss of rights to trade marks that haven’t been used for some time. In the 1981 Madrid System an International trade mark bureau was created, making it possible to register international trade marks 51. An applicant for an international trade mark has to have at least one national trade mark first before he can apply for an international trade mark. The applicant can choose the countries in which he wants his trade mark to be registered. The international trade mark is not a right in itself. It is merely a bundle of national trade marks. In every country the international trade mark is valid, the level and extent of protection is based on the national law of that country and registration costs have to be paid. Due to specific demands in national law, or the existence of older national trade marks, it is possible that an international application will be awarded in some of the designated countries, and denied in others. In Europe, national law on trade marks traditionally differed greatly. For example, some countries have a mandatory examination before approving a trade mark registration (e.g. Spain, Germany, UK, and the Benelux countries), while others have no preliminary examination at all (e.g. France and Italy). The countries that have a mandatory examination tend to have different standards for approval or denial of applications, so it’s possible that a trade mark that is valid in the Benelux countries can be denied in the UK for example, because it is the name of an existing person. Harmonization of all these different national traditions on trade mark law proved difficult if not impossible. The European legislators therefore chose another approach. Instead of trying to change the national trade mark laws of the member states, the 1993 Trade mark Regulation 52 created a completely new trade 51 Source: World Intellectual Property, http://www.wipo.int/madrid/en/ 52 Source: European Union Council, http://oami.europa.eu/en/mark/aspects/reg/reg4094.htm 109 mark; the Community Trade mark. The Trade mark regulation creates its own European Trade mark law, establishes its own trade mark bureau in Alicante, Spain (The Office for Harmonization in the Internal Market (OHIM)) 53. The OHIM examines all Community trade mark applications before allowing a preliminary registration. After examination and preliminary approval by the OHIM, a three month opposition period begins in which trade mark holders with a possibly conflicting older national or Community trade mark can oppose against definitive registration of an application. A Community trade mark will be valid in all Community countries and is therefore more likely to conflict with pre-existing national trade marks. After the opposition period, it is still possible for the holder of an older trade mark, to start legal proceedings against a Community Trade mark based on infringement. In case a community trade mark is lost in a single country, the Community Trade mark is not completely lost. The Community Trade mark itself ceases to exist, but the Trade mark Regulation created a possibility for the trade mark to live on as a collection of national trade marks in all remaining countries. As mentioned earlier, a trade mark is used as a distinctive sign, used to identify goods or services. Not every sign can be a trade mark though. A Community Trade mark may consist of any signs capable of being represented graphically, particularly words, including personal names, designs, letters, numerals, the shape of goods or of their packaging, provided that such signs are capable of distinguishing the goods or services of one undertaking from those of other undertakings (article 4 Trade mark Regulation). In article 7 the grounds for refusal of a Community Trade mark are listed. Community Trade marks will for example be refused because of a lack of distinctiveness, if they monopolise normal language or if they are purely describing in the sense that they only describe the characteristics of the goods or service. If however a Community Trade mark is granted, it gives the holder an exclusive right. The holder can prevent anyone from using in the course of trade: (a) any sign which is identical with the Community Trade mark in relation to goods or services which are identical with those for which the Community Trade mark is registered; (b) any sign where, because of its identity with or similarity to the Community Trade mark and the identity or similarity of the goods or services covered by the Community Trade mark and the sign, there exists a likelihood of confusion on the part of the public; the likelihood of confusion includes the likelihood of association between the sign and the trade mark; (c) any sign which is identical with or similar to the Community Trade mark in relation to goods or services which are not similar to those for which the Community Trade mark is 53 Source: European Union Council, http://oami.europa.eu/ows/rw/pages/index.en.do 110 registered, where the latter has a reputation in the Community and where use of that sign without due cause takes unfair advantage of, or is detrimental to, the distinctive character or the repute of the Community Trade mark (article 9 section 1 Trade mark Regulation). Article 9 describes the negative aspects of the exclusive right on a Community Trade mark. The positive aspect is the possibility of granting third parties consent to use the Trade mark, usually in the form of a license agreement. A Community Trade mark is granted for a period of 10 years and can be extended indefinitely with consecutive periods of 10 years. A Trade mark is an exclusive right, but only if actually used. A Community Trade mark can be lost if the holder doesn’t use it in the first five years after registration or during a period of 5 consecutive years (article 15 Trade mark Regulation). 5.4.7 Short summary of other Intellectual Property rights: 5.4.7.1 Neighbouring rights The rights of performers (e.g. actors, singers and musicians), producers of phonograms (sound recordings) and broadcasting organizations are protected through copyright and related or “neighbouring” rights. In the 1961 Rome Convention, these neighbouring rights were outlined 54. Contracting states are obliged to implement the outlines of the Rome Convention in their national law. In Europe neighbouring rights also include producers of films. Neighbouring rights are covered in the 1992 rental and lending Directive 55, later to be replaced by the 2006 Directive on rental right and lending right 56. 5.4.7.2 Plant breeders’ rights or plant variety rights Plant breeders' rights are exclusive rights granted to the breeder of a new variety of plant, giving the plant breeder exclusive control over all propagating material and harvested material of a new variety of plant. Plant breeders’ rights were internationally harmonized in 54 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/treaties/en/ip/rome/trtdocs_wo024.html 55 Source: European Union Law, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:31992L0100:EN:HTML 56 Source: European Union Law, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2006:376:0028:0035:EN:PDF 111 the 1961 International Union for the Protection of New Varieties of Plants (UPOV), revised in 1991 57. The 1994 European Regulation on plant variety rights58 the possibility of a Community right emerges, where the UPOV merely creates a possibility to file a collection of national rights. 5.4.7.3 Database rights Databases can contain a wide variety of information. Some or even most of this information will be protected under copyright. Where the creative aspect of copyright will generally be lacking in databases, databases may be the result of a substantial effort or investment. It’s these efforts and investments of the producer of a database that are the subject of the European Directive on the legal protection of databases. 59 The Directive creates a sui generis database right that gives the producer of a database an exclusive right. The Directive defines a database as: “a collection of independent works, data or other materials arranged in a systematic or methodical way and individually accessible by electronic or other means”. 5.4.7.4 Trade name Although there is a reference to trade names in the 1883 Paris Convention, stating that trade names will be protected in contracting states, international harmonization of trade name rights never came to pass. The contracting states still differ greatly on every aspect of trade names, even the definition. In some countries (e.g. France and The Netherlands) a trade name right is granted from the first moment a name is used to identify a company. In other countries (e.g. Switzerland and Germany) a trade name right is only granted after formal registration. In the UK and other legal systems that are based in English law, a trade name is merely a part of goodwill. 5.5 IP exploitation With the possible exception of patents, all intellectual property rights have a negative and a positive component. The negative component is the possibility to deny the use of the 57 Source: “INTERNATIONAL CONVENTION FOR THE PROTECTION OF NEW VARIETIES OF PLANTS” http://www.upov.int/export/sites/upov/upovlex/en/conventions/1991/pdf/act1991.pdf 58 Source: World Intellectual Property Organization, http://www.wipo.int/wipolex/en/details.jsp?id=1415 59 Source: European Union Law, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:31996L0009:EN:HTML 112 protected right to third parties, the positive is to right to grant the use of the protected right to third parties. 5.5.1 IP-rights for own use The negative component first creates a monopoly situation. The holder of the intellectual property right is the only one that is allowed to use that right or to exploit the knowledge or technique that is thereby revealed. The holder of the IP-right can then choose whether or not he wants to exploit this right himself or not. Exploiting the IP-right himself, or in his own organization gives the holder the assurance that he will be the only supplier of goods or services protected by the IP-right for the duration of the protection. The economic advantages of such a position are self-explanatory. 5.5.2 IP-rights granted to third parties If however the holder of an IP-right, such as for example an inventor, or author doesn’t have the possibility to produce or publish himself, he can choose to grant or transfer his rights to a third party. A contract by which the holder of an IP-right grants the right to use that IP-right to a third party is usually called a license. Licenses come in all shapes and sizes. A license can be restricted to the mere use of a product for specified purposes, such as for example private or workspace related software licenses. A license can even be restricted to a single event, for example a license to publicly show a movie on a specific date at a specific venue. It’s also possible to grant exclusive licenses to for example distributors in specified areas or countries, creating monopoly situations for every distributor in their respective areas. The license agreement can also dictate the use of the IP-right by the licensee. For example, it can dictate the way a trademark has to be used in advertisement, or the minimal technical requirements of a product sold under that trademark. Within a corporate structure, IPrights can be licensed to all or some of the involved legal entities. In return for granting a license, the holder of the licensed IP-right will usually demand compensation. The licensor is within reasonable limits free to decide the method and extent of compensation, thus making licenses a possibly profitable way of exploiting IP-rights. Another form of contracts relating to the use of IP-rights by third parties is franchising. In most franchising formulas, the franchise giver holds a collection of IP-rights, such as a trade mark, a trade name, possibly a patent or design rights, but in any case copyright. The franchise giver grants a franchise taker the right to use this collection of IP-rights under the condition that the franchise taker uses these rights in such a way as was dictated by the franchise giver to all of his franchise takers. Franchise formulas usually result in a uniform appearance of the companies, services or products of all franchise takers, with collective 113 advertisement and a recognizable image. Part of the franchise contract will always be a license for the use of the IP-rights involved in the formula. 5.5.3 Transfer of IP-rights Intellectual property rights are, as the term indicates, actual property rights, and therefore transferable. The holder can choose to sell his IP-rights. For example, an inventor that doesn’t have the means to produce a machine he invented can sell his patent rights. The inventor will still be named as inventor in the patent, but will no longer have the exclusive rights associated with the patent. It is also possible to sell off IP-rights related to production or services that the holder, for whatever reason, stopped using. These can still be interesting for former competitors or new-comers to a specific market. Later on in this contribution, we will further discuss the ins and outs of IP-transfers. In this section we merely state that transfer is one of the possibilities to exploit IP-rights. 5.6 IP management Just like other kinds of property, IP-rights can diminish in value, or even be lost without proper care and maintenance. With the proper care and maintenance, IP-rights can become or remain a valuable asset. In other words, IP-rights require constant management. 5.6.1 Action against infringement One way to lose an IP-right is to sit idly when third parties infringe upon an IP-right. If, for example, the holder of a well-known trademark knows about an infringement, but does not act, the trademark starts to lose its uniqueness, its distinctiveness (and part its value). Over time the trade mark gets “diluted”. If diluted enough, the trademark holder loses the ability to take action against any and all infringements by any third parties. With all IP-rights, doing nothing can be explained as tolerance (or even permission). If at any point, after having tolerated a competitor that infringed upon an IP-right for a certain amount of time, the IP-right holder wants to take action to end the infringement, legal action is not as straight forward as it should be. A simple request for a ban becomes more complex the longer the infringement was tolerated. If tolerated too long, any action will be denied. Until that threshold, the IP-holder may get the ban he’s after, but at a cost. Courts may find it reasonable that the IP-rights holder reimburses investments of the infringing party. The IP-rights holder will be held accountable for the fact that he did nothing while a competitor was investing, thus willingly creating more damage than necessary. 114 5.6.2 Prolonging and expanding IP-rights All registrations of IP-rights have an expiry date. Some of these registrations, like trademarks and design rights can be prolonged. A trade mark registration lasts for 10 years and can be prolonged indefinitely, a design right lasts for 5 years and can be prolonged 4 times. This prolongation has to be done before the registration expires. Although in many cases it is possible to ‘heal’ a tardy prolongation, it is better not to risk anyone registering a conflicting right in the period after the IP-right has expired. When developing IP-rights, or simply using them on a day-to-day basis, it’s important to stay alert. Any development, the slightest change, or even a difference in the daily use of an IPright may bring a possible new IP-right to life. For those IP-rights that need registering, it’s important to do so as soon as possible. For example, trade marks sometimes get abbreviated, creating a new distinctive sign that’s worth protecting, or a technician stumbles upon a better solution for an already patented invention. In that case, it might be worthwhile to also patent this improvement. If an IP-rights holder wishes to fully exploit and expand his IP-rights, his organization should be designed to support this wish. Knowhow that is present in the minds and skills of employees has to be made available permanently. Employment contracts and contracts with suppliers (and in some cases customers) have to contain secrecy and non-competition clauses to stop knowhow and possible new IP-rights from falling into the hands of competitors. The results of research and development are in danger of more than industrial espionage. Protocols and non-disclosure agreements can be put in place to avoid any leaking of research and development results. This is especially important in case of an invention that could be patented. If for any reason, like a presentation, or even placement of a proto-type next to a window that can be seen form a public space, a third party gets wind of the invention, the possibility to obtain (or maintain) a patent is at risk. As soon as the invention is made available to the public, it’s no longer new and is considered to be part of the state of the art. Another point of interest is the (annual) fees that are required for some of the IP-registers. Not paying the fee can result in the loss of an IP-right. Maintaining international patents may be a costly effort, as the patent holder has to pay an annual fee to all national patent offices in the countries the patent is valid. If the patent holder chooses to limit his economic efforts to specific countries, he can opt not to pay for some of the countries, thus losing the patent registration there, but maintaining the patent in the countries where it is profitable. 115 5.6.3 Positioning of IP-rights Another way to preserve, protect, and maintain IP-rights is to make sure that IP-rights are safely positioned in an organization. Any company that is actively involved in trade is at risk of running into legal disputes or financial problems. Since IP-rights are property in every legal sense, it is possible for a creditor to seize IP-rights in order to ensure redress. If at any given time, the creditor gains a right to foreclose, the seized IP-rights may be lost. To prevent this, IP-rights can be strategically placed in a legal entity that is not involved in trade of any kind, thus eliminating them as redress targets. This will also minimize the risk of loss of IP-rights in case of bankruptcy. If a company goes bankrupt, its assets will be applied for the benefit of all creditors. This usually means that the IP-rights will be sold off to the highest bidder. If however, the IP-rights are located in another legal entity, and the bankrupt company only has a license, the IP-rights stay under the control of the IP-rights holder to be used again in the future. Due to different national legislation regarding IP-rights, it’s also worth considering in what country the IP-rights are located. If creditors can seek redress on IP-rights, the IP-right holder can also use IP-rights as security interest to secure the payment of a debt or other obligation. In other words, IP-rights can be encumbered with, for example, a lien in order to get credit facilities from a bank. 5.7 IP transfer 5.7.1 Transfer by deed Previously we established that Intellectual Property rights can be sold, encumbered and transferred like any other property. Since IP-rights are intangibles, transfer has to be documented. A deed is required. In order to transfer registered IP-rights like trade marks, design rights or patent, registration of the deed of transfer is required. Third parties must be able to rely on the information in the public registrations of IP-rights. As long as the transfer of a registered IP-right isn’t actually registered and the register is corrected accordingly, third parties may in good faith consider the previous holder to still be the holder and act on that. 5.7.2 Reasons for transfer The most obvious reason for a transfer is of course a sale for a profit. But various other reasons for transfer may arise. When restructuring a corporate structure, or when building one, it’s important to strategically place IP-rights where they are at the lowest possible risk. But it’s also possible to transfer them to a country or legal entity for tax-related reasons, as IP-rights can be licensed for a fee. Internal licensing of IP-rights can thus generate cash flows within a corporate structure and may cause tax-related benefits or risks. 116 Also, strategically placing IP-rights in a corporate structure makes it possible for a corporate structure to sell or cast off unwanted legal entities, without risking the loss of IP-rights that where developed in or registered to that legal entity. Intellectual Property rights are usually transferred as a whole. In some cases it’s also possible to partially transfer IP-rights. For example, the holder of a patent may have a patent registration in 10 countries. In the last few years, his commercial efforts have been limited to only five of these countries. It may be worth considering selling the patent in the other five countries to third parties. If he’s not using it himself, he may as well exploit his rights by selling them off country by country. 5.7.3 Risks assessment and valuation issues First and foremost, parties need to verify whether or not the transferring party is actually the owner or holder of the IP-right to be transferred. With registered IP-rights, this is pretty straightforward; check the register. With copyrights and other non-registered IP-rights verifying ownership of IP is more complicated. Employment agreements, especially with research and development staff, hold important information. If IP-rights aren’t automatically transferred to the employer by law, employment agreements have to provide proof of transfer to the employer in order to be sure that the employer is authorized to transfer copyrights. When third parties are involved in the creation or development of IP-rights or product involving IP-rights, it’s important to establish ownership of the IP-rights on any new developments, creations or inventions that resulted in that involvement. If ownership isn’t assigned in an agreement, the owner of the IP-right is – most likely - the party that was responsible for or at least controlled and managed the actual creative or inventive work. This may not be the party that merely commissioned or paid for the work. Most IP-rights grant an exclusive right to the holder. IP-maintenance by the current holder can be a relevant factor in assessing the value of such an exclusive right. If for example competitors have been allowed to use a patented invention for years, exclusivity can probably not be re-established. If a trade mark has not been used for more than five consecutive years, new competitors are free to use the trademark. Finding out if others are already using it can be a factor in assessing the purchase of such a trade mark. The advantage being that after reusing the trade mark, the holder regains exclusivity, as long as no new competitors started using the trade mark before the first time the trade mark was used again. An IP-rights holder is free to grant exclusivity to others, but also the exclude the possibility of exclusivity by anyone. “Open source” software is an example of an IP-right (copyright) 117 that is made non-exclusive. Open source doesn’t mean that there are no limitations to the use of such software. On the contrary, open source software is usually made available under one of many open source licenses60. One common aspect of open source licenses is obligation to keep open source software “open”. The user is not allowed to use open source software in his own products and then exclude others from using the newly formed product. When valuating software, it’s worthwhile to check for evidence of open source software in the code. If the code holds large amounts of open source software or uses open source tools, exclusivity of the copyright on the code as a whole is less likely. IP-rights like design rights and patents have a limited duration. Exclusivity disappears at the moment these rights expire. The remaining lifespan may be an indication of the value or profitability of such an IP-right. Almost every IP-right will also have a geographical limitation. When planning to expand the use of an IP-right, it is necessary to assess whether or not conflicting IP-rights have been registered in target areas. Another issue when expanding the use of an IP-right may be the language of a target area. Words can have very different meanings in different languages. This may influence the chances of success for trade marks from country to country. A due diligence report on IP-rights by skilled professionals may offer a valuable insight, necessary to establish amongst others validity, durability, exclusivity and value of IP-rights. 5.8 Questions 1. What are the two main areas Intellectual Property rights are divided into? A. Designs and Patents B. Customs and Tariffs C. Tangibles and Intangibles D. Industrial property and copyright (and related rights) 2. Which of the following are considered Intellectual Property rights? A. Trademarks B. Patents C. Designs D. All of the above 3. All registrations of IP-rights have an expiry date. (True/False) A. True B. False 60 For example: http://www.opensource.org/licenses/alphabetical 118 4. In order to transfer registered IP-rights like trademarks, design rights, or patent, which of the following is required? A. Followers B. Deed C. High Revenue D. Positive Cash Flows 5.9 Answers 1. 2. 3. 4. D D A B 119 6 Accounting definitions of IP and transfer pricing Authors: Steven van Wijk/Lukasz Kubicki/Alon Wexler/Ryan Abrams 120 6.1 Introduction – Intangibles According to IFRS, US and Canadian GAAP, intangible assets are defined as identifiable nonmonetary assets without physical substance. Examples of intangible assets include trademarks, customer relationships and proprietary technologies. These assets can generate significant cash flows for a business. Different businesses have different portfolios of assets. Some businesses, such as manufacturing companies, are rich in tangible assets such as property, plant and equipment. Other businesses generate most of their cash flows from intangible assets. Consider a pharmaceutical company. Their largest asset is an investment in research and development, technologies and patents on their latest drugs. In the past, accounting standards did not allow for the recognition of intangible assets due to the complexity in measuring their future economic benefits. As a result, capital intensive industries tended to show higher asset balances and higher earnings (since capital assets are amortized rather than expensed immediately). Service companies appeared to have smaller asset bases even though these companies continuously invest in intangible assets. As such, new accounting standards, such as International Accounting Standard (IAS) 38, have developed recognition and measurement criteria to allow for the recognition of intangible assets. However, as stated in IAS 38, internally generated goodwill shall not be recognized as an asset. Internally generated brands, mastheads, publishing titles, customer lists and items similar in substance are not recognized as intangible assets. The impact of these standards is significant on both the financial position of the Company (balance sheet) and its performance (income statement). As such, these accounting standards can affect the relevance of financial statements to different users as follows: 1. Creditors – use financial statements to make credit decisions (either to make or call a loan): a. Creditors focus on a Company’s assets for collateral – they focus on the tangible assets of a company but may consider some intangibles. b. Creditors also focus on balance sheet ratios such as debt / equity. Since the recognition of intangibles raises the equity value, the capitalize/expense decision of intangibles becomes important. c. Lastly, Creditors focus on a company’s earnings over the term of the loan to consider whether interest and principal can be repaid. The recognition of intangible assets tends to raise earnings by avoiding large initial expenses. Investors – use financial statements to assess their return on investment 121 a. Investors focus on future profitability – usually through a company’s earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization (“EBITDA”). The recognition of intangible assets has a direct effect on EBITDA. If not recognized as an intangible, a purchase could be recognized as an operating expense and lower EBITDA. b. Ratios such as return on assets (“ROA”) and return on equity (“ROE”) are significantly affected through the recognition of intangible assets. Most companies have a presumed bias to increase earnings in order to appear more attractive to potential investors. Consequently, most companies would prefer to capitalize intangible assets rather than expensing them. Recognizing the potential for earnings management, accounting standards have created strict criteria in order to determine whether or not an intangible asset can be recognized. This chapter will summarize, at a high level, the accounting standards relating to intangible assets. The chapter will focus predominantly on International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS). IFRS is used in most European countries. Canada also uses IFRS for public companies. The chapter will also highlight key differences between IFRS, US GAAP and Canadian GAAP for private enterprises. 6.2 Recognition of Intangibles In order to recognize any asset on a company’s balance sheet (tangible or intangible), it must meet the basic definition. An asset is a resource: • Controlled by an entity as a result of past events; • From which future economic benefits are expected to flow from the entity. If the expenditure does not meet all the criteria, the amount is expensed immediately in the income statement. If all the criteria are met, then an asset is created on the company’s balance sheet and amortized over its useful life. An illustration of these criteria follows: Example 1: Apple Company is a pharmaceutical business, researching the cure for a rare disease. It believes to have found a formula that works on mice but does not have the cash to continue development for human trials. Orange Company therefore purchases the “formula” from Apple Company for $1 million USD. Note that probability of success of a drug through human trials is only 10%. Application of the criteria: The fundamental question in this example is whether Orange Company can recognize an asset or not. Since the probability of success of the formula is only 10%, we cannot establish that “there is a probable future economic benefit” from the 122 formula. As such, an asset cannot be recognized. Orange Company would therefore show a $1 million USD expense on its income statement at the time of purchase. Had it qualified as an asset, the formula would have been considered an intangible, as it arises from a contractual right and does not have any physical substance. There are three different scenarios in which a company can acquire an intangible asset: • The company can generate it internally. For example, Orange Company could have researched and developed the formula on its own. • A company can acquire it externally. For example, Orange Company can purchase the rights to the formula from another company. • A company can acquire it in a business combination. Orange Company can purchase the shares of another company, acquiring all of its assets and liabilities, including any intangibles it may have. The existence of intangible assets, from a purely economic perspective, does not necessarily mean that these assets are relevant from an accounting perspective. For example, The Coca Cola Company’s largest asset by far is it trade name (“Coke”). However, since the trade name does not meet the definition of an intangible asset for accounting purposes, all expenditures relating to its trade name are expensed. In this case, while the trade name is of great economic significance, it is not recognized for accounting purposes. This is due to the strict accounting standards relating to intangibles, of which a discussion follows. 6.2.1 Intangibles acquired externally Externally acquired intangibles are purchased from outside the firm and usually have identifiable costs and discernible benefits. However, there have been difficulties in accounting for these assets. There has been a conservative tendency to expense many of the costs involved, and for those capitalized there have been inconsistent approaches to recording, revaluing, and amortizing these assets. In order to be recognized as an intangible, IAS 38 requires the purchase to be identifiable. An asset is identifiable if it: a. is separable, i.e. is capable of being separated or divided from the entity and sold, transferred, licensed, rented or exchanged, either individually or together with a related contract, identifiable asset or liability, regardless of whether the entity intends to do so; or b. arises from contractual or other legal rights, regardless of whether those rights are transferable or separable from the entity or from other rights and obligations. 123 If the purchase is identifiable, it is recognized as an intangible if it meets the definition of an asset as stated above and all the following recognition criteria (you will note these criteria are the same as the ones listed for any asset at the beginning of this section): a. It must be probable that the expected future economic benefits that are attributable to the asset will flow to the entity. b. The cost of the asset must be measured reliably. The cost of a separately acquired intangible asset comprises: a. its purchase price, including import duties and non-refundable purchase taxes, after deducting trade discounts and rebates; and b. any directly attributable cost of preparing the asset for its intended use. IFRS, Canadian GAAP and US GAAP are all converged on this issue. Example 2: Consider the facts presented in Example 1. Let’s now assume that Apple Company has successfully completed all phases of human trials. The drug is now ready for production and marketing. However, since Apple has no experience in manufacturing or marketing, it sells the patent on its formula to Orange Company for $300 million. In order to complete the purchase, Orange Company was required to pay legal fees of $3 million. Further, executive management spent a total of 150 hours on the deal, which is the equivalent of $1 million in salaries. Application of the criteria: In this example, the patent is clearly identifiable. It can be sold separately as evidenced by its sale to Orange Company. Further, it also arises from a contract. The drug also meets all three recognition criteria: future economic benefits are likely since the drug has passed human trials, Orange Company controls the patent and its costs are known with virtual certainty. Therefore, the patent should be recognized as an intangible. What should be the cost of the intangible? Clearly, its purchase price forms the basis of the cost. To the purchase price, we would add any direct expenses. In other words, expenses the company would only incur because of the purchase. This would include $3 million in legal fees. The salaries of management are an indirect expense. Had the deal not gone through, Orange Company would have still paid their management. As such, the cost is $303 million (purchase price plus legal fees). 124 6.2.2 Intangibles generated internally An internally generated intangible asset is developed by the company using its own resources or by a service provider engaged by the company, or acquired externally and subsequently significantly modified by the company. Intangible assets are typically generated through research and development. Given a company’s bias to recognize the highest possible amount of intangible assets, accounting standards have given strict guidance on what qualifies as an internally generated intangible asset. First, accounting standards separate a business’ activities into a “research phase” and a “development phase.” All activities in the research phase are expensed as it cannot yet be established whether future economic benefits are probable. Examples of research activities are: • activities aimed at obtaining new knowledge; • the search for, evaluation and final selection of, applications of research findings or other knowledge; • the search for alternatives for materials, devices, products, processes, systems or services; and • the formulation, design, evaluation and final selection of possible alternatives for new or improved materials, devices, products, processes, systems or services. Activities in the development phase can be capitalized as an intangible asset if all of the following criteria are met: a. the technical feasibility of completing the intangible asset so that it will be available for use or sale; b. its intention to complete the intangible asset and use or sell it; c. its ability to use or sell the intangible asset; d. how the intangible asset will generate probable future economic benefits. Among other things, the entity can demonstrate the existence of a market for the output of the intangible asset or the intangible asset itself or, if it is to be used internally, the usefulness of the intangible asset; e. the availability of adequate technical, financial and other resources to complete the development and to use or sell the intangible asset; and f. its ability to measure reliably the expenditure attributable to the intangible asset during its development. 125 If an entity cannot distinguish the research phase from the development phase, the expenditure for that project should be treated as if it were incurred in the research phase. Some operations occur in connection with the development of an intangible asset, but are not necessary to bring the asset to the condition necessary for it to be capable of operating in the manner intended by management. These incidental operations may occur before or during the development activities. Because incidental operations are not necessary to bring an asset to the condition necessary for it to be capable of operating in the manner intended by management, the income and related expenses of incidental operations are recognized immediately in profit or loss, and included in their respective classifications of income and expense. IAS 38 provides examples of costs directly attributable to a value of recognized intangible assets. These include: a. cost of employee benefits arising directly from bringing the asset to its working condition; b. professional fees arising directly from bringing the asset to its working condition; and c. cost of testing whether the asset is functioning properly. d. Contrary, the costs which cannot be considered as a part of the cost of an intangible asset include: a. cost of introducing a new product or service (including costs of advertising and promotional activities); b. cost of conducting business in a new location or with a new class of customer (including costs of staff training); and c. administration and other general overhead costs. Recognition of costs in the carrying amount of an intangible asset ceases when the asset is in the condition necessary for it to be capable of operating in the manner intended by management. Therefore, costs incurred in using or redeploying an intangible asset are not included in the carrying amount of that asset. For example, the following costs are not included in the carrying amount of an intangible asset: a. costs incurred while an asset capable of operating in the manner intended by management has yet to be brought into use; and b. initial operating losses, such as those incurred while demand for the asset’s output builds up. 126 In some cases, expenditure is incurred to generate future economic benefits, but it does not result in the creation of an intangible asset that meets the recognition criteria. Such expenditures are often described as contributing to internally generated goodwill. Internally generated goodwill is not recognised as an asset because it is not an identifiable resource (i.e. it is not separable nor does it arise from contractual or other legal rights) controlled by the entity that can be measured reliably at cost. Therefore internally generated brands, mastheads, publishing titles, customer lists and items similar in substance shall not be recognized as intangible assets unless they were purchased or acquired as part of a business combination. As discussed previously, the Coke trade name would need to be expensed as it is considered internally generated goodwill. The following highlights the key differences between IFRS, US GAAP and Canadian GAAP as it relates to internally generated intangible assets: • US GAAP does not allow for the recognition of development costs as intangible assets (all are expensed). The exception to this rule is for website and software development costs which are capitalized once technical feasibility is proven. The IFRS development criteria would apply to website and software costs and would typically arrive at the same conclusion. • Canadian GAAP allows companies to adopt an accounting policy decision (to expense all development activities. This is done to simplify the bookkeeping process. If a company does not select this option, it follows the same criteria as IFRS to capitalize its development costs. Example 3: Now let’s assume Orange Company decides to develop their own drug for a rare disease. The following is a schedule of amounts spent on the process: Activity Date A B C D E F G H I 01-Jan-10 30-Jun-10 30-Aug-10 31-Oct-10 01-Jan-11 30-Jun-11 01-Jan-12 28-Feb-12 31-Mar-12 Amount Identify several possible compounds to cure the disease $ Increase testing on compound X on mice Engage consulting firm to audit results of lab tests Create report/forms to proceed to human trials Begin human trials Passes first phase of clinical trials. Second phase begins. Drug passes human trials. Enagage marketing firm for a market study File for patent Investigate manufacturing plants in China 300,000 200,000 400,000 200,000 500,000 700,000 400,000 500,000 300,000 $ 3,500,000 Application of criteria 127 The first challenge is to decide when the process switches from the research phase into the development phase. Suppose we were told (because we are not experts in pharmaceuticals) that there is a 70% chance of a successful drug once Phase One of clinical trials are completed. In this case, we would consider everything prior to Phase One trials as research, because we still don’t know if we have the correct compound and whether further research will be required. Therefore steps A to E are clearly research and should be expensed. Once we enter the second phase of trials (Step F), we will consider the criteria for development as follows: a. the technical feasibility of completing the intangible asset so that it will be available for use or sale; at this point, we have demonstrated feasibility by getting to phase II. Further, the company likely has the technical feasibility to advance to the next phase. b. its intention to complete the intangible asset and use or sell it; the company has a clear intention to complete the project. c. its ability to use or sell the intangible asset; the company has a clear intention to sell the drug. d. how the intangible asset will generate probable future economic benefits. Among other things, the entity can demonstrate the existence of a market for the output of the intangible asset or the intangible asset itself or, if it is to be used internally, the usefulness of the intangible asset; the company has completed a market study. Further, there is a 70% chance of success, thereby meeting the “probable” criteria e. the availability of adequate technical, financial and other resources to complete the development and to use or sell the intangible asset; the company likely has the technical feasibility to advance to the next phase. We will assume financing is not an issue in this example. f. its ability to measure reliably the expenditure attributable to the intangible asset during its development. As shown on the schedule, the expenditures are all known. Since all the criteria are met, Step F and beyond would be considered development activities. Any costs related to the development of the drug can be capitalized. Since Step I does not relate to the drugs development (it relates to production), the amount cannot be capitalized and would be expensed immediately. 6.2.3 Intangibles acquired as part of business combination A business combination is defined as a transaction or other event in which an acquirer obtains control of one or more businesses. Transactions sometimes referred to as true 128 mergers or merger of equals are also business combinations. Often intangible assets are acquired as part of the business combination. The acquisition method is used to account for a business combination which is applied by the following steps: Identification of the 'acquirer' – the combining entity that obtains control of the acquiree Determination of the 'acquisition date' – the date on which the acquirer obtains control of the acquiree Recognition and measurement of the identifiable assets acquired, the liabilities assumed and any non-controlling interest (NCI, formerly called minority interest) in the acquiree. a. As of the acquisition date, the acquirer should determine the fair value of the consideration paid for the business. If less than 100% of the business is purchased, than the acquirer should determine the implied consideration that would have been paid in the event that 100% of the business was purchased. The consideration paid for the business is then allocated to its assets and liabilities. Any residual amount is known as goodwill. The acquirer's application of the recognition principle and conditions may result in recognising some assets that the acquiree had not previously recognised as assets in its financial statements. For example, the acquirer recognises the acquired identifiable intangible assets, such as a brand name, a patent or a customer relationship, that the acquiree did not recognise as assets in its financial statements because it developed them internally and charged the related costs to expense. There is a presumption that the fair value (and therefore the cost) of an intangible asset acquired in a business combination can be measured reliably. An expenditure (included in the cost of acquisition) on an intangible item that does not meet both the definition of and recognition criteria for an intangible asset should form part of the amount attributed to the goodwill recognized at the acquisition date. The fair value according to IFRS 13 is defined as the price that would be received to sell an asset or paid to transfer a liability in an orderly transaction between market participants at the measurement date. Although the definition of the fair value provides a clear framework of valuation, in practice however the valuation process requires a thorough analysis from an economic and financial perspective. The detailed discussion about the valuation process is provided in Lesson 3. 129 IFRS, US GAAP and Canadian GAAP are converged on this issue. Any minor differences are beyond the scope of this chapter. Example 4: Fruit Company specializes in making storage containers which keep various fruit fresh for a long period of time. The company has been owned since inception by Mr. Smith, who would like to retire. As such, he agrees to sell 100% of his shares to a private equity firm for $13 million in cash. A & A, a chartered accounting firm, was engaged to complete the purchase price allocation. A purchase price allocation involves allocating the fair value of the company ($13 million) to its assets and liabilities. In order to complete the purchase price allocation, A & A first develops a complete understanding of the business and identifies the identifiable intangible assets. A & A’s findings were as follows: • Technology – The company’s technology in manufacturing its containers is the core competency of its business, allowing them to have superior characteristics than competing products such as superior strength and moisture/grease free surfaces. The technology could be sold to a competitor looking to improve its operations and are therefore identifiable and valuable. • Trade name – According to management, the company’s trade name has recognition in the industry and helps the company generate sales. Therefore, the trade name could be sold to a competitor looking to establish a higher market share. It is therefore separable and valuable. • Customer relationships – The company maintains strong relationships with its customers as its revenues are dependent upon repeat business. Relationships have spanned more than 10 years, making these repeat orders key to the sustainability of the business. A competitor would pay for these relationships in order to expand their business, making them identifiable. The next step in the purchase price allocation would be to determine the fair value of each intangible asset separately, using valuation techniques learned in Lesson 3. Finally, A & A would allocate the $13 million to the assets and liabilities of the company (see the table on the following page). The residual value not allocated to any other assets or liabilities is known as goodwill and is discussed in the next section. 130 FRUIT COMPANY ADJUSTED PURCHASE PRICE ALLOCATION AS AT THE ACQUISITION DATE (in $000s) Book Value Enterprise value Fair Value Adjustment Fair Value A $ 13,000 Purchase price allocated as follows: Net tangible assets Net Cash Working capital Accounts receivable Sales taxes receivable Inventory Prepaid expenses Accounts payable Property, plant, and equipment Intangible assets Technology (know how) Trade Name Customer relationships Book Value / Adjusted Book Value Goodwill Note 1 10 - 10 Note 1 Note 1 Note 2 Note 1 Note 1 1,000 150 2,300 100 (700) 700 - 1,000 150 3,000 100 (700) Note 2 2,850 1,500 700 500 3,550 2,000 4,360 1,200 5,560 - 1,100 1,400 2,000 1,100 1,400 2,000 - 4,500 4,500 4,360 5,700 10,060 Note 3 Note 3 Note 3 B A- B $ 2,940 Note 1: Book values taken from Fruit Company's balance sheet as of the acquisition date Note 2: Inventory and property, plant and equipment were bumped to their fair market value Note 3: Identifiable intangible assets recognized at the acquisition date because they meet the criteria from Section 2.1. Note they had never been recognized on Fruit Company's balance sheet pre-transaction. 6.3 Goodwill According to the 6 June 2012 Chapter 6 draft of the OECD TP Guidelines, in most instances, accounting and business valuation measures of goodwill and ongoing concern value are not relevant for purposes of transfer pricing analysis. As discussed in section 2.3, goodwill is only recognized as a result of a business combination. 131 Goodwill is measured as the difference between: • The consideration paid for 100% of the business; and the • Net of the acquisition-date amounts of the identifiable assets acquired and the liabilities assumed. Occasionally, an acquirer will make a bargain purchase, which is a business combination in which the amount of goodwill is negative. The acquirer shall recognize the resulting gain on the acquisition date directly in the statement of profit and loss. The gain is recognized as a bargain purchase in profit or loss. In the case of a business combination where the acquirer does not achieve 100% control of the acquiree, the non-controlling interest (NCI) has to be measured. IFRS 3 allows an accounting policy choice, available on a transaction by transaction basis, to measure NCI either at: • fair value (the full goodwill method), or • the NCI's proportionate share of net assets of the acquiree (the partial goodwill method). The fact that companies could elect how they will account for the NCI, leads to discrepancies in the value of goodwill calculated under each of the methods. This is best illustrated by the example provided below. Example 5: P pays $800 to purchase 80% of the shares of S. Fair value of 100% of S's identifiable net assets is $600. If P elects to measure non-controlling interests at their proportionate interest in the net assets of S of $120 (20% x $600), the consolidated financial statements show goodwill of $320 (800 +120 - 600). If P elects to measure non-controlling interests at fair value and determines that fair value to be $185, then goodwill of $385 is recognized (800 + 185 - 600). The fair value of the 20% non-controlling interest in S will not necessarily be proportionate to the price paid by P for its 80%, primarily due to control premium or discount as explained in paragraph B45 of IFRS 3. IFRS, US GAAP and Canadian GAAP are converged on this issue. Any minor differences are beyond the scope of this chapter. 132 6.4 Subsequent measurement When an intangible asset is recognized, the company would like to recover its value. The company could recover the value of the assets during the normal course of the business (e.g. trademarks will be used to increase sales of products which are manufactured by the company) or through sale of the intangible assets in the future. In case an asset is recovered during the normal course of the business, its value has to be measured reliably throughout the business process. In principle an entity must choose either the cost model or the revaluation model for each class of intangible asset. The cost model assumes that after initial recognition intangible assets should be carried at cost less any amortization and impairment losses. Under the revaluation model, intangible assets may be carried at a revalued amount (based on fair value) less any subsequent amortization and impairment losses only if fair value can be determined by reference to an active market. In practice however such active markets are uncommon for intangible assets and therefore most commonly a cost model is used. The treatment of an asset depends on its useful life. IAS 38 differentiates between: • indefinite life when no limit is foreseen to the period over which the asset is expected to generate net cash inflows for the entity; and • finite life where the period of benefit to the entity is limited. The assets with indefinite life will be carried in the amount initially recognized. However, its useful life should be reviewed each reporting period to determine whether events and circumstances continue to support an indefinite useful life. The assets with finite lives should be amortized on a systematic basis over their economic useful life. In the case that a company disposes of the asset, a gain or loss arising from the derecognition of an intangible asset shall be determined as the difference between the net disposal proceeds, if any, and the carrying amount of the asset. It shall be recognised in profit or loss when the asset is derecognised. Gains shall not be classified as revenue. Example 6: Going back to Example 4, let’s assume that Orange Company finally completes the drug on December 31, 2012. Let’s further assume the total amount capitalized to development costs by December 31, 2012 to be $4 million and that the company uses the cost method. The patent on the drug lasts for 15 years, however Orange Company believes (based on its extensive experience) that within 10 years, a better drug will come out, thereby rendering the patent worthless. Therefore, the useful life of the drug is 10 years, 133 because this is the time period that the company can financially benefit from its patent. Amortization expense would therefore be $400 thousand calculated as $4 million in total cost divided by its 10 years useful life. Let us further assume that by the end of December 31, 2016 (four years later), another company buys the patent for $3 million. At that point, the patent would have a carrying amount of $2.4 million (calculated as the initial $4 million less 4 years’ worth of amortization of $400 thousand per year). Since the proceeds of the sale are higher than the patents carrying amount, a gain would be recognized as the difference ($600 thousand) and would show on the company’s income statement. In this example it would be very rare for the revaluation method to be used, because there is no active market for pharmaceutical patents on specific diseases. However, if the revaluation method were to be used, the company would revalue the patent each year. For example, suppose in December 31, 2013 the fair market value of the patent was $4.5 million. In that case, the value of the patent would be increased by $500 thousand and an unrealized gain would be shown in the statement of other comprehensive income 61. US GAAP and Canadian GAAP require the cost model for intangible assets. The revaluation model is unique to IFRS. 6.5 Questions 1. Which of the following documents governs the recognition of intangibles for accounting purposes? A. International Accounting Standard (IAS) 38 B. Bill of Rights C. Annual Reports D. OECD Article 9 2. Which of the following is NOT a criterion needed to capitalize activities in the development phase as an intangible asset? A. Its ability to use or sell the intangible asset B. Its ability to measure reliably the expenditure attributable to the intangible asset during its development C. Its intention to complete the intangible asset and use or sell it D. Its ability to pay dividends to shareholders 61 Other Comprehensive Income is shown on a separate financial statement. It is beyond the scope of this chapter. 134 3. Which of the following costs are directly attributable to a value of recognized intangible assets? A. Cost of employee benefits arising directly from bringing the asset to working condition B. Professional fees related to brining the asset to working condition C. Cost of meals taken by the employees D. Cost of testing whether the asset is functioning properly 4. Goodwill is only recognized as a result of business combination. A. True B. False 6.6 Answers 1. 2. 3. 4. 6.7 A D C A Literature • IAS 38 • ASC 805 • CGAAP Section 3064 135 7 Corporate Income Tax Aspects of IP and Transfer Pricing Authors: Rudolf Sinx/Louan Verdoner/Raheem Farishta 136 7.1 Introduction This lesson outlines the corporate income tax aspects related to intellectual property and transfer pricing. Corporate income tax is a major factor affecting the placement and types of intellectual property in a business. Each country has its own rules regarding the taxation of intangible property. This lesson provides several examples from different countries to highlight how intangible property is taxed around the world. The following topics related to corporate income tax aspects are covered in this lesson: • • • • • • • • • • • 7.2 Initial Intangible Asset Value Depreciation/Decrease in Value Research and Development (R&D) Tax Credit Innovation Box/Patent Box and/or Other Incentives Replacement Reserve Withholding Tax on Royalty Payments Capital Gains Tax Business Restructuring and Related Taxes Value Added Tax (VAT) Purchase Price Allocation (PPA) Beneficial, Economic, and Legal Ownership Initial Intangible Asset Value According to International Accounting Standard (IAS) 38, as discussed in Lesson 6, an intangible asset shall be measured initially at cost. Also, IFRS 3 Business Combinations states that if an intangible asset is acquired in a business combination, the cost of that intangible asset is its fair value at the acquisition date. Furthermore, internally generated goodwill shall not be recognized as an asset. For corporate tax purposes, each country has its own way of recognizing which intangible assets are actually valid for taxing purposes. In the United Kingdom, the book value of an intangible asset in question is the value in accordance with UK GAAP. Most internally generated goodwill cannot be capitalized and therefore have a book value of zero. An asset is a ‘chargeable intangible asset’ at any time if a gain on its disposal gives rise to a taxable credit. 62 62 Source: HM Revenue & Customs, http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/manuals/cirdmanual/CIRD47020.htm 137 In the United States, Section 197 of the IRS Tax Code lists certain intangibles that should be accounted for on the tax return. The following assets are considered Section 197 Intangibles63: 1. Goodwill; 2. Going concern value; 3. Workforce in place; 4. Business books and records, operating systems, or any other information base, including lists or other information concerning current or prospective customers; 5. A patent, copyright, formula, process, design, pattern, know-how, format, or similar item; 6. A customer-based intangible; 7. A supplier-based intangible; 8. Any item similar to items (3) through (7); 9. A license, permit, or other right granted by a governmental unit or agency (including issuances and renewals); 10. A covenant not to compete entered into in connection with the acquisition of an interest in a trade or business; 11. Any franchise, trademark, or trade name; and 12. A contract for the use of, or a term interest in, any item in this list. If the Section 197 intangible is created internally, then it has a zero tax or bookkeeping value to the corporation. 7.3 Amortization/Decrease in Value of Intangible Assets Amortization of intangible assets deals with deducting the cost of a qualifying asset over the projected life of the asset. Along with determining which intangible assets to tax, each country has its own rules about the amortization of intangible property. In the United States, any Section 197 intangible held in connection with a trade or business is amortized straight-line over 15 years (180 months). In the year the asset is acquired and 63 Source: Internal Revenue Service, http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-drop/rr-04-49.pdf 138 sold, the amount of amortization deductible for tax purposes is prorated on a monthly basis. 64 In the United Kingdom, taxpayers may elect to amortize intangible assets over 25 years for tax purposes at 4% per annum. Upward revaluations of IP are taxable to the extent that previous tax relief has been given. 65 According to the Dutch income tax system, self-created intangible assets (except for goodwill), can be amortized at once in the year the intangibles are developed or created. Goodwill can be amortized at a maximum rate of 10% of the purchase price. 66 7.3.1 Methods of Amortization The most common methods of amortization include straight-line and accelerated. Straight Line Depreciation = (Purchase Price – Salvage Value) / Useful Life. Accelerated depreciation allows companies to write off their assets faster in earlier years than the straight-line depreciation method and to write off a smaller amount in the later years. The major benefit of using this method is the tax shield it provides early on in the life of the asset.67 The USA and UK tax systems only permit a straight-line depreciation on intangible assets, while the Dutch system allows a free choice of depreciation method as long as it follows sound business practice. 7.4 R&D Tax Credit Countries have R&D tax credit systems in place to encourage the development of intangible property in their respective jurisdictions. Many different types of tax incentives are in place to urge corporations to place their research and development facilities in certain locations. Since 2004, a number of EU Member States have introduced new tax incentives or substantially improved existing ones to stimulate investment in research. They now 64 Source: Internal Revenue Service, http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-drop/rr-04-49.pdf 65 Source: Buzzacott Chartered Accountants, “ UK taxation of Intellectual Property”, http://www.buzzacott.co.uk/insights/the-uk-taxation-of-intellectual-property--ip-/43 66 Source: PLC Cross-border Tax Handbook, http://www.stibbe.nl/upload/165ca5aaf011a06d6078e0113df.pdf 67 For more information please visit: www.Investopedia.com 139 constitute a substantial part of the total public effort to support business R&D in several EU Member States. According to the OECD Report on R&D tax incentives, the R&D tax benefits depend on country-level variables such as overall innovation performance, perceived market failures in R&D, industrial structure, size of firms and the nature of corporate tax systems. Some OECD countries (e.g. Sweden, Finland) neither subsidize nor extend preferential tax treatment to business R&D although these countries have high levels of private R&D expenditures. Most OECD and emerging economies apply a system where an R&D tax credit is provided on the volume of R&D expenditure undertaken (e.g. Canada, Japan, United Kingdom, France, Norway, Brazil, China and India) while others target R&D tax credits to incremental R&D expenditure (i.e. expenditure in excess of some baseline amount). R&D tax allowances are available in Denmark, Czech Republic, Austria, Hungary, and the United Kingdom. Payroll withholding tax credit for R&D wages, which are deduction from payroll taxes and social security contributions, are also being used in Belgium, Hungary, the Netherlands and Spain.68 The United States provides tax credits for qualified research expenses to offset corporate income tax. The US provides two methods for computing R&D tax credit, a traditional 20% credit equal to 20% of the amount of the R&D expenses exceeding a “base amount” or a simplified 14% credit. These credits are not subject to a cap, and unused credits can be carried back one year and carried forward twenty years. The US R&D credit has lapsed as of January 1, 2012, but Congress can reinstate it retroactively as it has done nine times previously. 69 A great example of the cross-national comparison of R&D expenses is seen in a 2004 article called "A Cross-National Comparison of R&D Expenditure Decisions: Tax Incentives and Financial Constraints" written in the Contemporary Accounting Research journal. The article compares the R&D tax credit systems in place in the United States and Canada. The two tax incentive mechanism designs are consistent with differing views of the degree of financial constraints faced by firms in these economies. The research shows that the Canadian credit system induces, on average, $1.30 of additional R&D spending per dollar of taxes foregone, while the U.S. system induces $2.96 of additional spending, on average. Also, the findings illustrate that firms that capitalize R&D costs in Canada spend, on average, 18% more on 68 Source: September 2011 Testimony by OECD at US Senate Committee, http://www.finance.senate.gov 69 Source: Deloitte Global Survey of R&D Tax Incentives, July 2011 140 R&D. Collectively, this evidence is important to the ongoing debates in both countries about the appropriate design of incentives for R&D. 7.5 Innovation Box/Other Incentives Many countries have special R&D tax incentives for certain taxpayers who meet special conditions. Netherlands 70 In the Netherlands, there are two important tax incentives for qualified taxpayers, the wage tax benefits for innovation (WBSO) and innovation box. The WBSO reduces wage tax and social security contributions for employees engaged in research. The Innovation Box, formerly known as the Patent Box, allows a deduction on corporate income tax rates from qualifying technology intangible asset profits. For the qualifying profits, companies effectively owe only 5% income tax as of 2010 (2007-2009: 10%), instead of the general tax rate of 25%. The incentive applies to certain self-produced (i.e., not purchased), technologybased intangible assets, such as the know-how for a new product or for a new production process. The company need not report the technology asset in its financial statements in order to qualify. Also, the volume of profits that is allowed to be included in the Box is, from 2010 onwards, no longer capped. There are two ways to access the Innovation Box benefits, through patented assets and R&D certificate assets. 1. Conditions for qualifying for the Innovation Box - Patented assets 70 • The company has a technology intangible asset that is expected to generate a significant technology-based profit. In other words, at least 30% of the expected future profits are expected to be derived from the new technology components, as opposed to from marketing efforts, brands, trademarks, etc. • The company has a patent (whether Dutch or non-Dutch) for the intangible asset. Patent applications that are still pending do not qualify. • The company produced the intangible asset; in other words, it did not purchase the complete asset. • The "self-production test" is met if the company's staff performs the required R&D work, or if they monitor the R&D work carried out by a third party ("contract R&D") in the Netherlands or abroad. Source: BOM Foreign Investments, http://www.foreigninvestments.eu/pages//ET---Innovations-Box.html 141 • Brands, trademarks, logos, etc. are not qualifying technology assets. 2. Conditions for qualifying for the Innovation Box - R&D certificate assets • The company has received an R&D certificate for the R&D work. • The company can apply for an R&D certificate if it employs staff engaged in qualifying research and development activities in the EU (this may include certain software development). The R&D certificate also allows the company to receive a certain tax credit against his wage tax obligations, so the company may, therefore, benefit from two incentives. • The company, and not a third party, produces the intangible asset. • For contract R&D, the "self-production test" is met if the company's staff performs the majority of the R&D work that is required for a particular R&D project, or if they monitor the R&D work carried out by a third party (i.e., if they organize and supervise the work). Also, the 2012 Dutch Tax Plan introduced a new tax incentive called the research and development deduction (“RDA”). The RDA incentive is an additional deduction to costs and investments directly related to R&D (other than wage costs) and is calculated over costs and investments that are currently deductible or depreciable. United Kingdom71 The United Kingdom offers two volume-based incentives; one that is available to companies falling within the definition of a Small-or-Medium-Sized-Enterprise (SME) and the other for companies that do not fall within that definition (Large Companies). Generally, an SME company must have fewer than 500 employees and either gross revenues of less than €100M or gross assets of less than €86M. The UK offers a 130% super deduction for Large Companies and a 175% super deduction for SME Companies. Companies may claim the incentive for their expenditures on the following cost categories as long as the total exceeds GBP 10,000 for the year: 71 • Employing staff who are directly and actively engaged in carrying out R&D; • Paying a staff provider for the services of personnel who are directly and actively engaged in carrying out R&D (limited to 65% of the payment); Source: Deloitte Global Survey of R&D Tax Incentives, July 2011 142 • Consumable or transformable materials used directly in carrying out R&D (broadly, physical materials which are consumed or transformed in the R&D process); • Power, water, fuel, and computer software used directly in carrying out R&D; • Subcontract costs if they are paid to a university, health authority, charity, scientific research organization, individual, or a partnership of individuals; and, • Payments to volunteers for participating in clinical trials. Belgium and Luxembourg In order to encourage R&D activities, the Luxembourg Government has recently passed a law that provides for an 80% exemption of certain types of IP-related income (or of deemed IP-income if a taxpayer creates IP for his own use). 72 Similarly, a patent income deduction in Belgium allows taxpayers to deduct 80% of their qualifying patent income from their taxable income. 7.6 Replacement Reserve In general, as stated in IAS 38, if in accordance with the recognition principle an entity initially recognizes in the carrying amount of an asset the cost of a replacement for part of an intangible asset and then it derecognizes the carrying amount of the replaced part, there may be a replacement reserve allowed. If it is not practicable for an entity to determine the carrying amount of the replaced part, it may use the cost of the replacement as an indication of what the cost of the replaced part was at the time it was acquired or internally generated. In the Netherlands, if fixed assets are lost, damaged, or sold at a price above book value, profits may be set aside in a tax-free replacement reserve. The tax reserve does not apply to intangible fixed assets that are kept as part of a portfolio investment. Although contributions to the replacement reserve are deductible from taxable profits, the reserve must be applied to the cost of replacing the assets and should be terminated within 3 years of its creation.73 72 Source: Luxembourg Ministry of the Economy and Foreign Trade, http://www.eco.public.lu/documentation/publications/broch_ip/MECO_FO_LUX_IP_DESTINATION.pdf 73 Source: Deloitte – Taxation in the Netherlands 201 143 7.7 Withholding Tax on Royalty Payments According to Article 12 of the OECD Model Tax Convention, the term “royalties” as used in this Article means payments of any kind received as a consideration for the use of, or the right to use, any copyright of literary, artistic or scientific work including cinematograph films, any patent, trade mark, design or model, plan, secret formula or process, or for information concerning industrial, commercial or scientific experience. Some countries apply a withholding tax on these cross-border royalty payments, while others do not to encourage the flow of these incomes through their countries. For example in the United States, royalty income falls under fixed or determinable annual or periodical (FDAP) income and is subject to a withholding tax of 30%, although a reduced rate or exemption may apply if stipulated in the applicable tax treaty. 74 On the other hand, the Netherlands does not levy a withholding tax on outbound royalty payments. Withholding taxes can complicate intentional set-offs of royalty receipts against corresponding activated assets, such as sales receipts. According to chapter 3 of the OECD TP Guidelines, an intentional set-off is one that associated enterprises incorporate knowingly into the terms of the controlled transactions. It occurs when one associated enterprise has provided a benefit to another associated enterprise within the group that is balanced to some degree by different benefits received from that enterprise in return. The terms of set-offs relating to international transactions between associated enterprises may not be fully consistent with those relating to purely domestic transactions between independent enterprises because of the differences in tax treatment of the set-off under different national tax systems or differences in the treatment of the payment under a bilateral tax treaty. 7.8 Capital Gains Tax 75 Capital gains tax is a type of tax levied on capital gains incurred by individuals and corporations. Capital gains are the profits that an investor realizes when he or she sells the capital asset for a price that is higher than the purchase price. Capital gains taxes are only triggered when an asset is realized, not while it is held by an investor. An investor can own shares that appreciate every year, but the investor does not incur a capital gains tax on the shares until they are sold. 74 Source: Internal Revenue Service, http://www.irs.gov/businesses/article/0,,id=180219,00.html 75 For more information please visit www.investopedia.com 144 Most countries' tax laws provide for some form of capital gains taxes on investors' capital gains, although capital gains tax laws vary from country to country. In the U.S., individuals and corporations are subject to capital gains taxes on their annual net capital gains. It is important to note that it is net capital gains that are subject to tax because if an investor sells two stocks during the year, one for a profit and an equal one for a loss, the amount of the capital loss incurred on the losing investment will counteract the capital gains from the winning investment. Similarly, in the UK, on the sale of an intangible asset the difference between the proceeds and the tax book value is taxed. 76 However, in the Netherlands there is no capital gains tax. 7.9 Business Restructuring and Related Taxes There is no legal or universally accepted definition of business restructuring. The OECD defines business restructuring as the cross-border redeployment by a multinational enterprise of functions, assets and / or risks and refers to the following typical business restructurings: • Conversion of full-fledged distributors into limited-risk distributors commissionaires for a related party that may operate as a principal; • Conversion of full-fledged manufacturers into contract manufacturers or toll manufacturers or a related party that may operate as a principal; • Rationalization and / or specialization of operations (manufacturing sites and / or processes, research and development activities, sales, services); • Transfers of intangible property rights to a central entity (e.g. a so-called “IP company”) within the group. or When business restructuring results, a taxable event is illustrated through an example whereby the response depends on the historical results of the activity of the transferor, the historical volatility of such results, and the future profit / loss expectations of the transferor and transferee in relation to the risk at hand. The German tax authorities defined business restructuring in a slightly different way: “a relocation of functions exists if an enterprise transfers or provides the use of economic goods and other advantages as well as the chances and risks pertaining thereto to another 76 Source: Buzzacott Chartered Accountants, “UK Taxation of Intellectual Property”, http://www.buzzacott.co.uk/insights/the-uk-taxation-of-intellectual-property--ip-/43 145 associated enterprise”. Rather than referring to “redeployment” of functions (OECD), the German tax authorities refer to “transfer” whereby the emphasis is more on an actual / physical movement of functions. In the United Kingdom, the HMRC imposes a charge to the corporation on the unrealized gains of a company which ceases to be a resident in the UK. The law creates an occasion of charge immediately before the time when a company ceases to be resident in the UK. Further, the rules deem the company to have disposed of all its assets at their market value immediately before the relevant time and to have reacquired them at that value at the relevant time. The resulting charge to the corporation tax is known as the “exit charge”. 77 Under US Treasury Regulations, to the extent that the transfer of a function between affiliated entities across tax jurisdictions are accompanied by a transfer of (tangible, intangible, or both) assets, both section 482 and section 367 require that the transferor recognize arm’s length compensation for the transfer of intangible assets. However, the IRS stops short of requiring exit charges for the transfer of routine services as shown by the position in its coordinated issue paper (CIP) on buy-ins pertaining to cost-sharing arrangements (commonly associated with research and development efforts). Further, under the US Regulations, a transfer of a business opportunity by itself is not considered the transfer of an asset and, therefore, does not seem to require compensation between controlled parties. 78 7.10 VAT 79 A value-added tax (VAT) is a type of consumption tax that is placed on a product whenever value is added at a stage of production and at final sale. Value-added tax (VAT) is most often used in the European Union. The amount of value-added tax that the user pays is the cost of the product, less any of the costs of materials used in the product that have already been taxed. OECD countries have agreed on two fundamental principles for charging VAT/GST on internationally traded services and intangibles: 77 Source: HM Revenue and Customs, http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/manuals/cgmanual/cg42370.htm 78 Source: ONESOURCE Transfer Pricing Insider, “Services, Intangibles, and Exit Charges: The Evolving Views on Intercompany Transfer of Services”, http://onesource.thomsonreuters.com/share/solutions/transferpricing/transfer-pricing/newsletter/42572/ExitChanges3-1-11 79 Source: OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3746,en_2649_33739_39874324_1_1_1_1,00.html 146 • For consumption tax purposes internationally traded services and intangibles should be taxed according to the rules of the jurisdiction of consumption; • The burden of value added taxes themselves should not lie on taxable businesses except where explicitly provided for in legislation. Within the European Union, services are, in principle, taxed where the supplier is established (“origin” rule). However, recognizing that this would breach neutrality in many cases, there are a large number of exceptions to this basic rule. The zero rating of exports and taxation of imports introduce a breach in the staged collection process. In most countries where an invoice credit method is used, tax on several services and intangibles provided from abroad are collected by to the so-called reverse charge mechanism. Normally, taxpayers that deliver services in countries where they are not established have to register for VAT purposes and fulfil all VAT obligations in that country. To avoid such administrative burden to foreign providers, the reverse charge mechanism provides that the VAT-registered customer is liable to account for the tax on supplies received from foreign traders. 7.11 Purchase Price Allocation Companies are generally required to allocate the purchase price of acquired corporations among tangible and intangible assets. Typically, this allocation is derived from fair market value estimates for the identifiable tangible and intangible assets held by the acquired firm. Under a purchase price allocation (PPA), an acquirer allocates the purchase price to the assets acquired and liabilities assumed at fair value (FV) on the acquisition date. The PPA allocation process provides an incentive for colluding firms, e.g. subsidiaries of a multinational firm, to shift profits to low corporate income tax countries in order to reduce the total corporate income tax burden for the group. Thus, there are transfer pricing constraints in place to prevent this. The US Internal Revenue Service has stated that “allocations or other valuations done for accounting purposes may provide a useful starting point, but will not be conclusive for purposes of the best-method analysis in evaluating the arm’s length charge in a platform contribution transaction (PCT), particularly where the accounting treatment of an asset is inconsistent with its economic value.” The IRS does not provide any discussion of the relationship between financial reporting and tax standards and, therefore, neither identifies, on the one hand, what parts of a PPA may provide “a 147 useful starting point” or, on the other hand, what changes have to be made to a PPA before it can be used as the basis for a transfer pricing analysis. 80 7.12 Beneficial/Economic/Legal Ownership The following questions arise when addressing Intellectual Property (IP) ownership: • How is ownership defined and determined? • Who is the owner of intangibles? • Who has the right to benefit from the ownership? These questions are typically raised in a discussion how to treat IP for transfer pricing purposes. The ownership of intangibles in general can be structured as: • Beneficial ownership; or • Economic or legal ownership; or • Centralized or joined ownership 7.12.1 Beneficial Ownership The concept of “beneficial owner” found in Articles 10, 11 and 12 of the OECD Model Tax Convention has given rise to different interpretations by courts and tax administrations. A taxpayer could have legal ownership of a residence and yet not have equitable or beneficial ownership. These articles generally provide for a reduced level of withholding tax on the relevant category of income: however, the reduced tax is only available if the beneficial owner of the dividends, interest or royalties is a resident of the state which is a party to the treaty. One of the characteristics of this type of ownership is that there is an economic effect. This would include such rights and obligations as: possession, obtain legal title upon full payment of the purchase price, construct improvements, pay property taxes, risk of loss, insure and maintain the property. 81 In the United States, a foreign beneficial owner can be established by filing Form W-8BEN Certificate of Foreign Status of Beneficial Owner for United States Tax Withholding. This 80 Source: BNA Bloomberg Transfer Pricing Watch, “Reconciliation of Purchase Price Allocation and Transfer Pricing”, 4 May 2010. 81 Source: OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/49/35/47643872.pdf 148 potentially can allow a taxpayer to claim a reduced rate or exemption from withholding tax under an income tax treaty. 82 7.12.2 Legal Ownership Legal ownership is defined according to the legal title and legal protection of the intellectual property. Thus, the intellectual property can be legally protected in the country it is registered, such as patents and trademark. From a transfer pricing perspective, the legal owner of the intellectual property is considered as the owner of the IP. For patent and trademark, the owner can protect their intellectual property by registering them; however, for embedded intangibles like know- how, it is usually hard to use legal system to protect it. Legal ownership offers the owner the protections and the rights to utilize the IP to generate further benefits. Thus, where the legal ownership is placed within an MNE is important for tax planning purposes. 7.12.3 Economic Ownership The OECD defines economic ownership of assets broadly as: “the right to the income attributable to the ownership of the asset, such as royalties; the right to depreciate a depreciable asset; and the potential exposure to gains or losses from the appreciation or depreciation of the asset.” In the context of intangibles, additional attributes associated with economic ownership include: • Ability to benefit from the IP and any income stream created by those assets • Possibility of one party having both legal and economic ownership • Economic ownership may easily be transferred without change in legal ownership • A party that bears the costs and risks of developing an intangible should be entitled to a corresponding economic interest, even if it is not the legal owner of the intangible. Economic ownership must be present in most tax jurisdictions to allow a company to gain tax benefits, such as amortization deductions on the asset, and take advantage of tax incentives that go along with the IP. For this reason, from a tax perspective economic 82 Source: Internal Revenue Service, http://www.irs.gov/businesses/small/international/article/0,,id=105139,00.html 149 ownership is closely scrutinized to determine which entity should bear the tax related consequences of the asset. The reasons why taxpayers may segregate legal and economic ownership could be to facilitate the centralized handling of all intangible registrations within a group. Another reason is Cost Contribution Arrangements (CCA) where economic ownership is shared but legal ownership cannot be registered under multiple names. For US tax purposes, the IRS is supposed to analyse ownership in two distinct ways: 1) legal registration and 2) the contribution, or economic substance, which an entity has made to create or increase the value of the intangible. The US transfer pricing regulations provide that the legal owner of intangible property pursuant to the intellectual property law of the relevant jurisdiction, or the holder of rights constituting intangible property pursuant to contractual terms, such as the terms of a license or other agreement, will be considered the sole owner of intangible property for purposes of this section unless such ownership is inconsistent with the economic substance of the underlying transactions. 83 According to the new OECD Chapter 6 discussion draft of the Transfer Pricing Guidelines 84, the idea of “entitlement of intangible related returns” determines ownership. In this light, the importance of the alignment of developing, enhancing, maintaining and protecting intangibles with legal agreements is necessary to have the proper right of ownership of the IP for transfer pricing purposes. 7.12.4 Differences between Economic and Legal Ownership The primary area where the difference between legal and economic ownership arises is in relation to marketing intangibles. This is addressed in both the US Internal Revenue Code (IRC) and in the OECD Guidelines. The US IRC provides guidance on the ownership of marketing intangibles in the so called “cheese examples.” • 83 FP, a foreign producer of cheese, markets the cheese in countries other than the United States under the trade name Fromage Frere. FP owns all the worldwide rights to this name. The name is widely known and is valuable outside the United States but is not known within the United States. In 1995, FP decides to enter the Source: Internal Revenue Service, IRC Section 1.482-4(f)(3)(i)(A) 84 Source: OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, Revision of the Special Considerations for Intangibles in Chapter VI of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines and Related Provisions, Discussion Draft, June 2012 150 United States market and incorporates U.S. subsidiary, US Sub, to be its U.S. distributor and to supervise the advertising and other marketing efforts that will be required to develop the name Fromage Frere in the United States. US Sub incurs expenses that are not reimbursed by FP for developing the U.S. market for the cheese. These expenses are comparable to the levels of expense incurred by independent distributors in the U.S. cheese industry when introducing a product in the U.S. market under a brand name owned by a foreign manufacturer. Since US Sub would have been expected to incur these expenses if it were unrelated to FP, no allocation to US Sub is made with respect to the market development activities performed by US Sub. • The facts are the same as above, except that the expenses incurred by US Sub are significantly larger than the expenses incurred by independent distributors under similar circumstances. FP does not reimburse US Sub for its expenses. The tax inspector concludes based on this evidence that an unrelated party dealing at arm's length under similar circumstances would not have engaged in the same level of activity relating to the development of FP's marketing intangibles. The expenditures in excess of the level incurred by the independent distributors therefore are considered to be a service provided to FP that adds to the value of FP's trademark for Fromage Frere. Accordingly, the district director makes an allocation under section 482 for the fair market value of the services that US Sub is considered to have performed for FP. • The facts are the same as above, except that FP and US Sub conclude a long term agreement under which US Sub receives the exclusive right to distribute cheese in the United States under FP's trademark. US Sub purchases cheese from FP at an arm's length price. Since US Sub is the owner of the trademark under paragraph (f)(3)(ii)(A) of this section, and its conduct is consistent with that status, its activities related to the development of the trademark are not considered to be a service performed for the benefit of FP, and no allocation is made with respect to such activities. The OECD also makes reference to similar situations as those summarized in the USA examples above. The following guidance is provided: • For example, if the distributor acts as an agent, it will earn a routine return for its marketing activities only. 151 • If instead the distributor is entitled to obtain long term benefits from the intangible through sole distribution rights then it is entitled to a return from its economic ownership of those intangible assets • In practice it can be extremely difficult to determine which marketing expenditure has contributed to the development of the intangible and over what time period. 7.12.5 Centralized vs. Distributed Ownership Centralized ownership has the following key attributes: • A single company in the group owns the intangibles, both economically and legally; • License agreements with other group entities (arm´s length price to be determined) are in place; and • Can create opportunities for tax planning. Distributed or joined ownership has the following key attributes: • A number of group companies (operating companies) share ownership of intangibles on a pre-determined basis (e.g. geographic territory or product application); • Always involves some form of shared economic ownership; • Usually takes the form of CCA; and • Less likely to be tax driven. 7.13 Conclusion As can be seen from this lesson, the treatment of intangibles for corporate income tax purposes varies from country to country. Each country has its own way of taxing intangibles and providing tax incentives for the development of intangibles within their respective jurisdictions. This lesson only provides an overview of how intangibles are taxed across many countries, and we hope the information provided leaves you with a good basic understanding of the aspects of corporate income tax relating to intellectual property. 7.14 Questions 1. Which section of the United States tax code lists certain intangibles that should be accounted for on a tax return? A. Section 197 B. Section 482 152 C. Section 3 D. Section 201 2. What is a type of consumption tax that is placed on a product whenever value is added at a stage of production and at final sale? A. CCA B. PPA C. VAT D. CAT 3. When is a capital gains tax triggered? A. when assets increase in value B. when assets decrease in value C. when assets are sold D. when assets are kept secret 4. In a centralized ownership system, a number of group companies share ownership of intangibles on a pre-determined basis. True or False? A. True B. False 7.15 Answers 1. 2. 3. 4. A C C B 153