Identifying the factors affecting tax experts’ perceptions of the desirability of adopting a comprehensive capital gains tax in New Zealand Alvin Cheng1, Howard Davey2 and Jim Ryan2 This study gathered tax experts’ perceptions of the desirability of adopting a comprehensive capital gains tax (CGT) in New Zealand. It identifies the main reasons given by tax experts for favouring or opposing a comprehensive CGT. The study revealed there were 23 factors/issues related to tax experts’ attitudes towards a CGT. These included taxation factors (such as current tax rate structure, tax burden) and non taxation factors (such as social and political factors). 1 Faculty of Creative Industries and Business, Unitec Institute of Technology Email: acheng@unitec.ac.nz 2 Waikato Management School, University of Waikato 1 Introduction An overwhelming majority of OECD countries have some form of comprehensive capital gains tax (CGT) regime. Drawing from experiences in different countries, the OECD concluded that the advantages of a CGT generally outweighed its disadvantages (OECD, 2006). The benefits of a CGT include: (i) securing tax revenues, (ii) improving efficiency, (iii) strengthening horizontal and vertical equity, (iv) encouraging savings and investment, and (v) simplifying the tax system. Burman and White (2003) describe the New Zealand tax system as unsystematic and “ad hoc”. It remains one of only three OECD countries that do not have a general CGT (Labour Party, 2011). New Zealand treats only some capital gains as taxable income. For example, taxable income includes capital gains from financial arrangements and foreign investment funds, but it excludes gains from the sale of land on capital account. This is generally not the case in other OECD countries. As a result, New Zealand has a hybrid tax system (or “New Zealand style CGT system”) which taxes not only ordinary income but also certain selected capital gains. This study seeks to provide an understanding of why there is no comprehensive CGT in New Zealand. It gathers opinions from tax experts on why they favour (or oppose) a comprehensive CGT. The opinions were gathered from 30 New Zealand tax experts who were asked to explore the key issues, aspects, and attributes concerning CGT in New Zealand. 2 Development of Capital Gains Taxation in New Zealand The discussion on whether or not New Zealand should have a CGT has continued for more than 40 years. Income tax legislation in New Zealand has not generally included taxing profits on gains of a capital nature. However, exceptions exist relating to land sales, financial arrangements (from 1986), share sales in certain situations, and sale of site goodwill in lease situations. The main arguments for a CGT relate to equity, efficiency and combating tax avoidance. An equitable tax system should treat equally those who have equal capacity to pay (Ross Committee, 1967). Proponents of a CGT argue that it is difficult to justify taxing people differently who earn the same amount of money, e.g., one in the form of salary and another from a capital gain on the sale of an asset. With no CGT only salary income is taxed in full and capital gains are tax exempt. It is also economically inefficient to exempt capital gains as it encourages resources to be diverted into activities which produce lower pre-tax returns (e.g. dividends) in exchange for higher long term capital growth (e.g. shares) (McLeod, 2001). The exemption of capital gains can also lead to tax avoidance schemes where taxpayers (particularly farmers) take advantage of the tax system by converting taxable income to tax free capital gains (Goldsmith, 2008, p. 249). An important aspect for not imposing a CGT is the political aspect. The ambivalence of both the major political parties in New Zealand is best illustrated in David Lange’s comment in 1985 during his time as Prime minister. He stated “It is the sort of thing that you put in place if you are sure you are going to lose the election and be in opposition for the next 20 years” (“Editorial: Capital gains”, 1989, p.7). 3 During the 1980’s there was high inflation and a renewed focus was placed on investigating the imposition of a CGT. Moreover, in 1985 a CGT was introduced in Australia. A number of government reports investigated the option of a CGT for New Zealand. The McCaw report (1982) stated that there would be substantial complexity and little revenue generated by a CGT. It recommended that a CGT should not be included in New Zealand’s tax base. On the other hand, other committees such as the Brash Committee, the Royal Commission on Social Policy, and the Valabh Committee released their reports which supported the introduction of a CGT based mainly on tax equity, efficiency and combating tax avoidance (Brash Committee, 1987; Royal Commission on Social Policy, 1988; New Zealand Government 1988). New Zealand experienced rapid growth in housing price during the period from 1990 to 2005 (OECD, 2007, p.63). This rapid growth put national home affordability in New Zealand in the “severely unaffordable” category according to international standards (Cox & Pavletich, 2006, p.8). One of the means suggested to deflate the overheated housing market and to make housing more affordable was to implement a CGT on property transactions. Despite the significance of the housing problems, there was little debate on taxing capital gains in the 1990s. But the first decade of the twenty first century saw more government policy recommendations directed toward debating whether a CGT should be implemented. For example, a government review was undertaken in 2001 by the Tax Review Committee (McLeod Committee, 2001). They acknowledged the existence of problems due to the lack of a comprehensive CGT but concluded that a general CGT was not worth pursuing because of the complexity and compliance problems that would be involved. Instead, they suggested incremental policy changes to eliminate the flaws in the system. 4 In 2010 the report by the Victoria University of Wellington Tax Working Group, titled “A Tax System for New Zealand’s Future”, identified several options for broadening the tax base and raising more tax revenue for the government. The Group noted that a comprehensive, accrual-based CGT would generate $9 billion in terms of the 2009/2010 price level. The amount of revenue would decrease to approximately $4.5 billion if capital gains were excluded on the disposal of owner-occupied housing (Tax Working Group, 2010). Given these figures, another strong argument for the introduction of a CGT in New Zealand would be the potential revenue it can generate, depending on the design of the tax. However, the group cautioned that the introduction of a CGT could pose “practical challenges and efficiency implications” (Tax Working Group, 2010, p.66). In particular, it expressed concerns about the complexity of a CGT, the CGT treatment of owner-occupied housing, and the lock-in effects of a realisation-based CGT. As such, the group finally concluded that it would not support the introduction of a CGT. Research Method This study seeks to determine what the important factors are that impact the decision as to whether a CGT should be implemented in New Zealand. It represents the third phase of a larger research project. This included interviews of tax experts to identify the major factors influencing the perceived desirability of implementing a CGT. It utilised individual face-toface interviews using a standardised semi-structured approach. All questions in the interviews were designed to be open-ended which allowed the participants to express their thoughts and feelings in detail. 5 A review panel was first convened to help determine the nature and form of the actual interview questions. A semi-structured interview guide was built based on five open-ended questions about the New Zealand tax system. The interviewees were asked to suggest improvements in the tax system to mitigate any identified anomalies. They were also asked to identify the central or primary considerations they factored into the policy decision on whether (and how) to tax comprehensive capital gains in New Zealand. The interviews lasted from one hour to an hour and half and most were tape recorded.In total, there were 33 interviewees (consisting of 20 tax practitioners and 13 tax teachers). The tax experts were drawn from across the north and south islands of New Zealand. All interviews were conducted between 7 December 2004 and 28 April 2006. A coding method was used to analyse the interview data. Computer software – Nvivo was used to develop categories of coding and analysis. Initially, there were 93 nodes (or codes) in respect to the tax experts’ perceptions about the current tax environment and the design features of a CGT model. At the end, these codes were merged into several themes. Research Results The result found that the majority of interviewees (n = 19) opposed the introduction of CGT, 13 supported the implementation of the tax and one was neutral. The analysis also found that tax experts from small business tended to oppose the tax (mean score of -1.09), tax teachers were mildly negative (mean score -0.23), and those practitioners from medium-sized firms were in favour of the tax (mean 1.5). Tax experts from large corporations tended to have neutral opinion (mean -0.2). 6 A careful analysis of the 33 tax experts’ opinions revealed that there are 23 basic underlying factors influencing the CGT adoption decision. These can further be grouped into five subcategories relating to (a) tax environment, (b) CGT structure, (c) tax evaluation, (d) social and political factors, and (e) international taxation factors. The 23 factors are ranked according to how many of the tax experts mentioned the item. The top three factors - (which mentioned by all 33 participants) - are high tax burden, negative political implications, and importance of private residence. These are followed by the factors of equity and the complexity of the CGT computation. Details are shown in Table 1. The top five factors are highlighted in bold. Table 1 Ranking of Factors Influencing CGT Adoption Category Factor Frequency (no. of tax experts) Ranking High tax burden 33 1 Gap between theory and practice Mistrust of IRD 15 15 12 16 Black-hole expenditure- nondeductibility of capital expenditure Complexity of the CGT computation Inflation and indexation 10 19 30 5 29 6 CGT additional record keeping CGT errors and tax penalty 22 9 16 14 Issues for preferential CGT tax rate Issues for accrual based CGT 8 20 5 22 Equity 31 4 Simplicity 27 7 Revenue consideration 22 9 Efficiency and neutrality 21 11 Taxation variables Tax Environment CGT Structure Evaluation 7 Category Factor Frequency (no. of tax experts) Ranking Negative political implications Importance of private residence Stopping property speculation 33 1 33 1 26 8 Distortion in investment behaviour Increase compliance for small businesses Hindering savings for retirements Tax harmonization 19 12 19 12 12 16 11 18 Tax competition 8 21 OECD’s recommendations 4 23 External variables Social and political International taxation The main theme of the clustering is clear: the decision for choosing the best way to tax capital gains is significantly affected by non CGT structural factors i.e., the high tax burden in the current tax environment, and social and political factors. High Tax Burden One major factor that hinders the introduction of a CGT in New Zealand is the high tax burden in the current environment. The tax experts generally considered New Zealand’s tax burden to be “high”. In fact, all of the tax experts perceived this as one of the major problems in the current tax system. Some of them even suspected that “the government was profiting from fiscal mismanagement by collecting excessive revenue” since the income thresholds for higher marginal tax rates had not been indexed for inflation and more people were pushed into the higher tax brackets, than initially intended. 8 About two thirds of the tax experts (six tax teachers and 18 tax practitioners) expressed the opinion that the high tax burden was due to the structure of tax rates and the system of social assistance and abatements. In their view the tax system together with the system of social assistance and abatements creates a very high effective marginal tax rate which has, in New Zealand, resulted in a high tax burden and a poverty trap. It is important to note that the effective marginal tax rate is different from the three aforesaid marginal tax rates. It is a marginal tax rate at which the individual taxpayer pays after considering the effect of having his/her receipts of certain social assistance and rebates being phased out. Social and Political Factors: importance of private residence and negative political implications The importance of private residence and the CGT’s negative political implications are two critical influences weighing against the adoption of a CGT. Strong opposition is expressed by the experts against a CGT if it is to be imposed on capital gains derived from a principal residence. An exemption for the private home was the most cited subject in the interviews related to social and political factors. Moreover, at the time of research, all tax experts acknowledged that adopting a CGT had negative political implications and that the topic was therefore avoided by most politicians in New Zealand. They often referred to former Finance Minister Michael Cullen’s description of a CGT as “political suicide” (New Zealand Press Association, 2000, p. 1). The general view was that any political party introducing a CGT would lose the subsequent election. Most of the tax experts considered that imposing a CGT would be “a vote killer” for any political party. Due to its damaging political effect, the tax experts simply gave up on its implementation and did not invest any effort into, or did not even begin, considering the design features of a CGT. 9 Other Major Factors Equity Equity evaluation is another critical factor. The tax experts often cited “equity” as the most important tax principle from amongst the three fundamental tax concepts, i.e., equity, efficiency and simplicity. However, their interpretation of “equity” sometimes differed from the one adopted in tax research. The experts provided many versions of “equity” in the interviews. For example, from the practitioners’ perspective, “fairness” often means “reward for risk-taking”. They considered a “fair” tax system as one that did not penalise those who earned more. This interpretation runs contrary to the traditional tax principle of horizontal equity and vertical equity. In the study, it was found that the concept of “equity” was very subjective. Some tax experts considered that justice and equity were the reasons for introducing a comprehensive CGT, while others opposed the tax because they considered it to be inequitable. These varying views had explained why the use of the same factor might often lead to a different decision. Complex CGT Computation Another major factor considered by the tax experts is the complexity of the computation of CGT. The experts opposed CGT because of its complexity and thought the tax would generate more problems than it would solve. A tax export gave a fair comment about the complexity problem of a CGT. He stated: “CGT would provide an opportunity to totally revamp tax and GST systems . . . political reality is 10 that it would be a hybrid system with exemptions, making it complex and creating compliance issues”. Other factors In addition to the top five factors, there were other important factors that were provided by the tax experts in the interviews. Other than equity, evaluation factors such as revenue consideration, simplicity, efficiency, and neutrality also played a significant role in the tax experts’ CGT adoption decision. The majority of the tax experts often supported a simple and neutral tax system which provided a “level playing field”. In most cases, the tax experts were unsure of the effects of a CGT in practice. Conclusion The result of the study revealed that there are factors other than those cited in the New Zealand Government committee reports that impact the decision as to whether a CGT should be implemented in New Zealand. These factors included taxation factors (such as current tax rate structure, tax burden) and non taxation factors (such as social and political factors). Striking an appropriate balance from amongst all these CGT adoption factors is important when considering the policy formulation of a CGT. 11 References Brash Committee. (1987). Comprehensive Tax reform and Possible Interim Solutions, Wellington, New Zealand: New Zealand Government. Burman, L., & White, D. (2003). Taxing capital gains in New Zealand, New Zealand Journal of Taxation Law and Policy, 9, 42-63. Cox, W., & Pavletich, H. (2006). 3rd Annual Demographia International Housing Affordability Survey. Demographia. Retrieved from http://www.demographia.com/dhi-ix2005q3.pdf Editorial: Capital gains. (1989, November 6). Listener.p. 7. Goldsmith, P. (2008). We won, you lost. Eat that! A political history of tax in New Zealand since 1840. Auckland, New Zealand: David Ling Publishing Limited. Labour Party. (2011). Labour’s fairer tax system explained. Retrieved from http://www.ownourfuture.co.nz/static/assets/CGTWebdoct%20July%202011.pdf. McCaw Committee. (1982). Report of the task force on tax reform. Wellington, New Zealand: New Zealand Government. McLeod Committee. (2001). Tax review 2001: Issues paper, Wellington: New Zealand Government. New Zealand Government. (1998).Final Report of the Consultative Committee on Full Imputation and International Tax Reform. Wellington: Author. New Zealand Press Association. (2000, November 30). OECD tells us to tax capital gains, The New Zealand Herald. Retrieved January 25, 2002, from 12 http://www.nzherald.co.nz/companytaxation/news/article.cfm?c_id=691&objectid=162521 OECD. (2006). OECD tax policy studies No. 14: Taxation of capital gains of individuals: Policy considerations and approaches. Paris: Author. OECD. (2007). OECD economic surveys: New Zealand 2007. Paris: Author. The Royal Commission on Social Policy. (1988). Wellington, New Zealand: New Zealand Government. Ross Committee. (1967). Taxation in New Zealand: Report of the Taxation Review Committee. Wellington, New Zealand: New Zealand Government. Tax Working Group. (2010).A tax system for New Zealand’s future: Report of the Victoria University of Wellington tax working group, Wellington, New Zealand: Centre for accounting, governance and taxation research. Retrieved from http://www.victoria.ac.nz/sacl/cagtr/twg/Report.aspx 13