VI.A. Austro-Keynesianism and deficit spending 1 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ SCHRIFTENREIHE DES LUDWIG BOLTZMANN-INSTITUTS FÜR ÖKONOMISCHE ANALYSEN WIRTSCHAFTSPOLITISCHER AKTIVITÄTEN ____________________________________________________________________________________________ Band 7 DEFICIT SPENDING AND STABILIZATION BEHAVIOUR IN AUSTRIA An empirical analysis of the budget balance in the central and general government sector Rainer Bartel Gerald Pruckner Wien 1992 Manzsche Verlags- und Universitätsbuchhandlung 2 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ VI. Summary of results VI.A. Austro-Keynesianism and deficit spending Though Austro-Keynesianism has never been clearly defined as an all-encompassing theory of economic policy, its components obviously go together well. Indeed, the individual concepts appear rather heterogeneous when considering its dogmatic roots, its coming into being as well as its unusual assignment of policy methods to the usual targets of stabilization policy. Nonetheless, in its core period Austro-Keynesianism was marked by the following ideas due to Keynes and his followers: (a) the principle of effective demand dominating economic policy decisions; (b) the endeavour to simultaneously realize high employment, low inflation and balance-ofpayments equilibrium; (c) the priority of high employment whenever this major target threatened to conflict with other targets such as budget consolidation; (d) the implementation of a "direct employment policy" to maximize production and maintain high employment by hoarding employees in the public sector of the economy even during long-lasting recessions; (e) the replacement of "cold turkey" as a means of combatting inflation by the Austrian Economic and Social Partnership's stability-oriented incomes policy; (f) the basic idea of stabilizing expectations, lessening uncertainty and preserving business confidence by stabilizing the development of macroeconomic key variables such as the real wage rate, nominal interest rate, nominal exchange rate and aggregate demand. From these characteristics it becomes obvious that Austro-Keynesian economic policy does not rely on the notion of self-correcting market forces clearing the single markets and pushing overall economic activity towards the full-employment level. Instead of reinforcing the mechanism of relative prices in order to solve economic problems without government interference, Austro-Keynesianism ascribes an active role to the state,and emphasizes the importance of a large public sector for contributing to social goals through positive external effects on the private economy. From this perspective, a close relationship can be established VI.A. Austro-Keynesianism and deficit spending 3 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ between Austro-Keynesianism and the Post-Keynesian school of economic thought. The latter has been promoted particularly by economists prone to socialist ideologies. This is why AustroKeynesianism has been occasionally called Austro-Marxism though Austria's society was always very distant from a Marxian system. Clearly, Austro-Keynesianism does also not have very much in common with Neoclassical economics: the policy of moderate real wage increases has not been adopted in the Neoclassical sense of the real wage rate determining employment immediately. In fact, economic liberalism and price competition have not been very marked in Austria. It seems unnecessary to stress that Austro-Keynesianism has nothing to do with New classical macroeconomics which proposes the ineffectiveness of government's demand-side policies. Moreover, one cannot find strong evidence (sometimes contended) that the Austrian National Bank pursued an Austro-Monetarist policy. Admittedly, Austrian monetary policy is influenced by the effects of the German Federal Bank's monetarist policy through the stabilized nominal exchange rate. However, institutional barriers to perfect mobility of capital, the minor importance of the Austrian currency, larger increases in productivity and the long-term development of the real exchange rate between the Austrian Schilling and the German Mark have granted (at least a moderate) autonomy in monetary policy which has never been utilized for monetary targeting. The monetary base has been mainly determined by net capital inflows and has not been neutralized through internal components of high-powered money. Of course there have been also supply-side measures of promoting exports, investment and employment in Austria. However, all these methods (except perhaps the 1988 tax reform) were not intended in the sense of, and not arranged similar to, the US understanding of supply-side economics (Reaganomics). Some of the Austrian supply-side measures actually restrict the mechanism of relative prices. Austro-Keynesianism rejects the notion of the Neoclassical synthesis which reduces Keynesian problems of insufficient effective demand to problems of sticky prices and limits the relevance of Keynesian economic policy to fighting only severe recessions. Finally, its Post-Keynesian character makes the theoretical concept of Austro-Keynesianism surpass the doctrine of hydraulic Keynesianism which contends the feasibility of stabilizing real output at a high level only through a fine-tuning type of demand management. In the concept of AustroKeynesianism, deficit spending fulfils the function of compensating the restrictive demand-side 4 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ effects of other policy elements such as the moderate incomes policy and the appreciating exchange rate policy ("hard-currency policy"). Relating the features of the theoretical concept interpreted above to the different political periods of Austrian post-war history one can confine the core period of Austro-Keynesianism roughly to the one-party governments of the Socialist Party between 1970 and 1983. In the course of the 80s the historically grown concept of Austro-Keynesianism has been increasingly changed. New elements replaced some of the features of the original concept: (a) a changed fiscal attitude which tends to believe that (large?) budget deficits slow down economic development; (b) a strict course of consolidating the budget (that is, reducing the net deficit step by step to a certain deficit ratio to GDP); (c) the abstention from direct employment policy and an increased exposure of the public enterprises to international competition at the expense of realizing non-commercial (political) goals; (d) privatization and deregulation for reasons of enhancing efficiency and unburdening the budget; (e) an increased readiness, or compulsion, to follow the interest rate policy of the German Federal Bank. In terms of Austria joining the European Economic Area or even the European Community, the informal institution of the Austrian Economic and Social Partnership will have to be thoroughly analyzed as to whether it conforms with the EC's understanding of market competition. VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 5 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance VI.B.1. The central government The period under review can be divided into two distinct subperiods of budgetary policy: (a) the "contractive" or "pre-deficit" period (1960-1972) in which structural budget deficits were rather low and occurred very seldom, and (b) the "expansionist" or "deficit" period (1973-1990) with permanent and considerable structural budget deficits. Therefore, it is argued that, in general, output gaps were not the factor that determined whether a discretionary budget surplus or deficit was incurred. The countercyclical or procyclical quality of the budgetary impacts, caused by a positive or negative full-employment budget balance, respectively, was influenced more by the sign of the corresponding output gap. The results show that 61 percent of the discretionary budget balances were countercyclical - 69 percent in the contractive and 56 percent in the expansionist period. A more appropriate measure of stabilization behaviour appears to be the amount of change in the full-employment budget balance. Three quarters of these budgetary reactions can be called countercyclical in the contractive period and only one third in the expansionist period. Over the entire investigation period the relative frequency of discretionary countercyclical budget reactions amounts to one half. Putting a somewhat higher demand on stabilization policy, by stipulating that the danger of overshooting trend GDP through exaggerated budgetary reactions be reduced, lowers the relative frequency of cyclically appropriate budgetary reactions by 7 percentage points for the entire period of observation. The fairly poor stabilization performance in the expansionist period is modified if you hypothesize budgetary decision rules requiring that contractive discretionary reactions - though countercyclical - are ruled out whenever the real growth rate of GDP declines and/or the unemployment rate rises. Subject to (a) the real growth rate condition, (b) the unemployment rate condition and (c) both conditions, the stabilization performance is not improved at all in the pre-deficit period but it is substantially improved in the deficit period raising the relative frequency of discretionary countercyclical reactions to (a) 50, (b) 56 and (c) even 72 percent. The results in detail show that between 1973 and 1980 a falling rate of real growth and from 6 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ 1983 to 1990 a rising rate of unemployment were important motivating factors for avoiding countercyclical reductions of the structural budget deficit and stimulating growth and employment through higher aggregate demand. Both in the contractive and the expansionist period countercyclical reactions of discretionary budget policy were more frequent in years with a negative than with a positive output gap. Such an asymmetry of stabilization policy holds true if you only consider the years of onsetting strains and recessions. The same asymmetry of stabilization behaviour reappears when you not only calculate the frequency but also relate the amounts of change of the countercyclical to the procyclical budgetary balances. Thus it is recognized that in the central government sector policymakers stabilized aggregate demand more readily, more strongly and more quickly in periods exceeding the trend GDP than in periods falling short of it. In addition, stabilization performance has also been assessed under the premise that the information basis of stabilization policy is lagged by one year. The results appear more stabilization-motivated in the era after 1979 changing the ratio of countercyclical to procyclical reactions of discretionary budget policy from 2:9 to 9:2. Hence one can conclude that, due to a rising uncertainty in the markets after the second oil-price shock, expectation formation became more backward-looking than forward-looking - a fact that might have deteriorated stabilization performance substantially. Considering the relative weights of the discretionary and the automatic component of the budget balance, one can say that after 1974 automatic stabilization lost importance relative to discretionary fiscal policy. This may be due to the comparatively small amplitudes and short episodes of the cyclical deviations, as well as the substantially higer structural deficits in the second half of our investigation period. Stabilization performance is further assessed with regard to the different political subperiods (inter alia the core period of Austro-Keynesianism from 1971 to 1983). Regarding the budgetary impacts which were exerted by the amount of the full-employment budget balance in the political periods, the conservative-led "old large coalition" governments were stabilization-oriented to the highest degree (the structural budget balances were then sufficiently small that their signs could be changed easily from year to year). The good and mediocre results of the socialist governments and socialist-led coalition governments were determined by the comparatively frequent occurrence of negative output gaps after 1974. VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 7 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ Analyzing the discretionary reactions of budget policy, the general result is reached that the later the political period occurred the less frequent were the countercyclical reactions or the more important were other economic factors of budgetary decisions. In the seventies (roughly during the SPÖ governments) it was the real growth rate condition and in the eighties (approximately the period of SPÖ-led coalition governments) it was the unemployment rate condition which, in retrospect, makes discretionary budget reactions appear more reasonable. Hence one may conclude that the motives of short-run budgetary policy changed between the terms of office of the conservative and conservative-led governments (just reduction of output gaps), the socialist governments (in addition to output-gap reduction: stimulation of real growth) and the socialist-led coalition governments (in addition to output-gap reduction: stimulation of employment, at least before the target of budget consolidation was realized). If reducing the danger of overshooting the trend is also required and the real growth as well as the unemployment condition are observed, one gets the interesting result that the core period of Austro-Keynesianism performs best and removes the ÖVP government from first position in stabilization performance. In terms of the asymmetry of stabilization policy, we have seen that, in general, negative output gaps were more readily countervailed than positive ones. The only exceptions to the rule represent the ÖVP government which fought more strains than recessions (in an era of accelerating inflation) and the SPÖ-led "new large" coalition government which (in the budget consolidation phase) dampened neither strains nor recessions. The same result is reached when looking only at the beginnings of recessions and strains. The overall assessment of stabilization behaviour, including discretionary budget impacts and reactions, leads to the conclusion that the later the political period occurred the worse was its government's stabilization performance. However, there remains one exception: the one-year minority government of the SPÖ in 1970 performed best in any respect considered here, but this might have easily been a "lucky strike". Reviewing the relative importance of automatism and discretion associated with the budget balance, one gets the results that the relative weight of automatic stabilization reached a maximum during the ÖVP's one-party government and also dominated under the ÖVP-led coalition governments, whereas discretion ruled under the SPÖ-led coalition governments. The core period of Austro-Keynesianism lay between the extremes but can be characterized as a period of mainly discretionary budget policy. 8 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ In terms of the public-choice issue of expansionist budget policy before elections, it has to be recognized that there is no general indication of strategic political behaviour in Austria. Nonetheless, there are two marked exceptions to this: the 1983 elections ending the series of socialist one-party governments and the elections of 1990. In both cases the SPÖ was firmly expected to suffer heavy losses. On the other hand, both of these procyclical reactions could have also been motivated by the rising unemployment rates that occurred at these points in time. Next, the orders of magnitude of the countercyclical and procyclical impacts and reactions of discretionary budget policy are assessed. A marked rise in the long-term level of the ratio of the full-employment budget balance to nominal trend GDP (FEBB ratio) is clearly discernible after the first oil-price shock. Since 1987, the FEBB ratio has declined due to attempts at budget consolidation. Based on the ratio of countercyclical and procyclical impacts and reactions of discretionary budget policy to the corresponding output gap, two straightforward measures of stabilization performance are created: the "impact ratio" (RATIO6) and the "reaction ratio" (RATIO9). Judging by the impact ratio,the one-party government of the ÖVP distinctly performs best, and the core period of Austro-Keynesianism only ranks fourth. A similar result is reached when you relate the full-employment budget balance to the volume of the budget. In general, it can be concluded that the policy of permanent structural surpluses till 1972 was markedly more appropriate for the cyclical conditions than the policy of uniform structural deficits was for the period after 1972. One has to add though that the policy of continuous budget surpluses (deficits) fitted better into the economic circumstances prevailing in the contractive (expansionist) period than if the reverse had been the case. On the whole the results are quite satisfactory with the impact ratio always being larger than unity (which means that the countercyclical dominated the procyclical impacts) and mostly larger than 2.3. Only the "new large coalition" government of SPÖ and ÖVP (i.e., the budget consolidation phase) performed poorly achieving an impact ratio of just 1.1. The reaction ratio actually yields the same results which were achieved when investigating only the relative frequency of countercyclical discretionary reactions of the budget balance: the later the fiscal and political periods, the worse was the stabilization performance of its government(s). The ÖVP-led coalition governments (1961-1966) lead overwhelmingly; the core period of Austro-Keynesianism is placed in the middle of the ranking. Again the general result VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 9 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ is not bad, with the reaction ratio being greater than 1.7, and the only exception being the "new large coalition" government which (in the budget consolidation phase) did not even once react countercyclically to the business cycle situation. The results given so far give the impression that the period of preponderantly positive structural budget balances and flexible reactions to the output gaps was ended by the adverse international supply-side shocks and their detrimental effects on economic confidence. In Austria this fact was supposed to require a long-term policy of pronounced deficit spending in order to secure high real growth and low unemployment rates. Perhaps such a "stronghold" of effective demand contributed to an increased capacity for self-stabilization in the economy resulting in shorter and smaller output gaps in the course of the eighties. In fact, this type of expansionist attitude was only revised under the influence of the ÖVP as a conservative, fiscally more restrictive, coalition partner. In spite of the (often declared) intention of cutting the budget deficit, during the core period of Austro-Keynesianism the concrete targets and the means of achieving them remained too vague to be effective for a long time. The chance of consolidating the budget while the economy was booming between 1971 and 1974 was clearly missed. Unfortunately, four of the six measures for cutting the budget deficit after the slump in 1975 were procyclical. Only one of these four procyclical consolidation measures fell into the core period of Austro-Keynesianism, another one was by the SPÖ-FPÖ government, and the remaining two were due to the "new large coalition's" firm intention of reducing the net deficit come what may. In general, one can state that when budget consolidation was achieved in the crisis-prone era after 1974, it mostly happened at the wrong point in time with respect to the business cycle situation. Initially, the primary motives of budget consolidation were the increasing share of interest payments in public expenditures, the rising concern about the capacity of financing the fastgrowing deficits and the need to regain the "freedom of fiscal action" which enables government to combat larger recessions in future. Later, under the "new large coalition" governments, however, there were no longer arguments in favour of demand management. Instead, government intended to focus on supply-side measures of modernizing and "internationalizing" the economy in order to improve Austria's competitiveness which for a long time had been supported by protectionist regulations and strong demand management. A new fiscal perspective entered the concept of Austrian economic policy, namely, that budget deficits impede the development of the economy. As a consequence, budget consolidation ceased to be 10 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ considered harmful to employment and has been strictly pursued since 1987. Thus the new fiscal attitude clearly differs from the one adopted during the core period of AustroKeynesianism. Finally, we analyzed in what manner the decomposed full-employment budget balance developed in relation to nominal trend GDP. Generally, one can say that the main components of the full-employment budget balance (interest payments, public investment, transfers and consumption) developed in the same direction. Interest payments on public debt is the category of public expenses which deviated least from the common development of discretionary public expenditures. Nonetheless, interest payments did affect the structural budget balance and the public savings ratio, mainly during the recession from 1967 to 1969 and to a markedly higher degree after the great slump in 1975. In five of the 31 years of observation the influence of interest payments turned the full-employment budget balance negative. Gross public fixed investment only behaved more expansively than the other discretionary public expenditures when, under the first two socialist one-party governments, public infrastructure was extended and improved and when the SPÖ tried to minimize expected losses in the 1983 elections. In general, public investment has not been an instrument used particularly to win elections, fight recessions or consolidate the budget. Public transfers by central government, most frequently and to the greatest extent, developed more expansively than the other current expenditures. Extraordinary increases in public transfers were brought about, especially when positive output gaps occurred. In the pre-socialist era public transfers were raised more than proportionately in every election year, whereas in the socialist period such behaviour could be observed only in the election years of 1975 and 1983. (Both years, however, are characterized by an increasing rate of unemployment.) The only periods of more than proportionate reductions in public transfers were 1979-1981 and 19881990 (the latter being the budget consolidation phase). Clearly, public consumption belongs to the comparatively expansionist components of current public expenditures. The only distinctive period of less than proportionate increases or more than proportionate reductions in public consumption can be observed between 1986 and 1990 (budget consolidation phase). Finally, excessive public consumption cannot be described as a special feature of election years. VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 11 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ In terms of the success of attempts at budget consolidation in the late eighties, it can be stated that a reduction in the ratio of the full-employment budget balance (gross and net of interest payments) to nominal trend GDP (FEBB ratio) was achieved after 1987. The same consolidation success holds true for the net public savings ratio (net of interest payments). In 1989 and 1990 the FEBB ratio net of interest payments even became positive but the interest payments left the FEBB ratio gross of interest payments negative. The public savings net of interest payments have always been positive. The interest payments on public debt, however, turned public savings into dissavings between 1976 and 1980 as well as after 1981. The public savings ratio gross and net of interest payments has been successfully increased since 1988. Budget consolidation measures have been directed at public transfers (since 1988), public consumption (since 1986) and public investment (since 1984 though with interuptions in 1988 and 1990). VI.B.2. The general government The fiscal aggregate under review consists of the consolidated budgets of the central government, the governments of the nine federal states, the municipal governments, the Association of Municipalities, the Syndicate of Social Insurance Corporations under public law and the chambers (profits and losses of the state enterprises under public law are included in the governmental budgets). Presenting the results for the general government sector the following characteristic fiscal subperiods are distinguished: (a) the stabilization period (1956-1959), with changing signs of the structural budget balance; (b) the contractive period (1960-1974), with exclusively positive full-employment budget balances; (c) the expansionist period (1975-1990), with uniformly negative full-employment budget balances. It was only in the contractive period that the operation of automatic stabilizers turned a procyclical into a countercyclical budgetary impact. The importance of discretionary budget 12 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ policy relative to automatic stabilization increased from one fiscal subperiod to the next, particularly from the point in time when the structural budget deficits started to be permanent. With respect to the proper direction of the budgetary impacts, the stabilization period performs best: the sign of the full-employment budget balance was flexibly adjusted to the business cycle situation. The results for the two long-term periods of uniform signs of the discretionary budget balance are very similar. They indicate that the policy of continuous surpluses and deficits, respectively, were appropriate for the specific situations prevailing during the distinct periods if you rule out the first-best solution of switching between structural budget deficit and surplus from year to year according to the output gap. Obviously, this result is partly due to the fact that the change from current and structural surpluses to deficits occurred exactly at the point in time when real growth slumped after the first oil-price shock. With regard to the relative frequency of the discretionary budget reactions to the business cycle situation, budget policy was far more stabilization-oriented in the contractive than in the expansionist period. During the stabilization period the budgetary reactions were mostly procyclical, but there was no great need to react properly to the output gap as the budget balance produced a countercyclical impact in three out of four cases. Over the entire investigation period positive output gaps were more often countervailed than negative ones. The opposite can be stated for the expansionist and stabilization period. However, if you consider only the beginning of recessions and strains in the economy it can be seen that, during the stabilization and contractive period, every recession (but not every strain) was fought immediately. In the expansionist period, however, the countercyclical budget policy reactions were symmetric for the onset of strains and recessions, but only a third of the initial cyclical fluctuations were properly reacted to. Our measure of satisfactory stabilization behaviour considers de-/stabilizing impacts and reactions jointly. It yields that only in the contractive period was the general government's stabilization behaviour preponderantly satisfying. In addition, the quantitative aspect of budgetary impacts and reactions is dealt with, giving an idea of the order of magnitude of the current and structural budget balance: their shares in GDP reached a maximum in 1987 and have decreased since then. In more than two thirds of our observations the structural budget balance was greater than the output gap (both expressed in absolute terms). VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 13 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ The "impact ratio" ("reaction ratio") is our measure which captures the relative size of the de/stabilizing impacts and reactions by relating the countercyclical to the procyclical impacts (reactions) of discretionary budget policy (the budgetary impacts and reactions are measured as percentage of trend GDP). It can be seen that the countercyclical outweighed the procyclical impacts in every fiscal period. The stabilization performance expressed by the "impact ratio" was about twice as high in the contractive period as in the other subperiods. It is interesting to learn that, with regard to the size of the de-/stabilizing impacts, the stabilization period performed even worse than the expansionist period (the former was termed stabilization period because of the flexible sign of the discretionary budget balance and the high relative frequency of countercyclical impacts). A similar picture emerges when considering the relative size of the countercyclical and procyclical reactions of discretionary budget policy. Again it is evident that in the contractive period the general public sector tried its best to countervail the output gaps. In the stabilization period the general government sector mostly produced countercyclical structural impacts but reacted only once countercyclically. Moreover, the countercyclical reaction was very small and the procyclical reactions overwhelmingly large. Judging the stabilization performance of the general government sector with respect to both the relative frequency and the relative magnitude of the impacts and reactions of discretionary budget policy, yields that the stabilization task was clearly performed best during the contractive period. In particular, this is true with regard to the quantitative aspect of discretionary impacts and reactions was well as to the relative frequency of budget policy reaction. Only with regard to the relative frequency of countercyclical impacts of discretionary budget impacts did the other subperiods perform better. In the contractive period, however, the structural budget surplus was kept at a level which was low enough for the automatic stabilizers to operate effectively and give the budget balance the proper sign in five out of the 15 years. Including the effects of automatic stabilization would raise the relative frequency of countercyclical impacts of budget policy in the contractive period to as high as 93 percent. Looking at the pre-deficit period (1956-1974), one can state that there were only two years of procyclical impacts of the current budget balance (1958 and 1962). The long series of countercyclical budget balances only came to an end as late as 1977. There were some successful attempts of consolidating the budget: to a rather modest extent in the late seventies, to a more considerable extent in 1981, and even more so in 1984. For a long 14 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ time, however, the success in consolidating the budget was only transitory. In 1987 the current and the structural budget deficit reached a maximum with respect to both their amount and their share in (trend) GDP. From 1988 onward the current and full-employment budget deficit ratios to (trend) GDP were reduced every year. But after the first slump (1975/76) in the deficit period, successful measures of reducing the discretionary deficit represented procyclical reactions in two thirds of the observed cases. It must be conceded, though, that the countercyclical impacts of the continuous full-employment budget deficits were always larger than their procyclical reductions. In the expansionist period reductions in the structural deficit were even over-represented in that they occurred more frequently than positive output gaps, but only a minority of the budget consolidation measures were countercyclical. The reverse is true for the contractive period, and in the stabilization period there were only reductions of the structural budget balance. In order to shed some light on the structural development of the full-employment budget balance, several structural budget balance ratios are defined. Comparing them to each other, the relative development of interest payments on public debt, gross public fixed investment, public transfers and public consumption is described. In more than three quarters of our observations the interest payments on public debt increased more than proportionately or decreased less than proportionately to the remaining components of the full-employment budget balance. In three of the years the interest payments rose sufficiently to make the full-employment budget balance ratio decrease though it would have increased without regard to interest payments. In the years 1975, 1978 to 1982 and 1984 to 1990 the influence of the interest payments even turned the full-employment budget surplus into a deficit. Moreover, in the period between 1984 and 1990 the interest payments on public debt even sufficed in turning public savings into dissavings. The results for gross public fixed investment do not allow a general verdict about whether the development of this spending category was comparatively strong or weak. You also cannot say that public investment was particularly employed for countervailing output gaps. At least two distinctive periods can be discerned. Between 1974 and 1979 as well as from 1987 to 1990 (the latter is the period of declared budget consolidation at the central government level) the restrictive conduct of public investment policy contributed particularly to the reductionin the full-employment budget deficit relative to trend GDP. VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 15 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ In terms of the relative development of public transfers,it is apparent that in two thirds of our observations this category of expenditures developed more than proportionately to the other components in the public savings ratio. In 1957, 1964 and 1985, when there was a strain on the economy, the expansionist development of public transfers even turned the public savings net of interest payments into dissavings. On the one hand, the years following the first and second oilprice shock were characterized by a particularly expansionist development of public transfers. On the other hand, public transfers contributed considerably to the budget consolidation achievements from 1988 to 1990. It has to be added, though, that after 1973 relatively restrictive measures in transfers policy were mostly adopted in years of negative output gaps. Finally, the relative development of public consumption shows that this spending category belongs, like public transfers, to the relatively expansionist components of the public savings ratio. In nearly two thirds of our observations public consumption showed a comparatively strong development. In the periods from 1958 to 1961 and from 1987 to 1990 public consumption, in particular, contributed to consolidating the budget. Summing up it can be stated that the share of the structural budget deficit in mid-term trend GDP was reduced after 1987 though the process of budget consolidation was clearly impeded by the interest payments on public debt after 1977. The success in slowing the growth of the current and discretionary budget deficit after 1987 was due to restrictive policies of public investment (since 1987), public transfers (in 1986 and from 1987 onwards) and public consumption (starting in 1987). VI.B.3. A comparison of budget policy in the general and central government sector With reference to the distinctive fiscal periods,there is no equivalent subperiod for the general government's stabilization period (1956-1959) because the data series for the central government starts as late as 1960. In the general government sector the expansionist period began in 1975, whereas the continuous structural deficits in the central government's budget had already started in 1973. In every year of the entire observation period the current and structural budget balances in the general government sector were greater than in the central government sector. At both federative levels the current and structural budget deficits reached a peak in 1987 differing by 0.69 percentage points of GDP and 0.97 percentage points of trend GDP, respectively. In the 16 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ general government sector the current and discretionary budget deficits decreased steadily both as amounts and as shares in (trend) GDP after 1987. In the same period the current and structural budget deficits in the central government sector also declined monotonically as a percentage of (trend) GDP, but as amounts they rose again in 1990. In the general (central) government sector the automatic stabilizers transformed the procyclical impact of the discretionary budget balance into a countercyclical impact of the current budget balance in five (three) cases all of which occurred in the course of the contractive period. Our measures of automatism and discretion indicate that, in general, the degree of automatism (discretion) was higher in the entire public sector than in central government sector. Only in the contractive period did the measure of discretion yield nearly the same results for both sectors. One procedure of assessing the stabilization performance is to calculate the relative frequency of countercyclical impacts and reactions of discretionary budget policy. For both of these aspects, basically the same results are received. In general, the stabilization performance hardly differed between the entire and the central public sector, whereas in the contractive (expansionist) period the central (general) government sector performed better. It should be added that at the central level of the federative state, the asymmetry of countercyclical reactions of discretionary budget policy is clearly larger in that negative output gaps are more frequently countervailed than positive ones. Our measure of overall stabilization performance which jointly takes account of the relative frequency of the impacts and reactions of discretionary budget policy, yields that over the entire period of observation the general government sector actually performed slightly better than the central government sector because the lead of the general on the central government in the expansionist period was greater than the lead of the central on the general government in the contractive period. Another procedure for assessing the stabilization performance, is to evaluate the magnitude of countercyclical and procyclical impacts and reactions of discretionary budget policy relative to the corresponding output gap ("impact ratio" and "reaction ratio"). In the contractive (expansionist) period the stabilizing as well as the destabilizing impacts per countercyclical and procyclical year, respectively, were larger in the general (central) than in the central (general) government sector. With respect to discretionary impacts of the budget, the central government performed somewhat better in both of the fiscal periods. In terms of the size of the discretionary budgetary reactions, it can be seen that in every subperiod the stabilizing and destabilizing budgetary reactions per countercyclical and procyclical year, respectively, were bigger in the VI.B. Budget policy in the light of the full-employment budget balance 17 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ general than in the central government sector. In the contractive period the stabilization performance with respect to budgetary reactions was far better in the central than in the general government sector. In the expansionist period, however, the general government reacted a bit more powerfully to the business cycle situation. Assessing the discretionary stabilization performance with regard to the magnitude of the stabilizing and destabilizing impacts and reactions relative to the output gaps, reveals that over the entire observation period (1960-1990) the general government sector was slightly more successful than the central government sector. In general, all components of the full-employment budget balance developed mostly in the same direction. Deviations from the direction of the general development of the discretionary expenditure categories were registered in the general (central) government sector in 11 percent (9 percent) of all observations. Such deviations are observed particularly with public investment and consumption in the general government sector and with public transfers in the central government sector. Interest payments on public debt very often reduced the increase in the full-employment budget balance ratio to a greater extent than all the other components of the structural budget balance. More precisely, this holds true for the general (central) government sector in more than three quarters (more than two thirds) of our observations between 1961 and 1990. Interest payments sometimes even sufficed in turning the structural budget surplus into a deficit. In the general (central) government sector this phenomenon occurred in 38 percent (16 percent) of our observations. The development of public investment within the structural budget balance ratio to trend GDP suggests that at the general and central government level gross fixed investment was neither specifically designed to countervail output gaps nor was it an especially expansionist spending category. Rather, public investment was employed for consolidating the budget in the seventies and eighties. In contrast, public transfers appear to be a spending category with the most expansionist development among the components of the discretionary budget balance, especially in the general government sector where the Syndicate of Social Insurance Corporations is represented. Public transfers contributed specifically to consolidating the budget only at the end of the seventies and early eighties at the central government level, and after 1987 at both federative levels. 18 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ Public consumption also constitutes a relatively expansionist spending category, particularly at the general government level. In both sectors the only distinctive periods of more than proportionate decreases or less than proportionate increases in public consumption relative to trend GDP occurred at the end of the fifties and in the early sixties in the general government sector and in the second half of the eighties. Attempts at budget consolidation were successful after 1987 in that the ratios of the discretionary and current budget deficit to (trend) GDP were reduced in the general as well as in the central government sector. In both of these sectors this was achieved by a restrictive policy of public investment, transfers and consumption. Only at the central government level were there some difficulties in slowing the pace of public investment. With respect to the business cycle situation, attempts at budget consolidation are over-represented in the general and underrepresented in the central government sector. For both federative levels which were distinguished the results achieved show that in the contractive (expansionist) period a clear majority (minority) of the attempts at budget consolidation operated countercyclically. Moreover, in this respect it can be stated that in both fiscal periods the central government performed notably better than the general government. VI.C. The identification of (full-employment) budget deficit determinants After the analysis of the countercyclical or procyclical character of the discretionary budget balance, a multiple regression model was applied to determine the main factors exerting an influence on the level of (structural) budget deficits. An overwhelming portion of government revenues depends on the level of macroeconomic output. That is why the actual budget deficits are influenced by the prevailing business cycle situation. This connection is reinforced by the inherently countercyclical nature of several expenditure components and by a fiscal policy of effective demand pursued to resist the onset of recessions. Due to the fact that the emergence of public deficits causes credit costs, interest payments on outstanding debts also play an important role in the planning of budget policy. Current interest rates and deficits incurred in past periods represent variables determining the extent of debt servicing burden. VI.C. The identification of budget deficit determinants 19 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ Another argument which has been often put forward is that different price levels in the private and public economy account for a growing public sector. This hypothesis is based on Baumol's "cost disease of public consumption" accompanied by a lag of labour productivity in the government sector. There are also political conditions which may help to illustrate the development of government deficits over time. Such politico-economic effects comprise the number of parties in the government, the tenure of ruling governments and the next election date as well as the degree of centralization or decentralization of political power between federal and local authorities and the potency of various interest groups. Several arguments are proposed to stress that multi-party coalition governments are more willing to incur larger deficits. The absence of a uniform objective function, the protection of specific groups of population (political clientels) and the competition for votes between the democratic parties are held responsible for the increase in government expenditures. But a growing number of parties constituting the government could also exert an effect in the opposite direction: if it is possible to strengthen mutual control mechanisms between coalition partners, democratic parties will come into a position of being able to resist increasing demands by their own interest groups by palming off the responsibility for budget cuts on their partners. Bearing all these considerations in mind, a simple multiple regression procedure was implemented for the Austrian central government. For the period from 1960 to 1990 the dependent variable (deficit-GDP ratio) was estimated as a function of the lagged dependent variable, the unemployment rate, the growth rate of real GDP, the interest payments on public debt and a political variable representing mutual control mechanisms. All estimated coefficients showed the theoretically expected sign at a significance level of at least 95 percent. The negative coefficient of the political variable confirms the results of NECK and SCHNEIDER (1988). Using the same specification, full-employment deficits related to trend output levels were estimated in a second regression analysis. The resultant coefficients were very similar to the parameters derived before. But the t-statistic for the GDP growth rate was reduced substantially - a reference to the proposition that there is no definite evidence for the existence of a countercyclical discretionary budget policy measured in growth rates of macroeconomic output levels. 20 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ But there are remaining problems with respect to an economic interpretation of a single estimation equation. The possibility of nonstationarity in the macroeconomic series under question or the existence of co-integration between various economic variables are reasons for a subsequent time series analysis of (full-employment) budget deficit ratios.1 After an introduction to the mathematical conditions of the stationarity of time series and a presentation of appropriate statitical test procedures, we investigated the development of the FEBD trend output ratio (FD) over time. We found that the existence of a unit root synonymous with nonstationarity - cannot be rejected. So the hypothesis of a random walk model without a positive drift or a trend component was supported by an augmented DickeyFuller test. Furthermore, the same test procedure applied to first differences of FD resulted in the differentiated series being stationary, which means that the ratio is integrated with order one. Suppose we have two time series yt and xt each of them being I(1). If there is a constant a with the linear combination yt - axt yielding a stationary series I(0), the variables are said to be cointegrated and this causes statistical implications for dynamic econometric models. The existence of co-integration between non-stationary time series can also be investigated by the application of the Dickey-Fuller method. The procedure is based on a test of unit roots in the estimated residuals of the co-integration equation. Testing the co-integration between FD and the regressors of equation (8), it was found that the variables are not co-integrated. That is why there is no need to establish an error correction mechanism to model the budget deficits over time. Taking into account these results and estimating relation (8) again in first differences, we found little empirical evidence - with the exception of the rate of unemployment - that the initial regressors play a major role in the determination of full-employment budget deficits. The result that the evidence of structural relations is reduced dramatically in the presence of stationary time series is aggravated by the argument that the regressors in the single equation do not represent exogenous variables in the sense of theoretical macroeconomics. 1 A further problem results from the fact that the different regressors in equation (8) do not represent exogenous variables but rather are determined simultaneously. But the purpose of our analysis has been to gain a first insight into the characteristics of Austrian budget policy. For a more detailed investigation it is indispensible to apply a macroeconomic model including dynamic links and simultaneous relations between the relevant variables of economic (budget) policy. VI.D. Concluding remarks 21 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ VI.D. Concluding remarks Our concluding remarks refer to the main items which have emerged from our analysis: (a) budget policy has been characterized by a long-run tendency of growing structural deficits after a long period of discretionary surpluses - developments which inparticular, suited the economic circumstances of the respective periods quite well; (b) there was no systematic policy of smoothing the course of the economy to the mid-term trend value of real GDP; (c) nonetheless, the countercyclical quality of the discretionary budget reactions was better than random outcomes of the change in the structural budget balance; (d) the unemployment rate (and perhaps also the growth rate of real GDP) appear to have exerted a significant influence on the reactions of discretionary budget policy. At the central government level, the era of structural budget surpluses was apparently ended by the expansionist public infrastructure policy of the first socialist one-party governments and by the expansionist demand management motivated by the adverse consequences of the first oilprice shock. These events marked a substantial change in the development of public finances in that a new fiscal attitude was created which basically accepted living with high and growing deficits (even as a ratio to GDP). This change in fiscal attitude might have enabled particular interest groups to get their demands on public funds through, and made deficit spending a universal method of coping with slow growth and high unemployment. Austria is well know to be a country in which pluralistic interests are densely organized and interest groups seem to have great informal influence on the formal centres of power (parliament, government and last but not least administration). Furthermore, bureaucratic behaviour in the sense of Leibenstein and Niskanen, which inevitably leads to waste and increasing budgets, also becomes apparent when you look at the process of budgeting. It constitutes a procedure for distributing the planned increase in public revenues (sometimes under the restriction of a net borrowing limit) among the different ministeries each of which can easily point out a few major projects that should not be curtailed for some commonsense reason or other. This process is termed "budgetary incrementalism". As experience shows, budgetary 22 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ incrementalism can only be reversed permanently under the influence of a coalition partner who has adopted a more restrictive fiscal attitude than the Socialist Party and by a switch in public opinion giving higher priority to the target of "sound finance" (whatever this slogan is supposed to mean). Facing the adverse consequences of the oil-price shocks, it turned out to be a common problem distinguishing to what extent the growth of natural output declined due to the productivity shocks (structural unemployment), and hence to determine how much growth slowed down due to the accompanying demand disturbances (cyclical unemployment). The verdict on the change in the NAIRU clearly calls for a reassessment of demand management and the importance of deficit spending (GORDON 1990, pp. 277-300). Obviously, the uncertainty about the structural changes in the labour and product markets favours quite a strong increase in budget deficits, especially under the conditions of a pluralistic democratic society. In chapter I we tried to point out the close relationship between Austro-Keynesianism and PostKeynesianism. In Austria the neoclassical or bastard-keynesian concept of natural unemployment, and hence the trade-off between high employment and low inflation, did not affect demand-enforcing budget policy too much (at least in the core period of AustroKeynesianism). Moreover, wage-induced inflation was countervailed by a stability-oriented policy of wage and price determination and a hard-currency policy. Finally, deficit spending was obviously intended to stabilize optimistic expectations of aggregate demand. These reasons, together with the uncertainty about the duration of the recessions following the supply-side shocks, introduced a period of pronounced deficit spending which was reinforced by the rising influence of the interest payments on public debt. Moreover, strong discretionary deficit spending reduced the importance of automatic stabilization immensely. For quite a long time deficit spending was not restricted lastingly because one was convinced of the negative effects of budget consolidation on real growth and employment. On the one hand, AustroKeynesian economic policy can be called naive in that it mainly relied on demand-side policies and put much less emphasis on supply-side measures to overcome structural deficiencies of the economy. On the other hand, such a policy of strong effective demand might have contributed to an increased capacity for self-stabilization in the economy resulting in shorter and smaller output gaps, as were observed in the course of the eighties. VI.D. Concluding remarks 23 ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ Unfortunately, the measures for reducing the budget deficit turned out to be mostly procyclical. Attempts at budget consolidation were successful after 1987. The 1986 coalition agreement between the Socialist Party and the People's Party set concrete quantitative targets for budget consolidation which have been realized. However, the deficit reductions were not only executed without regard to the business cycle situation but they were also realized mainly through shortrun measures that cannot be repeated frequently (e.g., sales of public property, using financial reserves, window dressing, etc). This is why the method used for consolidating the budget has been justly criticized (GANTNER and EIBL 1991, pp. 487-516). As some investigations have indicated, there is still considerable potential for productivity gains in the Austrian public sector. This refers to the production functions of corporations under public law and public firms under private law as well as to the procedures for planning the budget and managing public funds. As long as politics sticks to the traditional methods of organizing public projects, activities and expenditures there will be no way out of the inherent problems of budget maximizing behaviour and ill-considered expenditure cuts. In particular, there are several major problems in the public sector that obviously call for solutions: the retirement pension system, the system of medical aid and care, the system of agricultural subsidies, the regulations concerning the public railways corporation (ÖBB), the effective organization of public auditing, etc. The only way of solving such fundamental problems and departing from incrementalism is to put important allocative decisions in the public sector much more on the basis of economic reasoning. This requires, inter alia, setting reasonable priorities for the fulfilment of public purposes, that is, to set up a consistent plan of public projects in the short, medium and long run (GANTNER and EIBL 1991) in order to modify the inexpedient structure inherited from the past and preserved by incrementalism. Such an approach not only prevents measures such as proportionately cutting expenditures and/or resorting to purely short-run consolidation measures. It also opens up the opportunity of taking into account the business cycle situation. Recessions can be fought without hesitation if the short-run budgetary reactions are determined by the prevailing output gap. Stabilization policy would no longer be incompatible with budget consolidation policy as the reduction in the deficit would be secured by the long-run measures of saving resources in the public sector through increasing productivity and decreasing the relative price of collective goods provided by the state. 24 VI. SUMMARY OF RESULTS ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ Experience has shown that concrete coalition agreements on policy targets and measures are needed for conducting economic policy effectively. Such coalition agreements and governmental declarations (which are advisable even in cases of one-party governments) should not primarily refer to short-term budget consolidation targets but rather to long-term plans of reforming the public sector and thereby consolidating the budget efficiently (with regard to allocation and stabilization efficiency). This would render the proposed measure of prolonging governmental terms of office unnecessary, particularly since there is little empirical evidence for politico-strategic deficit spending before elections in Austria. In our concluding remarks we have suggested measures which appear to be straightforward or even trivial. Nonetheless, on the one hand, such points have to be made again and again because reality is still far from being optimal and does not even try to find second-best solutions. On the other hand we are aware of the fact that such suggestions can be easily made but that they are at the same time very difficult to realize. A lot of further research remains to be done in this direction.