CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 O 1988by The Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research. All rights reserved o o 1 1 - ~ ~ 0 ~ / 8 8 / ~ ~ o ~ - o o o ~ $ ~ . o o Rethinking Polygyny Co-Wives, Codes, and Cultural by Douglas R. White A new set of codes is offered to begin to unpack the dimensions of polygyny. Included are measures of frequency and statistical distributions of multiple wives, cultural rules, residential arrangements and kin relations among co-wives, male stratification, and marriage of captured women. Problems of coding and measurement are extensively illustrated. A series of hypotheses is supported regarding two types of polygyny: wealth-increasing and sororal. In the first, women's labor generates wealth and (if warfare allows) female captives are taken as secondary wives. Here polygyny stratifies males by wealth and most men are able to become polygynists with age. Residential autonomy of wives is an elaboration of this pattern. The second is marked by coresidence of husband and wives and dependence of the family mostly on resources generated by the husband. Here polygyny is usually dependent on the exceptional productivity of particular men such as hunters or shamans. The regional-historical adaptations of these types differ markedly. Neither fits the model of resource-defense polygyny found in other species. Explanations of polygyny, particularly of the first type, require close attention to resource and demographic flows within regional ecologies. The second type requires further functional and historical analysis. Both require more consideration of the way polygyny operates from the female point of view, a task only partially begun here. R. WHITE is Professor in the School of Social Sciences and the Program in Comparative Culture at the University of California, Irvine (Irvine, Calif. 92717, U.S.A.). and editor of the electronic journal World Cultures. Born in 1942, he was educated at the University of Minnesota (B.A., 1964; Ph.D., 1969)and taught at the University of Pittsburgh from 1967 to 1976. His publications include, with G. P. Murdock, "Standard Cross-cultural o~~ with Michael Burton and Lilyan Sample" ( ~ t h n o l 8:329-69); Brudner. "Entailment Theorv and Method: A Cross-cultural Analysis of the Sexual Division oi Labor" (Behavior Science Research I~:I-24);with Michael L. Burton and Malcolm M. Dow, "Sexual Division of Labor in African Agriculture: A Network Autocorrelation Analysis" (American Anthropologist 83:824-49); and, with Michael L. Burton, "Sexual Division of Labor in Agriculture" (American Anthropologist 86:568-83) and "Cross-cultural Surveys Today" (Annual Review of Anthropology 16:143-60) He is co-editor, with Linton C. Freeman and A. Kimball Romney, of Research Methods in Social Network Analysis (Chicago: NelsonPaul Publishers, in press) and the author of "The World Cultures Database" (Advances in Computer Archaeology 4 [Spring]:4-31). The present paper was submitted in h a 1 form 4 111 88. DOUGLAS I. The assembly of the research materials for coding the standard sample on polygyny and studies of the division of labor, female status, and world-system linkages were supported by NSF grants BNS #8023904, 8304782, and 8507685 to Douglas R. White and Michael L. Burton. John W. M. Whiting, Michael L. Burton, and Lilyan A. Brudner provided invaluable advice and extensive criticism, but any faults in coding decisions are mine alone. Polygyny presents a fascinating comparative problem that requires an examination of both cultural practices and historical and ecological features. An earlier paper (White and Burton 1988) examined ecological, economic, kinship, and warfare variables as factors affecting types and rates of polygyny. This one focuses on internal relationships in the organization of polygynous systems. From coded ethnographic data on systemic features of polygyny in the standard sample of 186 of the world's societies (Murdock and White 1969) and other crosscultural codes, three complexes of polygynous variables are identified. The theoretical goal is to interpret these complexes, begin to understand how they are differentially situated in historical and ecological context, and delineate the kinds of problems posed by the tendency to treat them under a common rubric (Boas 1896). For example, Darwinian evolutionary arguments have recently been advanced that link wealth to polygyny and polygyny to reproductive success. If modern evolutionary comparativists are to avoid treating polygyny as a unitary phenomenon, they will have to grapple with the various culturally and ecologically constituted systems of polygyny and the key parameters and world historical factors that constitute their systemic boundaries. The codes presented here are based on a rethinking of the comparative dimensions of polygyny as cultural practice. They reflect three shifts in the paradigm of cross-cultural research: an intention to make clear the problematics of working with multiple, complex ethnographic texts, where an array of models and theories at different levels can be constructed from the data; recognition of the need for more historically sensitive analysis; and an analytical goal of unpacking the comparative dimensions of phenomena in a way that allows them to be more closely linked with regional, ecological, and culture-historical contexts. With respect to the analysis of the historical context of polygyny, the goal of this paper is modest: it is not to perform such an analysis but to set the stage for one. Considering Polygyny in the Nexus of Multiple Systems One of the great advantages of ethnography over comparative research is that it makes it possible to see how practice is embedded in many parts of a local system. As comparative studies themselves begin to be richly layered, we can begin to see cultural practices as multiply embedded. This article is not an attempt to give a full account of all pertinent variables, but it does restore several critical dimensions to the comparative study of polygyny. It is important to distinguish at least three different aspects of polygyny. The first of these is its demographics-the rates of men and women married polygynously. For example, Whiting and Whiting (1975) have argued that, to the extent that married women are polygynous and living in separate quarters, a distinctive childrearing pattern is created whereby children tend to live 530 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 in a women's world somewhat set apart from that of the father. The percentage of polygynous married women will always exceed that of men in a society by at least 2 : I and sometimes more than zo : I. The percentages of married men and women who are polygynous vary independently to the degree that relative distributions for men classified by the number of their wives differ from case to case. Spencer (1980)proposes that the statistical distribution of men bv their numbers of wives indexes social differentiation among polygynists or elders (because older men usually have more wives), while the mean number of wives indexes the age bias or extent of gerontocracy that polygyny may bring about by creating a scarcity of dives for younger men. But there are many factors that might affect the demographics of polygyny, either indirectly through the adult sex ratio or directly through the relative proportions of adult males and adult females who are married (White and Burton 1988).Factors that affect the adult sex ratio include the natal sex ratio, relative malelfemale mortalities, relative rates of labor migration, and relative movement of men or women in or out of communities at puberty or marriage, including movements associated with bridewealth payments or capture of prisoners in war. Proportions of adult males and females married are affected by relative age at marriage, relative ease of divorce or remarriage, rates of bachelorhood or spinsterhood, and so forth. In order to distinguish the effects of these factors, it is helpful to have separate ethnographic codes on the relative frequencies of polygyny for married men and women.' Second, apart from a consideration of frequencies of polygyny, we need to distinguish which categories of men or women are polygynously married. Murdock (1949)noted that polygyny is associated with "moveable property or wealth which can be accumulated in quantity by men" (p. 206) and that within societies with surpluses it is the wealthier men who are more polygynous (p. 28); van den Berghe (1979) argues that surplus resources permit males to provide for multiple wives. These are instances of the common argument that polygyny is associated with rank or stratification among males. Marriage systems, however, contrast significantly on this dimension. Moreover, polygyny may also be associated with rank or stratification amonn females in competition for mates, as, for example, with the ranking among women characteristic of bridewealth systems (Ogbu 1978). Third, it is important to note how multiple wives are recruited (e.g., sororal or nonsororal) and how they are distributed residentially (e.g., in the same or separate habitations). Another aspect of the recruitment of cowives that has been neglected is the marriage of female captives and/or the adoption of girls captured in war and their subsequent marriage within the society. Equally important but not undertaken in the present study is examination of how recruitment of wives affects local and regional systems of alliance and exchange. Other major aspects of polygyny that require comparative treatment but cannot be addressed here are ( I ) stratification: frequency distributions of multiple wives for elites as opposed to commoners and prerogatives of rulers (see Betzig 1986); (z)rights and status: religious and legal codes as a source of restrictions on the number of wives; extent of widow inheritance and/or levirate as a source of secondary wives; types of ranking or differentiation among co-wives; legal status accorded to the second wife; marriage of concubines and status of children by different types of marriage; degree of formality of marriage; and bridewealth; (3)advantagesldisadvantages of polygyny and solidarity vs, competition among cowives: attitudes of women and of men towards polygyny (including that of parents towards a daughter's polygynous marriage); whether co-wives cooperate in a variety of tasks; degree, function, and impact of solidarity among co-wives; extent of jealousy among co-wives; whether the first wife often encourages a man to take a second wife or her permission is required or she helps to recruit kin or non-kin as wives; and so forth (a related topic, linked to reproduction, is the economic value of children in the household economy [Bradley 19871);and (4) reproductive aspects: fertility and family size (although good data are difficult to obtain); barrenness as a reason for taking a second wife; and confidence of paternal and veiling and claustration, recently reviewed by Dickemann (1981). Investigations of each of these factors need also to bear in mind questions about boundaries and regional distributions. Shifts in the Cross-cultural Paradigm u z. Some aspects of polygyny are particularly difficult to code or measure accurately in standard ethnographies or samples: fertility, for example, or even family size. Imbalance in the sex ratio is another factor that is difficult to code. Many ethnographers offer low sex ratios as an explanation for polygyny, but importation of wives from other communities automatically lowers the sex ratio. Combined with difficulty in determining birth years in nonliterate populations and settling on "adult status" definitions that are comparable for males and females, as well as in overcoming the tendency to overestimate ages of younger married women, it is nearly impossible to measure sex ratios independently of rates of polygyny. For similar reasons-lack of accurate censuses, difficulty in determining ages or cohort membership in a community, and possible absences through migration-it is difficult to measure the proportion of adult males who are unmarried. How one treats polygyny depends in part on how one sees the relations between cultural practice, history, and ecology. This is particularly evident in cross-cultural research, where the relations between these domains have been reexplored in each generation. The more one specifies the marriage system of a particular society in terms of features such as those listed above, the more the regional patterning of marriage systems becomes evident. This is an inevitable feature of the diffusion and ecological adaptation of particular patterns of social organization. In contrast, Murdock's coding of polygyny obscures marked differences in the upper ranges of frequency. The societies of sub-Saharan Africa, for example, are typically much higher in rates of polygyny than societies with "general polygyny" in the rest of the world. His monogamy/limited polygyny/>zo% po- w H I T E Rethinking Polygyny I 5 3 I y scale also obscures regional differences among @limited" types. Indeed, one of the salient motiva- tests for Galton's problem. This article (Murdock and White 1969) conclusively demonstrated to Murdock the tions for coding the additional features of polygyny pre- impossibility of avoiding historical effects in crosssented in this paper was to be able to test hypotheses cultural research. Sampling four domains of study (politabout the historical and ecological character of marriage ical structure, economy, language, social organization) systems. Such hypotheses have been offered in the spirit and applying a test for the effects of propinquity on of critique of functionalist theories ever since Boas's similarities between sample societies, we found that if (1896)critique of the comparative method. Among the one wanted a sample entirely free of historical or remany advances since his time is our ability to test his- gional similarities among sample cases, the spatial samtorical, ecological, and functional hypotheses simulta- d i n g interval would be at ~ . o o omiles or more and the neously (e.g., White, Burton, and Dow 1981, White and maximal sample size for statistically "independent" Burton 1988). cases between 10 and 20 cases, too small for work on Cross-cultural research from Tylor (1889)to Murdock multivariate ~roblems.In 1980, in his treatment of theo(1949) attempted to view cultural practices as autono- ries of illnesi, Murdock completed his first study commous at the level of society-independent, that is, of bining historical and macroregional with functional larger patterns of history and somewhat oblivious to the analysis. Murdock "converted," as it were, from the Tyinterdependent nature of larger ecological systems and lorian approach to cross-cultural studies to the type of to the complementarity of local and larger systems, as if combined historical-functional approach advocated by the societies sampled represented independent experi- Driver ( I95 6; Jorgensen I 974, White I 975). To cement ments bv means of which functional relations could be the gains in his perspective, Murdock in his late eighties identifieh. This approach is not entirely invalid but is went on to reconstruct his world sampling provinces and systematically biased towards a particular range of the- Atlas of World Cultures (1981) around greater cogniory and needs to be supplemented by analysis of local, zance of historical problems. In response to a query by regional, and world historical interdependencies. Hartung (1982:3),for example, Murdock judged his poMurdock's approach was to avoid historically related lygyny codes accurate but only a crude beginning in the clusters of societies by sampling at intervals of 200 miles cross-cultural treatment of the topic. A more integrated approach to the study of cultural in the absence of large-scale political systems. He treated large-scale societies such as China, Hindu India, practice, history, and ecology has been the focus of a or the European nations as "single" cases equivalent for series of papers by myself and Michael Burton on the sampling purposes to societies one-thousandth or one- sexual division of labor (Burton and White 1, 9 8 ~White. : millionth their size. Moreover, in his early work Mur- Burton, and Dow 1981).w e found a number of factors i i dock (1949) restricted the subject matter of cross- the intensification of agriculture that predicted a shift cultural research to avoid havine" to deal with the towards a greater contribution of male over female labor problems of historicity, regionality, and diffusion. He in nondomestic agricultural tasks. Although these preasserted that functional hypotheses could best be tested dictions were borne out in different world regions, two for those phenomena that were so often independently regional effects were observed: greater female participainvented that societies s a m ~ l e dat intervals of 200 miles tion than predicted in Bantu Africa and failure of populaor so could be assumed to 6e functionally independent. tion density to predict greater male participation, as in He maintained that features of social organization were Boserup's (1970)model, outside the Old World. One of sufficiently variable over these relatively short distances these papers examined polygyny in Africa as a possible to permit Galton's problem of the nonindependence of consequence of female agricultural participation, patcases to be safely ignored. But to make his approach rilocal residence, and the absence of a moralistic high work, he had to concentrate on the more abstract fea- god (White, Burton, and Dow 1981:840-46). Again, very tures of social organization, ignoring characteristics that strong regional clusterings of the exceptions were obshowed more obvious patterning over larger regions. served: less polygyny than predicted in North Africa, for The general distinctions about different types of polyg- example, and more than predicted in the African savanyny (common/limited, sororallnonsororal, separate1 nah. The cross-cultural research tradition that combines recommon residence of co-wives) that Murdock established in 1949 were carried fodard in his Atlas (1967) gional and historical with functional analysis is not new codes, but it was increasingly clear that these features as a general approach (e.g., Boas 1896, Driver 1956, exhibited large-scale regional clustering. His next set of Jorgensen 1980, Murdock 1980).While the specific concodes (Murdock and Wilson 1972) was less rather than tents of this approach will vary as advances are made in more specific, tending to obscure regional differences general anthropology as well as cross-cultural methods, it is a general approach that can play an integrative role rather than throwing them into relief. From 1969 forward, however, Murdock's work under- in the discipline. New perspectives that are currently went a transition in the opposite direction, towards rec- being absorbed into this approach have to do with ( I ) ognition first of the possibility and then of the impor- what we mean by historicity and historical interdepentance of treating historicity and regionality. The first is dencies, ( 2 )the importance and role of symbolic and beevident in our joint work of 1969, in which we in- lief systems in large-scale interconnected systems, (3) troduced both the standard sample and a set of stringent the possibilities of multilevel analysis of how local comA w 8 , 532 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 General polyandry Exclusive monogamy3 2a Polygyny permitted but incidence below 20% for married males3 zb Sororal polygyny permitted but incidence below 20% for married males 3a General polygyny, nonsororal or unspecified 3b General polygyny, with some preference for the Cross-cultural Research on Polygyny to Date sororal form 3c General polygyny, exclusively sororal The codes presented here for the standard sample are The three-point scale above for the frequency of polygoffered as a step towards a more comprehensive under- yny is retained in the World Ethnographic Sample standing of polygyny and related phenomena. It must be (Murdock 1957)~the Ethnographic Atlas (Murdock stressed, first, that the standard sample provides an early 1962, 1967)~ and the standard sample codes of Murhistoric baseline for comparative ethnographic study. dock and Wilson (1972): The societies in it represent each of 186 major world I Monogamy (no polygyny permitted or encultural provinces (Murdock and White 1969, Murdock ~ouraged)~ 1967).Most of them are pinpointed to the earliest date z Occasional or limited polygyny (less than 20% of at which a full ethnographic description is provided, married malesI3 whether by anthropologists, historians, envoys, travel3 Polygyny comkon or general (incidence 20% or ers, missionaries, teachers, or native texts. Further, each above) is pinpointed to a particular local group. In consequence, This is the classification of frequency of polygyny in the materials coded are not necessarily typical of the current use in cross-cultural studies. A supplement to larger ethnic units of which each pinpointed group is a the scheme by Whyte (1978)expands the monogamy-vs.part. These are not global descriptions of ethnic units limited-polygyny distinction into three types: monogbut highly specific accounts. The society chosen for each amy prescribed, monogamy preferred but with limited province is typically the one offering the fullest descrip- polygyny, and polygamy preferred but of low incidence. tive coverage. As for kin relations between co-wives, Murdock's While most of the societies in the standard s a m ~ l e 1949 typology (a, b, c in the first of the scales above) show the impact of the modern world system ( ~ b l f distinguishes nonsororal, preferentially sororal, and ex1982)~they are typical of the premodern period more clusively sororal. Exclusively nonsororal polygyny is not than of the contemporary horizon, in which some of distinguished (seeMurdock I 9 5 9 for ethnographic examthese groups are virtually extinct and nearly all the re- ples). His World Ethnographic Sample (1957)attenuates mainder are impacted by modem educational, religious, the distinction between preferred and exclusive sororal governmental, and economic institutions. polygyny, and his Ethnographic Atlas (1962, 1967) disAn advantage of taking early ethnographic accounts of penses with the distinction altogether. The Atlas treats polygyny is that such features as local warfare patterns form of marriage under the same code as form of family. can often be observed prior to Western colonial pacifica- In condensing the coding scheme, Murdock distintion. Intervening relationships between warfare and po- guishes kin relations among co-wives only for the case of lygyny may include the effects of male mortality in war- general polygyny (20% or greater).Dropped from the Atfare (Spencer 1876, Ember 1974)or the capture of women las codes is the distinction between sororal and nonand of plunder for bridewealth (Murdock 1949); con- sororal polygyny for the cases of limited polygyny. In the versely,~byincreasing the ratio of unmarried males, po- polygyny codes for the standard sample (Murdock and lygyny may fuel warfare and the capture of women Wilson 1972) the distinction between sororal and non(Whiting and Whiting I 975). sororal is abandoned. Polygyny has been coded several times for the stanBeginning with the Ethnographic Atlas, Murdock also dard sample: first by Murdock (1967) in his Ethno- distinguishes, in the case of general polygyny, whether graphic Atlas, by Murdock and Wilson (1972))by Whyte co-wives occupy the same or separate dwellings or apart(1978)for half the sample, and by Betzig (1986).The At- ments. There is a strong correlation between nonsororal las codes distinguish whether polygyny is sororal or general (nonsororal) and whether co-wives have separate habitations. These codes are less than satisfactory: in 3. "We shall classify a society as polygynous whenever the culture and public opinion encourages, a man to have more than Murdock's, for example, rates of polygyny are distin- permits, one wife at a time, whether such unions are common or comparaguished only as to whether the proportion of polygynous tively rare, confined to men of outstanding prestige or allowed to married men is less than or greater than 20%; Whyte anyone who can afford them." "The dividing line" between limited makes only one further distinction among types of "lim- and full polygyny "has been set arbitrarily at 20 per cent" (Murdock 1949:28). The same criteria are used by Murdock and Wilson ited" polygyny. (1972:261). Coder instructions for the latter study make it clear Murdock's codes follow a scheme that he established that the 20% refers to the percentage of married males with more in Social Structure (1949:28, 226) in defining a scale for than one wife. Murdock's Atlas (1962, 1967) presumably follows these same criteria. form of marriage: munities are embedded in and interact with larger systems, and, to some extent, (4)the new Darwinian evolutionism (where a great deal of debate and criticism by cultural anthropology is warranted). o I WHITE Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 33 rect association between the current number of wives and the likelihood of adding another. This distribution indeed predominates for Spencer's African sample, in 34 of his 50 societies. General polygyny under one roof (e.g., Bemba commoners), on the other hand, ought to fit the true binomial distribution, in which having successive wives lessens the likelihood of taking another-a model of conformity inhibiting further polygyny (additional wives perhaps, for example, experiencing increasing levels of discord).In Spencer's sample, seven cases fit the true binomial pattern. This distribution has an inverse association between the number of current wives and the likelihood of adding another. (Nine cases of his 50 societies fit the indeterminate Poisson model, in which neither tendency prevails.) Three pieces of information are important in assessing the different measures of polygyny extracted in analyses of frequency distributions (Spencer 1980). First, cases that fit the negative binomial poorly reveal discontinuities in the population from which the sample was drawn, which Spencer attributes to "a successful elite with a large number of wives and an underprivileged majority." Nine of the 34 societies in his sample that fit may have been invented and diffused as a concomithe negative binomial do so imperfectly; each shows evitant of the need for warriors, which in turn may be dence of elites1practicing polygyny at rates discontinurelated to the presence of a substantial capital invest- ously high compared with those for commoners. Second, ment that needs to be protected. If this assumption is Spencer regards the mean rate of polygyny, which varies correct, then the husband aloof pattern should occur independently of the shape and variance of the distribumore commonly among farmers and herdsmen than tion, as a measure of the imbalance in the distribution of among hunters, gatherers and fishermen since the for- wives between old and young. High mean rates of polygmer have more property to protect. yny generally index gerontocracy; generally older men In testing this hypothesis, they show that nearly all the have access to greater numbers of wives. One exception societies in which wives have separate habitations also is the Konso, who have age-grade marriage rules that have capital-intensive subsistence economies (i.e.,based limit polygyny for older men. Third, the variance in the on herding, horticulture, or agriculture), although only rate of polygyny and the shape of the distribution are about half of the latter have the separate-habitations pat- linked. If the ratio of variance and mean is greater than tern. one, the shape of the distribution approximates the Codes on separate habitations for wives are given by gamma function or negative binomial; if less than one, it Whiting and Whiting (197s). Hartung (1982) has pub- approaches the true binomial. As the ratio of variance to lished Whiting and Whiting et al.'s 1964 codes on the mean approaches one, the shape of the distribution apfrequency of polygyny for married women. Their soci- proaches Poisson. The ratio indexes degree of social difeties overlap with the standard sample but often are ferentiation among polygynists or elders. Betzig (1986)codes maximum harem size, at the high coded for a different focal date or unit. The original Whiting codes on polygyny also included frequency of end of the scale of social differentiation among polygypolygyny for married men, ethnographic dates, and esti- nists, for 106 societies in the standard sample that are politically autonomous or have de facto autonomy as an mates of data aualitv. For African societies, Spencer (1980) compares coded unadministered unit within an area subject theoretically ethnographic data on the relative proportions of married to alien (e.g., colonial) sovereignty. Her interest is in men with one, two, three, four, or more wives. He fits testing the Darwinian evolutionary hypothesis that the statistical distribution of polygyny (i.e.,frequency of power (specifically despotic rule) is exploited in the inmales by number of wives) to one of two statistical mod- terest of male reproductive success. Maximum harem els that differ in whether the likelihood that a man will size includes concubines and wives for the individual at acquire another wife varies directly or inversely with the the head of the social hierarchy or, in the absence of number of his current wives. If having extra wives is hierarchy, for the most polygynous man. In most of the world, accurate polygyny censuses are connected to the ability of wives to generate wealth, the African compound pattern ought to be associated with unavailable even for the comparatively well-described the negative binomial distribution, in which having societies in the standard sample. A world sample cannot wives begets having more wives-a competitive model hope to emulate Spencer's (1980)study for Africa, where whereby polygynous success breeds further success. In such censuses are frequently available. Better measures the negative binomial or gamma function there is a di- of the extent and features of polygyny can be provided, polygyny and occupancy of different apartments by cowives. In traditional Africa, separate habitation for wives is associated with the polygynous compound and separate apartments for the husband. Whiting and Whiting (197s)approach the study of polygyny in terms of effects of socialization and family structure on gender identity. Polygynous compounds and separate habitations for wives, for example, promote separate spheres of activity for males and females. The Whitings identify a general pattern of "aloofness" between husband and wife, associated with young men's moving in with their fathers and brothers as they come to sexual maturity (Whiting and DIAndrade 1959) or moving off to bachelor, warrior, or age-mate organizations (e.g., Maasai age-groups). Separate habitation for wives "thus is conducive to the formation of 'fraternal interest groups' which have been shown by recent studies to be associated with feuding . . . [and] a high value placed on military glory, with hyperaggressive males" (Whiting and Whiting 197~:194).They further hypothesize that the custom of wives1residing in separate quarters 534 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 however, from the available ethnographic reports. The the polygyny variable to identify various sources of difWhiting and Whiting et al, codes (unpublished except for fering polygyny frequencies and allow a fresh look at the Hartung 1982)are useful in this respect but apply to less various polygyny "complexes" but also to address issues than one-third of the sample and require checking and of social rank and stratification, residential arrangerecoding to provide comparable pinpointing to the spe- ments, and mode of recruitment of wives. Separating these dimensions yields improved variables for more cific times and local groups of the standard sample. While separate habitation for wives is reliably coded comprehensive tests of theories about possible causes by the Whitings (1975)for the standard sample, a code is and consequences of various forms of polygyny. needed for separate habitation for the husband. Separate habitation for wives does not entail that the husband D E F I N I T I O N O F C O D E S will have his own apartments. Whereas in traditional Africa this is the case, in other parts of the world the Twenty items of information for each society are sumhusband resides primarily with one wife and visits the marized in as many columns in table 1. In the discussion of coding categories that follows, codes bear the cumulaothers or rotates among the wives. Existing polygyny codes do not provide data on rank or tive codebook numbers for standard-sample variables, as stratification among males, such as whether polygyny is published in World culture^.^ To the right of each codassociated with ( I ) class or rank that is ascribed or ing category is the number of societies in the sample achieved; ( 2 ) achieved wealth, with additional wives as coded for it. The first code typifies the cultural rules underlying source of wealth or additional wealth needed to support extra wives; (3) differential achieved status, including polygyny, with categories ordered along an implied dithat of exceptional hunter or cultivator, leader, chief, or mension of permissible frequencies of polygyny. The headman, shaman or medicine man, warrior who cap- code stems from debate with John W. M. Whiting over tures women in warfare or battle, and warrior who re- the predictability of rules vs, behavioral frequencies in explaining polygyny. These rules are coded from ethnogceives female captives as booty. raphers' descriptive generalizations. While they probably reflect social norms held by each society, the culNew Comparative Measures of Polygyny tural rules for polygyny (Categories 2-5) are often contingent rather than prescriptive. Polygyny can be approached in two complementary ways. One is to ferret out the differences in types of I . Cultural rules constraining the frequency of polygpolygyny and account for the regional differences. An- yny (860) other is to emphasize common features, such as overall . = Missing data 3 frequency of polygyny or features that recur widely in I = ~ o n o G m prescribed ~ (children or condifferent regions, in order to test models of worldwide cubines or mistresses, if any, do not inherit similarities or effects. The first strategy is employed 27 intestate] here. To facilitate worldwide comparisons, a modifica2 = ~ o n o ~ preferred a k ~ but exceptional cases tion of Murdock's polygyny scale is provided that is of polygyny 32 based on the cultural rules that constrain the frequency 3 = Polygyny limited to individual men with of polygyny, taking into account social norms and leadership attributes (chiefs, medicine men, stratification. Cultural rules governing polygyny are outstanding hunters, et a1.-often no more likely to be more stable and intelligible than polygyny than one such man per community) 45 frequencies, and a cultural-rule-based code is less likely 4 = Polygyny limited to men of a higher social than one employing arbitrary categories such as 20% or class (men of wealth, inherited rank, nobilmore polygyny to produce misleading similarities beity, etc.) 33 tween societies in different regions. Whereas Murdock's 5 = Polygyny prevalent and preferred by most three-point scale obscures major regional differences in men and ~racticedbv most men of sufficient the frequency levels of general polygyny, the five-point age or wealth to obtain wives. Thus ( a )older scale offered here is sensitive to regional variants in marmen usually have more wives, (b)polygyny riage systems. It thus enables researchers to test hypothis generally based on the accumulation of eses about culturally generated variations in polygyny wealth, and (c)extra wives are an economic on a worldwide basis without obliterating regional difasset in terms of labor. 46 ferences. Codes on normative vs. statistical aspects of polygyny might also allow testing of hypotheses about The second code is Murdock's (1949, 1967)three-point factors that have differential effects on polygyny rules or scale of polygyny, plus his category for polyandry, polygyny frequencies for a specific gender and bring us modified by the distinction between categories of limcloser to testing the notion, complementary to the view ited polygyny (Categoriesz and 3) used by Whyte (1978). that rules generate behavior, that cultural rules may also be viewed as the culturally negotiated outcomes of be- 4. World Cultures is an electronic journal of cross-cultural studies havioral interactions and proclivities. published quarterly on diskettes for MS-DOS and Macintosh miIn sum, these codes are intended not only to "unpack" crocomputers and in other selected formats (see CA 27:83-84). w H I T E Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 3 5 TABLE I Coded Data on Forms and Frequencies of Polygyny Men by Number of Wives Society Nama z Kung 3 Thonga' 4 Lozi 5 Mbundu' 6 Suku 7 Bemba 8 Nyakyusa' 9 Hadza 10 Lugurn I I Kikuyu 12 Ganda' 13 Mbuti 14 Nkundo I 5 Banen 16 Tiv 17 Ibo 18 Fon 19 Ashanti 20 Mende 2 1 Wolof 22 Bambara 23 Tallensi' 24 Songhai' 25 Wodaabef 26 Hausa 27 Massa 28 Azande 29 Fur 30 Ot010 3I Shilluk 32 Mao 33 Kafa 34 Maasai 35 Konso' 36 Somali' 37 Amhara 38 Bogo 39 Nubians 40 Teda' 41 Tuareg' 42 Riffiansf 43 Egyptians' 44 Hebrews' 45 Babylonians 46 Rwala' I Focal Date I 2 34 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 1860 3 3 2 3 1 1 C P o o o 5 1 2 D C 1860 . I I 1 9 5 0 3 3 3 2 1 1 0 H 0 0 0 1 0 1 9 0 B 1952To4 1865 5 4 3 5 2 z C o L o C 4 0 6 6 o B 1895 . 6 o 1900 5 4 2 5 2 2 A o o o C 4 0 . o C . . 6 o 1890 5 4 2 5 I I C 0 L 0 C 2 7 4 5 0 B I 9 4 O N 3 I 1920 ( 5 4 2 5 2 2 . o o o . 27 41 B A <1945 N 6 o 1897 3 3 3 3 1 1 A o L o C z 7 ? A 1897 T I I 1 9 3 4 5 4 3 5 z z C o L o o 4 4 7 o B A 1934 . 6 0 1 9 3 0 2 2 2 4 1 1 0 o o o o 6 1 2 0 A 193oT 0 1 1925 3 3 2 5 2 2 . o L o . . . . . . . 6 o 1 9 2 0 ( 5 4 2 5 2 2 . 0 0 0 C . 32 0 A 1935 . 6 o 1875 5 4 2 5 z z C o L o C 5 5 8 o o B 1 8 7 5 N 6 0 1950 3 3 2 4 1 1 o H o o o 6 1 2 B A 1955 N o I I930 15 4 2 3 2 I . . . . . . . . . . . 4 0 1935 15 4 2 5 2 2 . . . . . . . . . . . 6 o 1 g 2 0 ( ~ 4 2 ~ 2 2 0 0 0 0 C 2 0 ~1 29 40 9~N 6 0 1935542522Co o o C2446o A . . 6 0 1890 5 4 2 5 2 2 . o L o C . . . . . . 6 o 1 8 9 5 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o o o C 4 9 7 2 o A 1945N6o 1945 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o L o C g o 9 7 o A 1945 N 6 o 1 9 5 0 ( 5 4 2 5 2 2 . o o o C 3 9 6 1 o A 1948 . 6 o 1902 [s 4 2 5 2 2 . . . . . . . . . . . 6 o 1 9 3 4 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o o o C 4 0 6 2 o A 1934N6o 19402325110 0 0 0 C I 2 E C . . 0 1 1 9 5 1 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o o o C 3 5 5 4 o A 1953N6o 1 g o o 5 4 z 5 2 z o o o o C 4 0 5 9 o B 1949N 6 o 1910(542522. 0 0 0 C . . . . . . 6 o 1905 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o L o C 3 2 5 7 ? B 1954 . 6 o 188oj332522. . . . C . . . . . . 6 o 193054252zCo L o C6077B A . N 6 0 1910(543321CoooC2337BA . . 4 0 1 9 3 9 4 . 2 3 I I C . . . . 5IOE E . . I I 1905 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o L o C . . . . . N 6 o 1900 5 4 2 5 2 2 C o o o C ~ I o ~ A I 1935 N 6 o 1935 3 3 2 6 2 2 C o o o o 1 0 2 4 o A 1965 . 5 o 1 9 o o 5 4 2 4 1 1 C P o o o 4 3 6 5 o A 1955N31 1 9 ~ 3 I I I I I I O O0 0 0 0 0 0 . . . 0 1 1855j322.11Co L o o . . . . . . I I 1 g o o j 3 3 2 5 2 2 . . . o . . . . . 1900 . 6 o 1 9 5 0 4 3 2 4 1 1 C o L o C 1 0 2 2 0 C 1g3oN 2 I 1 9 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 o o C o o o A 1940. 0 1 1926 4 3 2 2 1 1 C 0 L 0 0 1 1 2 5 0 A 1926 T I 2 195022 . . . . 0 0 0 0 0 3 7 O A 1 9 3 7 T . O 621 5 4 2 2 1 1 C o L o C . . . . . . 3 2 I750 2 2 . . 1 1 . 0 0 0 c . . . . -1750 . I I 1913(542321. . . o o . . . . . . 4 0 20 I 79 2 3 4 56 7 Comments 9 wives; a few chiefs many wives '50% men 1-2 27 9 0 80 14 5 33 I 1 I 1958 est. jest.) up to 8 wives: commoners 57 4 low rate of polygyny 33 o I 702461 jest.] 2-3 for many commoners 712361 2 8 6 4 0 0 7 6730671 12755 ?? ?? 912 53 mostly I or 2 3143105201 2, 3 + wives; king 9 in separate houses 5928 8 4 1 1 7237126 slaves not married 90 7 3 7 97 jest.] some men 2-3 wives 3 3 extensive; slaves not married NOTE: j indicates uncertainty in coding; dot indicates absence of information; indicates anomalous cases or details (sources identified in table 21, as follows: 3 Thonga, r r : capture of women in war, killing of men ([1'27]runod'62:g1z). 5 Mbundu, 5. 6: only spirit hut for man. 8 Nyakyusa, I : higher rates of polygyny after Pax Britannica due to breakup of girls' houses, earlier age at marriage for boys and girls, less age difference at marriage, and greater number of cattle for bridewealth; 3, 4: sororal and wife's brother's daughter polygyny preferred but unclear as to whether it is numerically predominant. 12 Ganda, I , 1 7 : king has hundreds of wives, petty chief ten or more, many peasants have two, three, or more but often can afford bride price for only one ([b]Murdock'34:~40); in 1931 62% of households were mother-child j[1~]Southwold'6~); 1 1 : wage war chiefly for captives and plunder ([b]Murdock'34:534-35). 23 Tallensi, r r : marriage of captured women but no plunder. 24 Songhai, 5, 6 : compound pattern, co-wives live apart, but low rate of polygyny. 25 Wodaabe, I : disfavored by women but tolerated because of long postpartum sex taboo. 35 Konso, I : age-grades function to prevent older men from monopolizing wives. 36 Somali, I : considerably higher rates of polygyny among Dolbahanta pastoralists than among neighboring more agricultural Somali; 8 : second wife often takes herds to southern pastures, so it is not male skill per se in pastoralism that supports polygyny. 40 Teda: wives very independent and usually dominate their households. 41 Tuareg: monogamy a strong part of original Berber culture in spite of Islamic overlay; female slaves as concubines. 42 Riffians: monogamy a strong part of original Berber culture in spite of Islamic overlay; polygyny results from preferential levirate. 43 Egyptians, I : strong decline of polygyny since 1920. 44 Hebrews, I : counting concubines, whose children are legitimate. 46 Rwala, 5, 6 : husband and wife room apart (Whiting and Whiting 1975:191]. + 536 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY TABLE I Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 (continued) Men by Number of Wives Focal Date Society 47 Turks 48 Gheg' 49 Romans' 5 o Basques 51 Irish 5 2 Lapps 5 3 Samoyed 54 Russians 5 5 Abkhaz 5 6 Armenians 5 7 Kurd' 58 Basseri' 59 Punjabi 60 Gond' 61 Toda 62 Santal 63 Uttar Pradesh' 64 Burusho 65 Kazak 66 Khalka 67 Lo10 68 Lepcha 69 Garo' 70 Lakher 71 Burmese 72 Lamet 73 Vietnamese 74 Rhade 75 Khmer' 76 Thai' 77 Semang 78 Nicobarese 79 Andamanese 80 Vedda 81 Tanala' 82 Negri Sembilan' 83 ravanese 84 Balinese 85 Iban 86 Badjau' 87 Toradja 88 Tobelorese 89 Alorese 90 Tiwi' 91 Aranda 92 Orokaiva 93 Kimam' 94 Kapauku' 95 Kwoma 96 Manus' - - - I 2 34 5 6 7 8 9 10 I I 12 13 14 15 19502222110 o o o o 3 6 0 A 1 9 1 0 1 5 4 2 2 2 2 . . . 0 0 2441 0 A I I O I I I I I I O O 0 0 0 0 O O A 1 9 3 4 I I I I I I O O 0 0 0 0 O O A I932 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 A I ~ ~ O 1 1 1 I I I O0 O0 0 0 O O A 1 8 9 4 2 2 . . 1 1 . . . . 0 o o o A 1955 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 o o o o o 0 0 A 1880 3 3 . . I I . . . . . . . . . 1843 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 o o o o o 0 0 A 1951332211Coo o o 4 7 B C 1 9 5 8 4 3 2 2 1 1 C o L . 0 713 0 B I 9 ~ 0 I I I I I I O0 0 0 0 0 0 0 A 1938 . 4 3 2 2 2 . . . . . . . . . 1900 2 0 1 0 1 1 o o o o o I I o A 19402222110 0 0 0 0 2 4 E C 1945 2 3 . 5 2 2 . . . . 0 . . . . 1 9 3 4 2 . 2 2 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 . . . . 1 8 8 5 4 3 2 2 1 1 C o o o o I O I ~ BC 1920 1 1 1 1 1 1 o o o o o o 0 0 . 1910422311CoL o C 3 5 E C 1937 2 2 3 2 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 2135 0 B 1955 4 2 3 2 I I C 0 0 0 0 9 1 7 0 B 1 9 3 0 2 2 . . 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 . . . . 1965 I I I I I I O o o o o o o E C 1940 (2 2 . . I I 0 . 0 . . . . . . 1930 3 3 2 3 I I c 0 L 0 . . . . . 1962 (2 . . . I I C . . . . . . . . 1292 4 3 . . . . A o L o o . . . . 195523.411Co o o o I 2 E A 1925 2 2 2 4 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 I 2 0 c 1870 12 . . . I I . . . . . 0 0 0 C 18601111110 o o o o o o o A 1860 I I I I I I o o o o o o o o . 1925 5 4 2 3 2 I c 0 0 0 . 3152 ? c 1 9 5 8 4 3 2 . 2 2 B o L . . IS? E 1 9 5 4 3 3 . . I I C O O O 0 2 4 0 A 1 9 5 8 4 3 2 . 1 1 A o L o o 1835 o B 1 9 ~ 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 00 0 0 0 0 0 0 A 1 9 6 3 1 1 . . 1 1 o o o o o o o o B 1910332411c0 L . c . . . . 1900 1 1 1 1 1 1 o o o o o o 0 0 . 1938442321C o o o 027440 A 1929 5 4 2 2 I I C 0 L 0 C 7 0 9 0 0 B 1896 5 4 3 2 1 1 C o L o C 6 0 7 8 o B 1925432311Co o o C 51oE C 1 9 6 0 2 3 2 . 1 1 0 C O M o 153oB B 1955 5 4 2 2 2 2 C 0 L 0 0 3150 0 B 1960542211Coo o o3859CB 19372222110 0 0 0 N 2 4 B C --- - - - - -- 16 17181920 I 2 3 4567 Comments at one time chiefs in older times 10, 11, 12 wives plentiful uncommon, rarely >2 - 48 Gheg, 5. 6: husband and wife room apart [Whiting and Whiting 1975:191). 49 Romans, I: while the nobles were monogamous among themselves, slave concubinage (and likely manumission of children) was very extensive. 57 Kurd, 7: extremely wealthy only, chiefs in older times. 58 Basseri, 7: wealthy herd owners, with additional labor needs, frequently have plural wives who "extend a man's fecundity in a way that saps his wealth" [[a]Barth'61:107). 60 Gond, 5, 6: wife aloof [Whiting and Whiting 1975:187),although Murdock 11967)indicates co-wives live together. 63 Uttar Pradesh, 6: men's quarters (Whiting and Whiting 1975:187). 69 Garo, 4: some widowldaughter marriage by wealthy men; also widowed mother-in-lawnominally not sexually a wife. 75 Khmer, I: king had 5 principal wives, over 500 concubines, nobility also many concubines; 11: slaves taken in war but despised and neither married nor taken into concubinage; concubines evidently given by lesser families to nobility. 76 Thai, 5: different house, sometimes in same compound. 81 Tanala, 6: husband rotates among wives' houses. 82 Negri Sembilan: I, 7: uncorroborated statement that different ranks of leaders are allowed four, three, and two wives respectively; monogamy predominates; 5, 6: a married man lives not with wife but with family of orientation and visits wife. 86 Badjau: limited by small size of boats as living quarters. 90 Tiwi, I: males start to take first and second wives only in their late thirties. 93 Kimam, I: polygyny always rare because of sister exchange and male gardening and obligations to wife's brother whereby extra wives drain rather than contribute to subsistence production; also considerable outlet for extramarital sex; rate may also have declined with missions and government administration. 94 Kapauku, 6: common male dormitory within the house (heie). 96 Manus, 11: captured women used as prostitutes [[l]Mead'30:118, 172, 177). WHITE TABLE I Rethinking Polygyny 1 537 (continued) Men by Number of Wives Society 97 Lesu' 98Trobrianders' 99 Siuai' IOO Tikopia IOI Pentecost' 102 Mbau Fijians 103 Ajie 104 Maori 105 Marquesans' 106 Samoans' 107 Gilbertese 108 Jaluit 109 Tmkese' I I O Yapese' I I I Palauans' 112 h g a o ' I I 3 Atayal I 14 Chekiang I I 5 Manchu I 16 Koreans' I 17 Japanese 118 Ainu' 119 Gilyak' 120 Yukaghir 121 Chukchee' 122 Ingalik 123 Aleut . 124CopperEskimo 125 Montagnais 126 Micmac 127 Saulteaux I 2 8 Slave 129 Kaska' 130 Eyak' I 3I Haida I 32 Bellacoola I 33 Twana' Focal Date I 2 34 56 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 1 9 3 0 4 3 z 3 z 2 . o L o o 1 z z 1 o A 1 9 z g T . o 1 9 1 4 3 3 2 5 2 1 C o L M o 3 3 9 o B 1914. . o 1 9 3 9 3 3 z 3 1 1 C o L o N 1 4 2 8 o B 1948N21 1 9 3 0 4 3 2 3 I I A O L o o 5 7 D B 1929. 0 1 1953 4 3 3 3 z 2 C o o o . 12 30 o C 1953 N 5 o 184033 . . . . A o L o C I 3 E C . . o . 1845 . . . . 2 2 . . . . . . . . . . . 5 o 1820 3 4 3 2 1 1 A o L o C I 5 o A . T o 3 1 8 o o z o z z 1 1 C o o o o o o o A 1920. 1 2 1 8 2 9 3 3 3 2 1 1 A o L o C o O O A 1829. 0 3 . . 0 3 1890324 . . . B o L o C I z E C 1 g 0 0 [ 4 3 2 5 1 1 A o L o . . . . . 1900. 1 1 1947 2 2 . 3 3 1 1 o o L o o o o o A 1950 . o 3 1 9 1 0 3 . . . 1 1 . O L O C ~ I O ?C 1 9 4 9 . 1 1 1 9 4 7 4 2 2 3 1 1 C o L o o 1 2 E C 1947. I I 1 g 1 0 2 2 2 3 1 1 C 0 o o o 2 4 E C 1910. I I 1 9 3 0 I I I I I I O O 0 0 0 0 0 0 A 1930. 0 1 1 9 3 6 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 o o o o o o A 1936. 0 1 1915 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 . . . 0 1 1 9 4 7 1 1 z z 1 1 o o o o o o o E A 1947. 0 2 I ~ ~ O I I I I I I O0 0 o o o O O A 1950. 0 1 1880322311CoL o C I 2 0 C . . I I 1890334.11CH. . C I 3 0 C . N z 5 1 8 5 0 2 2 2 3 1 1 o H o M C I 2 E C 1850. 0 1 1900 4 3 2 3 2 1 . H o o . 3349 C C 1890 . I o 188533zz11CHo o C 4 8 E C . T 1 2 18oo332211CHL o C . . . . . . 1 2 1915 2 2 2 2 I I o H o o o 5 10 B C 1915 . o z 1910 [z 2 . . . . C . . . o . . . . . . I . 1650 3 . . . I I C H . . . . . . . . . I 4 1 9 3 0 3 2 2 2 1 1 0 o L M o 2 4 E C 1930. 0 2 1 g 4 0 3 2 . . 1 1 o H o M o 2 4 E C 1940. 0 4 1 9 0 0 3 3 4 2 1 1 o H o o C 2 4 E A 1900. 0 5 18903422110HL o o . . . . . . 0 2 1875 4 3 3 2 1 1 B o L o C . . . . . . o 3 18804.2211B. . . . 5 1 o E . . . 0 2 1860433z11B o o M N 2 5 . . . . . 0 3 20 I 2 Comments 3 4 56 7 8812 21026 701 70 4 3 2 I 99 z jest.) jest.) rare 300 3 0 1 two wives only some over 3 wives might have 2-3 wives 97 Lesu: the 1929 situation reflects European influence of declining polygynyi many middle-aged polygynists have given up one wife to become monogamous; I: five formerly; 5, 6: men's house for married men [Whiting and Whiting et al. unpublished 1964 data), but it is unclear if they sleep there; have assumed they do since Whiting and Whiting 11975) code as rooming apart; 12: 60% formerly; 13: 70% formerly. 98 Trobrianders, 6, 7: two [rooming apart) for chiefsi 39% of females between ages 15-45 polygynously married to chiefs 13% of married men); monogynists room together (Whiting and Whiting 1975). 99 Siuai, 5, 6: husband rotates among wives with great difficulty, over many objections of wivesi 11: captured women used as prostitutes. I O I Pentecost: polygyny in marked decline with European influence; 90% of older men polygynous, frequency diminishing from nine to two wivesi considerable number of bachelors waiting to amass bridewealth. 105 Marquesans: pekio [male secondary husbands) numerous in chiefs' households and common in all families; female pekio very rare even in chiefs' householdsi men greatly outnumbered women; purpose of pekio was to obtain assistance in work. 106 Samoans, 4: wife's brothers' daughters brought as concubines of chief; 5: separate mosquito nets in open household act as separate bedrooms. 109 Tmkese I, 4: polygyny [rare)the result of customary remarriage of widow, resulting in mother and daughter married to same man. I I O Yapese, I: polygyny rare by 1949, 39 years after pinpoint date; 11: bachelors capture mistresses for their bachelors' house, pay fines to captured girl's kin group, polyandrous concubinage, with marriage to one of the bachelors resulting from pregnancy ([1o]Fumess'10:36-~~). 111 Palauans, I, 7: polygyny traditionally a right of rank, e.g., a chief was expected to have at least four wives from different locations to reflect rank and wealth; rare by 1947; for earlier date would code 7 as B. 112 Ifugao, 7: wealthy force polygyny or concubinage [with commoners) against social norms, "make it legal" by paying a substantial fine to the first wife's family. 116 Koreans, I: concubines occasionally, in separate room but same house; legally only one wife. 118 Ainu, I: concubines from warfare occasionally, in separate hut; legally only one wife; not uncommon to bring //small wives" to trading posts. 119 Gilyak, 7, 8: wealthy fur tradersltrappers several wivesi 11: female captives and children incorporated into clan of the conqueror, long-distance romantic intrigue, abductions, conflict over women important to warfare and revenge skirmishes. 121 Chukchee, 5, 6: sometimes separate house in community for second wife; among wealthy with two or more herds, sometimes a different wife living at each herd sitei probably 30% of married women living apart. I29 Kaska, I: "no limit to the number of wives so long as you can support them, but of late years . . . there are very few with more than one wife" [[c]P. Field MS'I 3Ii poor hunters polyandrous, must team up with another mani 4, 8: "even a widower had trouble securing permission to many a woman other than the deceased wife's sister, parents-in-law showing particular possessiveness about a man renowned as a hunter. To bring an unrelated 8: good hunters and woman into the family constituted a signal for the first wife to quit her husband and go home" [[6]Honigmann154:~32-33)i (salmon)fishermen polygynous. 130 Eyak, I: an old or barren wife was not divorced; the husband would take a young wife and the old woman would live with them and do the hard work. 133 Twana, 7: upper-class status involves manipulation of rank, wealth, personality; much more frequently polygynousi 10: shamans often upper-class, thus infer polygyny; however, with the new Shaker religion, //theother Indians did not believe such a one [with two wives] to be a fit leader in religion" [[c]E1ls'8~:436Ji 11: slaves taken in war stigmatized and not married. 538 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY TABLE I Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 (continued) Men by Number of Wives Society 134 Yurok' 135 Pomo' 136 Yokuts 137 Wadadika I 38 Klamath I 39 Kutenai 140 Gros Ventre 141 Hidatsa* 142 Pawnee' 143 Omaha' 144 Huron 145 Creek' 146 Natchez* 147 Comanche' 148 Chiricahua* 149 Zuni I 50 Havasupai I 5 I Papago I 5 2 Huichol* 153 Aztec* I 54 Popoluca I 5 5 Quiche 156 Miskito* I 5 7 Bribri* 158 Cuna 159 Goajiro' 160 Haitians' 16 I Callinago' 162 Warrau 163 Yanomamo* 164 Carib' 165 Saramacca' Focal Date I 2 34 56 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 1 8 5 0 2 2 4 . 2 . B o o o o 4 8 0 1850 2 2 3 2 2 2 o o o o o 2 4 o 1850 2 3 2 4 1 1 o o o o o 5 1 0 o 1870333211Co o M o 1 5 2 7 B 1 8 6 0 1 4 3 3 2 1 1 B . . . . 2035 o 1890 2 2 2 . I I . . . . . 1019 o 1880 5 4 3 2 1 1 c H L o ' 2 4 0 6 0 ! 1836543211CHo o Cgo97E 1867544211CHL ON54700 1 8 6 0 4 4 4 2 1 1 C H o o C3555 ? 163411111100 o o o o 0 0 1800 4 3 3 4 . . C o o o N . . . 1718443211Ao L o C . . . 1870 5 4 3 2 1 1 . o o M C . . . 1 8 7 0 4 4 4 2 1 1 C H o o o 18300 188011111100 o o o o 0 0 1918 3 3 2 2 1 1 C o o o C I O I ~ 1 9 1 0 4 4 3 2 1 1 C o L M o 2 7 4 9 0 1890322211Co L M o . . . I5203322IICO L 0 C . . . I940[4432II. 0 0 0 0 . . . 1 9 3 0 I I I I I I . 0 0 0 0 . . . 19213332110 o L M N 2 4 E 1917332.11COL 0 0 S I O ? 1 9 2 7 2 2 3 . I I O O L O 0 I 2 B 1947 5 4 2 5 2 2 C 0 L 0 0 4 0 9 0 ? 1935 5 4 2 4 1 1 0 0 O M O 2 5 . ! 1650 4 4 2 6 2 2 C o L o C 3 0 6 0 ? 1935 5 4 3 2 1 1 C o L M . 6 0 9 5 ! 1965 5 4 3 3 2 1 o H L o C 3 8 5 6 o I932 3 2 3 2 1 1 0 0 0 0 N 2 0 3 7 0 1928 5 4 2 4 2 1 C o o o o 6 0 8 5 ? C C C C C C C C B A . . . . C A O B B . . . . C c C E C E E B B C 16 17 18 19 1850 . o 3 1850 . . 3 1850 . o I 1890 T I 3 . . 0 3 I940 . I I 1880 . 3 4 1836 T 3 4 1867 . 3 5 1860 T I 5 1634 . o I . . I . 0 3 1870 N 3 3 1870 . I 5 1910 . o I 1928 . I 2 1870 . I 3 20 I II 2 2 higher in 18go! 10 50 30 6 3 65 30 5 90 10 ? ? 60 22 1 2 4 2 . I 2 . I 2 . I 3 . . I 1 1921 . o 3 0 I935 T 0 . . , I I [est.) jest.) extreme ease of divorce jest.) jest.) I 5-20% marriages most old men 2-4 wives . . . 1917 . I940 . Comments 3 4 5 6 7 upper class, some commoners "common" I 3 6 o I . 5 0 . 3 3 . 4 4 I932 . 0 3 1928 N 4 o up to 20 wives 75 22 3 40 30 20 8 jest.) 2 not common jest.] 134 Yurok, 11: debt slaves only, not captured in warfare or married; 6: husband and wife room apart [Whiting and Whiting 1975:191). 135 Pomo, 6: husband and wife room apart [Whiting and Whiting 1975:191). 141 Hidatsa: monogamy rare; sex ratio 1:2. 142 Pawnee, I : polyandry also common: girls marry older man, then one closer to own age [[14]Weltfish'65:464n)iboy becomes second husband to wife's brother's wife; younger brother is given sexual access to elder brother's wife if he resides with them and there is a close bond between the brothers [not a definite regular practice); greatest number of wives eight [four sisters in two families); 4, 7, 8 : where occasional nonsororal polygyny, man must make labor contribution to each of the separate wives' householdsi 4, 9: chief or great/successful warrior occasionally married more than one wife who were not sisters [otherwise exclusively sororal); 11: captive girls sought for sacrifice, not taken as wives. I43 Omaha, 11: captives sent home after peace, although they could remain voluntarily and be married. 145 Creek, 11: captives adopted but not taken directly as wivesi principal wife usually does not allow polygyny, men must go to great lengths to get her approval. 146 Natchez, 11: captives replace the slain through adoption, then marriage. 147 Comanche, 4: strong hostility among co-wives where nonsororal. 148 Chiricahua, 4: second wife often a suggestion of first; j : same house for defense in war, different house in peacetime. 152 Huichol, I : Zingg reports concubines of officials, elders, and shamans as "new," contrasting with the morality of earlier days, and argues that this could not have been overlooked by Lumholtz, who reported that "a man who wants to become a shaman must be faithful to his wife for five years"; polygynous concubinage pattern probably older, however. 15 3 Aztec, 11: concubines. 156 Miskito, 5: different hearths, not different housesi 11: prisoners sold as slaves to whites, not taken as wives. 157 Bribri, I : heavy influx of cattle since 1914 altering social structurei 11: warfare for captives and sacrifice, unclear whether women married. 159 Goajiro, J: unlike African compound, houses are temporary lean-tos; 11: prisoners of war not married. 160 Haitians, I : no multiple wives or concubines now 11935)kept in town but are kept in separate houses outside of Mirabalais; polygyny openly practiced in the hinterlands. 161 Callinago, I : fathers presented their daughters to successful warriors after each raid, and the captors would also marry the women they had taken captive; 5 : each wife lived in a separate hut in her own village, often on a different island; 6 : men's house, otherwise residence matrilocal, except for the chief. 163 Yanomamo, I : "norms which regulate a husband's obligations to his different wives . . . are relatively undeveloped" [[d]Shapiro172:~07); j : a man with more than one wife is likely to build and maintain a separate household for each, but not always [[c]Smole'76:189). 164 Carib, 11: male captives married to daughters of captors under a "son-in-law" institution; female captives, however, apparently not married, although it is not clear if they are resold as slaves. 165 Saramacca, I : extensive (50%) wage-labor emigration of men; scarcity of men, and girls marry early; well over half the women in their later years, widowed or divorced, are unable to remarry; j : the hypothesis suggested by the discussion of [e]Price184is separate houses where the woman is more dependent on the husband [i.e., wives competitive, as among the Saramacca) and same house where the man is more dependent on the wives [i.e., wives cooperative); 6: husband builds a separate house for himself and for each wife; 7: polygyny only for men of position [wealthier] reported by [lIHerskovits and HerskovitsJj4:~~g, but not wealth-increasing; women significantly more dependent on husbands than men are on wives [[e]Price184:78). WHITE TABLE I Rethinking Polygyny I 539 (continued) Men by Number of Wives Society 166 Mundurucu' 167 Cubeo* 168 Cayapa 169 Jivaro' 170 Amahuaca' 171 Inca* 172 Aymara* 173 Siriono 174 Nambicuara* 175 Tmmai' 176 Timbira* 177 Tupinamba' 178 Botocudo* 179 Shavante* 180 Aweikoma* I 8 I Cayua 182 Lengua 183 Abipon* 184 Mapuche* 185 Tehuelche 186 Yahgan Focal Date I z 34 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 18503322110 O L M C 7 1 5 193932..11. O L o . 3 6 ? 1908 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 o o o o o o o 1920 5 4 2 2 2 2 o o L o C 5090 C 1960 5 4 3 3 1 1 o H o o o 5070 ? 1 5 3 0 4 3 2 2 I I C C L O C I O 2 7 B 1940 I I I I I I A O o o o o 0 0 1942 13 4 3 2 I I . . . . . I I 38 o 194043321IBHLM03155 0 1938334211CoLMo12220 1915 1 1 3 1 1 1 0 o o o o o 0 0 I ~ S O ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ I B O ? 1884343z11oHLMo3355? 1958 5 4 3 2 I I C o L o . 24 49 o I932 3 4 2 2 1 1 0 H 0 0 0 3 0 5 0 0 1890 (3 2 . . I I . . . . 0 . . . 18893323110 o L M C 3 6 ? 17504324IICOL O N 5 I O ? 1950 4 3 2 3 2 1 C o L M o 6 1 0 o 1870 2 3 . . I I . . . . . I z E 186522421100 o o o ~ I o ~c C A C C A A B B B A EL B A B . 16 A C E C 20 I 2 . . I 1895 . o men of rank I I no mention only few old chiefs 4 wives 1946 N 5 o . . 3 4 . . I 1940. o 1941 . o 1939 . 1 1939T 1 1929. 0 IMS S C O N~4 1939T 0 1958 T 3 . T 0 . . . . 1750. 1948 . 1849 N . Comments 3 4 56 7 1850. o z E E 17 18 19 2 I monogamy now 3 4 5 8 I 1 IO 4 3 2 I I 0 1 I I z I z I . 0 3 ~ 67 O 15 8 5 3 13 5 I 104 31 13 7 3 I I man:14 lest.) lest.) up to 3 wives 300 o o I 166 Mundurucu, 4: younger wives sometimes solicited voluntarily by elder wife; 5, 6: men's house slept in by unmarried men only in 1850, but 11 presume following the shift from patrilocal to matrilocal residence that was associated with the rise of rubber trade in the 19th century) all men use it as residence by 1950; 7: no social class ranking-individual leadership rolesi 9: polygynous chiefs exempt from matrilocality, more patrilocal, but polygyny increasingly resisted by potential wives; 10: shamanic polygyny inferred from "men of rank polygynous" and "each communal house has its house chief and shaman." 167 Cubeo, 11: warfare waged for revenge or to capture women and children as slaves, unclear whether taken as wives. 169 Jivaro, 6: husbands and wives sleep at opposite ends of longhouse. I70 Amahuaca, 5: mostly sororal or leviratic polygyny with common habitation likely (Whiting and Whiting [1975]and Murdock [1967]agree), but one case of nonsororal polygyny mentioned ([h]Huxley& CapaJ64:39)with separate huts for wives, placed end to end. I71 Inca, I: commoners monogamous with rare exceptions; rulers have legitimate concubines (servants)in proportion to wealthi women distributed to war captains. 172 Aymara, I: nobility polygynous in former times. I74 Nambicuara, 9: chief, important men, and sorcerers polygynous; first wife tends house, others are younger and act as assistants to leader; deficiency of women from polygyny compensated by homosexuality between adolescent male cross-cousins. I75 Tmmai, I: less formal unions for second wives; not enough men to go around; polygyny must be approved by first wife, who often breaks up such an arrangement in the first few days; 11: mention of "plan to capture women" as sheer bravado, no actual evidence of capture of wives. 176 Timbira: polygyny ruled out due to strict matrilocality and no sororate. I77 Tupinamba, I: chiefs up to 30 wives, commoners may have several; j, 6: commoners initially matrilocal, often remaining so, with wives in different communitiesi chiefs and influential men establish patrilocality, wives inhabiting different quarters in longhouse; 11: female captives taken as secondary wives but unless they belonged to an influential man who became fond of them they were eventually ritually sacrificed. 178 Botocudo, 8, 9: common among chiefs, who require supernatural power, and highly energetic hunters; some up to 12 wives. 179 Shavante, I: customary for men to take second wives if they can; 7, 9: economic contributions of wives not needed for exercise of authority; 4: wives like the help co-wives provide. 180 Aweikoma, I: all marriages highly informal; often occurs with more isolated men. 183 Abipon, I, 4: first wife, when no longer young, often welcomes a companion to relieve her of part of the work; 11: female captives treated as slaves, Abipon refuse to marry them or take them as concubines, as they "lose caste" in the military societies by so doing. 184 Mapuche, I: once prevalent (through mid-19th century); declined with land scarcity [wives had their own garden plots), insufficient production to acquire bride price; polygyny remains a male ideal connected with ancestral worship: the more offspring, the more propitiation of the departed soul; 6: traditionally, husband and wife roomed apart in polygynous households: each wife had her own apartment and shared her husband's bed in turn; at focal time, however, it might appear that husband and one wife share apartments, second wife in separate apartments; husband and wife room apart I ~ 10:I polygyny ) ~ practiced by caciques, curers, men of wealth /[1o]Hilger'57);inspecting size of landholdings, [Whiting and Whiting I ~ ~ S ~7. 9, ([11]Faron'61)remarks that polygynists are poorer than others and that polygyny requires and depletes wealth. Discrepant ratings were recoded for consistency with the primary ethnography. 3 = Limited polygyny, < 20% of married males 54 4 = Full polygyny, 20% or more of married males 60 2. Standard polygamy code: Whyte, Murdock and Wilson, Murdock (861) . = Missing data 10 o = Polyandry z I = Monogamy prescribed 27 z = Monogamy preferred but exceptional cases of polygyny 33 The third code is the sororal/nonsororal distinction, adapted from Murdock (1949). Not all of the possibilities of drawing valid distinctions have been exploited here; there are sufficient data in ethnographies to code exclusively nonsororal polygyny (see Murdock 1959) and to distinguish a category of "sororal polygyny preferred but not predominant." 540 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 3. Recruitment of wife's kin as co-wives (sororal polygyny) (862) . = Missing data 24 I = No polygyny (M)5 25 2 = Most secondary marriages not to wife's kin (predominant nonsororal polygyny) (Atlas 93 3 = Secondary marriages to wife's kin (including sororal polygyny) strongly preferred or predominant (Atlas RS)5 35 4 = Nearly all secondary marriages to wife's kin (including exclusively sororal polygyny) 9 The fourth code, habitations for co-wives, is new. 4. Habitations for co-wives (863) . = Missing data 32 o = One wife, multiple husbands I I = One wife (Atlas M)5 25 2 = Coresidence for multiple wives (Atlas PR)' 59 3 = One wife resides with husband, others in 25 separate houseslrooms 4 = One wife resides with husband, others in 12 separate communities 5 = Separate housing in compound for every wife (Atlas QS)' 30 6 = Separate housing in village for every wife (as might occur, for example, with men's 2 houses, e.g., Otoro) The fifth code is Whiting and Whiting's (1975)wife'shabitation code and paraphrases their wording. Their intent was to indicate whether wives commonly (e.g., in 30% or more of the households where children were raised) roomed apart from their husbands. 5 . Habitations for wives vis-a-vis husband (864) . I Missing data 6 Wives share one room with husband, or less than 30% of married women are polygynous and the husband has no separate 130 bedroom = Husband in separate bedroom, hut, or men's house, or married women, if 30% or more are polygynous, have separate bedrooms for co-wives (e.g., 39% of Trobriand women as chief's wives) 50 = = The sixth code is new and clarifies the husband's habitation. 6. Habitation for husband vis-a-vis wife or wives (865) 5. Murdock (1967:47) distinguishes M, Monogamy; N, Limited polygyny; P, General polygyny, not preferentially sororal, co-wives same dwelling; Q, General polygyny, not preferentially sororal, cowives separate; R, General polygyny, preferentially sororal, cowives same dwelling; and S, General polygyny, preferentially sororal, co-wives separate. . = Missing data I = 2 = Husband usually has no room apart (as a predominant pattern, e.g., for Trobriand commoners), even if he rotates among wives Husband has a room apart, even if he rotates among wives 7 141 38 Codes 7-1 I are new and deal with rank, stratification, and capture. 7. Higher rates of polygyny for men of wealth, inherited rank, nobility, or higher social class (866) . = Missing data 33 o = No stratified polygyny 63 A = Hereditary upper social class 10 B = Achieved rank connected with groups 9 C = Achieved wealth 7I 8. Multiple wives for skilled hunters (867) . = Missing data 0 = No I = Yes, exceptionally skilled hunters have more wives than others 25 I39 22 9. Multiple wives for leaders, headmen, chiefs (868) . = Missing data 26 0 = No 95 L = Yes, leaders have more wives than others 65 Multiple wives for medicine men or shamans 10. (869) . o M = = = Missing data No, polygyny rate no higher than average Yes, higher than average rate of polygyny 26 140 20 Marriage of captive women (Code 11) includes concubinage where the children of the union are legitimate and adoption of female captives if they later become wives. In many cases the captive has slave status; usually she or her children attain freedom as a consequence of the marriage (Patterson 19823228-30). 11. Additional wives or concubines from slavery or capture in warfare (870) . = Missing data 28 o = No female captives 92 N = Women taken as captives but not married 8 C = Captives in war or slaves taken as wives or concubines 58 Codes 12, 13, and 15 are adapted from Whiting and Whiting et al.'s unpublished codes, which included ratings on the two percentage-polygyny variables for 60 of the standard-sample societies. These have been crosschecked and edited for about 40 societies (in other cases, the requisite sources were unavailable) to bring them in line with focal time, group, and source criteria for the standard sample. I rated another IOO societies, bringing the total to over 140. WHITE Rethinking Polygyny 1 541 12. Percentage of married men with more than one wife (871) . = Missing data 40 = Percentage given 146 13. Percentage of married women polygynously married (872) . = Missing data 42 = Percentage given I44 Code 14 was developed anew to provide additional data on reliability. 14. Reliability of data for percentage polygynously married (873) . = Missing data 39 o = Direct percentages: good quantitative data 87 B = Direct percentages for male polygyny; female polygyny estimated for minimum of two wives per man, where if P = % men married polygynously then Q = zP 1 IOO + P is % women married polygynously 13 D = Percentage female polygyny estimated from ratios of men with different numbers of wives, provided by ethnographer z C = Lower of two or more censuses used, or estimates where there is some other reason to believe that true percentages are higher for both males and females 3 E = Estimates from o to 5% male polygyny inferred from statements about limited polygyny; these are doubled for female percent23 ages (a minimal estimate) 2 = Uncertain coding 19 15. Polygyny data source (874) . = 46 A B = = 55 Missing data Sample of over IOO married men Sample of less than IOO married men but of an entire settlement C = Estimate from ethnographer statements E = Estimate from ethnographer statements involving a high degree of inference or extrapolation 29 48 8 Code 16 is the date of the polygyny census. It is chosen to be as close to the focal date for each society as the ethnographic sources allow. 16. Date for polygyny data (875) = Missing data 64 - I750 = - I750 B.C. I -620 = - 620 B.C. I I10 = A.D. I10 I 1 5 5 0 = 1550-59 I I 1630 I750 1820 1830 = = = = 1630-39 1750-59 1820-29 1830-39 I I I Code 17 is based on the best statistical fit of the distribution of number of married men with successive numbers of wives (Code 20) to either the binomial or the negative binomial distribution (Spencer 1980). A negative binomial indicates social differentiation among polygynists, or a tendency for additional wives to beget more wives. It is hypothesized to reflect the ability of wives to generate added wealth, as in the African compound pattern. Of the societies coded in the current study that are also found in Spencer's (1980) sample, eight fit the negative binomial and have dwelling compounds where wives have separate habitations. One (Bemba) fits the true binomial and lacks compounds and separate habitations. Two Islamic societies fail to show the expected association: the Hausa have compounds and separate habitations but fit the true binomial, and the Somali lack both but fit the negative binomial. 17. Social differentiation among polygynists (876) . = Missing data, including cases of monog- 135 amy T = Minimal differentiation (fits true binomial distribution) 25 N = Differentiation (fits negative binomial distribution) 26 Codes 18 and 19 are Guttman scales derived by analysis after all of the other coding was completed. Each has a coefficient of reproducibility of .97. 18. Male-stratified polygyny with autonomous cowives (877)Guttman scale . = Missing data 5 o = None of the following 72 I = Stratified polygyny (866) only 50 z = Differentiation among polygynists (876) plus I above 5 3 = Polygyny common (860)plus I and 2 above 12 4 = Wife has separate habitation (864)plus 1-3 above 7 5 = Husband has separate habitation (865)plus 1-4 above 9 6 = Polygynous compounds (863)plus 1-5 above 26 542 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY V O ~29,UNumber ~ ~ 4, August-October 1988 clarified where possible. Samoan mosquito-net compartments in a single open housing arrangement do not qualify as separate habitations, nor do the different hearths of Miskito co-wives. Tanala men rotate among their wives, and this is coded as "wives in separate habitations" but "husband without a separate habitation." Sometimes the codes obscure important differences in context. A Goajiro "compound," unlike its African counterpart, is a seminomadic lean-to, but the functional similarity in the pattern of polygyny is striking. Where possible, definitions of codes are operational ones that make relevant comparative distinctions. For example, in societies where marriage is formal, conCode 20 contains distinct columns for the numbers (or cubines are recognized as a separate category. The Kopercentages) of men married concurrently to I, 2, 3, 4, 5, rean case is prescriptively monogamous and coded as 6, 7, or more wives. Where indicated as "(est.)" state- such, although occasional concubinage is reported. The ments by the ethnographer were used to estimate this Romans are prescriptively monogamous, and concubinage with slaves is publicly repudiated though extensive; distribution. children by slaves do not inherit. In these cases, in which concubinage is treated as strictly outside mar20. Distribution of married men by number of wives riage, publicly denied, and lacking in rights of inherMost of the codes herein are derived from the original itance for offspring, concubines are excluded from the ratings of polygyny. (By this criterion, restrictions on ethnographic sources shown in table 2. sociological fatherhood are not necessarily good indicators of biological fatherhood.) In many societies where C O D I N G PROBLEMS marriage is informal, however, there is no such distincThe coding of ethnographic data for comparative re- tion. In the ethnographies, numbers of co-wives are alsearch poses a great many problems. As many have most never broken down to distinguish concubines. It is noted, and as Clifford (1986:7)reiterates, "ethnographic only in some state societies that monogamy, if practruths are inherently partial, committed [to a particular ticed, is prescriptive or legally enforced, in which case paradigm] and incomplete." Texts are not inevitably the offspring of concubines typically do not legally incommensurate one with the other, and, as when work- herit. In pre-state societies ethnographers usually regard ing with any body of text, it is important to avoid the concubine as another type of secondary wife, and "smoothing" the representation. Many problems generic Patterson (1982)has shown that female slaves taken as to the coding process are encountered in this work, concubines usually attain free status through such among them ( I ) ambiguity, ( 2 ) conflicts in sources, (3) unions and their children are normally regarded as legitiinsufficient evidence, (4)inference, ( 5 ) observer bias, and mate. Unless otherwise indicated by the ethnographer, I treat concubines in pre-state societies as secondary (6)meaning or measurement validity. Ambiguity. Coding categories may not always mirror wives and include the frequency of concubinage within the actual situation or may themselves require clarifica- that of polygyny generally. Thus, for example, the wife's tion. For example, the Garo take secondary wives (e.g.,a brothers' daughters who come as "concubines" with a widowed mother-in-law)who are not sexually activej for marriage to the Samoan chief are treated as lesser wives coding purposes this has little effect except in minor via a variant of sororal polygyny. This kind of "inadjustments to the frequencies of polygyny. Captive formed" coding decision also minimizes the European girls among the Omaha are sent home after peace settle- observer bias towards viewing secondary wives as "conments unless they elect to stay (and marry) among the cubines." Omaha. This I regard as "wives obtained through capCoding categories may be clarified by a comparative ture in warfare." The Creeks adopted their captives; perspective even when the definition of categories seems since the rate of polygyny is low and the first wife's obvious. In the Gilyak case, one must ask whether popermission to take a second wife is required and only lygynous hunters include the wealthy fur traders. The exceptionally given, it is likely that captured women are parallel with the Plains and subsequent analysis of the occasionally taken as first wives after adoption but are codes help to confirm that the traderlhunter roles ought not significant secondary wives. In a similar situation, not to be separated: even if many of the hunters in these the Natchez replace their slain through adoption; societies are not wealthy, some are highly involved in women who were captives are thus likely to be taken as trade and production for trade, and such producer1 secondary wives. These two cases, in which similar traders may be polygynists. Some distinctions cannot reliably be made in the codpractices are coded differently because of context, represent the kinds of inferences I considered justifiable, al- ing process. In the "exceptional hunter" code I note cases in which exceptional fishermen, herdsmen, or culthough they might lower intercoder reliabilities. Contexts that might affect the meanings of codes are tivators are reported as polygynists, but since many 19. Male-ranked polygyny with related co-wives (878) Guttman scale . = Missing data 3 o None of the following 44 I = Husband and wife coresident (864) 73 2 = Co-wives share habitation (863)plus I above 26 3 = Wife's kin as co-wives or sororal polygyny (862)plus I and z above 25 4 = Polygynous hunters (867)plus 1-3 above 9 5 = Exclusive wife's kin as co-wives (sororal) (862)plus 1-4 above 6 - WHITE Rethinking Polygyny 1 543 TABLE 2 Source Bibliography for Polygyny Coding Nama Kung 3 Thonga 4 Lozi 5 Mbundu 6 Suku 7 Bemba 8 Nyakyusa 9 Hadza I 0 Luguru I I Kikuyu 12 Ganda I 2 I 3 Mbuti 14 Nkundo 15 Banen I 6 Tiv 17 Ib0 18 Fon 19 Ashanti zo Mende 2 I Wolof 22 Bambara 23 Tallensi 24 Songhai 25 Wodaabe 26 Hausa 27 Massa 28 Azande 29 Fur 30 Otoro 31 Shilluk 32 Mao 33 Kafa 34 Maasai 35 Konso 36 Somali 37 Amhara 38 Bogo 39 Nubians 40 Teda 41 Tuareg 42 Riffians 43 Egyptians 44 Hebrews 45 Babylonians 46 Rwala 47 Turks 48 Gheg 49 Romans 50 Basques 5 I Irish 52 Lapps 5 3 Samoyed 54 Russians 55 Abkhaz 56 Armenians 57 Kurd 5 8 Basseri 59 Punjabi 60 Gond 61 Toda 62 Santal 63 Uttar Pradesh 64 Burusho [d]Murdock134:498;[z]Schapera130:z5~-5% Murdock(195g:~~) [a]Marsha11176:262-63;[f]Lee179:245;[ab]Shostak18~:~70; Murdock(1959:55) [1'27]Junod'62:282-89, 512; Murdock(1959:377) [z]Gluckman1g~:7g, 83, 65; [6]'50:180; [8*If65:30,69; Murdock(1959:367) [~]Childs'qg:jo,40; [3]Hamblyf62:~23-24;Murdock(1959:372) [a]Kopytoff165:452;Murdock(195g:zgg) [a]Richards'g1:181; [2]'39; [7jRichards'40:46, 89; [q]Whitely15o:~8; Murdock(1959:zgg) [a]Wilson'77:115; [d]'51a:15; [b]'51b:260; Murdock(1g~g:362) [b]Woodbum'64:108~Whiting and Whiting(1975:zoz); Murdock(1959:62) [a]Beidelrnan167:31;[d*]Fosbrooke'54:ms; Murdock(1g5g:310) [a]Leakeyf77v.z;Murdock(1959:345) [ I 5]Southwold165:1o5-6; [z]Roscoel~ I:IO, 87, 93-95, 205; [8]Kagwa134:68;[b]Murdock134:525,534-35, 539-40; Murdock(19~9:35a) [z]Tumbull'65: 181-83, 204, 207, table 4(Efe);[31162:35;[e*]Schebesta'33:128-29;~urdock(1959:50) Murdock(1959:287) Murdock(1959:241) [d]Bohannan165:527-+ [18]'54a:64-65; [~glBohannan& Bohannan153:70, 74, 35; Murdock(1g59:g~) [z]Uchendu165:50,54; [3]Green164:152;[b]Nzimirof62:zo8;Murdock(1959:246+) [a]Herskovitz138v.~:339; [aIf38v.z:~o, 38, 45-46; [h]Murdock134:582;Murdock(1g~g:z55) [5]Fortes1~o:28~, 215; [8'70 2nd ed.If7o:16-17, 24; [z]Rattray1z7:95;[4]Manokianf64:z~5; [b]Lystad158:16; Murdock(1959:z~s) [2'51]Little'67:140-44; Murdock(1959:262) Murdock(1959:269) Murdock(1959:75) [3]Fortes'qg:6~, 71; Murdock(1959:83) [c153]Miner'65:z~3-14;Murdock(1959:143) [c]Dupire163:63-70; [e]Stenningf65:385-87; [d]'59:183-93; [f]'58:108-10; [g]Hopen'58:141-45; Murdock(1959:419) [I 5]Smith160:z56;[17]'65:143-44; [z]Greenberg146:16in Minerf65; Murdock(19~9:143) Murdock(1g~g:236);[blde Garine164:16~,172 [~6]Baxter and Butt153:69-70, 63; [68]Evans-Pritchard'71:197, 250; [3]Legae1z6:160-63, 179; Murdock(1959:236) [a]Felkin 1885:234; Murdock(1ggg:143] [a]Nade1147:116-17, 147; Murdock(1959:166) [z]Seligmann'32:40, 55, 68; Murdock(1959:173+) Murdock(19~9:173+ ) [z]Huntingford155:~~4-15, 120-21; [d]Gmhlf35:233;Murdock(1959:189) [13]Huntingford'53:11~,122; [1]Hollis'o~:303;Spencer(1980:131); Murdock(1959:335) [a]Hallpike17z:5 5, 105, 182, 190, I 3; [42]Cemlli1~ 6:58; Murdock(1959:zo1) [18]Lewis'61:138-43, 103, 60-71; [aI165:342-43; Murdock(1959:322) Murdock(1959:186) Murdock(19~9:317) [glal-Katshain Kennedyf78:173; Murdock(1959:16a) [1]Cline'~o:42, 46-47; Murdock(195g:130) [d]Briggsf60:~5 8; Murdock(1959: I 17) [1]Coon'31:142, 120; [3]Hart176:zzg,232; Murdock(1959:117) [3]Ayrout'45:118; [1]Ammar'54:zo1 [b]DeVaux16~:zs; [h]Moscati157:~59-60;[aIDeuteronomy 17:17; [alcorinthians 6:8; [a]z Samuel 3:~-5, 5: 13, 19:6; [alchronicles I I : ~ I [a11 ; Kings II:I-3 [a]Saggsf62:~85, 214 Murdock(19~9:399) [7]Stirling'65:196-97 Murdock(1949:235) [1]Carcopin0'40:1oz; [d]Balsdon'69:107, 198, 215, 230 [concubinage] monogamous (not requiring new coding] monogamous (not requiring new coding) monogamous (not requiring new coding) [1]Hadju'63:zg monogamous (not requiring new coding) [a]Benet174:79 [j*]Villaand Matossianf82:7~-88 [z]Masters1g~:230; Murdock(1gqg:234) [a]Barth161:1z,107 [a]Eglarf60:no mention Whiting and Whiting(1975:187); Murdock(1967:194) [6]Murdock134:~zo-21;[1]Rivers'o6:5a1 [5]Culshaw14g:~z~, 146; [f]Kochar170:86 Whiting and Whiting(1975);[*]Gore165in Nimcoff and Middleton165:zzo-z~ [z]Lorimer139:182 544 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY TABLE 2 Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 (continued) 65 Kazak 66 Khalka 67 Lo10 68 Lepcha 69 Garo 70 Lakher 71 Burmese 72 Lamet 73 Vietnamese 74 Rhade 75 Khmer 76 Thai 77 Semang 78 Nicobarese 79 Andamanese 80 Vedda 81 Tanala 82 Negri Sembilan 83 Javanese 84 Balinese 85 Iban 86 Badjau 87 Toradja 88 Tobelorese 89 Alorese 90 Tiwi 9 I Aranda 92 Orokaiva 93 Kimam 94 Kapauku 95 Kwoma 96 Manus 97 Lesu 98 Trobrianders 99 Siuai IOO Tikopia I O I Pentecost 102 Mbau Fijians 103 Ajie 104 Maori 105 Marquesans 106 Samoans 107 Gilbertese 108 Jaluit Marshallese 109 Trukese I 10 Yapese I I I Palauans I I 2 Ifugao I I 3 Atayal I 14 Chekiang I I 5 Manchu I I 6 Koreans I 17 Japanese I I 8 Ainu I 19 Gilyak I 20 Yukaghir 121 Chukchee 122 hgalik 123 Aleut 124 Copper Eskimo I 2 5 Montagnais 126 Micmac 127 Saulteaux 128 Slave 129 Kaska 130 Eyak I 3 I Haida I 32 Bellacoola I 33 Twana [d]Kraderf63:z~5(not 247); [e]Kraderf66:136,141, 146, 15 I; [a]Murdock134:~~7; [1z]Hudson'64:40, 58, 79-80 monogamous (not requiring new coding) [1]Linf61:76-77; '47:62 [1'67]Gorer'67:166; [z]Morris138:263;Murdock(1949:235) [1]Burling'63:128, 142, 148; [a]Nakane167:77-78 [a]Parryf32:340 [a]Nash165:247-67 [b*]Izikowitz'85:165-67, 174 [a]Hickey164:I 12-13; [c]Donoghue164:42 [g']Hickey182:35 [i]Briggsfg~:245; [147(AM1]Aymonier'oo:76; [k*]Audricf72:82,90-91 [elsharp and Hanks'78:115 [e]Evans'jz:z50, 253-54; [c]Murdock1j4:gg-IOO not coded monogamous (not requiring new coding) monogamous (not requiring new coding) [1]Linton'33:132-33, 304-5, 249; [aIf39:26o [d'IJosselin de J o n g ' ~ I: 10-1 I, 125 [zo]Geertz'61:131-32 [d]Geertz and Geertzf75:13I; Murdock(19qg:zz8) [6]Freeman17I :29 [1]Nimmo'72:18 [3]Adriani and Kruijtf~z:35g,413, 431, 471-73, 483 monogamous (not requiring new coding) [1]DuBois'44:zg, 97, 100, 110-11, 513; [a]DuBois145:~43-44 [ ~ I H a rand t Pilling160:16-17 [~ISpencerand Gillin1z7:g, 15, 39, 467, 469-70, 583 [16]Murdock'34:38 [1]Williams'30:83, 92-93, 130-31 [a]Serpenti'65:131-32, 175 [1]Pospisil'~8:10~, 135; [51163:37 [~IWhiting'q~: 129 [1]Mead130:18,47, 105, 175, 197, zoo, 207, 173, 118, 172, 177-78 [1]Powdermaker'33:z26 [~IMalinowski'zg: I 30 [a]01iver155:zz3-26, 149 [z]Firth1s7:~32, 470-78, 565-72; [2]'36:132; Murdock(1949:235) [a]Lane and Lane ms, part II:9-12 [h]Roth153:75; [e*]Toganivaluf12: I [a]Leenhardt130;[b]'37 [ h ] B e s t ' g a : ~ ~[1I124,i:447-49 z; [1o]Linton'39:1~5-57;[1]Handy'z3:1oo-102, 123-36 [16]Tumer 1884:96-97, 155, 175-76; [a]Murdock134:7~, 64 [k]Sabatier177:80,~30? [2] Kramer100:z58, 264; [3]Erdland'14:go-91 [ I '5 ~]Goodenough'gI: 1% [z]Gladwin and Sarason'~ 3: I 3I Murdock(1949)for 1935; [f']Lingenfelderf7~;[10]Furness'10:36-55 [c]Bamett14g:~4~-44; [d']'60:50; [d*If79:6o;[1]Smith'83:145 [1z]Barton'j0:30, 253; [2'69]'69:10; Murdock(1949:229) [alokada [14]Fei monogamous (not requiring new coding) [zz]Osgood'5I :I I 3 [concubinage] monogamous (not requiring new coding) [c]Hilger'71:161-62; [7]Munro163:~47; [d*]Batchelor 1892:288; [g]Murdock'34:181, 176 [f]Ivanovet a1.'64 in Levin and Potapov164:778;Murdock(1gqg:239); [1]Shtemberg'33:156 [a]Jochelson126: I 10-1 I ; [clstepanova et a1.'64 in Levin and Potapov164 [~g]Antropova et a1.'64 in Levin and Potapov164:820; [1]Bogoras'og:gg8 [aIOsgood'~ 8200-203 [b]Lantis170:zo8-10, 245; [alveniaminov 1840:60 [13]Jenness'13-18:158, 161 [2'771Speck'77 [3]Denys108:4~o-11;[a]Bock166:6 [zz]Dunningfgg:181-82; [ z ~ ] H a l l o w e l5:300 l'~ [e]Masonf46:32 [6]Honigmann154:~32-33;[1]Honigmann'4g:194; Murdock(1gqg:247); [c]P.Field M S ' I ~ [a]Birket-Smith138:133,147, 139 [e]Niblack 1890:367; [b]Murdockf34:242,252; Murdock (1949:247) [1]McIlwraith'48:144; Jorgensen(1980:453+ ) [a]Elmendorff160:3~8, 367, 509; [c*]Ells'85:zg3-94, 341, 436; Driver and Massey (1957:map 153) WHITE TABLE 2 (continued) 134 Yurok 135 Pomo 136 Yokuts I 37 Wadadika 138 Klamath I 39 Kutenai 140 Gros Ventre 141 Hidatsa 142 Pawnee 143 Omaha 144 Huron 145 Creek 146 Natchez 147 Comanche 148 Chiricahua 149 Zuni I 50 Havasupai I 5 I Papago I 52 Huichol 153 Aztec I 54 Popoluca I 5 5 Quiche I 56 Miskito I 5 7 Bribri 158 Cuna I 5 9 Goajiro I 60 Haitians I 6 I Callinago 162 Warrau 163 Yanomamo 164 Carib 165 Saramacca I 66 Rethinking Polygyny 1 545 Mundurucu 167 Cubeo Cayapa 169 Jivaro I 70 Arnahuaca I 7 I Inca I 68 172 Aymara 173 Siriono 174 Nambicuara 175 Trumai 176 Timbira I 77 Tupinamba 178 Botocudo I 79 Shavante 180 Aweikoma I 8 I Cayua 182 Lengua 183 Abipon 184 Mapuche I 8 5 Tehuelche I 8 6 Yahgan NOTE: Sources keyed [g]Kroeber'z5:31; [ff76]Powers'76:56;[zlwaterman & Kroeberf34:283; Murdock(1g4g:230); [~IHeizerand Mills'5 2: 128; Jorgensen(1980:454);also Twana[a]Elmendorff'60:318, 367 [~ IKroeber'z~ :25 5; [3]Loeb1z6:243;Jorgensen (1980:454) [1]Gayton'48:94; [z]Kroeber1z5:493; Jorgensen(1980:453 ) [7]Whiting150:~g, IOO [1]Spier'30:49: Jorgensen(1980:453-54) Murdock(1949:228) [zIFlanne~'~3:73-74, 171-73, 98 [a]Bowers165:~42, 114, 260, 155; [b]Matthews 1877:53 [14]Weltfish'65:17, 464; [~IDorseyand Murie140:84, 107-9; [b]Lesser130:98-IOI [~IFletcher and LaFlesche'~1:326, 615; [z]Dorsey 1884261, 332; Murdock (1949:240) monogamous (not requiring new coding) [1]Swanton'28:371, 373, 167; [a]'46:704; Murdock(1949:247) [d]Swantonf46:708;[a]'11:97, 100, 102, 124 [a*]Linton'45:59;[3]Wallaceand Hoebe1152:138,141, 2 [a]Opler137:zo4;[ I ] ' ~ I : I151, ~ , 416-20, 55-56 [a]Eggan15o:~93 [c']Dobyns and Euler174:23; [3]Jamesfo3:zzg;[a']Whiting185:97; ['IKroeber et al.'35 [z]Underhillf3g:I 79, 182; [b]'65 in Nimcoff and Middleton165:I 5 2 [a]Zingg138:114, 136; [b]Lumholtz1oz:236 [33]Soustelle'55:103, 184-88; [a']Diaz del Castillo'10:60; [b]Murdockf34:38~; [c*]Bandelier 1880:613 [a]Foster142:7I monogamous (not requiring new coding) [1]Conzemius'32:14g-50, 83-84; [z]Kirchhoff'48:zzg, 227 [a]Johnson148245, 247 [4*]Wass6n14g:88;[1o*]Stout'48:27,260, 263; Murdock(1949:229) [8]Armstrongand MCtrauxf48:375-76, 379; [b*]Wilbertlg8:6o; [7]Bolinder157:61 [1]Herskovitz'37: I 16-20; [3]Leyburn14~:~g5ff. [5]Rouse148:556,8; [4]Du Tertre 1667:16; Murdock(19qg:232); [11]Taylor'46 [3]Kirchhoff148:874,880; [6]TurradoMoreno145:z54 [c]Smolef76:~89, 75; [11]Chagnon'68:63-64, 75; [d]Shapiro172:~07, 108 [a]Gillenf48:8~o [e]Price184:78-79, 58, 14, 20, 42-44, 50-57, 168, 203-5; [e]deGroot169:~32; [~IHerskovits and Herskovits134:I 59 [a]Y R Murphy'74: I 18, 146; [a]'85:144, 172; [1z]R,Murphy'60:88; [ I1]'58:30; [4']Horton148:274-75, 277-78 [a]Goldman148:782,786 [z]Murra148:no mention [1]Karsttn'35:186; [~glstewardand Mttrauxf48:624; [e]Service'71:196 [h]Huxley & Capaf64:71-73, 111, 39, 58 [3'61]de la Vegaf61:48, 132, 135; [3]1871:299-300, 306-7; [z]Cieza de Le6n159:41; [ ~ z * ] P o mde a Ayalaf36:184; [k]KarstCn'~o:gg,142; [g]Murdock'34:419; [1]Rowe'48:z53, 274 [1]Tschopik'46:543 [a]Holmberg148:457,461, 58-59 [~ILtvi-Strauss148:366, 67; [a'61]'61:303-7; [6]'43; Murdock(1949:232) [a]LCvi-Strauss148:336-37, 340, 345; [1'66]Murphy and Quain166:89,45, 47, 56 [f]Lowie146:492;[1]Nimuendaju'46:1zo-21, 124-25 [24]Mttraux'48:111-13; [1]Staden'z8:142-43; [z]Thevet 1878:64-66 [b]MCtraux146:5 36-37 [a]M.Lewis167:336-37, 47, 76-78, 87, tables 4-5 [z]Henry'41:z13-15, 21, 39-30 [3]Watson152:I 17 [d]MCtraux146:326,183, 327, 315, 303; [a]Grubb'13:z14-15 [z]Mttraux146:326,316-17, 309; [~IDobrizhoffer1822 [11]Faron'61:150-52, 178-79, 127?; [aIf68:35;[1o]Hilger'57:31, 125-27, 327; [zlCooper'46:721, 707 (earlier, traditional Mapuche) [1]Cooper'46:149; [z]Musters'71:187 [z]Cooper'46:gz; [d]Servicef7~:34; Murdock(1g49:230) + + to White (1986);numbers in brackets identify HRAF sources, letters other souces, asterisks sources added to bibliography for this study. Comparative sources not in the 1986 bibliography, which appear in standard form, are listed with the other references cited. 546 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 cases of this sort have certainly gone unreported I did not rilocality and common nonsororal polygyny by wives' report these distinctions in the final codes. The same maintaining separate houses in their own villages while problem occurs in distinguishing polygyny stratified by men reside in men's houses. wealth vs. class (e.g., nobility) or rank. This distinction Finally, aberrant patterns sometimes present themis feasible but involves a high degree of inference; a selves in their own terms, particularly when a variant proper study would require careful examination of the cultural practice-like secondary marriage-is achieved nature of social rank and stratification. While there are only at great "frictional" cost in terms of social norms. good codes in the literature for types of stratification, The Siuai husband's rotation among wives, for example, rank is nowhere well coded. Thus, distinctions as to type is bitterly attacked by the wives themselves. Among the of stratification were dropped from the cultural-rules Burusho and the Ifugao the polygynist must pay a heavy scale. By far the greatest number of cases in the stratified fine or compensation to his first wife's family or his own category, however, are wealth-stratified. I am unable at children by the first wife. this time to distinguish ascribed from achieved polygyConflicts in sources. Discrepancies in the evidence nous statuses. from different, or sometimes the same, sources can usuVariability within a society often generates ambiguity. ally be resolved by temporal and spatial pinpointing, The code for proximity of co-wife habitations, for ex- evaluating the authoritativeness of sources, or underample, is set up for the usual case, in which there is no standing the larger context. An interesting example is internal variability. In some cases there is such variabil- the Mapuche, for whom Hilger (1957)reports polygyny ity, but not sufficient to merit changing the coding cate- practiced by caciques, curers, and men of wealth but gories, and the exceptions are treated in the notes. Inter- Faron (1961) remarks that polygynists are more landnal variability also takes the form of differing practices poor than others, reflecting the requirement for and dein stratified populations. It is important to note for the pletion of wealth by polygyny. Both reports are true in first code that where polygyny is preferred within a par- the context of increasing land scarcity and restriction in ticular class or status, it is generally not prohibited but available land for women's garden plots and a major demerely infrequent for other groups that lack the requi- cline in polygyny over the past century. Hilger's observasite wealth or status. The husband's-habitation code, on tions are more indicative of older traditions, although the other hand, simply excludes internal variability in both reflect aspects of the situation at the focal date. favor of coding the predominant tendency in the populaInsufficient evidence. I have avoided weak inferences. tion. The Trobrianders exemplify stratification in this For example, I code reports of female slaves with no respect; commoner husbands reside with their wives but indication of whether they were married as missing data (usually, however, ethnographers do report presence or chiefs apart. A careful consideration of the semantics of the codes absence of concubinage or marriage to freed slaves).Failalso helps to resolve what appear to the coder as aberrant ure of the ethnographer to report the absence of polygor contradictory combinations of features. For example, yny is occasionally a problem in coding a society as moco-wives may reside together and the husband sepa- nogamous or near-monogamous. Inference. I have not avoided reasonable inferences rately; such is the case among the Jivaro, where men and women reside at opposite ends of the longhouse, and (see the notes to table I ) . For example, I inferred MunBarry and Paxson (1971)~Whiting and Whiting (1975)~ durucu shamanic polygyny from ethnographer stateand I code this as "husband rooms apart," although I also ments that "men of rank are polygynous" and "each code it as "coresidence for multiple wives." This is also communal house has its house chief and shaman." A the case in some societies with married men living in Trumai individual's "plan to capture women," on the men's houses. It is such possibilities that require the other hand, regarded by the ethnographer as sheer separate codes for wives' and husband's habitation. Nor bravado and not supported by any evidence of the actual are the numbers of men and women living in these ar- capture of women, was treated as the absence of marrangements symmetric, since different frequencies of riage to captured women. Inference is also involved in temporal extrapolation married men and women are polygynous. The Trobriand case, with a chiefly 2% of the men married to 39% of the and the assessment of change relative to a focal date. For married women, dramatizes the difference: wives (that the Huichol, for instance, Zingg (1938)reports concubinis, the 39% who are chiefs' wives) commonly live apart age of officials, elders, and shamans, contrasting with from their husbands, while husbands (the 98% common- the morality of earlier days when they were observed by ers) live with their wives. Lumholtz (1902)~ who he says could not have overlooked Reconciling polygyny patterns with other social fea- this pattern if it had occurred then. Lumholtz, however, tures such as matrilocal residence is sometimes required does not allude to the topic but does report that "a man in making coding judgments. If these were regarded as who wants to become a shaman must be faithful to his uniform societal "rules" they might be seen to conflict; wife for five years," which makes sense if experienced that they are context-specific behaviors, however, can shamans would normally be adulterous or take conbe seen in cases such as the generally matrilocal cubines. I infer that Zinggls observations are more indicTupinamba of I 5 50 and Mundurucu of I 850, among ative of the situation even for the focal date of 1890. This whom polygynous chiefs resided patrilocally. The Cal- is supported by distributional evidence. Temporal inference is often required, and I have aslinago resolve the apparent contradiction between mat- WHITE sessed polygyny for the focal time period. Declines in polygyny are indicated for Egyptians, Kurds, Kimam, Lesu, Pentecost, Yapese, Mundurucu, Aymara, Mapuche, and many others, but in cases such as the Nyakyusa and several other African societies the changes prior to the focal date are towards higher rates of polygyny. In the case of the Bribri, where a heavy influx of cattle since 1914 is reported as altering the social structure in major ways, temporal inferences are difficult, since it is not clear how far the changes had gone by the focal date of 1917. Sometimes resolving problems of temporal inference provides evidence of change. Mundurucu polygyny of chiefs and shamans, coded for 1850, is one of several features of social structure that apparently shift after the rise of rubber tapping in the 19th century: ( I ) from patrilocal to matrilocal residence, ( 2 ) from residential use of men's houses by younger unmarried warriors to use by all adult men, (3)from a positive attitude of women towards polygyny, illustrated by occasional solicitations for younger wives by the elder wife, to one of active resistance, even towards second wives of chiefs. In the transitional period, with incompatible practices of matrilocal residence and nonsororal polygyny, chiefs tended to establish patrilocal residence. Quantitative inferences are involved in the numerical extrapolations that are often needed to assess rates of polygyny. While good polygyny censuses are available for about one-sixth of the sample, I have used ethnographer statements about relative frequencies of men with one, two, three, or more wives to estimate polygyny distributions. The problem is ubiquitous in the Americas, where there are few polygyny censuses and much retrospective ethnography. In providing either precise or estimated polygyny distributions, one is often aware of how skewed is the baseline of "married men" in societies in which marriage is long delayed by the scarcity of potential wives for younger men. It is neither feasible nor desirable, however, to compute the percentage of polygynously married men over the pool of "adult men." For one thing, it is too difficult to assess the ages and numbers of young men or to determine a cutoff age at which to consider young men "adult." For another, unmarried males often emigrate or suffer high mortality in warfare and other activities. Finally, the percentage of polygynously married men and the very size and length of the tail of the polygyny distribution are the best indicators of the process by which, as a function of polygyny, wives become scarce for bachelors. Different degrees of inference are required in the various codes. Codes 1-6 involve low inference in that they are based on highly visible behaviors marked by spatial, customary, or legal arrangements. High-inference codes such as 9-1 3 and 17 typically require the various kinds of extrapolations discussed above. Similarly, ethnographer or demographic inferences about the causes or consequences of polygyny in particular societies, unless properly tested, may present a problem. We know from quantitative studies (see White 1988) that in many instances it is difficult to determine, for example, whether wealth attracts wives or wives augment wealth. And Rethinking Polygyny 1 547 whereas attempts to identify the reproductive costs or benefits of polygyny to wives have often led to the conclusion that polygyny decreases female fertility, Borgerhoff Mulder (1985)has shown that the accumulation of infertile wives in polygynous marriages may be a major confounding factor. Observer bias. Perhaps the most pervasive observer bias is the description of polygyny as if the males were the principal actors, "acquiring" wives (e.g., via bridewealth), rather than taking a more gender-balanced view in which women (as brides, wives, and kinswomen of brides) also actively "acquire" husbands and manipulate wealth flows. Meaning or measurement validity. A further problem has less to do with the coding itself than with what certain codes might be seen to index. For example, frequent polygyny might be expected to create and therefore index a shortage of wives, but it does not always do so: among the Pawnee, with high rates of polygyny, polyandry was also common and allowed mature women who had married young as second wives to take younger men as second husbands, while providing a first wife to young men who would not otherwise have one. The interpretation of wealth-stratified polygyny poses a more serious problem. Does one interpret the code as wealth "required" or establishing the "prerogative" for polygyny or as wealth "generated" by polygyny? For the Shavante, for example, where polygyny is common and rates are higher for leaders and important men, we learn that economic contributions of wives are not needed for exercise of authority. For the Kapauku, acquisition of a second wife is an important investment in production, and a first wife may divorce her husband if he has the money for bride price and refuses to remarry. While successful Kapauku men teach the behavior that leads to wealth and polygyny, the wealth does not follow without the productivity of extra wives. If ethnographers do not always clearly specify whether wealth leads to wives or wives to wealth, it may be because the two are often circularly linked, with the position of secondary wives offering investment opportunities (for both the wives and the husband) for productivity exceeding that of monogamous marriages. The investment analogy is often an apt one: wealth may be needed to initiate the investment, but the investment may enrich the family. Both males and females may be investors in polygyny, even in bridewealth systems, since both often manipulate wealth flows. Problems of indexing wealth considerations also occur for hunting societies. Where polygyny is associated with exceptional hunters it is not always possible to infer that the hunter must support additional wives, since in some cases the wives make major economic contributions. When wives are reported as often suggesting that the husband acquire another wife (which I noted but did not code systematically), a wealth-generating pattern of polygyny is likely indicated. Dorjahn (1959) was the first to raise the problem of confounding variables in interpreting the causal linkages between wealth, polygyny, and fertility, for example, 548 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 within particular societies. Borgerhoff Mulder (1987: 617-19, 624-25) has shown that even ethnographers directly concerned with testing the causal relationship between wealth or leadership and reproductive success or polygyny find it difficult to establish the direction of causality. Cross-cultural codes on economic productivity and the sexual division of labor, exchange, and consumption need to be brought into play to identify further aspects of polygynous systems. We need to incorporate more focused ethnographic insights and materials into comparative analysis, but sensitive comparative study of the problem may also have a contribution to make first to raising and ultimately to resolving some of the issues. The generation and expenditure of wealth by both cowives and husbands is centrally important to the study and eventual understanding of polygyny. Hartung (1982) has shown a close connection between polygyny, bridewealth, and male-biased inheritance of wealth and attempted an equation of the wealth element in polygyny with the type of territorial resource defense that is one of two characteristic forms of polygyny in other species. Commentators such as Pospisil (1982), Scott (1982))and Dickemann (1982)noted that human polygyny often augments wealth and power via the labor and exchange of wives and thus does not clearly constitute resource defense by males; polygyny is also accompanied by mate-defense elements such as wife capture in warfare, kidnapping, enslavement, or sale of women, rape, veiling, female claustration, and mutilation. Similarly, bridewealth is not an indicator that wives are acquired by men, since it is often the result of women's labor in polygynous households and in any case is not implied by resource defense. It is not at all clear that polygynous males control the resources that attract females to their territories. Even bridewealth, as Pospisil notes for the Kapauku, may be lent in expectation of return insofar as it is an investment in production. Judging from these critical reactions, Gray (1985:32-33, 75) suggests that the next step in the study of polygyny is a search for ecological conditions. Several critics, and Hartung himself, indicate that some term other than either resource-defense or mate-defense might be more appropriate for the type of polygyny he describes. Burton and I (Whiteand Burton 1988)have shown that the key ecological conditions of high-frequency polygyny are environmental quality, ecological homogeneity, and access to new lands for expansion, as found in tropical savannahs. The results of our regression analysis suggest that it is not movable property, as hypothesized by Murdock (1949))that predicts polygyny but movable productive units in the absence of fixed property in land, fishing, insular environments, or land-intensive technologies such as the plow. Schneider's (1979:106-7) description of the polygynous house-property complex of East Africa is apt for the broader region of high-frequency polygynous systems: "a man heads a household and allows his wife or wives to conduct their own production operation, passing the proceeds to their sons. . . . The glue in the H-P [house- property] complex is the kind and amount of property which a husband can confer on his wife when he marries her." The linkages in this complex would explain the association that Hartung (1982) finds between malebiased inheritance and polygyny. The sons have direct economic payoffs in this system via their polygynous mothers, and while extended bachelorhood is a byproduct of this system, it is the sons as warriors who provide the defense of it. Variants of the family estate system in central Africa, discussed by Gray (1964) and contributors to Gray and Gulliver (1964), would be a useful starting point for studying polygyny as it relates to property. In contrast to the resource-defense and mate-defense polygyny of other species, this polygyny complex might be characterized as wealth-increasing fraternal-defense polygyny. Indeed, the other factors that predict high-frequency polygyny are male-centered kin groups (patrilocal, with bridewealth) and warfare for plunder or captives (Whiteand Burton 1988).It would be useful to subject the idea of a wealth-increasing type of polygyny complex to further empirical examination. Borgerhoff Mulder (1987) has argued for malegenerated wealth as a cause of greater reproductive success of men, and clearly there are monogamous societies in which this is the case (e.g., the modem Ifaluk studied by Turke and Betzig 1985). What is neglected in Borgerhoff Mulder's analysis of the polygynous Kipsigis is that the wealth generated by female co-wives (not simply by children) may create a spurious correlation between wealth and number of offspring (even among younger cohorts of married men) and that such wealth passes through the father in sponsoring the bridewealth for the son's first marriage. Failure to see polygyny as a potential source of wealth creates the illusion that it is male wealth that attracts multiple wives and leads to reproductive success. Testing the Theory of Polygyny Complexes: Scales and Validity Issues The various features of the polygyny codes developed here fall into several clusters that constitute elaborations of fundamentally different types of polygyny. An entailment analysis (see White, Burton, and Brudner 1977, White and McCann 1988)of dichotomous features of polygyny from the codes above reveals two major clusters of variables. One cluster consists of husbandwife residential separation, prevalent polygyny, and wealth-stratified polygyny, as well as marriage of female captives. These are likely traits of the wealth-increasing fraternal-defense polygyny identified above. The other consists of sororal polygyny (recruitment of wife's kin as co-wives), coresidence of co-wives, and polygyny for exceptional hunters or for shamans. Each of these clusters contains a cumulative Guttman scale. Two other smaller clusters of polygyny traits (leadership or despotic polygyny and wealth-depleting polygyny) are independent of these complexes. WHITE Rethinking Polygyny I 549 TABLE ? WEALTH-INCREASING POLYGYNY correlaGons among Scale Items i n Wealth-Increasing PO~Y~PY Six items form a cumulative Guttman scale that can be labeled "male-stratified polygyny with autonomous cowives." This is hypothesized to be wealth-increasing polygyny. The features of this scale and their frequencies in the standard sample are as follows: 1. Polygynous compounds (863) 21% 2. Husband has separate habitation (865) 21% 3. Wife has separate habitation (864) 27% 25% 4. Prevalent polygyny (860) 5 . Negative binomial distribution of polygyny (876) 5 0% 6. Stratified polygyny (866) 56% Four hypotheses link the items in this scale: Hypothesis I . The residential autonomy of co-wives (from one another and from the husband, with the most elaborate form in contiguous polygynous compounds) predicts a polygyny pattern with a negative binomial distribution, in which the addition of each wife increases the likelihood of the acquisition of another. This is presumably because added co-wives augment wealth, facilitate the acquisition of other wives, and in doing so enhance their own material well-being and the chances of their progeny's success. Hypothesis 2. If the first hypothesis is true, then the negative binomial distribution of wives (indicating greater social differentiation among polygynists) should predict a ranking of polygynists by wealth, since ( I )additional co-wives will augment wealth and ( 2 ) there is a biological incentive for women to increase fitness by marriage to men who are or have the potential to be wealthy. Hypothesis 3 . If the above hypotheses are true, then the residential autonomy of co-wives should also predict higher rates of polygyny and cultural preferences for all or most men to seek plural wives. Hypothesis 4. If the above hypotheses are true, then each of the variables in this complex (autonomous residence, prevalent norms and frequencies of polygyny, the negative binomial distribution of polygyny, and wealth stratification of polygynists) should be correlated with higher female contribution to wealth, including subsistence. polygyny Residence 6 Compound 5 Husband apart 4 Wife apart Polygyny 3Prevalentpolygyny 2 Negative binomial I Stratified polygyny Residence I 2 3 4 5 6 .22 .23 .26 .53 .51 .53 .54 .53 .57 .67 .85 - .77 - - .24 .14 - .53 - - - - - Table 3 shows correlational tests in matrix form of the first three hypotheses. For Hypothesis I, the phi correlations between three measures of residential autonomy and the negative binomial distribution are .53, .5 I, and .5 3. For Hypothesis 2, the correlation between the negative binomial distribution and stratified polygyny is .14. For Hypothesis 3, the correlations between three measures of residential autonomy and the prevalence of polygyny are .54, .5 3, and .5 7 All these correlations are statistically significant (p < .oI).For Hypothesis 4, table 4 shows the correlation between the six items of the scale and female contribution to subsistence. Each of the traits in the cluster varies moderately but concomitantly with female contribution to subsistence. We should also expect the scale itself to be associated with relative subsistence autonomy of co-wives. The Guttman scale constructed from these items (table 5 ) is linearly related to female contribution to subsistence (r = 26; p < .oI). The interpretation that the items of this scale index a wealth-increasing polygyny complex is strongly supported. In general, the pattern is more common in the Old World, with more elaborate forms in Africa. Its most elaborate feature is the polygynous compound, found mostly in the African savannahs, the Sahel, and the Ethiopian highlands but also in northeastern Africa, 4 Correlation between Scale Items in Wealth-Increasing Polygyny and Female Contribution to Subsistence TABLE Female Contribution Scale Item Stratified polygyny Negative binomial 3 Prevalent polygyny 4 Wife apart 5 Husband apart 6 Compound I 2 Correlation 1% ) 0-2 3 4 5 6-8 .24 .29 .29 34 43 16 I4 9 58 40 .21 12 55 30 16 I9 I4 15 64 63 42 36 30 32 89 67 54 61 38 33 .2S .22 22 25 24 I9 Type of Relation Linear Linear Linear Linear Linear Linear 550 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY TABLE Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 5 Correlation between Wealth-IncreasingPolygyny Scale and Female Contribution to Subsistence Female Contribution ( % ) Guttman Scale 0-2 3 4 5 6-8 Mean S.D. N 0 I 2-3 4-6 Total among societies of the Cushitic and Chadic Afro-Asiatic actually aloof from one another, however, is still a matlanguage families and the Nubians of Chari-Nile. The ter of interpretation and may reflect a Eurocentric view compound entails the second feature, separate habita- of African polygyny, although Whiting and Whiting tion for the husband, which is also found in a number of (1975) show that sleeping apart is also correlated with Oceanic societies but without polygynous compounds eating apart and husbands' not attending childbirth or because of the presence there of men's houses. Separate helping with child care. habitation for the husband entails the same for the wife, The wealth-increasing polygyny complex thus indexes the more widespread third feature of the scale. This in the addition of polygynous wives to the ranks of the turn entails the fourth feature, a prevalent male prefer- wealthy, who take women to increase their human capience for polygyny, normally attained by older men. Such tal. These are not additional "de~endents"in the modgeneralized polygyny is also found in Australia and the ern sense, as they may add to wealth and productivity. New World-notably in the Plains-and a few Circum- With stratification and a long tail on the distribution of Caribbean ~ o c i e t i e sIt. ~entails the fifth feature, a direct the number of wives, co-wives gain autonomy from their association between taking another wife and the likeli- husbands that may be augmented by the husband's havhood of taking yet another (the negative binomial distri- ing a separate habitation. Without autonomous female bution of polygyny). The extended tail on the distribu- productivity, however, such expanding polygynous systion of number of wives (indexing social differentiation tems are im~ossibleto maintain. Where thev exist, such among polygynists) in turn entails the sixth feature. Ap- engines of &oductivity and stratification db indekd bepropriately, this feature is stratification of polygynous come the ideal pattern sought by the majority of males, marriages, or greater frequency of polygyny among men and women's bargaining position is strong. The African polygynous compound is typically an industrious conof wealth, rank, nobility, or higher social class. The higher levels of this scale indicate co-wife resi- sortium of highly productive and autonomous co-wives. The capture of wives is strongly associated with the dential autonomy (residential separation of husbands, wives, and co-wives from each other). This fits Whiting wealth-increasing polygyny complex, as hypothesized and Whiting's (1975) conceptualization of polygynous by Whiting and Whiting (1975).As a scale item, wife husband-wife aloofness and Schneider's ( I 979) concep- capture (found in 37% of the sample) would fit between tion of the house-property complex in which wives Items A and < of the scale. It has been excluded for two , colonial pacification inhibits "conduct their own production operation, passing the reasons. ~ i r s ihistorically, proceeds to their sons." Whether husbands and wives are warfare and wife capture, and while rates of polygyny often fall subsequently they are often maintained, especially where conditions favor extensive coo~erativefe6. The Saramacca or "Bush Negroes" were ex-slaves who set up a male labor and males are engaged in wage laior. Second, society in the interior of Dutch Guiana. The Goajiro show obvious African influences, including an extensive black-market trade in the marriage of captive women has a different relation(curvilinear instead of linear] to female subsistence the Caribbean, and are the only "Indian" cattle herders in South s h i ~ America. The Caribs were driven from 13 of the Lesser Antilles by coit;ibution than the other iteAs in the scale and the the end of the 17th century, with bastions remaining in St. Vincent correlation between marriage of captive women and and Dominica. The arrival of shipwrecked Negro slaves on St. Vin- rates of polygyny goes from near zero to positive with incent ca. 1675 and possibly on neighboring islands as early as 1632 (Steggerda 1g48:107] led to intermarriage with the Indians. The creasing female contribution. intermarried population of Negroes and Island Caribs was moved to a reservation in Dominica at the end of the 19th century (Rouse 1948:548) The 1675 focal date for the Callinago falls in the middle of the period from 1650 to 1700 when missionaries and other observers provided the basis for the historic ethnographic description and is well after the earliest date of 1632 suggested for the beginnings of intermarriage. See White (1986)for sources. SORORAL POLYGYNY Five items form a cumulative Guttman scale that can be labeled "male-ranked polygyny with wife's kin as cowives" or more simply "sororal polygyny." The features WHITE Rethinking Polygyny I 5 5 I TABLE 6 Correlation between Scale Items in Sororal Polygyny and Female Contribution to Subsistence Female Contribution ( % ) Correlation Scale Item 5 Husband-wives together 4 Co-wives together - .29 -.I2 3a Shamans 3 Sororal Hunters I Exclusively sororal -.II NOTE: Frequencies .OI -.16 .12 0-2 93 40 15 19 [23] 2 3 4 5 6-8 86 1511 1191 33 14 0 76 35 66 23 6 16 3 3 54 33 10 1381 10 1131 o [33] [zo] 1161 Type of Relation Linear Curvilinear Curvilinear Bimodal Bimodal Bimodal Intercorrelation Matrix .28 .19 .IS .zo .IZ .23 .47 .29 .26 .18 .08 .oo .29 .40 .31 in brackets are those that do not fit a monotonic ally decreasing or increasing pattern either for rows or for columns. support the additional wife. Traits in this cluster will be expected not to vary positively with the percentage of female contribution to subsistence. Hypothesis 5 is supported by a correlation of r = .22 between the true binomial distribution for wives and husband-wife coresidence (but gamma = .88; there are only two exceptions to the first part of the hypothesis). For cases in which husband and at least one wife 3a. Polygynous shamans (869) 12% coreside, Hypothesis 6 is weakly supported by correlaThe taking of second wives by shamans is an auxiliary tions (r = .I 5, .12) between co-wife coresidence and low element in this cluster that entails co-wives' sharing a female contributions to subsistence or male-dominated dwelling (i.e., entailing Scale Items 4-5 but not 1-3). types of subsistence (hunting, fishing, pastoralism, permanent agriculture), and Hypothesis 7 is supported by Four hypotheses link the items in this scale: Hypothesis 5. Where the husband must generate the the correlation (r = .28) between sororal polygyny and wealth (indexed by the true binomial distribution of multiple wives for skilled hunters. Hypothesis 8 is number of wives) to support one or more wives, husband strongly supported by the data (tables 6 and 7).As might and wife (orwives) will coreside. Conversely, where hus- be expected, the features of this second scale are negaband and wife coreside, the wife is usually insufficiently tively related to those of the first. Items of this scale support an interpretion of maleautonomous in terms of generating her own wealth to reside independently. If so, then where husband and at dependent polygyny quite different from the resourceleast one wife are coresident, nonsororal co-wives are in defense polygyny of other species in which females have competition either over household resources or, if in dif- independent territories within a larger male territory. ferent households, over the division of the husband's The sororal polygyny pattern is most common among food collectors (especially hunters) of the New World. time among them. Hypothesis 6. With potential competition between The most elaborate feature is exclusive "sororal" polygnonsororal co-wives (i.e.,where the husband dwells with yny, or secondary marriage to wife's kin. This feature one or more wife), co-wives will tend to dwell apart from entails exceptional hunters' taking second wives, rarely one another where women contribute at least as much more than two. This in turn entails at least predominant to subsistence as men (e.g.,in gathering or shifting culti- "sorwal" polygyny, which entails that co-wives occupy vation) and to dwell together where women contribute the same dwelling. Occupancy of the same dwelling by less to subsistence than men (e.g., in hunting, perma- co-wives in turn entails that husband and wife or wives nent cultivation, and pastoralism) or where polygynous share a dwelling. The sororal pattern is most frequent in wives depend on an occupational specialization of the areas with elaborate food-collecting technologies, usually on rich resource bases, such as in Paleo-Siberia husband such as shamanism. Hypothesis 7. Where co-wives are in potential compe- (Gilyak-fishing), on the Northwest Coast (Kaskatition (as above) and women contribute less than men to fishing), in the northern Plains and the Southwest (Pawsubsistence and co-wives coreside, the predominant nee, Omaha, Chiricahua-buffalo and agriculture), and form of polygyny (if any) will be sororal. This will be the occasionally in the tropical savannah of South America case where polygynous wives depend on a male-domi- (Trumai).In these cases, social relations are dominated by warfare/hunting/shamanic patterns and close relanated subsistence mode such as hunting. Hypothesis 8. In the sororal polygyny complex, the tionships between wives' families and their husbands. requirements are mostly on the husband to attract and Among the buffalo-hunting, warring, and agricultural of this scale and their frequencies are as follows: 6% I . Exclusively wife's kin as co-wives (862) 2. Polygynous hunters (867) I 3% 3. Wife's kin as co-wives or sororal polygyny (862) 28% 4. Co-wives same dwelling (863) 38% 5. Husband and wife coresident (865) 79% 552 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY TABLE Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 7 Correlation between Sororal Polygyny Scale and Female Contribution to Subsistence Female Contribution ( % ) Guttman Scale 0-2 3 4 5 6-8 Mean S.D. N 0 I 2-3 4-5 Total Pawnee, for example, the incidence of polygyny, while nearly exclusively sororal, reached something like 5 5% for men and 75% for women. A good hunter/warrior might lay claim to a family of sisters whose cooperative activity in agriculture and hide preparation was of great value. This case, however, illustrates a feature of this pattern that ties it in with the first: the extremes of this type, including those that are exclusively sororal, nearly always entail wealth or rank stratification among polygynists. None of the extreme cases are simple hunters: they are mostly hunter/traders, often with horses, in the extractive peripheries of the world economy. Thus, from intensive hunter-gatherers through the mid-range of food producers, polygyny is again involved in strategies of resource intensification. It is some form of rank or stratification-skill, wealth, or position-that connects the two variant patterns of polygyny. The differences between Old World and New may reflect different dominant types of subsistence regimes (food production vs. collection). The Old World pattern of co-wife autonomy, bridewealth, and marriage of war captives shows strong intersocietal flows of women and wealth in large regions that are almost certainly long-term ecological adaptations to savannah agriculture, the cattle complex, and other features (White and Burton 1988). For hunters and fishers in the New World the pattern is that of limited polygyny dependent on the exceptional productivity of certain men; rarely do co-wives generate substantial wealth. The two polygyny scales are thus differentiated in terms of both male and female roles. The basis of female differentiation is relative autonomy in the one case and assistance from female relatives in the other; the alternative bases of male differentiation are ascribed stratification (often hereditary and/or class-based) and/or wealth (often generated by co-wives) as opposed to achieved male rank (lacking the differential access to resources typical of stratified systems). Maps of the distributions of these features are more informative than cross-tabulation by region (figs. I and 7 2.' 7. Maps of individual features are readily generated by the MAPTAB program published through World Cultures. OTHER CLUSTERS The linking of stratification with polygyny seen in these two complexes is also manifest in the distribution of societies in which political leaders take multiple wives. This pattern is found, sporadically, in West, East, North, and South Africa, the Middle East, Southeast Asia, Melanesia, Polynesia, Australia, and North and South America. These societies also usually show stratification of polygyny by wealth, rank, or class. Polygynous leadership also shows weak associations with other features: negative with exclusive sororal polygyny, as befits the nonsororal nature of most political alliances, and positive with marriage or concubinage of captives. Extreme stratification of polygyny is not an extension of the wealth-increasing pattern. The standard sample is not particularly long on representation of elite groups in premodern states or empires, where polygyny is often a means of extending and stabilizing political alliances. Betzig (1986),however, analyzed all 106 societies in the sample that were de facto or politically autonomous at the pinpoint date to test the hypothesis that despotic groups have greater reproductive success via harem polygyny. She identified 14 "despotic" societies, defined as societies in which "conflicts of interest among individuals are resolved with extreme bias, one individual being immune from sanction . . . while the other may incur severe punishment . . . for trivial offenses or no reason at all." Of these, 8 (Ganda, Fon, Ashanti, Azande, Khmer, Mbau Fijians, Aztec, and Inca) had a maximal harem size in excess of 1 0 0 ~ (Bemba, 4 Kafa, Samoans, and Natchez) a maximum of 11-99, and 2 (Lozi, Fur) an unspecified large number. None had harems smaller than 10. The complex of traits identified with large harems (Betzig I 9862-3, I 35-36) includes despotic rule (exercised rights by the heads of societies to murder their subjects arbitrarily and with impunity, but particularly in the capacity of conflict resolution) and exploitative perquisites (the exploitation of positions in the jurisdictional hierarchy in the form of bribes, fees, fines, and confiscations in connection with conflict resolutionl. There is no correlation between this complex and eithe; of the other two complexes above. Seven of Betzig's despotic societies (Bemba, Khmer, Mbau, Samoans, Natchez, Aztec, w H I T E Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 5 3 F I G . I . World distribution of scale values of male-stratified polygyny with autonomous co-wives. Each code entails that all or most of the lower-numbered features on the scale are also present. Dots of decreasing size, polygynous compounds; husband has separate habitation; wife has separate habitation; prevalent polygyny; negative binomial hstribution; stratified polygyny; -, none of the above. 554 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 Inca) are associated with low levels of co-wife autonomy or wealth-increasing polygyny (0-1 on Code 18) and 7 (Lozi, Ganda, Fon, Ashanti, Azande, Fur, Kafa) with high levels (6 on Code 18). Dickemann's (1979)investigation of polygyny in caste societies shows fertility strategies that allow the highest groups to prevent downward marriage of their women and investment strategies of somewhat lower groups to foster upward (hypergamous)marriages. These systems are often associated with dowry. These societies are not well represented in the standard sample and require separate study. In three cases in the standard sample, polygyny is specifically described by the ethnographer as wealthdepleting. Among Basseri pastoralists, the limited polygynous marriages of wealthy herd owners, with additional labor needs. "extend a man's fecunditv in a wav that saps his wealth" (Barth 1961:1o7). The ~ a s k a , hunter-gatherers and salmon fishermen, had "no limit to the number of wives so long as you can support them, but of late years . . . there are very few with more than one wife" (P. Field, MS, Ross River, Feb. 8, 1911, Peabody Museum, New Haven). Parents-in-law showed particular possessiveness about a man renowned as a hunter, and poor hunters were often polyandrous, needing to team up with another man (Honigmann 1954: 132-33). The agricultural Mapuche had prevalent polygyny through the mid-19th century, but polygyny declined with land scarcity, as wives required their own garden plots. Agricultural production became insufficient to acquire bride price. The total incidence of polygyny for males is estimated at 7% for the Basseri, 2% for the Kaska, and 6% for the Mapuche. Although it may be a valued ideal for men in some of these cases, the incidence of polygyny is low in comparison with that in many of the societies in the wealth-increasing complex. The Saramacca (Price 1984) are a fascinating intermediate case in which there are elements of both wealth-increasing and wealth-decreasing polygyny. Throughout this century, boys have been taken by their fathers at the age of eight or ten to work for wages on the coast, leaving an extreme shortage of men in the villages. Girls marry early, and polygyny is very common, although each co-wife sets up her own independent and self-supporting household. Once divorced or widowed at middle ages, women's opportunities for remarriage are very constrained. Wives are significantly more dependent on men (especially for benefits of wage labor) than the men are dependent on them. Jealousy and hostility are rife among co-wives, although they live apart. Although only men of position and relative wealth can afford multiple wives, a majority of the men who return from wage labor have sufficient means to support polygynous marriages. Reliabilities of the Codes The assumption in Code I of a greater frequency of polygyny associated with stratification (Category 4) than 8 Relationship between Frequencies and Cultural Rules Governing Frequency of Polygyny TABLE Percentage of Polygyny Men Cultural Rule Monogamy Exceptional polygyny Limited polygyny Class polygyny Prevalent polygyny Mean Women S.D. 0.0 4.2 7.3 15.5 43.2 Mean S.D. N 9.1 14.8 18.0 17.9 25 35 45 30 45 0.0 5.1 8.1 10.8 17.0 8.1 15.7 27.4 64.7 with exceptional characteristics of individual men (e.g., leadership, shamanism, hunting skills) is one that can be tested empirically against the percentage frequency variables (Codes 12 and 13). Table 8 shows the mean percentage of polygyny for married men and women, respectively, in each of the five categories of the code. The ordering of frequencies is monotonically increasing, and the differences at each step are sufficient to justify the distinctions. Starting with exceptional polygyny, the frequency of polygyny (either for men or women) nearly doubles with each step in the cultural-rules code. The code, however, is in several respects not unidimensional. Stratified and gerontocratic polygyny (Categories 4 and 5 ) are conceptually independent, and each might best be measured by a separate scalee8Neither conceptual nor temporal or evolutionary progression from limited to stratified to prevalent polygyny is implied. To estimate the intercoder reliability of the new polygyny codes in comparison with previous ones, four codes were trichotomized using the following categories : I = No polygyny = Limited polygyny, <2o% for married males 3 = Full polygyny, 20% or greater for married males The four codes were Code (codedby me), Murdock and Wilson's (1972)polygyny variable (World Cultures Variable 79, coded by Wilson); Murdock's (1967) Ethnographic Atlas polygyny variable (World Cultures Variables 21 I and 212); and Whyte's (1978)polygyny variable (World Cultures Variables 606 and 607, with Category I defined as "monogamy preferred and multiple spouses not allowed"). My Code I, while not strictly comparable, was also recoded as follows: I = No polygyny (Category I ) = Exceptional, limited, or class-specific polygyny (Categories 2-4) 3 = Prevalent polygyny (Category 5 ) In table 9 these five codes are labeled A through E. Pear8. Stratified and gerontocratic polygyny are, however, not empirically independent, in the sense that polygyny is not likely to be gerontocratic when polygyny is practiced within a particular social class unless that class is also endogamous or castelike. WHITE Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 5 5 TABLE 9 Reliabilities of Polygyny Codes Percentage of Agreement Code A B C A Code B Murdock and Wilson (1972) .88 C Ethnographic Atlas (1967) 37 97 91 .81 95 91 91 91 - .90 .82 .79 D E Average Adjusted E Adjusted Average D Whyte (1978) E Code I Pearson Correlation intercode agreement for Categories I vs. and 3; lower, intercode agreement for Categories I and 2 vs. 3. "Average" is average percentage of agreement of each code with the four others; "adjusted E" is computed by dividing the preceding E scores by 98% and 93% (the maximum possible agreement between E and the other codes), and "adjusted average" reflects this adjustment. NOTE: Upper percentage, son correlations in the lower diagonal indicate the pattern of reliabilities among the three-point scales. A is more strongly correlated with B and C than they are with one another. E, while conceptually different, is about equally correlated with B and C as they are with one another. The new codes A and E appear highly reliable by all measures. A more fine-grained indication of the reliabilities of these codes is given in the pair of percentages above the diagonal in table 9 for each pair of variables-the intercode agreement for Categories I vs, 2 and 3 and Categories I and 2 vs. 3. (The same definitions are used for A, B, and C while D differs modestly in the operational instructions for identifying monogamy [no multiple spouses allowed].) E defines Category 3 differently, on the basis of a generalized ideal of polygyny for all men, usually attained with age, rather than an arbitrary 20% cutoff for polygynously married men. The agreement between A and El differing only on this distinction, is 93%. This is the upper,limit of the reliability of E with B, C, and D. E also defines Categories I and differently by ignoring polyandry, which is lumped with Category I in the other scales. The agreement between A and E on monogamy vs, polygyny is 98%. The Toda and Marquesans, with polyandry, are treated in Category I of A, but with exceptional cases of polygyny they fall in Category 2 of E. The highest reliabilities are achieved by A (90-95%), followed by E (89-95%)) then B (89-92%), C (87-89%), and D (83-86%). The lower reliabilities of C are probably due to minor differences in pinpointing and those of D, coded on the pinpointed societies and dates, to the somewhat lower ethnographic familiarity of the coders. The percentage of agreement on sororal versus nonsororal polygyny (Code 3) versus the Ethnographic Atlas (World Cultures Variables 210 and 211) for 65 cases coded in the Atlas as having full polygyny is 92% (r = .82). To evaluate the reliabilities of the codes for husband and wife habitations, which are closely related empirically, six codes from three distinct sets of coders were constructed and correlated. One set deals with whether the husband and one or more wives reside in the same room or the husband has a separate room or dwelling: my Code 6, an independent coding by Barry and Paxson (1971)) recoded from World Cultures Variable 23, and my Code 4. A second set deals with whether the "typical" wife has a room with or separate from the husband: Code 5, from Whiting and Whiting (1975). The third deals with whether co-wives reside in the same or different rooms or quarters: Code 4 codes this distinction together with whether a single wife resides together or apart from the husband. Murdock's Atlas codes this distinction where over 20% of the males are polygynous. The reliabilities cluster as expected (table IO), with 9 I-97% agreement and correlations between .74 and .g I for separate habitation for husband (F, G, H), separate habitation for wives agreeing 87-92% with this cluster (r = .70-.81), and 94% agreement (r = .88) for the two measures of co-wife separation (J, K). These findings show co-wife separation variables (J, K) to be poor indicators of husband or wife separation (F-I). They also suggest that the recoding in H of the co-wife separation Code 4 is not a strong surrogate for the direct measure of separate habitation for the husband. Whiting and Whiting (1975:185-87) rated societies for husband-wife habitations and noted 92% agreement with Barry and Paxson (1971) in 76 societies rated in both studies. Combining their scores with those of Barry and Paxson resulted in a sample of 159. There is 97% 556 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 TABLE I 0 Reliabilities of Wife and Husband Habitation Codes Percentage of Agreement Code F Code 6 GBarryandPaxson(1971) H Code 4 (0-4 vs. 5 and 6) I Code 5 J Code 4 (0-2 vs. 3-6) KAtlas (Murdock 1967) F G H I J K .91 .85 .81 .54 .45 97 .74 .79 .53 .49 95 91 .70 .57 .58 93 92 87 .61 .54 75 75 75 79 .88 71 74 83 77 94 - Pearson Correlation agreement between the Whitings' codes and the present ratings9 Additional correlations among selected polygyny codes are shown in table I I. E x c e ~ for t correlations between a composite scale and two items used to construct 9. Discrepancies between the Whiting and Whiting (1975)roomingarrangements variables and the present habitation code can also be checked against Barry and Paxson (1971) and Atlas codes. I disagree with both the Whitings and the Barry and Paxson codes in three cases. First, husband and wife occupy opposite sides of the same room in the Alorese lineage house, but separate households are established by the Alorese for plural wives. The Whitings did not code this case as "polygynous wives room apart," since they computed the rate of polygyny for married women as 22%. Du Bois (1944:97), however, indicates 93 married men, 2 5 of whom have second wives, thus a 50/118 = 42% polygyny rate for women (the Whitings seem to have used the male polygyny rate). Thus, I code 5 as "wife rooms apart" and 6 as "husband has no room apart," which also differs from Barry and Paxson's coding of sleeping arrangements as "mother and father in the same room." Second, the Whitings and Barry and Paxson code the Mundurucu in 1850 as having separate habitations for husbands and wives, which is a later pattern, perhaps because they missed that the men's houses at that date were only for unmarried males. Within the longhouse, at that time, families had partitioned quarters. Third, the Whitings and Barry and Paxson follow Chagnon (1983) in coding the Yanomamo as "husband and wife occupying the same dwelling," but Chagnon's data are not specific in this regard. Analysis of Smole's (1976) data shows that while classificatory sororal polygyny is common, men usually build separate dwellings within the shabono for adult second wives, although not for their secondary "child" wives. In six cases (Songhai, Shilluk, Gheg, Tanala, Chukchee, and Pomo), my codes agree with the Whitings', contra Barry and Paxson's. The Songhai are an interesting exception to the co-wife autonomy Guttman scale in that they have low rates of polygyny but the African compound pattern. By the definition of Code 5, I agree with the Whitings that this does not register as separate habitations for wives. According to Whiting and Whiting et al.'s unpublished data, the Pomo and Gheg have men's houses. In two cases (Manus and Lepcha) the Whitings appear to be wrong and Barry and Paxson correct. Polygyny is unusual in Manus, where a married man ceases to sleep in the men's house, sleeping on the opposite side of the longhouse from his wife but not in a separate room. This is a judgment call, however, since the Manus husband keeps his distance from the wife. In a comparable case, for the Jivaro, where husband and wife reside at opposite ends of the longhouse (presumably at an even further "distance"), all of the independent coders-myself, the Whitings, and Barry and Paxson-coded "wife rooms apart." the scale, shown in brackets, the highest correlations are above the line, among independent measures of polygyny. Within this set, the highest is between the percentage measures of polygyny. Of these, it is the percentage of polygynous married females that correlates best with other measures of polygyny, among them, in order of strength of correlation, the new Codes I, z, 17, and 18 and Murdock's original Atlas code. Among the other features of polygyny, shown below the line, stratified polygyny shows the highest correlations with the new Codes I and z and Murdock's Atlas code. Separate habitation for the husband shows the strongest correlations with the negative binomial distribution and the percentage measures. Wheeler's (1974) ratings of warfare for plunder or the capture of women and/or slaves (World Cultures Variable 895) provide a reliability check on the present ratings of marriage of women captured through warfare. There are only 5% exceptions to the expected entailment relationship: in societies with marriage of women captives (50 cases), warfare for plunder will be present (43 cases; 7 exceptions).The converse is not expected to be true. Thus, not all societies with warfare for plunder (77 cases) marry female war captives (43 do; 44 do not). The phi correlation of .36 is relatively low because of cases with plunder lacking marriage to women captives. Finally, the reliability of temporal inferences regarding polygyny is indicated by a correlation of r = .97 between the pinpointing dates for each society and the dates of the polygyny census materials (table 12). Findings and Discussion The purpose here has been to rethink the knowledge base from which anthropology makes and tests its generalizations and to reconceptualize and test various theories about the dimensions of polygyny. At the same time it shows the compatibility of alternative theories. The hypotheses and results of this paper confirm, in sharper detail, a number of things ethnographers have long known about polygyny that have been somewhat obscured by comparative studies using Murdock's polygyny codes. World regions differ markedly in type of polygyny, revealing major world-historical and ecological patterns. The notion of "macroculture" helps to conceptualize the anthropologist's knowledge about the wider areal distributions of cultural institutions. It is not helpful to try to classify whole societies into culture areas on the basis of a totality of features, as was once attempted for material culture as a basis for museum collections. But it is clearly of major importance to examine the differing areal distributions of features in institutional complexes and ascertain the relationship of these distributions to ecology (climate, natural resources, production systems, and other patterns), intersocietal trade and conflict systems, and processes of diffusion. The determination of these and related regional patterns constitutes study of macroculture. w H I T E Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 5 7 TABLE I I Correlations among Major Polygyny Codes Cultural basis of polygyny Revised Atlas-Whyte code - Original Atlas code I 3 % female polygyny 12 % male polygyny I 7 Negative binomial I 8 Autonomous co-wives scale .88 .80 .81 .76 .65 .73 .86 .78 .72 .64 .70 7 Stratified polygyny Captives as wives 6 Separate husband habitation 9 Leaders polygynous .60 .47 .43 .35 .54 .46 .43 '3 5 I 2 II .70 .65 .65 .65 .97 .76 .7I -.69 .68 .74 - - - - .49 .41 .40 .3I .38 .38 .S 1 .26 ,35 .38 .47 .23 .38 .5 5 .I4 .52 1.751 1.691 .30 .36 .22 .4I .35 .3I .09 - TABLE I 2 Decade of Polygyny Census Relative t o Pinpoint Date Relative Decade Frequency Society Number 105 5, 19, 28, 36, 139, 178 26, 41, 79 3, 34, 35, 110, I49 6, 16, 48, 137, 158, 169 11, 67, 99, 109, 150, 176 all not elsewhere listed 21, 77, 96, 97, 100, 121, 168, 174, 184 40, 43, 76, 84 95,185 151 The two major complexes revealed in the present study and several smaller ones match very closely the anthropological knowledge base about polygyny. Com~ a r a t i v estudies that illuminate rather than obscure regional patterns and differences clearly can play a major role in translating anthropological knowledge bases into a form that can be more widely utilized. Coded variables and areal distributions offer the possibility for testing hypotheses using statistical methods and for relating anthropological findings to those of related disciplines. While peoples at the food-collecting level in the New World have largely been displaced and despotic harems leveled, the Old World pattern of wealth-increasing polygyny is still intact. That this complex in particular should have survived is no accident, as its wealthgenerating properties at the extended-household level have made it an economically viable production system-a point that is often lost in contemporary development planning. At the time that these societies had de .20 facto or political autonomy, women were captured in warfare and taken as wives because of their economic value. With loss of autonomy and indigenous patterns of warfare, polygyny did not disappear in those areas where co-wives contributed to wealth. However, systems of wealth-increasing polygyny are likely to be undermined with the loss of new lands for expansion. Thus, this cultural pattern is important in understanding ecological adaptations and development processes in the Third World. The wealth-increasing Dattern is found in its fullest elaboration in sub-~ah&anAfrica and outliers such as the creolized cattle-keeping Goajiro of the Caribbean. Hypotheses about the relationships implicated in this complex have been strongly supported: co-wife residential autonomy predicts that polygynous wives generate wealth, that there is wealth differentiation among polygynists, that polygyny is more likely to become a preference of most men (and, by further implication, most women). What has been least well known to date is how warfare patterns, particularly marriage or concubinage of female captives, and negative binomial (long-tailed)distributions of the number of wives are part of a generic substratum from which the other features in this pattern emerge. The areal clustering of this polygyny complex has rather obvious macrocultural aspects. The area includes African settled savannah agriculture and pastoralism, or the cattle complex. Not coincident with the Bantu language family or Bantoid phylum, it excludes the tropical forest as well as the desert nomads, or the camel com~ l e x It . corres~ondsto the classic bridewealth area, in which wives flow between groups with counterflows of cattle. Cattle typically flow from cattle-rich areas, helping to prevent overgrazing and tending to equalize wealth differences among the most pastoral societies while contributing to wealth stratification among the agricultural societies, where co-wives form highly productive units (Schneider I 979, Turton I 980). Wives flowing to cattle-rich areas assist in the pastoral division 558 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 of labor but cannot provide the levels of productivity of women seen in the societies in which women contribute agricultural labor. A second major process of convection for both women (through the marriage of captives) and cattle, based not on exchange but on direct expropriation, operates through raiding and warfare. Reflections of the general pattern are found in the CircumCaribbean, most fully among the Goajiro but to a lesser extent in other societies. The complex of wealth-increasing polygyny supports the plausibility of functional explanations of Whiting and Whiting (1975)and others who stress the separation of habitations in general polygyny and its possible association with fraternal interest groups, capital goods, male warriors, military glory, hyperaggressive males and the child-training patterns that produce them, male initiation, the capture of wives or concubines in warfare, and tendencies for older and wealthier males to monopolize marriage ties. The present database provides a more concise and comprehensive set of variables for the testing of such hypotheses, some of which has been done by White and Burton (1988). The second pattern, sororal polygyny, is found in hunting societies of the Plains, the Northwest Coast (Kaska), and the South American savannahs (and to a lesser extent the Kalahari) in conjunction with shamanism or exceptional hunting abilities. The more generic "predominantly sororal" pattern expands to contiguous areas in the Americas, southernmost and outlier Oceania, and Tibeto-Burma. The ecological or macrocultural aspects of this pattern are less well understood. However, in the nomadic societies that are typically shamanic and food collectors, it has been noted that sisters assist one another in packing and unpacking for moves and setting up temporary houses. The coresident pattern is an excellent one for defensive reasons. Chiricahua cowives, for example, were coresident in time of war but separately housed in time of peace. While the historical-ecological aspects of polygyny are emphasized here, it is not at all unlikely that, in further analysis of these distributions, additional functional explanations for variation in type and rates of polygyny may be found. Comparative research has come a long way from the days when Murdock, justifiably wary of problems raised by Galton of artificial inflation of correlations due to common historical origin and diffusion, declared that it was possible to use cross-cultural methods of testing functional hypotheses only when historical effects had been culled from world samples by careful selection of "independent" cases or when the phenomena under study showed a great number of widely distributed independent inventions. Polygyny is not a single syndrome but is produced by diverse strategies under a range of different conditions and comprises different systems of meaning and function. Although a great diversity of specific marriage arrangements may give rise to polygyny (ability to take second wives on the part of leaders, shamans, hunters, nobles, wealthy menj taking a second wife because of widow inheritance, levirate, wife capture, sororate, barrenness, bride price, male mortality, fluctuations in the sex ratio, male labor emigration, etc.; allowing a co-wife because of postpartum sex taboos, economic assistance from co-wives, and so forth), the overall rates and distributions of polygyny are equally worthy of careful measurement and study. Measurements on this dimension allow us to transcend the older comparative notion that a practice is either present or absent to say more about its centrality to the cultural system. They also allow for the testing of multivariate models of contributions to the overall polygyny rate of a variety of demographic and cultural factors. To this end, in following Spencer's (1980) pioneering work on a much better quantitative database, it is remarkable that the present effort is nonetheless relatively successful in extracting from particular ethnographies estimates, although varying in precision, of the percentage of married males and married females polygynously married and the distribution of the numbers of wives. Ideally, these efforts may lay the base for further investigations and a deeper understanding of the forces shaping social and cultural practice. Reopening some of the issues in the study of human polygyny calls attention to some unfinished business. There remains a need to examine polygyny from a female-oriented perspective as well as the male-oriented one that has dominated such interpretations to date. In exploring female incentives to polygyny it will help to have at hand comparative codes on many of its multifarious aspects, only some of which are provided here. In reviewing the topic, and in the process of doing the coding, a number of other variables were discovered that might be pertinent to a more balanced view of polygyny. Having data on many types or aspects of polygyny may also prove advantageous in testing other hypotheses about the different types of polygyny and determining whether they are responsive to some of the same effects or generate the same consequences. These multivariate problems, in a large sample, can be explored by subjecting hypotheses to multiple tests using regional replications to try to disconfirm recurrent relationships. The problem of representation, modeling, and testing of complex data and hypotheses dealing with multifarious institutions such as polygyny also requires recognition of the fact that there is no sharp division between external factors and internal strategies that shape sociocultural phenomena. In the case of polygyny this is seen in the extent to which marriage choices reach out to involve intersocietal linkages and transactional flows of people and wealth (e.g., bridewealth and dowry), warfare and capture, group fission and expansive migration (White and Burton 1988). These flows operate in the context of larger historical systems to stratify a population in terms of wealth, power, and reproductive strategies. A historically sensitive representation of such phenomena consequently often requires not only multiple theories but multiple models and tests of multivariate hypotheses. w H I T E Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 59 Comments LAURA BETZIG Evolution and Human Behavior Program, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Mich. 48x09-1070, U.S.A. 22 IV 88 This paper is part of an imperative attempt, on the part of White and a few others, to make the comparative record on human societies accessible to tests of general theories about human social behavior. Though the vast majority of such tests have been done in single societies, the most general test of any general theory must be by the comparative, or Darwinian (Ghiselin 1969)~ method. The usual advantage in studying single societies is that richer data can be gathered on the question at hand. In this paper, in others, and in World Cultures, White is trying to enrich the data accessible from the comparative record. Richer data means data on historical, cultural, and ecological forces. As White points out, any complex human phenomenon, including polygyny, is bound to be determined by many different kinds of factors. Some of these will sort out regionally; some will correlate evenly across all culture areas (discussion in Dow 1987). The big problem will be, as it may always have been, distinguishing functional from diffusionist explanations. Regional associations may indicate two things: ( I )Historical factors may have overpowered present cultural and ecological constraints; this is the diffusionist model. ( 2 ) Similar local conditions may have favored similar local adaptations; this is the functional model. This problem is shared by biologists who try to determine whether common phylogenetic constraints or common social and ecological conditions are responsible for similarities among close taxonomic groups (e.g., Clutton-Brock and Harvey 1978). The models can be distinguished where specific factors likely to have produced regional effects, such as food extraction and consumption, are common across the region in question. Richer data means not just data on more causal variables but more and better definitions of variables to be explained. As White, again, points out, complex behaviors like polygyny can be defined in many different ways. Depending on whether the question at hand concerns, for example, its advantages and disadvantages for women (e.g., Borgerhoff Mulder n.d.), its association with male reproductive variance (e.g., Low 1 9 8 8 ~or) ~its correlation with dominance (e.g., Betzig 1986), different measures will be appropriate. White provides an unprecedented number of polygyny measures. It is likely, though, that people interested in polygyny, or any other variable, will have to generate codes of their own, sometimes on samples of their own. In my own study, I found that a completely different set of factors explained harem polygyny in politically autonomous traditional societies and in modern societies and their colonies (Betzig 1986).I also found that none of the existing codes on polygyny directly measured what I wanted to measurethe reproductive assets available to dominant men. Consequently, I limited my sample to politically autonomous societies and combed through the ethnographic record myself to measure polygyny as the number of women in dominant men's harems. Having congratulated White on doing what I think is the most important methodological job to be done in anthropology-improving the comparative record-I want to make a small critical point about his theory. Here and elsewhere, he has found that polygyny is more prevalent in societies in which women have more to offer the household economy. It is undoubtedly true that men find women more attractive-and more affordable-when they bring wealth with them, but, as White notes himself, it is just as true that women are attracted to wealthy men. That under these circumstances we find polygyny much more common than polyandry may be explained by biology. Along with the males of the vast majority of other species, men gain more reproductively from collecting a harem of women than women do from collecting a harem of men (e.g., Trivers 1972).It is exceedingly difficult to determine whether wives, or anybody else, are net economic assets or costs. It seems likely that men have evolved to like to collect wives but find it easier to collect them when they pay at least part of their own way. MONIQUE BORGERHOFF MULDER Evolution and Human Behavior Program, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Mich. 48x09-1070, U.S.A. 25 IV 88 White has two aims: to unravel the diverse marriage systems that are labelled "polygynous" and to determine the various contexts in which polygynous marriages occur. The new codes he develops are an extremely valuable contribution to anthropology, particularly insofar as they identify aspects of polygyny that are important to males and females, including means of recruitment, residential patterns, and links between stratification and marriage. Recognizing that there are many different kinds of polygyny can only improve the quality, resolution, and rigor of cross-cultural studies. Furthermore, it is reassuring to see the problems of coding so explicitly discussed: such practice should help to dispel some of the widespread mistrust among anthropologists of crosscultural codes. I question, however, White's emphasis on major regional complexes, in particular, "wealth-increasing" polygyny, most characteristic of African agriculturalists and pastoralists, and "sororal" polygyny, common among food collectors of the New World. Clearly such regional complexes of clustered features exist, but what do they tell us about the sources of behavioral diversity or the causes of different marriage patterns? Insofar as there are major dissimilarities within regional complexes and intriguing parallels between complexes, it 560 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 may be more useful to focus on the socio-ecological correlates of various aspects of polygyny than on the existence of regional types. I will use the apparent oddity of polygyny among Kenyan Kipsigis, which should fall into the "wealth-increasing" category but does not, to illustrate the distortions that can result from trying to fit specific cases into regional types. Although Kipsigis women make major contributions to maize production and animal husbandry, close ins ~ e c t i o nof data from the ~ o ~ u l a t i oI nstudied shows &at land and cattle (whethe; i h e r i t e d or independently acquired) are important determinants of a man's polygyny potential: ( I )marriage requires the payment of substantial bridewealth (a third of an average man's livestock holding [Borgerhoff Mulder 1988a1);( 2 )the number of a man's wives is correlated with the number of cattle he inherits (Borgerhoff Mulder 1988b), a quantity that is independent of his wives' productivity; (3)wealthy men can attract more wives (my interviews with parents revealed a preference for wealthy sons-in-law [Borgerhoff Mulder 1988~1);and, most important, (4)very little land has become available since Kipsigis settled as squatters on Maasai land in the 1940s because of interethnic tensions over cultivation rights (Manners 1967). In this particular case, then, it is difficult to see how a polygynist is likely to marry subsequent wives as a result of his current wives' productivity: cattle (for bridewealth) are acquired primarily through inheritance and raiding, and land (required for settling a wife) is simply not available (see Borgerhoff Mulder 1988d for further arguments). In short, White is right to point out that the costs, and hence incidence, of polygyny will vary between subsistence types (cf. Irons 1983) but wrong to assert (at least without auantitative datal that wives in some societies are a net iconomic benefit'and that this benefit accounts for the high levels of polygyny. More generally, I doubt whether the poor fit of the Kipsigis with White's African complex is unusual. Comparative studies of African family life suggest that economic autonomy, conflict, and cooperation among colLeVine wives varv markedlv, even within local regions " 1962)~ prikarily becyuse of sex differences in the'control of resources (Brabin 1984). White clearly recognizes this variability, which is central to the study by Spencer (1980) that he cites, but its significance is rather obscured by his focus on regional complexes; this is unfortunate, because carefully controlled cross-cultural comparisons within regions are often more valuable than global contrasts (Eggan I 9 5 4). An interesting parallel arises when we compare the polygyny of the Mapuche, New World agriculturalists, with that of the Kipsigis. With increasing land scarcity in both contexts, polygyny becomes costly because each wife demands an adequate-sized agricultural plot; wealth-increasing polygyny is likely to be undermined by the loss of new lands for expansion, whether in the New or the Old World. This parallel suggests the value of identifying the critical ecological and social factors that constrain changes in marriage practices in all parts of the world rather than focussing too narrowly on regional types. Finally, I think it is important to note that although hypergynous polygyny may not be well represented in the standard sample, upward mobility of women must characterize all systems in which the rich and powerful accumulate wives. GARRY CHICK Department of Leisure Studies, University of Illinois a t Urbana-Champaign, Champaign, 111. 61820, U.S.A. 19 IV 88 For some time the use of the cross-cultural comparative method in anthropology has been declining. Although articles using cross-cultural data and methods are occasionally published in Ethnology and the journal of the Society for Cross-Cultural Studies, Behavior Science Research, is published occasionally, cross-cultural psychology has usurped much of the domain, and reports appear in sociology journals from time to time as well. This paper is part of a revitalization of cross-cultural research in anthropology, led largely by a relatively small group including White and several of his colleagues at Irvine. There appear to be several reasons for anthropologists' decreasing use of cross-cultural comparative methods. One may be the recent paroxysm of phenomenology and/or hermeneutics and the concomitant abandonment of the search for cross-cultural patterns and regularities. While the rejection of positivism is justified in social science, what is not justified is the renunciation of techniques and data that, with care, can be utilized to good purpose in favor of epistemological standards that have their own problems, including the banality inherent in relativism and the paradoxes of reflexivity. Part of the problem may also stem from the competition among the several cross-cultural samples -(see Levinson and Malone 1980: I 6), including the World Ethnographic Sample (Murdock I 95 7), the Ethnographic Atlas (Murdock 1967)~the Standard Cross-Cultural Sample (Murdock and White 1969), and the Human Relations Area Files Probability Sample (Human Relations Area Files 1967, LagacC 1979). This competition may lead to unnecessary duplication of effort and to the observation by critics that sampling in cross-cultural research is largely haphazard and samples are selected so as to support the hypotheses of researchers. As indicated by Burton and White (1987)~existing samples underrepresent societies at the upper end of the cultural-complexity scale, and the development of a standardized sample would provide a valuable cumulative data base of separate studies having more than 900 variables. The major contribution of White's paper is to recode polygyny in a more useful and meaningful way, especially in emphasizing cultural rules that constrain the practice rather than arbitrary categories such as the 20%-or-more polygyny code of the Ethnographic Atlas. White's codes move toward a rapprochement with more WHITE Rethinking Polygyny I 561 interpretive paradigms in anthropological research while lineations and his established reputation for accuracy, maintaining a realist conception of the world that per- the codes presented in this article are building materials mits the comparison of cultures and provides a possible for the future. Indeed, they are likely to prove a lasting basis for understanding and explanation. As humans, we and valuable contribution independent of the empirical express ourselves in culture in a myriad of ways. An- and theoretical framework in which they are presented. thropologists must attempt to give some unifying acGood thing, because, in contrast to Murdock (who alcount of this if we are to do more than just catalog the ways bowed out gracefully when his data did not support various human ways of life. his hypotheses), White has engaged in a series of contrivCross-cultural comparative research using standard ances which suggest that he has contributed far more samples and variables is extremely cost-effective than building materials. The most embarrassing of these (though not necessarily inexpensive) when compared is his contention that "sons as warriors" defend their with comparative projects such as the Six Culture Study. mothers' (their fathers' mates') abilities to pass earned Further, White and his colleagues, among others, have wealth to them (the warriors) and this constitutes been developing statistical methods of ever greater wealth-increasing ' fraternal-defense polygyny, which sophistication that effectively deal with many of the contrasts with resource-defense polygyny and matecriticisms that have traditionally been leveled at cross- defense polygyny. It is true that warriors defend commucultural research. In particular, they have dealt with nity wealth and generic mothers (and females and males Galton's problem using spatial autocorrelation (see, e.g., of all description, including potential mates). At a groupDow et al. (19841)and approached the inference of cau- selection level this could be construed as a combination sality through multivariate models instead of the simple of resource-defense polygyny and mate-defense polygyny cross-tabulations of an earlier day. Of course, no meth- that is distinct from either of these forms alone. Howodological advances or improved coding schemes will ever, such a system would not lead to any kind of polygcompensate for information that is wrong in the first yny unless individual warriors converted their valor into place, but that problem is not unique to cross-cultural individually held resources (resources they could use to research. obtain mates) or mates were captured directly (e.g., Indeed, as I have suggested, some of the research para- Chagnon 1988).Either way, when wealth-increasing fradigms from which criticism of cross-cultural compara- ternal-defense polygyny gets down to cases, what's new? This theoretical muddle aside, White has committed a tive research is most likely to emerge, such as the various humanistic traditions, have their own interesting serious breach of the rules of empiricism. He has done a problems. Moreover, when a research tradition is re- cogent and admirable job of data exploration, which has jected because of the dogma that certain matters are in- resulted in the identification of interesting clusters (asexplicable, unresolvable, or unworthy of study, the vic- sociations), but after poking and pinching these clusters tors may feel smug about it, but somebody else is going he discusses his findings as tests of hypotheses. This is to take the rubric and run. like announcing a logic, after the fact, for having picked While it may be possible to criticize some of White's a winning lottery ticket. A less serious empirical faux pas is White's characteriinterpretations, it is clear that this new set of codes on polygyny represents an advance over previous codes and zation of my 1982 work as "unsuccessful" on the adds to the collection of variables available for research- grounds that Dickemann and Pospisil voted against it. ers working with the Standard Cross-Cultural Sample. Science is not a democratic process. Lf any of White's Those who deny the virtue or the possibility of making polygyny codes could be used to partition the variables generalizations about human societies will remain un- in my analyses so as to dissolve the reported associations convinced, but to those who feel that the attempt is (by controlling for a factor previously obscured in a reworthwhile these codes will be welcome. ductionistic oversimplification), I would welcome the elucidation. As it is, White has merely parasitized an extraordinarily robust and powerful relationship by showing that it holds for even finer breakdowns of polygTOHN H A R T U N G Department of Anesthesiology, State University of yny. In fact, Dickemann's complaints resulted from a N e w York Health Science Center at Brooklyn, 450 creative misinterpretation of my presentation of MurClarkson Ave., Box 6 , Brooklyn, N. Y. I 1203 -2098, dock's codes (see Dickemann 1982 and Hartung 1983)~ U.S.A. 21 IV 88 and Pospisil's Bongo-Bongo argument (1982; see Hartung 1985) is best refuted by his own monograph on the White deserves anthropology's gratitude for following in Kapauku (1963).Pospisil argued (1982:9)that "the conhis mentor's footsteps. Murdock always encouraged tention that a mother and her son would oppose her elaboration and refinement of his cross-cultural codeshusband's spending of his fortune upon himself and prefer a far nobler response to their inadequacies than hand- to save the resources for the son's inheritance is conwringing and niggling complaints. Of all the variables tradicted by empirical evidence from the Kapauku culcoded, none has greater potential for elucidating the ture. There a woman urges her spouse to spend money mysteries of human evolution than polygyny. Given the on pigs and an additional wife . . . [who] is not only a astuteness of White's typological and quantitative de- source of prestige for her husband, but primarily an im- 562 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, ~ u g u s t - ~ c t o b e1988 r Dortant investment in ~roduction." However, in his Lonograph (1963: esp. 2;-28) he states that a feature of every Kapauku inheritance is that a man's main heir is his first wife's first son and that wealth is shared with that son's siblings only at the heir's discretion. Given this rule, if there is a substantial material advantage to having additional wives, second wives are an investment in first wives' first sons, which explains the urgings of first wives to become co-wives. In short, Pospisil's account of the Kapauku indicates that even this variation on the theme of resource-defense polygyny supports my argument. (I badgered Pospisil with this in private correspondence in 1983 but received only thick descriptions in return.) White's unsubstantiated criticism of Borgerhoff Mulder (1985, I 987) and Betzig (1986) stems fro& the intensity of his attachment to the realization that a wife often enhances a man's ability to advance his economic status and thereby gain an additional wife. This is true, but it is not a blinding insight. Ray Charles, in his musical version of the old adage "Them as has gits," says, "If you gotta have somethin' before you can get somethin', how you get your first is still a mystery to me." In this case it is not so mysterious. Fortunate men get bride-price and inherited wealth from their fathers, who got the same from their fathers, etc. These are the men who become polygynous. Wives beget wives as capital begets capital as capital begets wives as wives beget capital: hence the association between polygyny, bride-price, and inherited wealth (Hartung I 982). Those who pontificate against reductionism should be sentenced to maintain an old British car. When they begin to doubt that complexity is a virtue in itself, they should be rewarded with a German car. When they begin to see that simplicity is, ceteris paribus, a virtue in itself, they should be forced to rethink concepts like wealthincreasing fraternal-defense polygyny. Then they should be allowed to read Williams's "A Defense of Reductionism in Evolutionary Biology" ( I98 5 ). WILLIAM IRONS Department of Anthropology, Northwestern University, Evanston, 111. 60201, U.S.A. 22 IV 88 White is to be congratulated for an important contribution to the study of polygyny. He has convincingly demonstrated that the category "polygyny" encompasses several distinct patterns of marriage. He has also demonstrated that we must seek both ecological and historical explanations of the development and maintenance of these patterns. The new codes he has given us will be an important resource for future research on polygyny, and his analysis of the newly coded data will be the starting point for much future work. I have only a few minor criticisms of the work presented in this paper. First, I suspect that close examination of the economics of marriage in a number of the societies White identifies as practicing "wealth- increasing" polygyny will reveal that polygyny is not wealth-increasing but merely inexpensive. This is my reading of Borgerhoff Mulder's (1987, 1988a) Kipsigis data, to which White refers specifically. For a Kipsigis man to marry he needs cattle for a bridewealth and land that can be placed in the hands of the woman so that she can support herself and her children. Thus contracting a marriage is costly and easier for wealthy young men than for poorer ones. Once established, a wife does make a substantial economic contribution through her agricultural labor, but it is not clear to me from the available data how much of this contribution is also absorbed by her and her children. My guess is that the geographic Dattern White has identified is real but the distinction is basically one between expensive and inexpensive polygyny. A situation in which wives are expensive to acquire but inexpensive to maintain combined with late age at first marriage for men could generate the negative bionomial distribution discovered by Spencer (1980)as easily as a situation in which wives are wealth-increasing, It is also worth noting that if wives are in fact initially expensive but inexpensive thereafter, there is no reason to question Borgerhoff Mulder's view that, among the Kipsigis, male wealth is translated into multiple wives rather than the reverse. The concept of macroculture used by White is a valuable one that reflects a robust empirical phenomenon. However. I think it is necessarv to make clear what a macroculture consists of. There is considerable variation within a single society in such variables as the economic costs and benefits of marriage for a man. Within a large region such as East Africa or all of sub-Saharan Africa, this variation is going to be greater, and the reasons for the variation will also be variable. On the other hand, whenever one compiles statistics on large regions sharp contrasts emerge. Macrocultures are real, but they are, in my view, statistical tendencies rather than types. As such they have ecological and historical causes, and White's analysis helps us to understand these causes. There is danger, I think, that some anthropologists will tend to see things such as "wealthincreasing polygyny" as a relatively invariant pattern manifest throughout sub-Saharan Africa and consider the presence of a reified macroculture an adequate explantation of this pattern. As far as I can tell, White would agree that macrocultures are sharply dstinct statistical patterns associated with different regions, but I wish he had been explicit on this point. I do not think that the presence of polyandry alongside of polygyny is good evidence against a scarcity of potential wives as White argues using the case of the Pawnee as a example. A shortage of potential wives is well documented for the Yanomamo (Chagnon 1979, 1983; Melancon 1981) yet they combine occasional polyandry with polygyny. All of these criticisms are, in my view, minor and should not detract from the generally high quality of the work presented here. I am very pleased to see White's research appear and think that it does a great deal to improve our understanding of polygyny. WHITE BOBBI S. LOW Evolution and Human Behavior Program and School of Natural Resources, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Mich. 48109-1115, U.S.A. 27 IV 88 With many others, I welcome White's new codings of variations on the theme of polygyny. It has been clear for some time that previously existing codes are inadequate for tackling a variety of biological and anthropological questions. White's codes and his treatment of the patterns found in them highlight major differences between biological (really behavioral ecological) and anthropological approaches to analyzing polygyny, and consideration of these differences may be useful. Anthropologists inay define polygyny as a social institution, but its biological impact is great, influencing important patterns including differential investment in offspring (e.g., review by Trivers 1985) and physical (e.g., Alexander et al. 1979) and behavioral (e.g., Trivers 1972, LOW1978) sexual dimorphism. For a biologist, the crucial aspect of polygyny is the fact that male reproductive success varies much more than female reproductive success (Bateman 1948, Clutton-Brock, Guinness, and Albon 1982).This asymmetry reflects the relative intensity of sexual selection (Wade and Arnold 1980; cf. Falconer 1981). The greater the variance in male compared with female reproductive success, the more intense the sexual selection. As a result, in polygynous species, the curves of return in offspring for effort expended are strikingly different for the two sexes. Males of polygynous species must expend much more effort to get even a single mating; additional matings typically cost comparatively little additional effort. Females are likely to have little trouble getting matings, but each offspring imposes as much additional cost as the first. When return curves differ as a result of sexual selection, highly dimorphic behavior is predicted for males and females, with the degree of difference reflecting the differences in potential reproductive payoff and the differences in variance. Measures summarizing the percentage of marriages polygynous and maximum number of wives are not really adequate to reflect this fact (cf. Low 1 9 8 8 ~although )~ they roughly reflect variance. The actual distribution of offspring (ideally) or at least of wives (more pragmatically) among men in a population is necessary. This is a vital step. Much behavior, particularly behavior leading to male mortality, looks like sexual selection in operation to a biologist, but without measures of the intensity of sexual selection-most simply as distribution of wives among men-we can only speculate. Data like Chagnon's (1988)and Spencer's (1980) are all too rare. The importance of the ecological system is as a selective pressure "filtering" the relative survival and reproduction of individuals and thus, over time, the relative persistence, increase, and decrease of competing genetic lineages. Nothing has more impact on this process than the distribution of mates and age-specific fertility (cf. Fisher I 930, Williams I 966), and any ecological or social Rethinking Polygyny 1 563 factor that exacerbates variation in male quality or ability to compete is important (cf. Flinn and Low 1986, Low 1988b). One predicts, for example, that major biological uncertainties such as pathogen stress may exacerbate the impact of sexual selection, increasing the degree of polygyny (Hamilton 1980, Hamilton and Zuk 1982, LOW 198827).As another example, men's ability to reap reproductive gain by sexual striving can be limited by institutionalized stratification. White's codes help greatly in factoring out different issues, allowing better testing of hypotheses. White criticizes Murdock and others for viewing cultural practices as autonomous at the societal level, independent of larger patterns of history and ecology. Yet it is not clear that we have come much farther with these new variables; it seems as though White views cultural practices as autonomous at the cultural level. In other species, mating systems (polygyny, polyandry, monogamy) and their resource bases (resource control competition, status competition, and so on) have clear ecological correlates. White's treatment of wealth-increasing and sororal polygyny shows no awareness of these larger patterns. We seem to have some distance to go in integrating biological and anthropological views of polygyny. In fact, I am unclear about the origin of a number of White's hypotheses. If they are suggested by patterns in the new codes, clearly the codes do not provide tests. If they are suggestions or assertions made in the past, there are clearly alternative and additional hypotheses, arising from evolutionary theory, that ought to be explored. For example, yes, one might expect different child-rearing practices if wives occupy separate or conjugal dwellings, and one might also predict, on the basis of very different confidence of paternity depending on whether husband and wives live together or apart, very different male investment patterns (e.g., in own or sister's children [Alexander 19791). Similarly, why, in the discussion of the advantages and disadvantages of polygyny for women and the cooperative patterns among wives, is there no mention of the obvious prediction that when wives are sisters, genetic confluence of interests makes cooperation more probable (and thus there is no surprise when sororal co-wives occupy the same dwelling more often than unrelated co-wives)?This is surely a very basic prediction, much more basic than the observation that sororal polygyny is common among food collectors in the New World. It is time to assemble hypotheses, both true alternative hypotheses and noncompeting ones, so that testing can proceed in an organized fashion. Fortunately, White's new codings, if not his analysis of their patterns, will be very helpful in this endeavor. KEITH F. OTTERBEIN Department of Anthropology, State University of N e w York at Buffalo, Buffalo,N.Y. 14261, U.S.A. 10 IV 88 The central contribution of this article is the refinement of existing and the development of new polygyny variables. This is an accomplishment long overdue. Ethno- 564 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 graphic studies of social organization for years have described the various facets of polygyny, but the basic marriage-system variable has had for its categories simply polyandry, monogamy, limited polygyny, and general polygyny. The richness of the ethnographic record was not captured by a basic variable that arbitrarily used a cutting point of 20% to distinguish between limited and general polygyny. In the treatment of marriage in a 1977 textbook that summarized much of the crosscultural literature and set forth a series of 34 questions for each of 32 topics, I described the desirability of distinguishing marital groups, "the social groups which are formed when individual men and women enter into one or more marital unions," and computing the frequency of each type of group (1977:84, 86). Sororal polygyny, the levirate, and the sororate were also discussed. Nevertheless, the section concluded with the above basic marriage-system variable. Thus, both ethnographic accounts and general theoretical discussions of polygyny offered data and analyses that would have allowed the development of a substantial number of variables of theoretical significance, but until now no such set of refined variables has ever been developed. White has performed that service for the profession. His codes and bibliography will be utilized repeatedly in future cross-cultural studes. The situation of polygyny, where despite a plethora of data and theory there have been no well-developed variables for hypothesis testing, is not the usual case. Typically cross-cultural research stimulated ethnographers to collect data that previously were seldom gathered. For example, pre-1940 ethnographies seldom have rich information on child rearing and personality. Focus on these topics began under the influence of neo-Freudian theory in the 1930s~and the publication of the cross-cultural study Child Training and Personality (Whiting and Child 1953) led to further field research. Again, prior to the late 1960s ethnographies contained few or no data on lethal group conflicts; the publication of The Evolution of War: A Cross-cultural Study (Otterbein 1970) was followed by numerous ethnographic treatments of armed combat. Divale's (1970) cross-cultural study of infanticide, by demonstrating its widespread nature, stimulated both further theoretical work and more thorough data collection on the topic. I hope that my recent study of capital punishment (1986)will have the same effect. In all of these instances the ethnographic data on the topic were so scant at the time that comparativists often failed to find codable data for even the simplest variables. Today a comparativist conducting research on child rearing, warfare, or infanticide can utilize more refined variables thanks to the better data base generated by the initial cross-cultural studies. PAUL C. ROSENBLATT Department of Family Social Science, University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minn. 55108, U.S.A. 28 111 88 I respect and value White's many contributions to crosscultural research, and I think this newest contribution is important, useful, and wise. However, I worry about the limitations of attempts to break new ground through the analysis of old ethnographic texts. Feminist critiques of ethnographies raise questions about the body of literature on which cross-cultural research is based, particularly research on gender-connected topics such as polygyny and male status. New developments in analyzing the rhetoric of ethnography raise questions about the meaning and validity of ethnographic assertions. Developments in the emics of languages and cognitive systems raise questions about the theoretical categories we use in attempting to understand cultures. Scholars who argue for the importance of sensitivity to history argue for over-time data. The consistencies and patterns found in the ethnographic literature may arise at least in part from consistency and pattern in biased observation, interpretation, and reporting. White has enormous methdological and theoretical sophistication and knows full well the limitations of the sources with which he must work. I would like to have more of his thoubts on why it seems to him safe and useful to go aheid with thk comparative work he reports here and how he decides whether the literature is adequate or inadequate to address a given research topic. The new codes and the commentary and theorizing that went into them enrich the literature on polygyny and ~rovideresearchers with new tools with which to stud; the embeddedness of a number of aspects of polygyny in cultural systems. The discussion of coding decisions, comparatively rare in cross-cultural reporting of codes, is enlightening and will help all who use the codes to understand more fully what it is they are using. With my appetite whetted, I wish White had given us more. Does he have a more com~leteversion of his coding notes? Perhaps cross-cultural researchers need booklength reports of the coding process in important projects like this one in order to evaluate the codes and the research on which they are based. That would help to clarify how given ethnographies were understood and also what codes actually mean. I do not fully understand all of White's codes. Ouestions that arise for me include . the following: In Code I, what is meant by "rules"? We need more information to know what actually went into the codes-what was done, for example, with a report of a single occasion or an ethnographer's undocumented assertion. Category 5 seems more a behavior assessment than a rule. And what should the reader make of the assertion that the rules of polygyny are often contingent? Why not code the contingencies? For Code z, are there additional words that might further differentiate Point z from Point 32 In Code 5, the "or" for both scale values makes it unclear what is being coded. Can White say more to clarify what the coded freauencies mean? In Code 7, can w i be sure that evaluations of wealth, inherited rank, nobility, or social class were independent of polygyny? If not, perhaps this code is tautological. For Code I I, a question that arises in comparative research dealing with marriage is the extent to which the w H I T E Rethinking Polygyny 1 5 65 rights and duties are the same for women who become mates in the various ways. Do glosses like "wives" and "concubines" obscure important cultural differences? White's discussion is helpful, but I would like more clarity. The reliability estimates are useful, but there is an obvious question that I would like answered. To what extent were the new codings done in ignorance of the older codings with which they were correlated? In the discussion of validity, it seems to me that there could be a tautological relationship between co-wife residential autonomy and relative subsistence autonomy of co-wives. To what extent were the two sets of codings based on the same sentences in the same ethnographic sources? I want to emphasize that I consider the paper important and worthwhile. Cross-cultural research has too often ignored the ecological and historical forces that have influenced the matters being studied. While enriching our understanding of the worldwide complexity of polygyny, White offers an understanding of the influence of ecological and historical forces of polygyny, a foundation for further understanding of those forces, and a model for evaluating such forces in the study of any other phenomenon of interest. wives' living apart subsequently. Nevertheless, it seemed worth reexamining my earlier sample for comparable data on residence patterns. This proved both time-consuming and inconclusive, and there were so many gaps in relation to White's categories that I abandoned the search. Of more direct relevance for my earlier exercise is the pattern of distribution of wives among elders, which is summarised as "N" or "T" in column 17 of table I . This is central to White's discussion on Old World polygyny and suggests a far wider availability of data on this topic than I had realised. In my original analysis, "Nu (a negative binomial distribution) suggests a situation of runaway competition for wives: successful polygynists appear poised for more success. "T" (a true or positive binomial distribution), on the other hand, suggests a strong element of conformity, as if a handicap were imposed on successful polygynists, making it increasingly difficult for them to obtain more wives. By no means all sets of polygyny data conformed to one or the other type. Where the sample was small or the average polygyny rate low, and especially towards the "T" end of the scale, the statistical test for significance left room for doubt. Polygyny rates based on genealogical data which included completed marriages introduced an unsatisfactory bias into the analysis. The aggregation of elite and commoner marriage patterns in certain societies led to a bimodal distribution of polygyny and a divergence from PAUL SPENCER a negative binomial. The developing thrust of my article Department of Anthropology and Sociology, School was the anthropological interpretation of these deparof Oriental and African Studies, Malet St., London tures from a negative binomial profile, and this has a W C I E 7HP, England. 21 IV 88 bearing on the present article, which glosses over these Some intriguing points arise from this reanalysis of Mur- refinements. My concern here is with the accuracy of the author's doch's HRAF sample, and had there been time I would have liked to replicate White's findings with a similar Sub-Saharan data in table I, column 17. The HRAF exercise based on my own sample of 50 Sub-Saharan sample and my own sample overlap in 11 cases. Of societies, to which he refers (Spencer 1980). The two these, White and I appear to agree on 5: ( 5 ) Mbundu, ( I6) samples are complementary, each with its strengths and Tiv, (34)Maasai, (36)Somali, and (23)Tallensi each apweaknesses. The HRAF sample can claim a greater rep- pear to have a negative binomial distribution of polygyny, implying competition for wives. However, in anaresentativeness in its global spread, but it is inconsister lyzing Fortes's Tallensi data further, I pointed out that in the extent to which it provides adequate data on pc this competitive profile hardly exists among younger ellygyny. The Sub-Saharan sample (as White notes) has stronger quantitative data base. A certain geographic; ders but increases with age (Spencer 1980:136-37). This clustering is evident (Spencer 1980: I 19), however, and points again to the relativity of competition, and it also the sample is only plausibly random inasmuch as it was suggests that one should be cautious in interpreting podetermined by the arbitrariness of various authors in re- lygyny data that are not broken down by age. Of the cording relevant data and the haphazardness of my own remaining 6 societies shared by the two samples, we search through the literature. The following paragraphs agree that (30) Otoro is "N," but I also noted that the indicate the extent of my assessment of this article primary data were unsatisfactory and to this extent the within the time available. finding could be distorted. We agree that (7) Bemba is White's findings on polygyny in relation to patterns of "T," but I also noted that the exercise was statistically residence are clearly worth pursuing, especially as he trivial and therefore "T" might be questionable. White links them with the types of polygyny profile that I had identifies (26)Hausa as "N," whereas I interpreted more explored. I would, however, note that my interpretation reliable data as "T" but again noted that the exercise was of competition and conformity related to the context of statistically trivial. He identifies (19) Ashante and (20) obtaining wives and explicitly denied that this reflected Mende as "N," whereas I noted a significant divergence a distinction between "competitive" and "conformist" from "Nu in each instance. He appears to have oversocieties (Spencer 1980:139).Thus I would question the looked the (21) Wolof data, which I noted as "Nu suggestion that any competition between elders for (Spencer 1980:146-52). White reports "T" or "Nu profiles for a further eight wives has a necessary bearing on the reasons for these 566 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 tion allow us to undertake projects that would not have been possible several decades ago. My own strategy, because of the intricacy of the data and methods, has been to construct a number of concatenated models (White 1974)rather than to depend on typologies and correlations of the characteristically Murdockian type. My general position is that systems interpenetrate and are embedded in one another and that we need to hold this complexity in awareness while we attempt to identify the best model or models for capturing critical relations in a specific comparative problem. Many of the keys to the understanding of complex systems lie not in the theory of homeostatic functionalism but in the exploration of their embedding in other structures and systems, sometimes larger (as in the embedding of local in regional and regional in larger systems), sometimes of one institution or activity within a larger field, and sometimes at different systemic levels (as in the embedding of cultural systems in different types of environments and in human biology). Increasingly we are relying less on typology and more on formal testing of multiple relations, features, and variables. This movement is not only a logical progression but follows from the necessity of looking beneath surface structure to the intent of theory itself. The activity of coding data is of critical importance, and I obviously feel that theories of coding should be explicit. It is at this rudimentary and deceptively commonsensical level that major biases and errors can be inadvertently introduced into our research. The nature of the coding itself may make it impossible to test critical alternative theory or fail to identify distinctive features of different systems or strategies. I thank the commentators for their positive comments on the value of the extended coding process in the present paper. My paper deals, on the face of it, with polygyny, yet my deeper concern among other things has been to look for evidence not only of regional differences but more specifically of macrocultural organization in the regional patterning of clusters of variables. More important, in focusing on subsystems in cross-cultural comparison based on the standard sample the paper marks a break from prior approaches in the Murdockian tradition, since I agree with Sahlins (1981)on the weakness of D O U G L A S R. W H I T E Irvine, Calif., U.S.A. 26 v 88 that tradition with regard to the central problem of h s torical contextualization. I have argued that phenomena The recent period in anthropology has been one of re- such as polygyny may have subsystems embedded quite markable intellectual ferment for comparative research. differently one from the other. It is not so much, for For one thing, the sharp dichotomy between history and example, that polygyny or other practices are culturally science has begun to break down. My own agenda has specific or that human nature is infinitely variable as increasingly included addressing a basic problem noted that varied histories of connection and the adaptive preslong ago by Boas (1896)-attempting to reconcile the sures imposed by specific types of contexts tend to estabconcerns of historical particularism with those of world lish the range of possibilities and shape the internal relahistorical processes and the search for more universal tions among subsystems. regularities in human systems of adaptation. CrossIn particular area studies, many anthropologists have cultural studies are, as Chick notes, undergoing revitali- pointed to the significance of regional variability, and zation. Recent developments that contribute to the fer- certainly region is an important unit of analysis within a ment occur because our cumulative literature and comparative perspective, especially if we are to build databases, theoretical advances, increasing sophistica- upon well-supported insights in the anthropological littion in modeling and computing, and reconceptualiza- erature. I agree with Irons, Borgerhoff Mulder, and Sub-Saharan societies in the HRAF sample. Of these, two add new and useful sources to my original sample: ( 2 5 ) Wodabe (Hopen 1958:144)~ has a clear "N" profile close to that of the Samburu, and ( 2 ) !Kung (Marshall 1958:144) is cited as "TI" although by my calculation the data indicate a very similar profile to that of the Hima, with a Poisson distribution-poised between "Nu and "T"-but again statistically trivial. Fitting "N" or "T" to the remaining six samples is problematic. White cites (9)Hadza as "T" and (13)Mbuti as "N," but the data are statistically trivial for both samples. Such numerical data as exist for (40) Teda could be interpreted either way, and therefore one would question that they are necessarily "Nu as he suggests. The sources he cites for (12) Ganda and (33) Kafa would lead one to expect bimodal distributions because of the highly polygynous elites rather than "N" as he suggests, but again numerical data appear to be entirely absent in both cases. The resources of London Universitv have been unable to unearth numerical data for (6)~ ; k u . In sum, of the 18 polygyny profiles that I have been able to check, we appear to agree unquestionably in relation to 6 and arguably in relation to another A . We disagree over 8. T ~ leads S one to question the labeling of "T" or "N" for 33 societies outside Sub-Saharan Africa, where the data on polygyny are generally thinner. It would be reassuring to have independent views of the other columns of table I . If this appears to be a negative assessment of what White has done, it should not be taken as a criticism of what he is trying to do. The main problem, I suggest, is the huge investment that underpins the HRAF sample. Samplewise, it has an undeniable logic, but its strengths and weaknesses in relation to specific topics are necessarily variable. Polygyny is one such topic, and I would place my money on a sample that is ethnographically strong for the research topic in question and examine the weakness of sampling bias as a subsidiary issue. WHITE Spencer on the significance of variability within regions, including sub-Saharan Africa, and the usefulness of within- as well as across-region comparisons. The clustering of the polygynous compound pattern around the African savannah (fig. I ) indicates not homogeneity but the possibility that polygyny may be organized around a systemic axis of variability in this region. With Borgerhoff Mulder, I think that detailed explanations of much of the variation in polygyny are to be found in ecological and organizational factors (White and Burton 1988). Within this aspect of the more general comparative problematic, I have suggested that the concept of the macroculture represents a viable systems approach to the problem. Several commentators have asked for clarification. The concept of the macroculture is a relational or systems concept. It emerges from the work of systemsoriented theorists, and perhaps I did not make it sufficiently clear that it expresses the idea of a system of linked variables (Przeworski and Teune 1970) based on identifiable patterned variability, not a typology of constant or homogeneous features. For example, I have elsewhere (White 1967) sought to identify distinctive sets of correlations among bridewealth, lineage organization, divorce frequency, return of bridewealth, rights over children at termination of marriage, etc., and found major regional associations that hold in the African polygyny area but not in other areas. Consequently, I more than agree with Borgerhoff Mulder and Irons that "macroculture" should not be equated with regional homogeneity. I have not yet done a macrocultural analysis of polygyny. Such an analysis would involve identifying interactions between key parameters and internal relations among system variables (White, Pesner, and Reitz 1983, Przeworski and Teune 1970, White and Pesner 1983). Parameter values help to define membership in or boundaries of specific subsystems. Such systems are often localized, since networked or linked units in social fields often come to have similar or complementary functional relations (if not localized, they may represent parallel or independent functional systems). A localized system of this kind may constitute a macroculture in the sense of a system of local variants developed in historical, interactive, or ecological relationshp to one another. There is no necessary correspondence between macroc~lltureand region-it is possible, for example, for there to be several macrocultures in a region. Macrocultures can be given names, but this does not constitute explanation (see again Przeworski and Teune 1970). The immediate conceptual framework of my study seeks to unpack some key variables associated with a possible range of polygyny complexes. Polygyny complexes are systems and as such need to be understood in the context of a larger totality. In this regard my work collides head-on with the shibboleths of evolutionary biology, although there are numerous points of agreement with each of the proponents of this perspective. (For a critique of the extreme adaptationist or sociobiological view of evolutionary biology, see Lewontin 1978, 1979.) Rethinking Polygyny 1 567 I have no quarrel with some applications of evolutionary biology to the polygyny problem, such as ( I ) that males have greater variance in reproductive success than females (Darwin 1859, 1871)~( 2 ) that wealth is often decisive in securing mates in polygynous societies, (3) that the reproductive-success value of transferable wealth in polygynous societies is probably maximized by leaving it to male offspring (Hartung 1976, 1977, 1982), and (4) that bridewealth is an alternative way of transferring wealth so as to increase one's offspring's reproductive success in polygynous societies. Low's discussions of polygyny from the biological perspective (see also Low 1988b) are also very useful and a model of clarity, even if I disagree on some details. But some key insights are missing. I use the term "wealth-increasing polygyny" to raise the central problem with the concept of resource-defense polygyny. Hartung, who has done some excellent studies on polygyny, misunderstands key aspects of my arguments and manages to obscure the best points of his own. To clarify: in wealth-increasing polygyny, what is likely to make a male more polygynous and more reproductively successful is not that some males produce more wealth than other males or than females or that they defend their wealth individually against all comers but that some males, in addition to their own productivity, acquire more wealth through ( I ) inheritance (e.g., Hartung 1982)~( 2 ) productivity of wives and father's wives, and (3)bridewealth stemming from sisters' or female relatives' marriages. There is an element of control here, but extensive control of resources also devolves on women, as men typically divide acquired wealth among their wives (and ultimately their sons). Sons defend the father's wealth because it devolves both onto their own mothers as producers and onto themselves through inheritance and/or bridewealth paid for their wives. Women also retain control over much of what they produce. Hartung's reading misses the tendency in the precolonial period for the activity of warriors in these societies to include-not surprisingly, given their likely shortage of wives-extensive taking of female captives as wives, thus providing direct reproductive benefits. The logic of this system of circular effects, including exchange, pooling, and redistribution, is moderately complex in comparison with the case of a single male bird that by defending a richer territory acquires a disproportionate share of mates (an example of resourcedefense polygyny). Hartung's objections notwithstanding, I see nothing inaccurate, even according to other sociobiologists, in my rejection of his 1982 arguments for human polygyny as resource defense. It is surprising to find him deriding the notion of circular or self-reinforcing systems while at the same time intimating that the entire systems argument is already contained in his 1982 article, which it is not. Even more surprising is the nature of his objection to the possibility of replication of his correlation between polygyny and patrilineal inheritance with a new polygyny measure. Yet I agree with the thrust of his 1982 arguments predicting this correlation. 568 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volme 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 As Betzig notes, "it is exceedingly difficult to determine whether wives, or anybody else, are net economic assets or costs." It follows from my presentation of the codes, in which I noted the difficulty of drawing direct measures from ethnographies of economic costs and benefits of polygyny, that I agree with Irons and Borgerhoff Mulder that my scale for male-stratified polygyny with autonomous co-wives (Code 18)predicts some conditions under which wives might be net economic assets but does not unequivocally identify them. A systems-oriented examination of the ethnographies would be required for this assessment, and this has not yet been done. Nonetheless, just as Caldwell (1976) changed the theoretical debate over demographic-transition theory by introducing the theory of wealth flows, it may be important for us to change the terms of the debate over polygyny even if the ethnography on the standard sample may not resolve all of the issues. The evidence presented here supports the assumption that polygyny in which co-wives play a major role in the production and exchange of wealth is dissimilar in some basic critical features from either resource-defense or harem-defense polygyny (see also Borgerhoff Mulder 1988d).Hartung (1982:11),in reply to critiques of his use of the comparative ethological label of resource-defense polygyny for the human case, stated, "the respondents . . . have caused me to agree with Scott [p. IO] that a new phrase or term should have been coined rather than overextending 'resource-defense polygyny1-which has generated more confusion than clarity, even to the point of obscuring the central hypothesis." Although I have offered contrastive type characterizations of polygyny, it will obviously be more useful eventually to recast all of these type distinctions in terms of dimensions such as resource control and defense (asfor components of reproductive effort, see Kurland and Gaulin 1984). Borgerhoff Mulder is quite right to note the difference between cases in which wives are a net economic benefit and cases in which wives' productivity (as with their contribution to Kipsigis maize production and animal husbandry) makes them less costly but men must accumulate the additional wealth needed to sustain polygyny. There are a number of pastoral societies in the present sample (e.g., Wodaabe, Basseri) in which wives are more or less costly although they still make important economic contributions. But, for the Kipsigis example, with bridewealth as high as a third of an average man's holdings and with a man's lineage acquiring bridewealth through the marriage of his female relatives, the mediation of wealth through women may still be an important part of the complex by which men acquire wives. Borgerhoff Mulder has shown a number of links that condition the relationships between wealth and polygyny, not the least of which is the availability of land (see also White and Burton 1988). There are many demonstrations to this effect in her work and in reports on other societies. She has not as yet demonstrated, however, that it is the male component of wealth rather than the component mediated by females (ultimately deriving from their labor productivity and passed on from the father's to the son's generation through bridewealth, with female relatives playing a mediating role in attracting bridewealth) that causes some men to acquire more wives and reproductive success. To establish the causal argument, she must test or control for the rival hypothesis (in reply to my questioning on this point [White 19881, Borgerhoff Mulder [1988d] has provided evidence that is convincing in this regard on a number of points). To do so properly, one needs to look at the series of wealth exchanges processually as they affect different parties in different ways over time (Borgerhoff Mulder's more recent arguments still do not make clear whether bridewealth receipts for daughters and cattle stocks held bv women are not used to helu finance their sons' marriages). I do agree that the ~ i i sigis, certainly at the present time with land scarcity, are not a type case of wealth-increasing polygyny. The type cases of wealth-increasing polygyny in subSaharan Africa are likely to be found where women's contribution is dominant through agriculture and the domestic economy and often in trade and marketing, even though it may not be recognized as equal to men's in terms of formal economic institutions. Blumberg (1979; 1981a, b; 1984)has documented the vast extent of bias in underreporting women's labor contributions and examined the implications of the facts that women contribute the bulk of locally consumed food crops in Africa, that separate accounts and expenditures are typical of African polygynous households, and that women's expenditures are devoted to a much greater extent than men's to the well-being of their children and familiesincluding their husbanchs. By applying Darwinian theory to polygyny without reckoning properly the couplings of human behaviors to exchange, pooling, and redistribution systems (in which women as well as men control resources), sociobiologists omit the crucial point that women (as co-wives, sisters, mothers, lineage members, etc.) may mediate both the wealth and (through wealth) the reproductive success of their sons (and themselves) through a system of exchanges. The complexity and circular linkages of the wealth-increasing system of polygyny, as opposed to the simple formula "males control and defend (wealth, resources, territory, etc.) and the more successful attract more mates and are reuroductivelv more successful." is one of its key definingieatures. ~ h u sI,have argued ;hat it is useful to examine polygyny as a "complex" or system of interrelated variables and interactions rather than as a simple set of attributes. Also, rather than present composite scales to show the elaboration of these complexes and their regional clustering (as in figs. I and 2), the hypotheses I offered attempted to explore some of the relationships among the elements in these complexes. A primatologist's expression of my view that polygyny and related reproductive strategies must be analyzed from a female as well as a male viewpoint and a critique of the male-dominated biases of various extreme Darwinian positions are found in Fedigan (1982:269-85, 300-306). While the sociobiological approach can poten- WHITE Rethinking Polygyny I 569 tially add new dimensions and explanations to a com- on the "T" coding (although statistically trivial) on two parative perspective, such approaches need to take care- cases (7, 9).Both of us fit (19)Ashanti and (20)Mende to fully into account the complex cultural and social "N," although I did not attempt to compute discrepanfactors that organize, distinguish, and differentiate sub- cies in fit. The two cases (12, 33) of bimodal distributypes of systems and their characteristic relations and tions with highly polygynous elites (Ganda and Kafa) fit transactional processes. It is not sufficient for evolution- within my use of "N," since I did not compute disary biologists simply to amend their arguments, for ex- crepancies. He fit ( 2 ) !Kung to the Poisson (intermediate) ample, by regarding multiple wives as "expensive" or distribution, which I treated as "T," so our disagreement "inexpensive" for a man to acquire or keep-the re- there is not serious. His data on (21) Wolof and (26) sponse of Betzig and Irons. This insufficient mod- Hausa are from different sources and pinpointed groups; ification clings to a definition of the advantages of I did not code the Wolof and got a different result for my polygyny solely from a male viewpoint and ignores the Hausa sample. critical role of female mediations. Even if women do Random errors such as those just mentioned usually produce extensive wealth in some polygynous systems, act to lower correlations. In a valid model, correction of more to the point would be to ask, as did Hartung (1982)~ random errors ought to raise correlations. Indeed, the whether it is not to the women's reproductive advan- corrections above did reduce the Guttman-scale errors, tages to pass their wealth through their sons. Wealth increase the contrast between regions, and increase supthus transmitted increases the sons' reproductive advan- port for Hypotheses I and 3 (the former correlations tage through acquiring multiple wives and thereby their were .38, .41, and .52 for one and .26, .so, and .58 for the mothers' reproductive advantage as well. Bridewealth other). Support for Hypothesis 2, however, decreased may have a similar function from the sisters' point of from . z to ~ .14. It would appear that this is because the view of increasing the brothers' reproductive success in negative binomial distribution (when correctly compolygynous societies; bridewealth brought into a lineage puted) includes the "Nambicuara" phenomenon (e.g., through the marriage of the sister may be used to finance Mbuti, Tehuelche) of a single polygynist with three or her brother's acquisition of an additional wife. more wives. The comments of Spencer, Low, Betzig, and others are Chick may be correct that those new to cross-cultural extremely valuable both for integrating debates on the research are often confused by the alternative postopic and for refinement of the particular study. I also sibilities for sampling, but the current sample has bethank Otterbein; Rosenblatt, and Chick for very useful come the standard for the majority of the cross-cultural comments on cross-cultural methods and substantive data published in the last two decades. The Murdock and problems. Some points need technical clarification. White standard sample was not originally a sample of In response to Rosenblatt, there was little if any societies in the Human Relations Area Files, but the tautological relationship or semantic confusion between percentage of HRAF coverage of materials relevant to the codes on stratification (Code 7) and polygyny or be- this sample has increased in this period from about 70% tween those on co-wife residential and subsistence au- to 85%. Ethnographers are welcome to send me materitonomy. The codings for these pairs of variables were als on well-described ethnographic cases to assist in the almost entirely based on different statements and evi- compilation of a bibliographic listing of the larger unidence. My comments above and details of the text verse of cases from which revised and additional samples should be consulted to clarify most of Rosenblatt's other might be drawn. questions. A more general conclusion of the polygyny study reSpencer pointed out that I had miscollated the polyg- lates to Ember's critique in these pages of the work of yny distribution (Code zo) for (13) Mbuti (Tumbull Guyer. According to Ember (1988:261), 1965:table 4), and indeed I had miscounted one polygynGuyer seems to rejoice in some cross-culturalists' ist as having two rather than three wives. This also having found regional differences, as if that somehow changed the binomial distribution (Code 17)from "T" to brought comparativists and particularists closer to"N." In the interests of accuracy, both of these changes gether. I don't think that this is so. . . . the finding of have been made in proofs. His critique also helped me to regional differences may simply be a temporary state locate an error in the algorithm that I had used to fit the of affairs, researchers having so far failed to find an polygyny distributions to the negative (N)or the true (T) important contingent factor that is more frequent in binomial. Fortunately, I had taken pains to include the one region than in another. raw distributions (Codezo),and recomputations (involving computing a variance, mean, and checking whether Ember seems not to allow for the possibility that systheir ratio exceeds I ) altered Code 17 for some societies tems and subsystems might be nested and that a systems and some scale values for Code 18. Again, these correc- approach might provide a valid means for linking histortions have been made in table I, and I am indebted to ical, regional, and worldwide comparative theory. Yet, him for his careful observations. On the binomial codes decades of documentation in the anthropological literafor sub-Saharan Africa, Spencer and I are in agreement ture support the basic axiom of important regional difon the "N" coding for eight cases (5, 13, 16, 23, 25, 30, ferences that are more than differences in trait frequen34, and 36), some of which are statistically trivial. We cies. The fact that at some levels of integration there are also agree on indeterminate data for two cases (8, 35) and also profound and more general processes occurring does a 570 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 not negate the importance of modeling and explaining regional or macrocultural differences. At the very least this is a research question close to the heart of anthropological theory. References Cited A L E X A N D ER. R ,D . 1979. Darwinism and human affairs. Seattle: University of Washington Press. [BSL] ALEXANDER, R. D., J. L. HOOGLAND, R. D . HOWARD, K. M. N O O N A NA,N D P. W. S H E R M A N1979. . "Sexual dimorphism and breeding systems in pinnipeds, ungulates, primates, and humans," in Evolutionary biology and human social behavior. Edited by N. A. Chagnon and W. Irons. North Scituate: Duxbury Press. [BSL] B A R R YH, E R B E R T 111, , A N D L E N O R A P A X S O N . 1971. Mancy and early childhood: Cross-cultural codes 2. Ethnology 10:466-508. BARRY, HERBERT, 111, L. JOSEPHSON, E. LAUER, A N D C. M A R S H A L L . 1976. Traits inculcated in childhood: Cross-cultural codes 5 . Ethnology 15 :83-114. B A R T HF, R E D R I K1961. . Nomads of South Persia. Boston. B A T E M A NA. , J. I 948. Intrasexual selection in Drosophila. Heredi t y 2249-68. [BSL] B E T Z I GL, A U R A L. 1986. Despotism and differential reproduction: A Darwinian view. Hawthorne, N.Y.: Aldine. BLUMBERG R A, E L . 1979. Rural women in development: Veil of invisibility, world of work. International Iournal of Intercultural Relations 3:447-72. , 1981a. "Females, farming, and food: Rural development and women's participation in agricultural production systems," in Invisible farmers: Women and the crisis of agriculture. Edited by Barbara Lewis, pp. 24-100. Washington, D.C.: USAID. . I 98 I b. "Rural women in development," in Women and world change: Equity issues i n development. Edited by Naomi Black and Ann B. Cottrell, pp. 32-56. Beverly Hills: Sage. . 1984. "A general theory of gender stratification," in Sociological theory. Edited by Randall Collins, pp. 23-191. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. BOAS,F R A N Z1896. . "The limitations of the comparative method in anthropology," in Race, language, and culture, pp. 271-304. New York: Macmillan. B O R G E R H O F F M U L D ER, M. 1985. Polygyny threshold: Application to a Kipsigis case study. National Geographic Research 21:33-37. . 1987. On cultural and reproductive success: Kipsigis evidence. American Anthropologist 89:617-34. . 1988a. "Kipsigis bridewealth payments," in Human reproductive behavior: A Darwinian perspective. Edited by L. L. Betzig, M. Borgerhoff Mulder, and P. W. Turke, pp. 65-82. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [MB,WI] . 1988b. "Reproductive consequences of sex-biased inheritance," in Comparative socioecology of mammals and man. Edited by V. Standen and R. Foley. Oxford: Blackwell. In press. [MBI . 1988c. "The relevance of the polygyny threshold model to humans," in Matingpatterns. Edited by C. G. N. Mascie-Taylor and A. J. Boyce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. In press. [MB] . 1988d. Polygyny and the extent of women's contributions to subsistence. American Anthropologist. In press. [MB] . n.d. Marital status and reproductive performance in f i p sigis women: A reevaluation of the polygamy-fertility hypothesis. MS. [LB] B O S E R U PE,S T E R . 1970 Woman's role i n economic development. New York: St. Martin's Press. B R A B I NL. , 1984. Polygyny: An indicator of nutritional stress in African agricultural societies? Africa 54:3 1-45. [MB] BRADLEY CA , N D I C E . 1987. Women, children, and work. Ph. diss., University of California, Irvine, Calif. B U R T O NM, I C H A E L L. A N D D O U G L A S R. WHITE.1984. Sexual division of labor in agiiculture. American Anthropologist 86:568-83. . 1987. Cross-cultural surveys today. Annual Review of Anthropology I 6: 143-60. [GC] C A L D W E LJLO, H N C. 1976. Toward a restatement of demographic transition theory. Population and Development Review 2:321-66. C H A G N O NN,. A. 1979. "Mate competition, favoring close kin, and village fissioning among the Yanomamo Indians," in Evolutionary biology and human social behavior: A n anthropological perspective. Edited N. A. Chagnon and W. Irons. North Scituate, Mass.: Duxbury Press. [WI] . 1983. 3d edition. Yanomamo: The fierce people. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. . 1988. Life histories, blood revenge, and warfare in a tribal population. Science 239:985-92. [JH] C L I F F O R DJ A , M E S1986. . "Introduction: Partial truths," in Writing culture. Edited by James Clifford and George E. Marcus. Berkeley: University of California Press. CLUTTON-BROCK, T . H., F . E. GUINNESS, A N D S. D. A L B O N . 1982. Red deer: The ecology of two sexes. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [BSL] C L U T T O N - B R O C K . T. A N D P. H. H A R V E Y 1078. "Primateecolow and social organization," in Readings i n sGiobiology. Edited T. H. Clutton-Brock and P. H. Harvey. San Francisco: Freeman. b;; [LBI DICKEMANN M ,I L D R E D . 1979 The ecology of mating systems in hypergynous dowry societies. Social Science Information 181163-95. . 1981. "Paternal confidence and dowry competition: A biocultural analysis of purdah," in Natural selection and social behavior. Edited by Richard D. Alexander and Donald W. Tinkle, pp. 417-38. New York: Chiron Press. . 1982. Comment on: Polygyny and inheritance of wealth, by john Hartung. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 23:8-9. DIVALE, W I L L I A M T. 1970. An explanation for primitive warfare: Population control and the significance of primitive sex ratios. The N e w Scholar 2:173-92 [KFO] D O R J A H NV ,E R N O N R. 1959. "The factor of polygyny,"in Continuity and change i n African cultures. Edited by William R. Bascom and Melville j. Herskovits, pp. 87-112. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. D O W ,M. 1987. Subsample replication in cross-cultural surveys. American Anthropologist 89: 125-3 3. [LB] DOW, M A L C O L M M., M I C H A E L L. BURTON, D O U G L A S R. . Galton's problem as netWHITE,A N D K A R L P. R E I T Z1984. work autocorrelation. American Ethnologist I 1:754-70. [GC] D R I V E RH, A R O L D E . 1956. A n integration of functional, evolutionary, and historical theory b y means of correlations. Indiana University Publications in Anthropology and Linguistics Memoir 12. D R I V E RH, A R O L D E., A N D W I L L I A M C. M A S S E Y . 1957 Comparative studies of North American Indians. Transactions of the American Philosophical Society 47(2):165-45 6. E G G A N , F. 1954. Social anthropology and the method of controlled comparison. American Anthropologist 56:743-63. [MB] E M B E RM , E L V I N1974. . Warfare, sex ratio, and polygyny. Ethnology 13:197-206. . 1984. Alternative predictors of polygyny. Behavior Science Research 19: 1-23. E M B E RC, A R O L R. 1988. Comment on: The multiplication of labor, by Jane I. Guyer. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 29:261. FALCONER D., S. 1981. 2d edition, Introduction to quantitative genetics. London and New York: Longman. [BSL] F A R O NL,O U I S . 1961. Mapuche social structure. Illinois Studies in Anthropology I . F E D I G A NL,I N D A M. 1982. Primateparadigms. Montreal: Eden Press. S H E RR. , A. 1930. Thegenetical theory of natural selection. Oxford: Clarendon. [BSL] F L I N NM. , v., A N D B O B B I S. L O W .1986. "Resourcesdistribution, social competition, and mating systems in human societies," in WHITE Ecological aspects of social evolution. Edited by R. W. Wrangham and D. I. Rubenstein, pp. 217-43 Princeton: Princeton University Press. G H I S E L I NM. , T . 1969 The triumph of the Darwinian method. Berkeley: University of California Press. [LB] GRAY,J . P A T R I C K . 1985. Primate sociobiology. New Haven: HRAF Press. G R A YR, O B E R T F. 1964 "Introduction," in The family estatein Africa. Edited by R. F. Gray and P. H. Gulliver. Boston: Boston University Press. G R A YR, O B E R T F., A N D P. H. G U L L I V EEditors. R. 1964. Thefamily estate in Africa. Boston: Boston University Press. G U Y ER,J A N E I. 1988. The multiplication of labor: Historical methods in the study of gender and agricultural change in mode m Africa. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 29:247-72. H A M I L T O NW. , D. 1980. Sex versus non-sex versus parasite. Oikos 35:282-go. [BSL] H A M I L T O NW. , D., A N D M. Z U K .1982. Heritable true fitness and bright birds: A role for parasites? Science 218:384-87. [BSL] H A R T U N GJ,O H N .1982. Polygyny and inheritance of wealth. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 23: 1-1 I. . 1983. In defense of Murdock: A reply to Dickemann. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 24: 125-26. [JH] -. 1985. Matrilineal inheritance: New theory and analysis. The Behavioral and Brain Sciences 8:661-88. [JH] H I L G E RI,N E S .1957. The Araucanian childlife a n d i t s cultural background. Smithsonian Miscellaneous Collections I 33. HONIGMANN J. , J . 1954. The Kaska Indians. Yale University Publications in Anthropology 5 I . H U M A N R E L A T I O N S A R E A F I L E S1967. . The HRAF quality control sample universe. Behavior Science Notes z:81-88. [GC] I R O N SW. , 1983. "Human reproductive strategies," in Social behavior of female vertebrates. Edited by S. K. Wasser, pp. 169213. New York: Academic Press. [MB] J O R G E N S E JNO,S E P H J. 1974. Comparative s t u h e s by Harold E. Driver and essays in his honor. New Haven: HRAF Press. . 1980. Western North American Indians. San Francisco: Freeman. KURLAND J E, F F R E Y A., A N D S T E V E N J . C. G A U L I N1984. . "The evolution of male parental investment: Effects of genetic relatedness and feeding ecology on the allocation of reproductive effort," in Primate paternalism. Edited by David M. Taub, pp. 259-308. New York: Van Nostrand Reinhold. L A G A C ER,O B E R T 0. 1979. The HRAF probability sample: Retrospect and prospect. Behavior Science Research IQII-29. [GC] L E VINE,R. 1962. Witchcraft and co-wife proximity in southweste m Kenya. Ethnology 1:39-45. [MB] LEVINSON DAVID, , A N D M A R T I N J . M A L O N E . 1980. Toward explaining human culture. New Haven: HRAF Press. [GC] L E W O N T I NR., C. 1978. Adaptation. Scientific American 239:212-30. . 1979 Sociobiology as an adaptationist program. Behavior Science 24:s-14. L O W ,B O B B I S . 1978. Environmental uncertainty and the parental strategies of marsupials and placentals. American Naturalist 112:197-213. [BSL] .1988a. Measures of polygyny in humans. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 29:189-94. [BSL] . 1988b. "Pathogen stress and polygyny in humans," in Human reproductive behavior: A Darwinian perspective. Edited by L. L. Betzig, M. Borgerhoff Mulder, and P. S. Turke, pp. 11527. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. L U M H O L T ZC ,A R L . 1902. Unknown ~Mexico.2 vols. London. M A N N E R SR,. A. 1967 "The Kipsigis of Kenya: Cultural change in a 'model' East,African tribe," in Contemporary change in traditional societies, vol. I, Introduction and African tribes. Edited by J. Steward, pp. 207-359 Urbana: University of Illinois Press. [MBI MELANCON T., 1981. Marriage and reproduction among the Yanomamo Indians of Venezuela. Ph.D. diss., Pennsylvania State University, University Park, Pa. [WI] M U R D O C KG,E O R G E P. 1934. Our primitive contemporaries. New York: Macmillan. Rethinking Polygyny I 571 . 1949. Social structure. New York: Macmillan. 1959. Africa. New York: Macmillan. -. . 1957. World ethnographic sample. American Anthropologist 59:664-87. . I 962. Ethnographic atlas (1st installment). Ethnology 1:III-ld. :196~.Ethnographic atlas. Ethnology 9:122-225. . 1980. Theories of illness. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. -. 1981. Atlas of world cultures. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. MURDOCK, G E O R G E P., A N D D I A N A 0 . M O R R O W . 1970. Subsistence economy and supportive practices. Ethnology 9:30230. MURDOCK, G E O R G E P., A N D D O U G L A S R. WHITE. 1969 Standard cross-cultural sample. Ethnology 8:329-69. M U R D O C KG ,E O R G E P., A N D S U Z A N N E F. W I L S O N1972. . Settlement patterns and community organization: Cross-cultural codes 3. Ethnology I 1:254-95. o G B U ,J O H N 1978. . African bridewealth and women's status. American Ethnologist 5:241-62. OTTERBEIN KE , I T H F. 1970 The evolution of war: A cross-cultural study. New Haven: HRAF Press. [KFO] . 1977. zd edition. Comparative cultural analysis: An introduction to anthropology. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. [KFO] . 1986. The ultimate coercive sanction: A cross-cultural study of capital punishment. New Haven: HRAF Press. [KFO] PATTERSON OR , L A N D O . 1982. Slavery and social death: A comparative study. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. P O S P I S I LL,E O P O L D . 1963. The Kapauku Papuans of West New Guinea. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. . 1982. Comment on: Polygyny and inheritance of wealth, by John Hartung. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 23:9-10. P R I C E S. , 1984. Co-wives and calabashes. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. R O U S EI,R V I N G1948. . "The Arawak," in Handbook of South American Indians, vol. 4. Edited by Julian H. Steward. Bureau of American Ethnology Bulletin 143(4). S A H L I N SM, A R S H A L L . 1981. Culture andpractical reason. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. SCHNEIDER HA , R O L D K. 1979. Livestock andinequality in East Africa. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. S C O T TE, U G E N I E C. 1982. Comment on: Polygyny andinheritance of wealth, by John Hartung. CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY 23:10. S M O L EW, I L L I A M J. 1976. The Yamoama Indians: A culturalgeography. Austin: University of Texas Press. SPENCER S I,R H E R B E R T . 1876. Principles of sociology. Vol. I . London: Appleton. SPENCER P ,A U L1980. . "Polygyny as a measure of social differentiation in Africa," in Numerical techniques in social anthropology. Edited by J. Clyde Mitchell. Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues. S T E G G E R DM A ,O R R I S1948. . "Mestizos of South America," in Handbook of South American Indians, vol. 6. Edited by Julian H. Steward. Bureau of American Ethnology Bulletin 143(6). T R I V E R SR,O B E R T . 1972. "Parental investment and sexual selection," in Sexual selection and the descent of man 1871-1971. Edited by B. Campbell. Chicago: Aldine. [LB,BSL] , 1985. Social evolution. Menlo Park: Benjamin/Cummings. [BSLI T U R K EP,. w., A N D L . L . B E T Z I G1985 . Those who can do: Wealth, status, and reproductive success on Ifaluk. Ethology and Sociobiology 6:79-86. T U R T O ND, A V I D . 1980. "The economics of Mursi bridewealth: A comparative perspective," in The meaning of marriage payments. Edited by John L. Comaroff, pp. 67-92. London: Academic Press. T Y L O RS,I R E D W A R D B . 1889. On a method of investigating the development of institutions applied to the laws of marriage and descent. Iournal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 18:245-69. 572 1 CURRENT ANTHROPOLOGY Volume 29, Number 4, August-October 1988 WHITE, D O U G L A S R., A N D H. G I L M A N M C C A N N . 1988. "Cites BERGHE, P I E R R E L. 1979. Human family Systems: An and fights: Material entailment of the eighteenth-century chemevolutionary view. New York: Elsevier. ical revolution," in Social structures: A network approach. W A D EM. , J., A N D S. J. A R N O L D1980. . The intensity of sexual Edited by Barry Wellman and Steven Berkowitz. Cambridge: selection in relation to male sexual behavior, female choice, and Cambridge University Press. sperm precedence. Animal Behavior 28:446-61. [BSL] D O U G L A S R. A N D R O B E R T P E S N E R . 1983. IntemalrepliWHEELER, V A L E R I E . 1974. Drums and guns: A C ~ O S S - C U ~ ~ U ~ ~ WHITE, ~ cation and the systems concept in non-experimental research. study of the nature of war. Ph.D. diss., University of Oregon, Behavior Science Research 18:26-44. Eugene, Ore. W H I T ED, O U G L A S R. 1967. Concomitant variation in kinship sys- WHITE, D O U G L A S R., R O B E R T PESNER, A N D K A R L R E I T Z . 1983. An exact significance test for three-way interaction. Behavior tems. M. A. thesis, Department of Anthropology, University of Science Research 18:1o3-22. Minnesota, Minneapolis, Minn. W H I T I N GJ,O H N W. M., A N D I R V I N G C H I L D . 1953. Child train. 1974. "Mathematical anthropology," in Handbook of soing and personality: A cross-cultural study. New Haven: Yale cial and cultural anthropology. Edited by J .J. Honigmann, pp. University Press. [KFO] 369-446. Chicago: Rand McNally. W H I T I N GJ,O H N W. M., A N D R O Y G. D ' A N D R A D E . 1959. A . 1975. Process, statistics, and anthropological theory: An cross-cultural study of residence from infancy through marriage. appreciation of Harold E. Driver. Reviews in Anthropology Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American An21295-314. thropological Association, Mexico City. . 1986. Focused ethnographic bibliography for the Standard WHITING, J O H N W. M., A N D B E A T R I C E B. W H I T I N G . 1975. Cross-Cultural Sample. World Cultures ~ ( 1 ) . Aloofness and intimacy of husbands and wives: A cross-cultural . 1988. Questioning the sociobiological evidence for wealth study. Ethos 6:183-207. as cause of male reproductive success among Kipsigis: Is polygWHYTE,M. 1978. Cross-cultural codes dealing with the relative yny not a cause of both wealth and children! MS. status of women. Ethnology I ~ : Z I I - 3 7 . WHITE, D O U G L A S R., A N D M I C H A E L L. BURTON. 1988. Causes W I L L I A M SG. , C. 1966. Adaptation and natural selection. Princeof polygyny: Ecology, economy, kinship, and warfare. American ton: Princeton University Press. [BSL] Anthropologist. In press. . 1985. A defense of reductionism in evolutionary biology. WHITE, D O U G L A S R., M I C H A E L L. BURTON, A N D M A L C O L M M. Oxford Surveys i n Evolutionary Biology 2: 1-27 [JH] D O w. I 98 I . Sexual division of labor in African agriculture. American Anthropologist 83:824-49. W O L FE , R I C .1982. Europe and the people without history. Berkeley: University of California Press. WHITE, D O U G L A S R., M I C H A E L L. BURTON, A N D L I L Y A N A. Z I N G G ,R O B E R T M. 1938. The Huichols: Primitive artists. New BRUDNER 1977. . Entailment theory and method: A cross-culYork: G. E. Stechert. tural analysis of the sexual division of labor. Behavior Science Research 12:1-24. VAN DEN Calendar October 17-20. 6th Inuit Studies Conference, Copenhagen, Denmark. Write: Jens Dahl, Institute of Eskimology, Fiolstraede 10, I I 7 I Copenhagen K, Denmark. December I 3-15. Theoretical Archaeology Group, 10th Conference, Sheffield, England. Themes: Archaeology: An Independent Discipline at Last? Intensification of Social Organisation, Politics and the Future of World Archaeology, Presentation of the Past, Gender, The Myth of Egalitarianism, The Individual in Social Reproduction, Ethnicity, Language, and People, Post-Processual Archaeology, The Implications of Literacy. Write: TAG Organising Committee, Department of Archaeology and Prehistory, The University, Sheffield SIO 2TN, England. March 30-April 2. Society of Ethnobiology, 12th Conference, Riverside, Calif., U.S.A. Deadline for papers December I 5 . Write: Elizabeth Lawlor or Sharon Rachele, Department of Anthropology, University of California, Riverside, Calif. 9252 I, U.S.A May 7-11. 8th International Symposium on Dental Morphology, Jerusalem, Israel. Themes: The Evolution, Differentiation, Function, and Genetics of Teeth. Write: Patricia Smith, Hebrew University Hadassah School of Dental Medicine, P.O.B. I 172, Jerusalem 9 IOIO, Israel. October 3-5. 3d International Conference of Food Science and Technology Information, Budapest, Hungary. Themes: Utilization and Deficiencies of Databases in Food Science with Special Reference to Marketing Aspects, Information Systems in Food Science and Technology, Computer Control in Food Production. Write: Udo Schiitzsack, International Food Information Service, Herriotstr. 5, 6000 Frankfurt am Main 71, Federal Republic of Germany. September 3-9. International Association for the History of Religions, 16th Congress, Rome, Italy. Theme: The Notion of "Religion" in Comparative Research. Write: XVI International Congress of the History of Religions, Dipartimento di Studi Storico-Religiosi, FacoltP di Lettere e Filosofia, UniversitP di Roma "La Sapienza," Piazzale Aldo Moro, 5,I-OOI85 Rome, Italy.