Management Decision Emerald Article: Rapid growth and rapid internationalization: the case of smaller enterprises from Canada Christian Keen, Hamid Etemad Article information: To cite this document: Christian Keen, Hamid Etemad, (2012),"Rapid growth and rapid internationalization: the case of smaller enterprises from Canada", Management Decision, Vol. 50 Iss: 4 pp. 569 - 590 Permanent link to this document: http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/00251741211220138 Downloaded on: 25-04-2012 References: This document contains references to 92 other documents To copy this document: permissions@emeraldinsight.com Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by ZHEJIANG LIBRARY For Authors: If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service. Information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Additional help for authors is available for Emerald subscribers. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information. About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com With over forty years' experience, Emerald Group Publishing is a leading independent publisher of global research with impact in business, society, public policy and education. In total, Emerald publishes over 275 journals and more than 130 book series, as well as an extensive range of online products and services. Emerald is both COUNTER 3 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation. *Related content and download information correct at time of download. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0025-1747.htm Rapid growth and rapid internationalization: the case of smaller enterprises from Canada Christian Keen Rapid growth 569 Department of Management, Universidad ORT Uruguay, Montevideo, Uruguay, and Hamid Etemad Department of International Business, McGill University, Montreal, Canada Abstract Purpose – The main objective of this paper is to develop a deeper understanding of high growth and rapid internationalization characteristics in terms of: empirically characterizing growth deriving the profile of high-growth enterprises, exploring influential factors in high-growth, pointing out the factors that stimulate internationalization, presenting the combined influence of these factors in both the high-growth and early internationalizing enterprises, and formulating research-based policy recommendation for longer and higher growth rates and for decreasing the chances of demise in such younger firms. Design/methodology/approach – The authors have built a longitudinal sample of more than 1,140 micro, small and medium-sized enterprises that have grown at exceptionally high rates for at least five years at the earlier stages of their life-cycle, and even from inception in some cases. The data-base’s origin is a popular Canadian business publication, the Canadian Business Magazine, which annually identifies and ranks growing firms in order to publish an annual list called “Profit 100: Canada’s 200 fastest-growing companies”. Findings – The findings of this analysis point to a rich population of high-growth enterprises with diverse ages, locations, sizes and revenues that manage to achieve high domestic and international growth for much longer and in ways not explained by the extant literature across time and industries. Research limitations/implications – This research carries the limitations of secondary data. In spite of its richness in terms of the high growth rates, annual lists offer a limited number of attributes per firm. It would be highly recommendable to use case studies in future research and broadly based surveys are necessary for deeper understanding of both the high and rapid growth and internationalization as well as the influential factors, including the internal characteristics of its agents, especially the management. Practical implications – This research indicates that rapid growing enterprises (RGEs) and rapid internationalizing enterprises (RIEs) are distinctive firms and are primarily small and medium-sized enterprises. Although the relative frequency of the appearance of various firm size-categories varies over time, RGEs are found across all the size and age categories. Although their total number as a proportion of all continuing firms in the economy is small, they are among the highly prominent and contributing corporate citizens. Social implications – This topic deserves the attention of scholars for the remarkable potential it offers to uncover the puzzle of growth, which is a time-dependent phenomenon. HGEs attain higher growths in shorter times; thus requiring a relatively shorter tracing of the growing firms. The topic also deserves the special attention of policy makers as HGEs generate employment, income, social benefits, taxes and wealth at much higher and faster rates than an average growing firm. Originality/value – The attractive features of HGEs’ and RIEs’ high-growth phenomenon compelled the authors to explore the topic in more depth than initially intended. By examining rapidly-growing smaller and younger enterprises, this study covers a wide gap in the extant literature of growth pertaining to the internationalization of smaller firms and thereby contributes the interaction of the two fields. Keywords Small to medium-sized enterprises, Entrepreneurialism, Competitive strategy Paper type Research paper Management Decision Vol. 50 No. 4, 2012 pp. 569-590 q Emerald Group Publishing Limited 0025-1747 DOI 10.1108/00251741211220138 MD 50,4 570 Introduction Rapid-growth enterprises are a selected group of firms with significant impact on their respective economies as they create more jobs while their larger counter parts lose net jobs (Acs and Mueller, 2007; Halabisky et al., 2006). They also create more wealth and innovate more effectively (Markman and Gartner, 2002; Rothwell and Dodgson, 2007; Van Praag and Versloot, 2008) than other firms. Most of these types of companies internationalize[1] their activities early-on in their life and tend to have greater productivity growth (Baldwin and Gu, 2003). For example, a recent Industry Canada report states that “growth firms are very important to the Canadian economy; hyper growth firms accounted for 4 percent of continuing business between 1993 and 2003, but were responsible for 45 percent of net jobs created by continuing firms” (Parsley and Halabisky, 2008, p. 1). Business community has long recognized the importance of rapid and high-growth enterprises, celebrated their success and held-them up as models to be emulated. Similarly, a UK NESTA report, suggests that high-growth firms are “responsible for 1.3 million out of the increase of 2.4 million new jobs in established businesses employing ten or more people between 2005 and 2008 (54 per cent).” (Anyadike-Dane et al., 2009, p. 4). Business publications, such as Canadian Business and Inc. Magazine (a US-based publication), have carefully identified and published annual lists of such firms in Canada and the US for the past quarter century. Best seller books, such as the Blue Print to a Billion: 7 Essentials to Achieve Exponential Growth (Thomson, 2005), have prominently featured high-growth firms for their achievements and impact for the general population[2]. However, with the notable exception of a few (Davidsson et al., 2009; Shepherd and Wiklund, 2009) there is little systematic and analytically-based knowledge about growth processes in these firms and factors influencing the growth process. Similarly, we do not know how these firms attain higher-growth, while some of their larger counter-parts with rich resources fail to do so and even cannot survive. To the extent that other entrepreneurs and firms learn from and emulate such firms they enable the society to attain economic and social benefits associated with the high and rapid growth phenomenon; thus pointing to the importance of potent public policy formulation to induce high-growth. This resonates with the Bygrave and Minnti’s (2000) and Minniti and Bygrave’s (1999) analysis suggesting that entrepreneurs learn from one-another and their enterprises contribute to the society’ well-being and economic growth (Bygrave and Minniti, 2000, p. 25)[3]. The main objective of this paper is to develop a deeper understanding the characteristics of high-growth and rapid internationalization in general, and those of Canadian enterprises in particular, in terms of: . empirically characterizing growth by deriving the profile of high-growth enterprises; . exploring influential factors in high-growth; . pointing out the factors that stimulate internationalization; and . presenting the combined influence of these factors in both the high-growth and early internationalizing enterprises. Following this introduction, a brief background and a survey of literature will be presented. A discussion of research question and the literature review provide for the theoretical underpinnings of the phenomenon and will allow for formulation of six hypotheses. The methodology for forming a database of Canadian high-growth enterprises and selecting a sample of high-growth enterprise for further analytical examination will appear next. Prominent characteristics of these enterprises, including age, location, growth in revenue and number of employees, temporal and internationalization processes of these firms are presented next. Then, the analysis of the hypotheses and findings will be presented and discussed. Finally, conclusions, implications and suggestions for further research and public-policy formation appear last. Rapid growth 571 Literature review The high and rapid growth phenomenon The phenomenon of rapid growth was initially viewed as special case of “normal” growth, which has been of interest to scholars from different perspectives for a long time, including economic growth, job creation, entrepreneurship, management of small enterprises, and strategy (Fischer and Reuber, 2003; Lotti et al., 2003). Birch (1987) drew attention to the significant contributions of rapid growth of smaller firms to creation of jobs, generation of income and positive impacts at the local and national levels, but he did not reflect on how rapid growth is achieved. However, appropriate data did not exist then and the lack of information still persists in many countries (Hoffman and Junge, 2006; Schreyer, 2000). A further complicating factor is that definitional aspects have not reached a consensus (Delmar et al., 2003; Shepherd and Wiklund, 2009). In general, rapidly growing enterprises (RGEs) refer to companies that achieve high-growth in a relatively short period of time. Birch (1987) profiled a family of firms that grow at higher rates and made more extensive contributions to employment than others. Birch et al. (1993) characterized firms that grow at higher than 20 percent per annum as “gazelles”. This annual growth rate corresponds with a five-year compound growth rate (FYCGR) exceeding 149 percent. Markman and Gartner (2002, p. 67) reported on speedier gazelles, with even higher FYCGRs, falling between 500 and 30,000 percent. They characterized that range as “extraordinary growth”. The above discussion suggests that there exists a continuum of growth rates, ranging from normal growth (1 to 10 percent) to extraordinary growth (over 200 percent per annum), parts of which are well-populated and well-characterized and others are not yet well defined. Currently, only two categories of firms – gazelles and firms with extraordinary growth – have been empirically identified and characterized, but other categories remain under-defined or uncovered, as highlighted in Table I. Annual growth rates (%) Corresponding FYCGR (%) * 0 to 10 10 to 20 20 to 43.1 43.1 to 213.2 213.2 and higher 0.0 to 61 61 to 149 149 to 500 500 to 30,000 30,000 þ Gazelles Gazelles Gazelles Birch, Hagerty and Parson’s characterization Uncovered Uncovered Markman and Gartner’s characterization Current characterization Extraordinary Uncovered Uncovered Uncovered growth Normal growth Normal growth Gazelles/ RGEs RGEs Uncovered RGEs Table I. The continuum of growth rates and their corresponding characterizations MD 50,4 572 As shown in Table I, gazelles are defined as firms with growth rates exceeding 20 percent per annum (or FYCGR $ 149 percent) with no upper bound and a lower bound that has not been too difficult to achieve, while the range for extraordinary growth is bounded on both ends (500 percent # FYCGR # 30,000 percent), with a higher lower bound than that for gazelles, leaving an undefined gap between 149 and 500 percent (FYCGRs). Similarly, growth rates higher than 30,000 percent (FYCGRs) are also under-defined and not frequently achieved. This perspective suggests a need for a further exploration of growth rates. Furthermore, although a few empirical studies have suggested certain bounded ranges for different growth rate (Birch, 1987; Markman and Gartner, 2002), the agents contributing to high and rapid growth have not been profiled. We suggest that this lack of clarity may have hindered research and contributed to RGEs being viewed as “illusive” (Barnard et al., 1998; Parker et al., 2005). However, there is little disagreement that RGEs’ contribute to job and income creation significantly. However, since these firms represent a small portion of the continuing domestic population of firms, less than 5 percent in Canada and in the UK (Anyadike-Dane et al., 2009; Halabisky et al., 2005), they are difficult to study. This discussion suggests that there is a strong need for an examination of the rapid growth phenomenon and portraying an empirically-based profile of its agents. Towards high-growth and rapidly internationalizing enterprises David Birch’s (1987) seminal research pointed to the high impact of rapidly growing enterprises (RGEs) on the economy of the US. He also showed that such firms created more net jobs as larger firms contracted. This phenomenon is well recognized in Canada (Bordt et al., 2005; Parsley and Halabisky, 2008) and UK (Anyadike-Dane et al., 2009) as noted earlier. Although the management of strategy and employment are internal challenges, the external impact of the high-growth phenomena are significant. In addition to high employment, some 50 percent of innovations and 95 percent of radical innovations are also attributed to such firms (Robson et al., 1993). Furthermore, the literature suggests that high-growth in small and medium size enterprises (SMEs) tend to be in part due to entrepreneurial initiatives, R&D expenditures, innovativeness, and faster commercialization of knowledge in these firms (Bordt et al., 2005; Dechenaux et al., 2003; Yang and Huang, 2005). High and rapid-growing enterprises gain further competitiveness as their scale economies increases thereby enabling them to expand beyond their domestic market and penetrate into the international markets. We refer to this international expansion as internationalization. When RGEs continue their rapid growth in international markets, we call them as rapidly internationalizing enterprises (RIEs). However, different terms and terminologies are also used. Rennie (1993) reported on smaller younger Australian firms that entered larger international markets at or near inception to overcome home market limitations and called them “Born Global”. McDougall and Oviatt (1994) identified a family of smaller and younger firms in some eleven countries that generated a “significant” portion of their revenues from international markets at, or near, inceptions and called them as international new ventures (INVs). Knight and Cavusgil (1996) suggested that “born global” in the US generated some 25 percent of revenues in international markets. Furthermore, McDougall and Oviatt (1994) suggested that these firms’ pattern of growth and internationalization would not follow the extant theory. Etemad and Keen (2009) has found that most of the high-growth enterprises were true born global that derived a large portion of their revenues from international sources. About 65 percent of the firms in their sample derived more than 50 percent of their revenues from international sources. Keen and Etemad (2008, 2011) have identified a large number of Canadian high-growth firms that have attained high-growth and internationalized rapidly and extensively. The fundamental question is what accounts for such high-growth at home and international market (internationalization). In the next section, we examine potentially influential factors. Economies of agglomeration and externalities: location and rapid-growth This aspect is related to the expansive literature on the economics of proximity and agglomeration in a region (Torre and Rallett, 2005; Breschi and Lissioni, 2001), which have served as the policy instrument for enterprise and job creation in regional industrial clusters (Porter, 1998). The idea of agglomeration economies, based on geographical proximity, goes back to Alfred Marshall (1961). Marshall’s arguments served as the genesis for the formulation of public policy that encouraged the formation of regional industrial clusters later on. Marshall attributed certain positive externalities to being located in the geographic proximity of an industrial region, resulting in additional competitiveness for firms active in the region. He observed, for example, that a cluster of firms in a region would result in higher demand for labor, which would in turn attract higher supply of laborers, leading to lower wage rates enabling specialization and division of labor enhancing the cluster firms’ competitiveness. One of the market manifestation of the added competitiveness would, among others, be higher or faster growth. Porter (1998) further elaborated on Marshall’s agglomeration and the concept of externality by arguing that cluster of firms within an industry, as well as the related and support firms, would prefer to be located close to their competitors for monitoring them and also close to their suppliers and buyers in order to benefit from higher supply of skilled workers and new market developments. Porter (1998) defined an industrial regional cluster as the “geographical concentration of interconnected companies and institutions in a particular field” (p. 2). Most of the policy instruments designed for providing environmental incentives (Krugman, 1991a; Shirley, 2005) for increasing a region’s innovativeness (Porter, 1998) and creating functional cities or regions (Pouder and St John, 1996; McEvily and Zaheer, 1999) are based on conceptual extensions and variations of regional clusters’ economies and the externalities associated with the economics of geographic proximity (Maccarini et al., 2004; Johansson, 2004; Feldman et al., 2005). One of the main characteristics of “economics of proximity” in regional cluster is to enable firms to collaborate with others within the proximity of the region. Such proximity, both in geographical and industrial terms, may facilitate participation in collaborative arrangements and in networks to further enable high-growth and rapid internationalization through higher competitiveness. Similarly, such collaborative arrangements may also allow companies to access resources embedded in the regional networks, including the unused or underutilized resources of network members, thus reducing the adverse impact of SME’s resource constraints. It may also help firms to capitalize on economies of scale and scope through the division of labor within the regional and industrial networks. Overall, it may reduce their combined costs, enhance their joint efficiencies and competitiveness for enabling higher and earlier growth that would not be Rapid growth 573 MD 50,4 574 otherwise possible without networks, network membership and their mutual collaborations (Brunello and Gambarotto, 2007; Combes and Duranton, 2006; Gulati, 1995) in the region. Geographical proximity also provides easier access to a high density of competitive information and spill over (Breschi and Lissioni, 2001; Acs et al., 2009) associated with a regional industrial cluster thereby providing for higher efficiencies not available elsewhere. The formation of alliances and collaboration with others embedded (Granovetter, 1985) in a synergistic network such as those in a globally competitive industrial regional clusters, or in functional regions (Karlsson et al., 2008), might reduce firm’s search, acquisition and transaction costs (Bougrain and Haudeville, 2002; Williamson, 1975) in areas that may otherwise expose them to higher costs and risks, especially in highly competitive foreign markets (Hymer, 1960; Covin and Slevin, 1989). The presence of such policies resonates with Hallberg (2001, p. 8), who discusses enabling environments that “provide an enabling business environment that opens access to markets and reduces policy-induced biases against small forms”. This discussion can be summarized in three related arguments. First, collaborative buyer-supplier relations within the cluster, or the region, would regulate competition, reduce opportunism and encourage a cooperative hyper-competition among the firms (D’Avani, 1999; Chen and Glen, 2004; Jack et al., 2004) within the cluster environment, which will distinguish firms based in such regions from others. Similarly, Karlsson et al. (2008) point to increased innovation, knowledge creation in what they call “functional regions”, which in turn enable internationally-oriented entrepreneurs and firms based in such regions to sustain or further their growth through access to international markets. Second, Audertsch and Sanders (2008) suggest that globalization has given rise to the emergence of “entrepreneurial economy”, whereby internationally oriented smaller firms take advantage of the falling barriers in globalized markets to grow even further than they would have at home. Third, the higher competitiveness enables rapid and intense internationalization that represent a means for cluster-based firms to exploit the advantages embeddedness in a given territory to exploit the associated positive externalities (skilled and specialized labor, specialized services, access to “collective international knowledge”, easy access to information on the internationalization strategies of main local competitors) on a larger scale in international markets (Maccarini et al., 2004). In sum, the above literature suggest that firm’s growth is related to their location and size, incentives associated with that location and its positive environmental incentives enable higher growth. Consequently, a higher concentration of rapidly growing smaller firms is more likely to be found in certain functional and enabling locations. The above discussion suggests the formulation of the first family of hypotheses, in the null form, as follows: H1a. There is no significant regional difference in the RGEs’ growth rate-related characteristics. H1b. There is no significant difference in the growth rates of RGEs with different sizes in terms of the number of employees. H1c. There is no significant difference in the growth rates of RGEs of different age (age of the enterprise from inception). International expansion and resource-based view (RBV) of the firm There is a wealth of literature pointing to the higher and faster growth of smaller firms that also internationalize earlier-on and are among the newly-emerging forms of organizations to which McDougall and Oviatt (1994) referred as international new ventures (INVs). The literature of entrepreneurship and small firm growth document a host of influential factors, both internal and external to the firm, stimulating growth (Covin and Slevin, 1989; Lu and Beamish, 2001; Wiklund et al., 2009). These smaller firms manage to rise above the adverse confluences of factors that cause demise in other similar firms and even grow at high rate beyond the short term. While some of their growth patterns are partially explained by the extant theories of growth and internationalization of smaller firms from different perspectives, including those emanating from entrepreneurship (Acs and Yeung, 1999; Morena and Casillas, 2007; Fischer and Reuber, 2003), international business (Maccarini et al., 2004; Nummela et al., 2004), economics of agglomeration and regional clusters (Huggins, 2008; Johansson, 2004) and management of small enterprise (Covin and Slevin, 1989; Wiklund et al., 2009), there is a need for an integrated explanation. From a more encompassing perspective, Penrose (1959, p. 24) considered the firm as “a collection of productive resources”, including management resources, and suggested that growth is the result of a manager’s strategic use of firm’s resources efficiently. Logically, the state of management impacts smaller firms’ growth more than that of the larger firms, as smaller younger firms suffer more from constrained resources, especially management experience and capabilities, than the larger firms. The above discussion is best captured by Penrose’s (1959) view that a company may or may not have better resources, but will achieve rents because of making a better use of its resources (in strategic and efficiency terms). This resonates highly with the issue at the heart of entrepreneurship: it is not the state of resources that motivate en entrepreneurs, but it is the ambitions of capable entrepreneurs and managers (Gundry and Welch, 2001; Wiklund et al., 2003) and their beliefs, attitudes and expectations (Wiklund et al., 2003), regardless of their resources, that put an entrepreneurial firm on strategically more efficient path that enables its higher growth. High-growth has been directly attributed to the presence and preponderance of other influential factors, prominent among them are the firm’s age and size (Dunne and Hughes, 1994; Knight et al., 2004), the type of small firms (Verhees and Meulenberg, 2004), firm’s strategic flexibility. Similarly, the resource-based view of the firm in particular (Barney, 1991; Grant, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1984) maintains that certain resources are required for supporting competitive strategy (Porter, 1998) to lead to the higher competitiveness necessary for higher growth. This higher growth is posted to be contingent upon more resources. In contrast, the entrepreneurship literature has focused on opportunity and the entrepreneur as the enabling factors of growth (Aldrich and Martinez, 2001; Gundry and Welch, 2001; Upton et al., 2001). Entrepreneurial theories (Kirzner, 1973; Aldrich and Martinez, 2001; Shane and Venkataramen, 2000) have maintained that a firm’s growth and overall success emanate from the confluence of the entrepreneurial characteristics or the fit in entrepreneur-owner-mangers and exploitation of opportunities (Acs and Yeung, 1999; Shane and Venkataramen, 2000). While Schumpeter (1934) saw a firm’s growth as the consequence of creating opportunity in the market place and fulfilling it through the process of creative destruction, Kirzner Rapid growth 575 MD 50,4 576 (1973) suggested that firms would only need to identify and then respond to such opportunities through strategic arbitrage. Therefore, the managers’ cognition of how to identify and fulfill opportunity (e.g. effectively formulating strategies for operating at the dynamic nexus of opportunity, information and resources as Shane and Venkataramen (2000) put it) may have a significant impact on the firm’s growth. However, this stance can be combined with the Penrose’s view of resource utilization by managers: For example, when earmarked resources are not efficiently utilized to realize an opportunity, a firm will have to bear the additional costs of acquiring more resources. Such inefficiencies result in lower, or slower, growth. This argument suggests that size, as a proxy for the possession of resources, may not be an appropriate indicator, because entrepreneurial firms with highly efficient and effective entrepreneur-owner-managers can compensate for their relatively poorer state of resources, whereas firms with richer resources but ineffective managers may fail to realize their full resource potentials. Size and age may enable higher growth, but they neither are necessary nor sufficient conditions[4]. There is a general agreement that the younger smaller firms suffer from constrained resources, which may include management capability and experience, especially in the early stages of their lifecycles (Davidsson and Honig, 2003; Karra and Phillips, 2004; Upton et al., 2001), which may inhibit rapid growth. However, the entry into the much larger international markets offer higher opportunities than a firm’s domestic market (which are necessary for higher growth) may compensate for the initially weaker state of entrepreneurship in smaller firms. Not only does the larger size and the higher diversity of international markets offer richer opportunities, but also the risk of realizing opportunities may be reduced as diversity may create room for new and novel activities not possible in the domestic context. This suggests that not only growth is dependent on the firm’s state of management (with number of employees as a proxy) but growth is also moderated by managerial acumen in seeking opportunity and on the way opportunities are exploited. In summary, the extant theory points to an unclear, if not contradictory, a-priori relation between internationalization and rapid growth. We formulate the second family of hypotheses, in a null form, to enable results to point to the actual direction, as follows: H2a. There is no significant difference in the growth rates of strictly domestically oriented and internationalized firms. H2b. There is no significant difference between the internationalization intensity for RGEs with different number of employees. H2c. There is no significant difference between the internationalization intensity for RGEs of different ages. These families of hypotheses enable us to explore selected aspects of rapid growth and internationalization and examine their variations across a few factors such as location, size, age, and internationalization intensity. Methodology We have built a longitudinal sample of more than 1,140 micro, small and medium-sized high-growth enterprises that have grown at exceptionally high rates for at least five years at relatively earlier stages of their life-span and in some cases from inception[5]. The data-base’s origin is he most prominent Canadian business publication, the Canadian Business, which annually identifies and ranks growing firms in order to publish a highly-popular annual list called “Profit 200: Canada’s 200 fastest growing companies”[6]. Although there are other lists of high-growth companies (e.g. McKinsey’s Top 50 High Technology, Touch Ross Top Fifty, etc.), we decided to use this list as a starting point because it uses a five-year time span and for its methodological and measurement prudence. In building the data base, we were cognizant of the recommendations of researchers regarding validity and concurrent reliability of growth measurements (Shepherd and Wiklund, 2009; Davidsson et al., 2009; Weinzimmer et al., 1998) and complied with them throughout this research. The annual members of the list had attained the highest growth in revenues over five consecutive years ending at the beginning of the publication year. We have compiled selected characteristics of all 200 members of six annual listings, from 2003 to 2008. As a small number of firms sustain their high-growth for more than five years and appear in more than one annual list, we decided to keep only the first appearance of the firm in the annual listing of such firms to avoid double counting. As a result, each firm appears only once in the database. The criteria for eligibility are very strict (also methodical, rigorous and transparent). In order to be eligible for consideration, certain pre-requisites must be met and much information must be submitted for further analysis: (1) All firms must submit complete financial statements based on GAAP for five consecutive years for calculating their five-year growth rates. (2) They must have been founded and been generating revenues for at least five consecutive fiscal years from the first week of their fiscal year five years ago (called the base of “t”, hereafter) and to show continued five full years of revenue growth (called “t þ 5”, hereafter). (3) All firms must have had their headquarters in Canada with a significant Canadian operation and be independent as of December 31st of the nomination year. (4) All firms must have had more than 50 percent Canadian ownership if a privately owned company, while public companies with 50 percent or less Canadian ownership are judged on a case-by-case basis). (5) All firms must have had a minimum revenue of $100,000 in the base year “t” in order to ensure that their rapid growth had been built-upon a substantial base. (6) All firms must have had a minimum revenue of $1,000,000 in the most recent year (t þ 5); and independent contractors are excluded. (7) All firms must have also had some full-time and part-time employees in the base year, which are both included in the head count. (8) Subsidiaries or divisions of other companies, except for holding companies are excluded from consideration. Sample characteristics Although the majority of the 1,200 fastest growing, Canadian-based and independent companies in the original database qualify as SMEs, the selection criteria does not impose size restrictions; and as a result, the list includes firm with Rapid growth 577 MD 50,4 578 Table II. Summary profiles of sample characteristics of selected characteristics sizes ranging from micro to large firms. Table II provides a summary profile of these high-growth and rapidly internationalizing firms. A total of 46 of these companies are micro enterprises with one to nine employees, while there are 108 large firms with more than 500 employees with a wide range; but more than 85 percent are SMEs (see Tables II and III). Internationalization appeared to have had a positive impact on growth rates and other characteristics. We dichotomized the sample based on internationalization intensity in order to compare the impact of internationalization. As shown in Table II, internationalized firms have more impressive characteristics across all variables. For example, while the local enterprises (i.e. no reported international sales) attain impressive average FYCAGR of 1,560 percent, firms with internationalized activities achieve even higher FYCAGR of 1,883 percent. For this latter group, about 72.5 percent of the sample, the average internationalization intensity measured in terms of the proportion of revenues from international sources is about 55 percent with a median of 65 percent. These young firms have an average age of less than 11 years with the median of nine years from inception. Their revenues after five years of high-growth increase by a factor of 10, more than $27 million for the local firms and more than $50 Million for internationalized firms. Finally, the median FYCAGR for the local high-growth firms is consistently smaller than the corresponding average FYCAGR for internationalized firms, indicating that the cumulative growth distribution is skewed to the left of the median for the entire sample. In other words, more than 50 percent of the firms in the sample attained larger FYCAGRs than that of the median over five year. Exports as % revenues (n ¼ 1136) Revenues @ t (n ¼ 1139) Revenue @ t þ 5 (n ¼ 1139) Age (n ¼ 1139) Staff @ t (n ¼ 1112) Staff @ t þ 5 (n ¼ 1138) Delta staff (n ¼ 1138) Growth rate (n ¼ 1138) (%) Median Average Maximum Minimum 0.26 $1,011,760 $10,123,0630 9 13 67 48 729.5 0.396 $4,803,537 $44,300,054 10.64 36 202 182 1,795 100 $184,000,000 $2,130,210,580 40 484 6,993 6,520 112,519 0 $16,980 $512,850 5 2 2 0 179 Local firms (n ¼ 313) Average Median Table III. Comparison of selected characteristics for local firms and internationalized firms Exports as % of revenues Revenue @ t Revenue @ t þ 5 Age Staff @ t Staff @ t þ 5 Delta staff Growth rate (%) 0 $3,233,023 $27,400,00 11.48 31 175 145 1,560.5 0 $853,908 $7,530,641 9 10 41 29 613 International firms (n ¼ 826) Average Median 0.547 $5,398,660 $50,700,00 10.98 38 213 56 1,883.7 0.65 $1,147,792 $11,500,000 9 15 77 197 786 Analysis Given the distributional properties of the data and the non-random sampling, we choose non-parametric tests because they assume fewer statistical restrictions (Robinson and Hofer, 1997) and produce more conservative results than parametric tests (Siegel, 1956) as statistical requirements are not violated. As we aim to compare firm characteristics across geographical locations, size (defined by both the revenue and employment sizes), age and incremental employment over five years (i.e. Staff @ t þ 5 less Staff @ t, called Delta Staff in Tables II and III and hereafter) rather than explaining the causality in potential relationships, we used two-tailed tests of significance. The Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney and Chi-square tests were used to test the difference of the means in pair-wise comparisons. Similarly, the Kruskal-Wallis test, a nonparametric alternative to the analysis of covariance, was utilized to test for significance in n-sample cases (for a detail description see Siegel, 1956). Consistent with the extant literature on different categories of firm sizes, we assigned firms to four categories based on the number of employees: micro (1-9), small (10-99), medium, (100-499) and large (500 and more employees). Given the relatively lower number of firms based in the Canadian Prairie (Manitoba and Saskatchewan), Maritime (New Brunswick, Nova Scotia and Prince Edward Island) and the northern provinces and territories, we pooled them all together in a category called the “rest of Canada”. Therefore, we will be analyzing regional influence of five “regions” that refer to Alberta, British Columbia, Ontario, Quebec Provinces and the rest of Canada pooled together. We also followed Statistics Canada’s practice of assigning each firm’s location to one of five “regions” and referring to them as such hereafter. As noted earlier, we have stated our hypotheses in the null form to allow for objective interpretation of the empirical results of the statistical tests. The first hypothesis was designed to detect the potential differential impact of different geographic locations on the firms’ growth-related characteristics resulting from high-growth after five years. In our extensive statistical testing in search of differential regional impacts, we did not find significant statistical difference in growth-related characteristics of different firm sizes across the five regions. However, we found significant difference between the two extremes (i.e. micro and large firms). These two firm sizes have more pronounced differences regardless of their internationalization. Location seems to be relevant only when small and large firms (in pair-wise comparison) are compared at 5 percent significance level and the micro and large firms at a 10 percent significant level. The results for the tests are summarized in Tables III and IV. Stated differently, we found strong evidence (at a 5 percent significance level) that small-large firms and weak evidence that micro-large differ with respect to their location. The comparative impact of different growth-related characteristics of different firm sizes for local and internationalized firms are shown in Table III. The differential impact of location for both the local and internationalized firms are shown in the column entitled “location” in Tables IV and V respectively. Regarding age and size hypotheses, the results for age and the two indicators of size are shown in Tables IV and V under three different columns entitled “Age”, “Revenue @ t þ 5” and “Delta Staff”. The relationships between the indicators of age and size categories are mixed. The Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney tests suggest that there exists a statistically significant difference between the means of firms in terms of age except for the case of micro and small firms at a 5 percent significant level. The revenue @ t þ 5 Rapid growth 579 MD 50,4 580 Table IV. Comparison of the growth-related characteristics of local firms Prob . jzj and Z values Revenue @ t þ 5 Age Growth rate Delta staff Location Micro-small 0.000 24.159 0.328 20.977 0.242 1.170 0.000 2 7.790 0.754 Micro-medium 0.000 25.950 0.044 22.009 0.748 0.321 0.000 2 7.315 0.325 Micro-large 0.000 26.030 0.274 21.092 0.062 21.865 0.000 2 6.141 0.073 Small-medium 0.000 27.860 0.039 22.063 0.203 21.272 0.0000 2 11.604 0.258 Small-large 0.000 27.875 0.582 20.550 0.0007 23.376 0.000 2 8.272 0.038 Medium-large 0.000 25.738 0.443 0.766 0.017 22.374 0.000 2 7.503 0.260 Prob . jzj and Z values Revenue @ t þ 5 Age Growth rate Delta staff Location Micro-small 0.003 22.972 0.263 21.118 0.448 20.758 0.000 2 8.262 0.622 Micro-medium 0.000 27.462 0.016 22.398 0.235 21.186 0.000 2 8.101 0.817 0.0010 23.279 0.080 21.748 0.000 2 7.508 0.705 Micro-large Table V. Comparison of the growth-related characteristics of international firms 0.000 7.500 Small-medium 0.000 217.451 0.000 24.294 0.173 21.361 0.000 2 21.295 0.420 Small-large 0.000 214.855 0.000 25.450 0.022 22.287 0.000 2 14.987 0.718 Medium-large 0.000 211.409 0.003 22.892 0.222 21.220 0.000 2 13.580 0.861 and delta staff significantly differ by size of firms. However, the pair-wise comparison of different size categories suggests that there is no evidence that growth rate differs across the various size categories except for the pair-wise comparison of small and large firms. We found evidence that micro-small, micro-medium firms and small medium firms do not differs significantly on their growth rates. However, the evidence indicates that large firms grow faster than small and medium-sized firms and there is weak evidence to suggest the same for the case of micro-large firms. Similarly, we did not find evidence that the size in terms of number of employees is influenced by the firms’ regional location. The results of the tests are summarized in Tables IV and V under the corresponding columns. With respect to the impact of internationalization, we found strong evidence that local firms statistically differ from their internationalized counterparts with respect practically all growth related characteristics. Our overall comparison of local and international firms showed that they significantly differs in term of revenue at t þ 5, growth rate, delta staff, staff at t, staff at t þ 5. Furthermore and as shown in Table VI, the sign of Z values is always in favor of the internationalized firms in comparison to local firms. For example, the increases in revenue (Revenue at t þ 5) and employment size (Delta staff) of the internationalized firms are significantly larger (using the Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney test). In terms of age, only micro-medium and small-medium firms showed weak evidence that their age differ (alpha ¼ 5 percent). Based on the results presented in Table VI, we can strongly argue that internationalized firms have attained higher figures, while the local and international firms have similar means. Rapid growth 581 Discussion Factors enabling high-growth rates Our analyses show that Canadian RGEs are not exclusively in high-knowledge intensive or high-technology industries or specific to one or two regional industrial clusters. Nevertheless, Ontario, British Columbia, Alberta and Quebec have the highest concentration of RGEs and RIEs but these companies are also present in the rest of the provinces. Similarly, they are found in a diverse set of industries and different sizes with different, but all high, growth rates across times. Interestingly, more than two thirds of them are active in the international markets. Their average five-year cumulative growth rate is 1,795 percent. On average, they are less than ten-years old. The number of their average employees in the base year is about 36 staff members, which increases to more than 200 after five years of growth. While domestically oriented firms (RGEs) have impressive figures, their internationally oriented counterparts (RIEs) achieve higher performance. For example, they achieve higher average growth rates (1,883 vs 1,560 percent), generate higher revenues ($50,700,000 vs $27,400,000) and become larger (213 vs 175 staff members) after five years of high-growth at a younger age (10.98 vs 11.48 years). Although, they constitute a small portion of continuing firms in Canada; they are by no means “illusive” as there is a continuous stream of them in all sizes across time and industries. While Table I provides the profile of these firms in terms of selected characteristics of the entire population of REs, Table II distinguishes RGEs that export from those who do not in our sample. We called them “internationalized firms” and “local firms”, respectively. In fact, the former characterize typical rapidly internationalizing enterprises (RIEs). Regarding influential factors, the literature of growth points to a confluence of three influential factors as noted earlier: external influences, internal factors and their interactions. The economics of agglomeration (Marshall, 1961), externalities (Combes and Duranton, 2006; Johansson, 2004; Scitovsky, 1954), regional industrial clusters (Marshall, 1961; Feldman et al., 2005) and conducive policy environment (Acemoglu and Johnson, 2005; Porter, 1990) are among the external factors found to be influential. Prob . jzj and Z values Local-international firms Revenue @ tþ5 0.000 2 5.174 Age Growth rate 0.922 0.000 20.097 24.712 Delta staff Staff t 0.000 0.0007 2 5.016 23.404 Staff @ tþ5 Location 0.000 24.948 0.017 2.386 Table VI. The comparison of the growth-related characteristics of the local and international firms MD 50,4 582 Such factors are capable of generating certain economies and conferring the corresponding advantage on the firms located in a region that are not available to firms located elsewhere. These economies reduce the firm’s transaction costs (Williamson, 1975), which contribute to the firm’s competitiveness and consequent high and rapid growth. Logically, when a firm’s management recognizes and exploits such regional incentives and externalities to its advantage, it can grow faster. However, our analysis provides almost no support for such external economies as factors impacting rapid growth and rapid internationalization, although smaller firms appear to benefit from location-specific advantages more than the larger firms. We could not accept the hypothesis regarding the impact of location (H1A) as we did not find significant difference among RGEs located in different regions in Canada. It appears that regional incentives and externalities may have fostered higher concentrations of RGEs; but have not resulted in significantly higher growth rates. We suggest that this mixed result is because of behavioral factors: when positive externalities results in incremental competitiveness for some firms, competitors are forced to catch-up in order to compete for survival. Naturally, strategic emulation is a logical choice: by moving into enabling environments and regional industrial clusters, entering firms can access similar pertinent economies for exploitation to gain comparable competitiveness (Karlsson et al., 2008). These economies would attract more firms to the cluster, increase competition among them that results in the cluster’s and region’s growth, but may not lead to competing firms’ higher growth. Therefore, extra-market economies that are available within a region may confer differential advantages that help firms to gain initial competitiveness but it would erode over time as more firms enter the region and vigorously compete for similar advantages. On the subject of the internal influences, these firms appear to be highly entrepreneurial. For example, they do not seem to have been hampered by insufficient resources by compensating for disadvantage, and other deficiencies, by rapidly covering their potential gaps in order to avoid slowing-down their growth. Their entrepreneur-owner-managers may have recognized early on that markets treats all firms roughly in the same fashion and it is hard, if-not impossible, for a young firm to exploit intra-market externalities, if and when such externalities can be identified within the market. However, extra market externalities may confer any initial incremental comparative advantage on the firm to place itself on a higher growth platform before others migrating to the location to take advantage of them. This explains as to why location failed to account for RGEs’ higher growth rates averaged across five years possibly in the later growth stages. This failure also suggests other interesting possibilities: . the theory of agglomeration does not have much explanatory power for RGEs as high-growth firms use efficiencies that are far beyond regional agglomeration economies; . the contribution of other potent factors may have over taken regional externalities; and . our index of location was not powerful enough to have discriminated between firms. In addition, there is little evidence to suggest that these firms have not taken advantage of inter-firm externalities within their proximity which is not necessarily bounded by geographical terms. In fact, Author suggest that RGEs and RIEs draw upon their social network and social capital that may be spread very widely. Such previously-not identified advantages may have provided opportunities to build a competitive position as rapidly as possible and to cover for families of gaps facing smaller growing firm (e.g. shortage of resources, inexperience, information, knowledge, contacts, lack of international presence, etc.) to avoid the adversity of fundamental chasms that most newly-emerging firms cannot overcome. Some manage to survive but fall behind others that grow faster. Our analysis provides indirect support for internal influential factors. We drew on the seminal work of Penrose (1959), who was among the earliest scholars to realize the impact of management as a valuable resource, similar to other valuable firm resources, as suggested by the resource-based view of the firm (Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1984). Assuming that management could identify and access all the necessary resources from external and internal sources, the necessary time and efforts for doing so is bound to take a toll in terms of taking time and adding to operating costs and even reduce a firm’s effectiveness, which would adversely impact its growth potential. As Porter (1991, p. 108) points out, “resources are not valuable in and of themselves, but they are valuable because they allow firms to perform activities [. . .] business processes are the source of competitive advantage.” Porter’s suggestion resonates with Penrose’s (1959) view that a company may not have more resources but still achieve rents because it of making better use of the resources at its disposal. Our results lend further support to the potency of internal factors, especially management. As noted earlier, the above review of literature formed the basis for the formulation four hypotheses (H1b, H1c, H2b and H2c) designed to examine the impact of age and a firm’s size on growth in terms of number of employees and revenues as proxies for resources and endowments. Age presented us with complexity of its own. On the one hand, progression of time provides the younger, smaller firms with larger customer base, experience and possibility of accessing larger and riche networks resulting in larger pool of resources. On the other hand, however, it becomes much more difficult to maintain the same growth, or attain higher growth rate, as the size of the firm becomes larger due to growth over time. These conflictive effects may have contributed to the failure of age in having significance impact on high-growth. Although we did not intend to show a cause-and-effect relations, both the overall test and pair-wise comparison tests show that the age difference among firms are not significant. Based on the results, we can refute the popular myth that only small firms are capable of rapid and high-growth and high-growth is a small size phenomenon. Regarding the impact of internationalization in terms of international intensity (the percentage of revenues generated in international markets), internationalized firms achieved higher average growth than the high-growth localized firms across the board. We argued that larger international markets offer larger potential opportunities for enabling further growth. This argument received empirical support as internationalized firms have done significantly better than the domestic ones. Conclusion This research indicates that RGEs are distinctive firms and are primarily small and medium-sized enterprises. Although the relative frequency of the appearance of various firm size-categories varies overtime, RGEs are found across all the size and age Rapid growth 583 MD 50,4 584 categories. As discussed earlier, this suggests that rapid-growth is not specific to only smaller sizes. In other words, high-growth is not an argument about the small starting base (the size @ t) enabling high-growth rates. Nor is it about the advantages of a particular region, time period or economic conditions. We used a commonly-accepted four size-categories in terms of micro (one to nine employees), small (10 to 99 employees), medium (100 to 499 employees), and large firms (more than 500 employees). Our analysis clearly shows that high-growth is not specific to smaller firms, nor is it specific to a particular region. Our analysis also shows that RGEs span across all the six time periods in our longitudinal sample and the five geographical regions (four provinces and others combined in a category termed the “rest of Canada”) in Canada. Furthermore, our findings provide implicit support for the impact of management capabilities and strategy as influential factors in growth. As regards the rarity of RGEs, the fact that Canadian Business has identified a continuous stream of RGEs in most of the Canadian regions across time and sizes, suggests that they are not rare or illusive. We suggest that the notion of illusiveness may have arisen in part due to the understudied and less-understood aspects of the high-growth phenomenon and in part due to the perceived rarity of growth rates beyond two to three times the normal rates of 1 to 10 percent per annum (corresponding to 5 percent to 61 percent FYCAGR, respectively). In this study, we found that more than 300 firms attained FYCAGRs higher than 2000 percent and internationalized firms achieved even higher rates across the board. Furthermore, broad country-based studies, as noted earlier, have reported that the number of high-growth enterprise is in the range of four to five percent of continuing firms’ population. The topic of high-growth deserves the attention of entrepreneurship and growth scholars. As growth is a time-dependent phenomenon and RGEs attain higher growths in shorter times, they offer a remarkably shorter, and thus richer, potential for uncovering the puzzle of growth and growing firms. The topic also deserves the special attention of policy makers as high-growth firms generate employment, income, social benefits, taxes and wealth at much higher and faster rates than an average growing firm. However, they may require a special policy environment as their overall benefits seem to well outweigh the cost of such environments. We suggest that formulaic rule without due consideration for RGEs’ capacity to create knowledge, generate high technology and spill-over for other firms, foster change and act as catalyst for other firms to emulate, cannot well-serve the interest of any of the stake holders concerned. We suggest that RGEs deserve close attention for their high potentials. However, if our observation regarding HGEs as under-studied phenomenon is an indication of the difficulties in examining them, the policy community faces even tougher challenges than the academic community for creating highly conducive policy environments to stimulate the growth of potential firms to become RGEs. On the face of it, the a priori odds are not in favor of typically smaller and younger firms turning into rapid growing enterprises. The silver lining, however, is in the empirical evidence that these firms maintain high-growth potentials beyond one or two years, which offer the policy community the opportunity to improve upon their diagnostic tools and measures to identify them earlier-on in order to augment their growth with conducive policies. This study covers a gap in the extant literature of growth pertaining to the internationalization of smaller firms and thereby contributes to the interaction of the both fields. However, in-depth case studies and broadly based surveys are necessary for deeper understanding of high-growth and internationalization as well as the influential factors, including the internal characteristics of its agents, especially those of the management. Although this research carries the limitations of using secondary data, the publicity and prominence associated with the Profit Top 200 lists and the strict standards of its publisher have instilled a high level of rigor and reliability in the list over the past two decade that is at least matching, if not exceeding, characteristics of primary data. Furthermore, the authors’ exercise of extreme prudence, as discussed earlier, gives this research a high level of reliability and validity. Notes 1. Internationalization belongs to an extensive literature on the subject and is defined broadly as a firm conducting a part of its activities beyond its home country. “Forward internationalization” refers to generation of revenues in international markets; while “backward internationalization” refers to “out-sourcing” and “off-shoring” from international sources. For a more extensive definition and analysis of internationalization’s impact on smaller firms’ competitiveness and growth, see Etemad (2011). 2. In his book, A Blue Print to a Billion: 7 Essentials to Achieve Exponential Growth, Mr Thompson, a former McKinsey consultant, examined the seven common essentials in a set of 387 “Blueprint companies”. The book chronicled the common processes by which “billion dollar firms” grew rapidly from an IPO since 1980 and reached $1 billion in revenue by 2005. The book became available in 2006. 3. Using Bygrave and Minniti’s (2000) terms, entrepreneurial activities expand the society’s “production possibilities frontier”, which benefits the society as a whole (i.e. is a social benefit). Naturally, HGEs’ contribution to that expansion is relatively higher than that of other firms and thus have higher social benefits. 4. The mixed empirical evidence regarding the relationship between size and age and rapid growth are consistent with the above arguments. 5. It is important to note the fact that high-growth rates are located on the right side of growth rate distribution and in that sense high-growth enterprises are representing the right-tail of overall population of continuing firms’ growths. 6. This lists serves as the bench marking baseline for others to emulate. It has become a de-facto list of young corporate heroes. Many companies on the lists are recognized by the Chamber of Commerce, relevant industry associations and the government agencies. The executive of these companies receive top awards for their achievements. As a result of this attention the process of identifying them for the list has become methodical, rigorous and transparent. References Acemoglu, D. and Johnson, S. (2005), “Unbundling institutions”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113 No. 5, pp. 949-95. Acs, Z.J. and Mueller, P. (2007), “Employment effects of business dynamics: mice, gazelles and elephants”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 85-100. Acs, Z. and Yeung, B. (1999), “Entrepreneurial discovery and the global economy”, Global Focus, Vol. 11 No. 3, pp. 63-71. Acs, Z.J., Braunerhjelm, D.B., Audretsch, H. and Carlsson, B. (2009), “The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 32 No. 1, pp. 15-30. Rapid growth 585 MD 50,4 586 Aldrich, H. and Martinez, M. (2001), “Many are called, but few are chosen: an evolutionary perspective for the study of entrepreneurship”, Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, Vol. 25 No. 4, pp. 41-56. Audertsch, D. and Sanders, M. (2008), “Globalization and rise of the entrepreneurial economy”, discussion paper no. 08-21, Tjalling Koopmans Research Institute, University of Utrecht, Utrecht. Baldwin, J.R. and Gu, W. (2003), “Export-market participation and productivity performance in Canadian manufacturing”, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 36 No. 3, pp. 634-57. Barnard, P., Fischer, E., Reuber, R. and Rumball, D. (1998), “Elusive gazelles: finding them and helping them grow”, summary of a think tank organized by Fulcrum Partners, January. Barney, J. (1991), “Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage”, Journal of Management, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 99-120. Birch, D. (1987), Job Creation in America: How Our Smallest Companies Put the Most People to Work, Free Press, New York, NY. Birch, D., Haggerty, A. and Parsons, W. (1993), Gazelle Jobs, Cognetics, Boston, MA. Bordt, M., McVey, J. and Short, A. (2005), “Characteristics of firms that grow from small to medium size: industrial and geographic distribution of small high-growth firms”, Statistics Canada, Catalogue No. 880006XIE2005005, Ottawa. Bougrain, F. and Haudeville, B. (2002), “Innovation, collaboration and SMEs internal research capacities”, Research Policy, Vol. 31, pp. 735-47. Breschi, S. and Lissioni, F. (2001), “Knowledge spill over and local innovation system”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 975-1005. Brunello, B. and Gambarotto, F. (2007), “Do spatial agglomeration and local labor market competition affect employer-provided training? Evidence from the UK”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 1-21. Bygrave, W. and Minniti, M. (2000), “The social dynamics of entrepreneurship”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 25-36. Chen, X. and Glen, C. (2004), “On the intricacies of the Chinese guanxi: a process model of guanxi development”, Asia Pacific Journal of Management, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 305-24. Combes, P. and Duranton, G. (2006), “Labor pooling, labor poaching and spatial clustering”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 36 No. 1, pp. 1-28. Covin, J. and Slevin, D. (1989), “Strategic management of small firms in hostile and benign environments”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 10 No. 1, pp. 75-87. D’Aveni, R.A. (1999), Hypercompetition: Managing the Dynamics of Strategic Maneuvering, Free Press, New York, NY. Davidsson, P. and Honig, B. (2003), “The role of social and human capital among nascent entrepreneurs”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 301-31. Davidsson, P., Steffens, P. and Fitzsimmons, J. (2009), “Growing profitable or growing from profits: putting the cart before the horse”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 388-406. Dechenaux, E., Goldfarb, B., Shane, S. and Thursby, M. (2003), “Appropriability and the timing of innovation: evidence from MIT inventions”, working paper 9735, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Delmar, F., Davidson, P. and Gartner, W.B. (2003), “Arriving at the high-growth firm”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 18, pp. 189-216. Dunne, P. and Hughes, A. (1994), “Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s”, The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 42 No. 2, pp. 115-40. Etemad, H. (2011), “International growth of smaller firms from emerging economies and internationalization theories”, in Etemad, H. (Ed.), The Process of Internationalization in Emerging SMEs and Emerging Economies, Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, MA. Etemad, H. and Keen, C. (2009), “Profiling and modeling high-growth and rapidly internationalizing enterprises from Canada”, Proceedings of the Annual ASAC Conference, June 6-9, Niagara Falls. Feldman, M., Francis, J. and Bercovitz, J. (2005), “Creating a cluster while building a firm: entrepreneurs and the formation of industrial clusters”, Regional Studies, Vol. 39 No. 1, pp. 129-41. Fischer, E. and Reuber, R. (2003), “Support for rapid-growth firms: a comparison of the views of founders, government policymakers, and private sector resource providers”, Journal of Small Business Management, Vol. 41 No. 4, pp. 346-65. Grant, R. (1991), Contemporary Strategic Analysis: Concepts, Techniques, Application, Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, MA. Granovetter, M. (1985), “Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness”, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91 No. 3, pp. 481-510. Gulati, R. (1995), “Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in alliances”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 85-112. Gundry, L. and Welch, H. (2001), “The ambitious entrepreneur: high-growth strategies of women-owned enterprises”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 16 No. 5, pp. 453-70. Halabisky, D., Dreessen, E. and Parsley, C. (2006), “Growth in firms in Canada, 1985-1999”, Journal of Small Business and Entrepreneurship, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 255-68. Halabisky, D., Lee, B. and Parsley, C. (2005), Small Business Exporters: A Canadian Profile, Small Business Policy Branch, Ottawa. Hallberg, K. (2001), “A market-oriented strategy for small and medium-scale enterprises”, discussion paper no. 40, World Bank, Washington, DC. Hoffman, A. and Junge, M. (2006), “Documenting data on high-growth firms and entrepreneurs across 17 countries”, mimeo, FOR A, Copenhagen. Huggins, R. (2008), “The evolution of knowledge clusters”, Economic Development Quarterly, Vol. 22 No. 4, pp. 277-89. Hymer, S. (1960), The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Foreign Direct Investment, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Jack, S.L., Dodd, S.D. and Anderson, A.R. (2004), “Social structures and entrepreneurial networks: the strength of strong ties”, International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 107-28. Johansson, B. (2004), “Parsing the menagerie of agglomeration and network externalities”, CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series No. 2, CESIS (Centre of Excellence for Science and Innovation Studies), The Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, available at: www. inra.kth.se/cesis/research/workpap.htm (accessed 21 October 2010). Karlsson, C., Johansson, B. and Stough, R. (2008), “Entrepreneurship and innovation in functional regions”, CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series No. 144, CESIS (Centre of Excellence for Science and Innovation Studies), The Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm. Karra, N. and Phillips, N. (2004), “Entrepreneurship goes global”, Ivey Business Journal Online, p. A1. Rapid growth 587 MD 50,4 588 Keen, C. and Etemad, H. (2008), “High-growth and rapidly internationalizing smaller enterprises from Canada”, 11th McGill International Entrepreneurship Conference, December 15-18, 2008, Dunedin, New Zealand. Keen, C. and Etemad, H. (2011), “The impact of entrepreneurial capital and rapidly growing firms: the Canadian example”, International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 273-89. Knight, G. and Cavusgil, T. (1996), “The born global firm: a challenge to traditional internationalization theory”, in Cavusgil, S. and Madsen, T. (Eds), Advances in International Marketing, JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, pp. 11-26. Knight, G., Madsen, T.K. and Servais, P. (2004), “An inquiry into born-global firms in Europe and the USA”, International Marketing Review, Vol. 21 No. 6, pp. 645-65. Kirzner, I. (1973), Competition and Entrepreneurship, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL. Krugman, P. (1991), “Increasing returns and economic geography”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99 No. 3, pp. 483-99. Lotti, F., Santarelli, E. and Vivarelli, M. (2003), “Does Gibrat’s law hold among young, small firms?”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol. 14, pp. 213-35. Lu, J. and Beamish, P. (2001), “The internationalization and performance of SMEs”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 22 Nos 6/7, pp. 565-86. McDougall, P. and Oviatt, B. (1994), “Toward a theory of international new ventures”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 45-64. McEvily, B. and Zaheer, A. (1999), “Bridging ties: a source of firm heterogeneity in competitive capabilities”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 20 No. 12, pp. 1133-56. Maccarini, M., Scabini, P. and Zuchella, A. (2004), “Internationalisation strategies in Italian district-based firms: theoretical modeling and empirical evidence”, working paper 2004/3, Facoltà di Economia, Università dell’Insubria, Varese. Markman, G. and Gartner, W. (2002), “Is extraordinary growth profitable? A study of Inc. 500 high growth companies”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 65-75. Marshall, A. (1961), Principles of Economics, An Introductory Volume, 8th ed., Macmillan, London. Minniti, M. and Bygrave, W. (1999), “The microfoundations of entrepreneurship”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 41-52. Morena, A.M. and Casillas, J.C. (2007), “High-growth SMEs versus non-high-growth SMEs: a discriminant analysis”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp. 69-88. Nummela, N., Saarenketo, S. and Puumalainen, K. (2004), “A global mindset-a prerequisite for successful internationalization?”, Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 51-64. Parker, S.C., Storey, D.J. and van Witteloostuijn, A. (2005), “What happens to gazelles? The importance of dynamic management strategy”, research report, Entrepreneurship Research Series, Centre for Entrepreneurship, Durham Business School, Durham University, Durham. Parsley, C. and Halabisky, D. (2008), “Profile of growth firms: a summary of Industry Canada research”, Industry Canada, Government of Canada, Ottawa, March. Penrose, E. (1959), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Wiley, New York, NY. Porter, M. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Macmillan, London. Porter, M. (1991), “Towards a dynamic theory of strategy”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12 No. 2, pp. 95-117. Porter, M. (1998), “Cluster and the new economics of competition”, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 90 No. 2, pp. 73-93. Pouder, R. and St John, C. (1996), “Hot spots and blind spots: geographical clusters of firms and innovation”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 21 No. 4, pp. 1192-225. Rennie, M. (1993), “Global competitiveness: born global”, The McKinsey Quarterly, Vol. 4, pp. 45-52. Robinson, K.C. and Hofer, C.W. (1954), A Methodological Investigation of the Validity and Usefulness of Parametric and Nonparametric Statistical Data Analysis Techniques for New Venture Research, Babson College Press, Wellesley, MA, pp. 143-705, Frontiers of Entrepreneurship. Robson, G., Gallagher, C. and Daly, M. (1993), “Diversification strategy and practice in small firms”, International Small Business Journal, Vol. 11 No. 2, pp. 31-40. Rothwell, R. and Dodgson, M. (2007), “External linkages and innovation in small and medium-sized enterprises”, R&D Management, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 125-38. Schreyer, P. (2000), “High-growth firms and employment”, OECD Science, Technology and Industry working papers 2000/3, OECD Publishing, Paris. Schumpeter, J. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development, Harvard University Press, Boston, MA. Scitovsky, T. (1954), “Two concepts of external economies”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 62, pp. 143-51. Shane, S. and Venkataramen, S. (2000), “The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 217-26. Shepherd, D. and Wiklund, J. (2009), “Are we comparing apples with apples or apples with oranges? Appropriateness of knowledge accumulation of growth studies”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 33 No. 1, pp. 105-23. Shirley, M. (2005), “Institutions and development”, in Menard, C. and Shirley, M. (Eds), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Springer, Dordrecht, pp. 611-38. Siegel, S. (1956), Nonparametric Statistics for the Behavioral Sciences, McGraw-Hill, New York, NY. Thomson, D. (2005), Blueprint to a Billion: 7 Essentials to Achieve Exponential Growth, Wiley & Sons, New York, NY. Torre, A. and Rallett, A. (2005), “Proximity and localization”, Regional Studies, Vol. 1 No. 39, pp. 1-13. Upton, N., Teal, E. and Felan, J. (2001), “Strategic and business planning practices of fast growth family firms”, Journal of Small Business Management, Vol. 39 No. 1, pp. 60-72. Van Praag, M.C. and Versloot, P.H. (2008), “The economic benefits and costs of entrepreneurship: a review of the research”, Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship Research, Vol. 4 No. 2, pp. 65-154. Verhees, F. and Meulenberg, M. (2004), “Market orientation, innovativeness, product innovation, and performance in small firms”, Journal of Small Business Management, Vol. 42, pp. 134-54. Weinzimmer, L., Nystrom, P. and Freeman, S. (1998), “Measuring organizational growth: issues, consequences and guidelines”, Journal of Management, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 235-62. Rapid growth 589 MD 50,4 590 Wernerfelt, B. (1984), “A resource based view of the firm”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 171-80. Wiklund, J., Davidsson, P. and Delmar, F. (2003), “What do they think and feel about growth? An expectancy-value approach to small business managers’ attitudes toward growth”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 27 No. 3, pp. 247-70. Wiklund, J., Patzelt, H. and Shepherd, D. (2009), “Building an integrative model of small business growth”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 32 No. 4, pp. 351-74. Williamson, O. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications, Free Press, New York, NY. Yang, C.-H. and Huang, C.-H. (2005), “R&D, size and firm growth in Taiwan’s electronics industry”, Business Economics, Vol. 25 No. 5, pp. 477-87. Further reading Baldwin, J.R. (1998), “Were small producers the engines of growth in the Canadian manufacturing sector in the 1980s?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 349-64. Birch, D.L. and Medoff, J. (1994), “Gazelles”, in Solmon, L.C. and Levenson, A.R. (Eds), Labor Markets, Employment Policy and Job Creation, Westview, Boulder, CO, pp. 159-67. Gomes-Casseres, B. (1997), “Alliance strategies of small firms”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 33-44. Makino, S., Isobe, T. and Chan, C. (2004), “Does country matter?”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 25 No. 10, pp. 1027-43. Corresponding author Christian Keen can be contacted at: keen@ort.edu.uy To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: reprints@emeraldinsight.com Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints