EXECUTIVE PAY POLITICS Read three typical scenarios about executive compensation. How justifiable, fair, & equitable are those outcomes? What are some legitimate criteria for basing your judgments? A. Medical diagnostic firm captured another 10% of its market & stock price rose +25%. Its Board gave CEO $1.5 million bonus plus options to buy 200,000 shares; vice presidents got similar compensation. Each employee received $800 bonus. B. Airline company lost 20% of passengers after Sept 11th, share price plummeted by two-thirds. It laid off 2,000 workers but, thanks to $15B federal aid voted by Congress, top executives still took home their 10% bonuses voted by its Board last year. C. Widget manufacturing firm closed one plant, laying off 300 workers. Executives agreed to take a 10% salary cut and no bonuses while they try to restructure company operations. Distributive Justice Principles Distributive justice theory offers several alternative norms for allocating goods (wealth) in limited supply relative to demand All except the first principle involve some correlation between work performance and rewards: Strict Egalitarianism: Everyone should be rewarded identically regardless of their work effort Contribution: People should be rewarded according to the value of their work contribution to the social product Effort: People should be rewarded according to the amount of effort they expend on their work activity Compensation: People should be rewarded according to the costs they incur in their work activity WHICH PRINCIPLES SHOULD APPLY TO EXEC PAY? A Widening Gap Business Week reported diverging ratio of CEO compensation to average worker pay, sharply increasing during the 1990s: U.S. vs the World Executive pay levels in Europe and Japan are lower than in U.S. Average CEO Pay for Medium-Sized Firms (revenues of $250-500 million) United States $1,072,400 CEO-worker pay ratios in 1999: U.S. 34:1 Britain 24:1 France 15:1 Britain $645,540 France $520,389 Germany 13:1 Canada $498,118 Japan 11:1 Average $480,037 Netherlands $449,889 Australia $431,890 Japan $420,855 Germany $398,430 Source: Towers Perrin, Worldwide Total Rewards 1998 (April 1998) p.21 “It’s the European mentality. The enrichment of the individual on the backs of the workers is considered exploitation.” - Director of German shareholder protection association (1998) Are CEOs Underpaid for What They Do? CEOs deserve huge rewards for undertaking high-risk tasks where they can’t control macroeconomic conditions shaping their company’s growth, profits, stock prices Salary.com, a compensation advisory firm, argues that corporate executives are worth every penny and more: • CEO job requires extreme skills and responsibilities • Limited number of people who can fill this role • 80% of CEO compensation tied to firm performance • CEO pay level signals of how well the company is doing • Yardstick for all other employee benefits and bonuses Winner-Take-All Contests Under free market capitalism, executive pay set by supply & demand for scarce talent, similar to the auctions bidding up prices for exceptional athletic and entertainment “stars”: • Shortstop Alex Rodriguez signed record $252M ten-year contract with Texas Rangers • Timberwolf Kevin Garnett held out for $126M over 6 years • Is Jim Carey really worth $20M per movie (Ace Ventura; Cable Guy; Dumb & Dumber; Grinch Who Stole Christmas)? (Socially constructed) scarcity in supply of top managerial skills, plus large transaction costs of searching for replacements, makes company boards willing to pay very high premiums to attract and hold onto CEOs and their executive teams. Sources of CEO Compensation CEOs & other top executives’ primary compensation not in salaries, bonuses & perks (planes, clubs), but from stock options How Do Stock Options Work? Stock options give employees the right, but not the obligation, within a specific time span to purchase a pre-set number of shares at a fixed price (“grant” or “strike price”), usually set at current share value when option is granted. Employee hopes stock price will rise, so that selling his optioned shares at a later date will yield a profit. EX: Firm X grants a 1-year option to buy 1M shares at Nov 2001 price of $10. If market raises value to $12 per share by Nov 2002, how much profit could CEO make by buying at the strike price then immediately selling at the market price? What if the stock price falls to $8 per share by Nov 2002? Pay-for-performance incentive: By inducing CEOs & other employees to take larger stakes in company’s performance, stock options act as strong incentives for them to work to improve the firm’s performance Principals & Their Agents Agency theory is finance economists’ predominant theoretical explanation of the link between exec pay & firm performance Agency relationship: a principal (board of directors) contracts with an agent (CEO) to perform services requiring delegation of decision-making authority to the agent Problem: Transaction cost difficulties for a principal to obtain accurate information about agent behavior & thus to safeguard shareholders’ interests: - how competently is agent performing services? - is agent deceptively pursuing personal goals (opportunism = self-interest with guile)? Solution: design compensation policies that align agent and shareholder interests – Incentives that reward improving observable outcomes (shareholder wealth) Pay for Performance Systematic evidence about the pay-for-performance accountability suggests mostly weak relationships CEOs often risk-averse to having a large percent of their pay package vulnerable to events beyond their control To protect their investments & avoid catastrophes, CEOs may undertake more cautious, less-innovative actions Jensen & Murphy (1990) found that changes in firms’ shareholder wealth explained only 3% of the CEOs’ pay variation from 1974-86, about one week’s income! They considered this effect “small for an occupation in which incentive pay is expected to play an important role” Booming economy further weakens pay-for-performance connection: A rising stock market means executive stock options usually have substantial pay-off even when a firm under-performs the other companies in its industry Decoupled Performances & Rewards Annual rite of notorious news reports about CEOs who made out like bandits despite poor company performances. Some 2000-2001 “outrages” during the bear market: Minnesota’s ADC Telecomms paid retiring CEO William Cadogan $45M, but laid off half of its 22,500 employees and plans to eliminate 150 managers Staples Inc stock fell -47%; board gave top execs $45M Novell stock fell from $43 to $5; CEO Eric Schmidt’s salary freeze & bonus cut was offset by new million-share stock option to "retain and motivate superior executive personnel." Pacific Gas and Electric Co. paid $50M bonus to Chairman Robert Glynn and top execs before declaring bankruptcy; asked federal judge to allow $17M more to keep senior managers from leaving General Electric Co.'s Jack Welch made $ 136 million in 2000, an 80 percent increase over 1999 even as total GE shareholder return fell –6% Disney’s Eisner cut 3% of payroll to save $400M, but got a $11.5M bonus. Graef Crystal said, “He’s willing to live by the sword, but not die by the sword.” One of the Good Guys? Disney CEO Michael Eisner is often slammed as poster-boy for excessive executive pay. But look at his company’s performance: • Disney’s stock grew 21.6% annually over 1987-97 decade • Eisner’s 1997 contract option on 8M shares may be worth $771M by 2006 Mouse & Friends But, when Disney’s profits fell –22% in 1999, top execs lost their bonuses. Eisner had to live on mere pittance: $700,000 salary and $50M in exercised stock options Graef Crystal, repentant pay consultant, argued “Eisner plays the game fairly by assuming a relatively high degree of pay risk” (1992) Playing Board Games To protect their interests, CEOs have learned to become skillful corporate politicians who enhance their power at expense of board of directors’ independence. CEOS subvert the legal principal-agent relationship by • Using proxy machinery to stack boards with insiders, friends, and similar outsiders (“homosocial reproduction”: Kanter) • Drawing on social capital ties (interlocking director networks) to perpetuate passive approach to compensation • Persuading board’s compensation committee to apply low-risk criteria (subjective judgment of efforts not objective results) • Controlling information to conceal evidence of poor performance, incompetence & deceptive behavior • Using ingratiation (opinion conformity, flattery, favors) & persuasion (defending policies, blaming external events) to remove threats of ouster Farewell to the Chief CEOs rarely ousted for poor performance by a Board Coup GM board’s 1992 forced resignation of Robert Stempel Dismissals disguised as “I want to spend more time with my family” Nonvoluntary CEO turnover usually preceeded by poor firm performance & steep share price drop, which trigger: - Takeover attempts - Shareholder lawsuits - Institutional investor pressures CEO succession dynamics (Ocasio) Institutionalization of power: entrenched & insulated CEO’s inflexible strategies increasingly fail to solve firm’s performance problems Circulation of power: Rivals within dominant coalition emerge to contest for control, force CEO expulsion, attempt revitalization Data show rising forced CEO turnovers in past decade Shorter Writing #11: Under the U.S. legal system, corporate boards of directors have a duty to govern in the best interests of the firm. Despite this shareholder-primacy principle, CEO pay continues to accelerate and often seems only weakly related to firm performance. Discuss at least two aspects of CEO-board relations that help to explain why directors appear unable or unwilling to link executive pay tightly to such company performance indicators as profits & share prices.