Currency Appreciation in Emerging Asia and Trade Deficit in the US James Xiaohe Zhang Newcastle School of Business Faculty of Business and Law, University of Newcastle, University Drive, Callaghan, NSW, 2308, Australia Telephone: 612-49215034, Fax: 612-49216919 Email: James.Zhang.@newcastle.edu.au Abstract Despite the global trade imbalance narrowed during the current economic recession, the improvement is not evenly distributed across different regions. While many economists blame the US trade deficit to the undervaluation of currencies in emerging Asia in general, and to the undervalued Chinese RMB in particular, no consensus has been reached as yet. Since a unilateral revaluation of the RMB has failed to reduce the trade deficit in the US, some commentators have recommended a joint appreciation of currencies in the emerging Asia as an instrument to restore trade balance between the US and Asia. Based on several simulation exercises on a multi-country macro-econometric model (the Fair model), this paper examines the likely consequence of the joint appreciation of the emerging Asian currencies on the trade deficit in the US. According to the results of simulations, neither a drastic unilateral appreciation of the RMB, nor a joint appreciation of currencies in emerging Asia, would reduce the trade deficit in US significantly. Paper prepared for the Joint conference of Edith Cowan University and Yokohama National University2010 Globalization, Monetary Integration and Exchange Rate Regimes in East Asia,22 - 23 November 2010, Perth Western Australia. Notes on Contributor Dr James Xiaohe Zhang is lecturer in economics at the University of Newcastle specializing in economic development and international economics. He has published many articles in journals including China Economic Review, Journal of Development Studies, and the Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy. Key words: China, RMB, exchange rate, revaluation, appreciation ACE theme: Aspects of the China Economy and Business; International Economics, International Finance, Trade and Political Relations JEL system: O19 (International Linkages to Development), O24 (Foreign Exchange Policy), O53 (Asia) 0 Currency Appreciations in Emerging Asia and Trade Deficit in the US 1. Introduction In the new millenarian, we have witnessed rising global imbalances that can be characterized by large current account deficits for the US and large current account surpluses for most East Asian countries and oil exporting nations. Despite the global trade imbalance narrowed during the current economic recession, the improvement is not evenly distributed across different regions (IMF, 2010). In economies with large external surplus before the crisis, most notably the emerging Asia in general and China in particular, the growth of exports remains strong, and trade surplus keeps surging. Most interestingly, the surge in China’s exports in recent years has been accompanied by an accumulated appreciation of the Renminbi (RMB) for more than 20% against the US dollar in nominal terms between 2005 and 2010. When the RMB broke 7 yuan per US dollar for the first time in 13 years, China's current account surplus hit a historical record of US$ 296 billion in 2008, accounting for 10% of its GDP. As a result of rapid growth in exports and trade surplus, China’s foreign exchange reserves exceeded US$2.27 trillion by November 2009 (Chung, 2009), more than double the foreign exchange reserves of Japan, the second largest holder of foreign exchange reserves in the world. As compared, the US, the largest economy in the world, has been suffering from huge current account deficits. When China’s current account surplus increased to an astonishing 11% of GDP in 2007, the US current account deficits reached 6.5% of GDP in 2006 (Benhima and Havrylchiyk, 2010:107). The US absorbs an overwhelming share of the world’s trade surplus, particularly from Asia. For instance, the US imports from China overwhelmingly excesses its exports to China despite both exports and imports maintained at double digit growth rates until 2008. The surging Chinese exports in the US market makes China the largest contributor to the US rising trade deficit with its share on the overall US trade deficit increased from 1 22% in 2000, to 25% in 2003, 31% in 2006 and 38% in 2008. Figure 1 presents evidence that the movements in the US current account deficit have been symmetrical with those in the current account surpluses of China. Figure 1 China's Export, Import and Trade Balance (1978-2008) 1500 1000 US$b 500 0 1978 1985 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 -500 -1000 exports imports China's current account US' current account Sources: National Statistical Bureau of China, and US. Census Bureau. The figure is plotted in the basis of official data obtained from China Statistical Yearbook for China (see http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/statisticaldata/yearlydata/) and from the US. Census Bureau, 2009 Statistical Abstract (see http://www.census.gov/compendia/statab/brief.html). Against this backdrop, the US Congress has attempted to pressure the Chinese authorities to revalue the RMB further. At the time when this paper was written, Premier Wen Jiabao and President Barack Obama were met in the US for the UN general meeting. When Obama argued that the RMB is "valued lower than market conditions say it should be" and that gives China "an advantage in trade," Premier Wen Jiabao said a 20% rise in the RMB would cause severe job losses and trigger social instability, putting the nation on course for a clash with US lawmakers demanding a stronger currency. 2 These events have also attracted tremendous academic interests on the issues of how trade imbalance in the world economy is created, and what is needed to be done to mitigate it if complete removal is impossible. Many, if not most, economists blame the US trade deficit to the undervaluation of currencies in emerging Asia in general, and to the undervalued RMB in particular. Although there is no agreement reached on how a RMB appreciation should make to the correction of global payment imbalances, particularly reducing the large US trade deficit, some commentators (see for instance, Cline and Williamson, 2008, Goldstein and Lardy, 2008, 2009:51) have recommended that the RMB should appreciate for at least 25% from its current level to cut the share of its trade surplus on GDP by half, and for 45% to remove the surplus completely. Furthermore, Goldstein and Lardy (2009:67) argue that “because emerging Asia plus Japan has roughly a 40% weight in the Fed’s trade weighted dollar index, a 20% real appreciation in all Asian currencies would translate into an 8% real depreciation of the dollar and probably a $100 billion to 140 billion improvement in the US current account deficit”. This proposal, nevertheless, is based on an assumption that the currencies in emerging Asia in general and the RMB of China in particular, are seriously undervalued, as estimated by a variety of measures. Many economists believe that the RMB is undervalued on an order of 15% to 35% before 2005 (Frankel 2006, Zhang and Pan, 2004, Chang and Shao, 2004, Goldstein 2007, and Goldstein and Lardy, 2003, 2006, among others), and is still about 30 to 40% above its long run equilibrium exchange rate, much larger than it was few years ago when the RMB was firstly revalued in July 2005 (Evarard and Chong 2007, Bénassy-Quéré et al, 2008, and Goldstein and Lardy, 2008:51-55, 2009:26).1 Among those who believe that the RMB is significantly undervalued, many argue that the appreciation of RMB would be the major instrument of removing the trade imbalance at least between China and the US. For instance, Goldstein and Lardy (2009:51) maintain that a 10% real effective appreciation of the RMB could reduce China’s global trade balance by a range of 2.5% of GDP, so to eliminate China’s global trade surplus of roughly 10% 3 of GDP, a minimum real effective appreciation of RMB by 40% is required. When many, if not most, economists are in favor of a considerable revaluation, a case against the revaluation has also emerged. The opponents include Mundell (2006), Stiglitz (2005), McKinnon (2006, 2007), Corden (2007, 2009), and Woo (2008), among others. Mundell maintains that a too sharp revaluation of RMB would even cause a financial crisis because the revaluation will lead to a fall in import price and deflation which could bring more pressures on RMB. Other adverse impacts include slowing down in foreign direct investments, shrinkage in profit margin in Chinese exports and increase in unemployment. In reference to the conflict over trade imbalance between the US and China, Stiglitz (2005) believes that even if the Chinese exports are reduced as a result of RMB appreciation, the US trade deficit will not be removed since the other East and Southeast Asian exporters could easily fill the gap. This view is shared by McKinnon (2006) who believes that an expectation for RMB appreciation, along with a negative interest rate risk premium, could create a near zero interest rate trap, a consequence that has been experienced by Japan for a decade. He therefore suggests China keeping its pegged exchange rate regime. While acknowledging that the appreciation would have little effect on the current account in both China and the US, Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009) maintain that a revaluation of the RMB alone would lead to improvements in the current accounts of other East Asian countries while having little effect on the Chinese current account. Thus, the revaluation might aggravate the current account imbalance that exists between the US and East Asia. To remove the global imbalance, coordinated exchange rate policy among the East Asian countries is therefore necessary and deadly required. Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009) maintain that since China and other Asian economies are structurally distinctive, while an appreciation of the RMB alone would have no impact on the US trade deficit, it is not only the Chinese RMB but also other East Asian currencies that need to be revalued or allowed to appreciate against the US dollar in order to reduce the current account imbalance. 4 Corden (2007, 2009) considers China’s huge trade surplus and the trade deficit in the US as a kind of “inter-temporal trade” which may only be resolved by policy coordination between the credit countries such as China and the debit countries such as the US, should the restoration of world trade balance be a goal of the first priority for these countries. Bergsten (2009) also points out that the only healthy way to reduce the US external deficits to a sustainable level is to raise the rate of national saving and to maintain budget rectitude. Weather currency appreciation is an effective solution for the global trade imbalance especially for settling the conflicts in trade between China and the US is an empirical question that cannot be answered without some quantitative analysis on a variety of issues. Furthermore, since the two notable proposals being offered, i.e., a considerable once-for-all revaluation of another 25% for the RMB, plus 20% appreciation in other emerging Asia (Goldstein and Lardy 2008, 2009), versus implementing a fiscal stimulus in China instead (McKinnon 2008, McKinnon and Schnabi 2009, and Ogawa and Iwatsubo 2009), are conflicting with each other, the controversy cannot be solved without some quantitative assessment on the relevant policy scenarios. Given the fact that empirical study in this area is still limited, this paper attempts to fill the gap. The task is carried out through experimenting simulation exercises on a simple macro-econometric model with the two policy recommendations. This paper contributes to the existing literature by shedding a new light on the issue of how the appreciation of the currencies in the emerging Asia in general, and the revaluation in RMB in particular, affect the trade balance in the US. This is compared with an alternative expansionary fiscal stimulus policy adopted in China since 2009. This paper is organized as follows. The next section reviews briefly the empirical studies on the relationship between the value of a currency and the global trade balance, with a focus mainly on the RMB appreciation and its impact on the trade deficit in the US. Section 3 presents the research methodology and summarizes the 5 simulation results. Concluding remarks and policy implications are generalized in the final section. 2. An overview of empirical studies on currency and trade Imbalance Despite the theoretical discussion on the relationship between changes in the value of a currency and its impact on the trade flows and hence trade balance is well documented, empirical studies on the real impact of joint appreciation of Asian currencies in general, and the appreciation of RMB on the US trade deficit in particular are still limited. The majority of studies has been based on a partial equilibrium elasticity approach where no multi-country trade structure is specified. 2 For instance, Thorbecke (2006), employing Johansen MLE and dynamic OLS techniques, finds that the long run real exchange rate coefficients for exports and imports between China and the US equal approximately unity, indicating a possibility of improving the trade balance between the two countries when the RMB is appreciated. Marquez and Schindler (2006), using an autoregressive distributed lag model and China’s shares in world trade, report that a 10 percent appreciation of the RMB would reduce China’s share of world exports by half a percentage point and China’s share of world imports by a tenth of a percentage point. After estimating structural vector autoregressive models with contemporaneous restrictions based on neo-classical and Keynesian theories to assess whether the main determinant of the current account for each of the East Asian countries is GDP or the real effective exchange rate, Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009) distinguish China from other emerging Asian countries from a fact that China is the only country for which domestic GDP, or aggregate domestic demand, determines its current account whereas the exchange rate, rather than domestic GDP or US GDP that contributes to the current accounts of other East Asian countries. Based on this, they suggest that policy-makers should adopt different measurements to reduce the current account surplus between China and other East Asian countries. They thus hypothesize that the RMB revaluation would improve trade balance of current accounts of Japan, Korea, Indonesia, and Thailand because these countries’ trade structures are substitutable with that of 6 China, but deteriorates the current accounts of Singapore and Malaysia because the negative indirect effect through GDP is larger than the direct effect of appreciation. Other studies use either theoretical mathematical models (e.g., Liu and Zhang 2010, Whalley and Wang 2010) or computable general equilibrium models (e.g. Zhang and Fung 2006, Willenbockel, 2006, and Zhang, 2009) to assess the economic particularly the sectoral impact of the appreciation. With the former, Liu and Zhang (2010:12) maintain that despite its effective role in bringing down inflation, a large nominal appreciation of the RMB brings about large fluctuation in the economy and tends to lead large welfare losses. Whalley and Wang (2010), on the other hand, maintains that the net impacts of RMB appreciation are elasticity dependant, means larger substitution elasticities in preference yield larger effects on trade flows and the surplus. Based on the result derived from a multi-country computable general equilibrium (CGE) model, Zhang and Fung (2006) point out that a significant appreciation of the RMB would result in a general decline in welfare across the globe, but it would not reduce the trade deficit in the US. Using a modified CGE model, Zhang, Fung and Kummer (2006) conclude that RMB appreciation will have no impact on the trade imbalance between China and the US because the Chinese exports are necessary goods with inelastic demand. Through simulations in a 17-sector CGE model of the Chinese economy, Willenbockel (2006) indicates that a real exchange rate revaluation which results in a fall of 4% in China’s trade balance would require a fall in China’s real exports by 10.7-11%, depending on different assumptions used. The strongest negative employment effect occurs in the textile, sewing and leather sector, which is also the sector with the strongest reduction in exports and the highest initial export-output ratio. Machinery and equipment sector, with the highest share in total exports and the second-highest benchmark export-output ratio also shrinks. Using a more generalized GTAP model, Zhang (2009) derives a similar result. However, since all these studies are based on the CGE models that are usually sensitive to the calibration of the elasticities, their results may need to be qualified and confirmed by 7 some macro-econometric models. As compared with the studies based on economic modeling framework for the Chinese economy, the empirical studies using applied empirical models for the emerging Asia are even more limited. Using a dynamic general equilibrium (DGE) model of the world economy, Cova et al (2009) attribute the growing trade imbalance between the emerging Asia and the US as a result of productivity deceleration in the nontradable sector and the desired net foreign asset increase in the emerging Asia. Using a panel dataset including China’s exports to 33 countries, Thorbecke and Smith (2010) find that while a 10% RMB appreciation would reduce ordinary exports by 12% and processed exports by less than 4%, a 10% appreciation of all other East Asian currencies would reduce China’s processed exports by 6%. Rahman and Thorbecke (2007), based on a generalized method of moments techniques, indicate that while a joint appreciation would significantly reduce China’s exports, a unilateral appreciation would not. Applying a multi-country macro-econometric model developed by himself for more than a decade, Fair (2010) finds that even with a drastic appreciation of 25% of the RMB in the early 2000s, the estimated effects on US output and employment are still modest. When the international repercussion effect is taking into account, the positive effects of output from a decrease in imports from China are offset by the negative effects on US output from increased inflation and from a decrease in US exports to China because of a Chinese contraction. Since there are many links among countries, and these links must be taken into account for analyzing the effect of exchange rate changes, the use of a multi-country macro-econometric model seems appropriate. The Fair model which permits changes in a large group of countries and a variety of national and regional macroeconomic variables including the exchange rate, interest rate, government spending and taxes, is one of the best models that one can use to carry out a quantitative analysis for the currency appreciations in the emerging Asia. 8 3. The Model, the Scenarios and the Results 3.1 The Model In order to assess the effectiveness of currency appreciation on trade imbalance between the emerging Asia and the US, a multi-country econometric model (MC) of Fair (2004, 2009, 2010) is used. The MC model is presented in Fair (2004), and the last version of the model is called MCE which was updated January 30, 2010. There are two parts in the model, the “US model,” and the rest of the world (ROW). The ROW model consists of estimated equations for 37 countries which include most countries in the emerging Asia. There are up to 13 estimated equations and 16 identities per country, totalizing 274 estimated equations in the ROW model. The estimated equations explain total imports, consumption, fixed investment, inventory investment, the domestic price level, the demand for money, a short term interest rate, a long term interest rate, the spot exchange rate, the forward exchange rate, the export price level, employment, and the labor force. The MC model is completely estimated (by 2SLS) from historical data and there is no calibration at all. In the MC model, any changes in one or more exogenous variables in a country will make a difference between the projected dataset and its original benchmark dataset which is based on econometric regression of long term historical statistics (1960-2008) for each variable and for each country. After the model is solved and the results obtained, one could compare the new dataset with the benchmark dataset and take the divergence between the two datasets as the “net impact” of the proposed policy. A group of endogenous macroeconomic variables including GDP growth, inflation, consumption, investment, export, import, current account and employment could be then compared and analyzed. The latest version of the MC model allows its users to forecast some proposed policy changes such as revaluation of currency and a fiscal stimulus policy for a country for a future period between 2010 and 2020. In its dataset, the exchange rate is defined 9 as local currency per US dollar, so a decrease in the exchange rate is a revaluation against the dollar. 3.2 The scenarios The macroeconomic setting of the effect of revaluation under a fixed or pegged exchange rate regime is well documented in economic literature. When a country revalues its currency, the export price level will rise in terms of foreign currencies in international market and the price of imports will fall in terms of domestic currency in domestic market. Since the foreign demand for the country’s exports falls when the price of its exports increases, the revaluation will lead to decrease in demand for the country’s exports. Opposite consequence occurs simultaneously for imports. The revaluation is thus contractive and deflationary: the level of exports falls, the level of imports rises, and the domestic price level decreases. This in turn, through the trade and price links of the MC model, affects the production and international trade of all other countries in the rest of the world. Furthermore, so long as the sum of export elasticity and import elasticity is greater than unit, a situation defined as the Marshall-Learner condition in international economics, the current account surplus of the country will be reduced as a result. However, the fall in export of a country that appreciates its currency, will also result in a fall in its real GDP, which in turn, reduces the domestic aggregate demand including demand for imports. If the fall in domestic aggregate demand is big enough, the price effect of the appreciation could be more than offset by the income effect. One of the advantages of using multi-country macro-econometric model is its ability to identify not only the price effect but also the income effect of a currency change, through the model’s price and financial links among a large group of countries. The following three experiments attempt to simulate and examine the overall impact of the two notable policy recommendations offered by Goldstein and Lardy (2008, 2009) that China should lead a joint appreciation in currencies of the emerging Asia 10 to help the US restore its trade balance, and by Stiglitz (2005), McKinnon (2006, 2007), and Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009) who believe that the appreciation of RMB will have little impact on the US trade deficit, but an expansionary fiscal stimulus policy may alternatively do a better job. Scenario 1: unilateral RMB revaluation. The RMB rate is revalued by 25% in 2010 and then the new rate of 5.123 yuan per dollar would be maintained for the whole period between 2010 and 2020. Since all other things remain the same, it is termed as unliterary revaluation, a policy option proposed by Goldstein and Lardy (2008, 2009), among others, as a first step to restore the world trade imbalance, particularly aimed at reducing the US trade deficit. Scenario 2: fiscal stimulus in China. Since China would spend 4 trillion yuan ($586 billion) to stimulate its domestic economy by funding extensive infrastructure construction, aiding poor farmers, and cutting export taxes, it is assumed that the stimulus fiscal expansion plan would result in a 25% increase in government purchases between 2009 and 2012.3 This is a policy package advocated by McKinnon and Schnabi (2009), Krugman and Obstfeld (2009: 655), and Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009). Scenario 3: joint revaluation in emerging Asia. This is a scenario proposed by Goldstein and Lardy (2008, 2009), and Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009) who believe that the appreciation of currencies in Asian economies collectively may help to restore the global trade balance. Four Asian emerging economies, namely China, Thailand, Malaysia and the Philippines where national data are available in the Fair model are chosen for the following experiment: each country revalues its currency by 20% from its 2010 level and the new rate remains constant over the projected period between 2010 and 2020. 3.3 The Results 11 The experiments of a drastic unilateral appreciation of RMB by 25% in 2010, an expansionary fiscal policy of increasing 25% of government purchases in China between 2009 and 2012, and a joint appreciation of all of the four emerging Asian currencies are separately simulated. To assess the international repercussion for the policy change in China and emerging Asia, the US and Japan are chosen as reference countries in the world economy for comparison and analysis. The percentage change of five major macroeconomic variables, namely GDP, GDP price index (as a proxy of inflation), export, import, and trade balance which is defined as the difference between a country’s export and import for all countries are reported in the following three tables. Interestingly, as one can see from the first two tables, the two policy packages of a drastic unitary revaluation of the RMB and a fiscal stimulus in China create quite different sequences in almost every aspect. While the revaluation policy is contractive and deflationary, the fiscal stimulus is expansionary and inflationary. When the overall impact of RMB revaluation on production and trade in China and the rest of the world including the US is generally negative, though quite moderately, the impact of the fiscal stimulus policy is more constructive not only in boosting domestic economic growth, but also for improving the external trade imbalances between the two countries. As displayed in Table 1, there are modest drops in GDP and trade in all countries in the unilateral RMB revaluation scenario. While the impact is contractive and deflationary for China, there is a stagflation effect in the US. While the trade surplus in China and trade deficits in the US both fall moderately, the trade deficit as a share of GDP keeps growing in the US over time. With the 25% revaluation of the RMB, the trade surplus as a share of GDP falls marginally in China within a range of only a half to one percentage point over time. 12 Table 1 The Impact of 25% Revaluation of the RMB on Global Trade Balance (Percent Changes as Compared to the Benchmark Database) a GDP Price Index Exports Imports Trade Balance Trade Balance b on GDP (%) China 2010 -0.92 -0.083 -1.54 -0.31 -7.49 6.92 2011 -1.73 -0.123 -2.66 -0.88 -11.63 6.69 2012 -2.06 -0.142 -2.96 -1.48 -10.79 6.77 2013 -2.12 -0.151 -2.97 -1.94 -8.63 6.92 2014 -2.06 -0.155 -2.87 -2.24 -6.57 7.03 2015 -1.97 -0.156 -2.78 -2.38 -5.31 6.85 2020 -1.6 -0.153 -2.34 -2.23 -3.32 6.02 2010 -0.17 0.004 0.03 -0.69 -3.79 -2.63 2011 -0.15 0.005 -0.07 -0.98 -5.01 -2.66 2012 -0.11 0.006 -0.16 -1.01 -4.60 -2.91 2013 -0.09 0.006 -0.23 -0.94 -3.70 -3.33 2014 -0.08 0.007 -0.26 -0.85 -2.95 -3.78 2015 -0.08 0.007 -0.28 -0.77 -2.46 -4.17 2020 -0.06 0.007 -0.26 -0.55 -1.81 -4.16 2010 -0.06 0.001 -0.29 0 -0.75 5.91 2011 -0.11 0.001 -0.48 -0.01 -1.06 7.11 2012 -0.17 0.001 -0.65 -0.03 -1.32 7.98 2013 -0.22 0.002 -0.8 -0.05 -1.53 8.69 2014 -0.27 0.002 -0.93 -0.08 -1.69 9.36 2015 -0.31 0.002 -1.11 -0.11 -2.06 8.88 2020 -0.5 0.003 -1.75 -0.24 -3.16 9.17 2010 -0.06 0.002 -0.06 -0.01 -1.26 3.23 2011 -0.1 0.003 -0.1 -0.02 -1.70 3.89 2012 -0.13 0.003 -0.13 -0.03 -1.88 4.32 2013 -0.15 0.003 -0.16 -0.05 -1.95 4.63 2014 -0.16 0.003 -0.18 -0.06 -1.96 4.89 USA Japan Thailand 13 2015 -0.17 0.003 -0.2 -0.08 -2.10 4.70 2020 -0.22 0.002 -0.28 -0.14 -2.86 4.41 Notes: a. The percentage change indicates the difference in values between the variables in the new dataset and their counterpart in the base dataset. While China’s data is shown annually, the fourth quarter of the US data is displayed. b. The trade balance is defined as the difference between export and import, i.e., net export. Since China has trade surplus and the US has trade deficit, a positive figure in the current account indicates an increase in the surplus (deficit) of the corresponding country. Table 2 The Impact of A Fiscal Stimulus in China on the Global Trade Balance (Percent Changes as Compared to the Benchmark Database) GDP Price Index Exports Imports Trade Balance Trade Balance on GDP (%) China 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 USA 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 Japan 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 3.26 2.70 2.13 1.67 -1.44 -0.97 -0.56 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.00 -0.18 -0.37 -0.47 -0.48 -0.34 -0.19 -0.09 -0.04 3.97 6.19 7.21 7.49 3.55 1.36 0.31 -0.09 -19.46 -32.14 -39.26 -42.62 -21.90 -9.21 -2.62 0.46 5.70 4.90 4.42 4.20 5.87 6.75 6.95 6.16 0.05 0.07 0.09 0.09 0.03 0.00 -0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.29 0.50 0.62 0.69 0.41 0.23 0.12 -0.06 -0.04 -0.05 -0.07 -0.09 -0.10 -0.13 -0.14 0.08 -1.49 -2.44 -3.11 -3.38 -2.08 -1.43 -1.03 0.67 -2.55 -2.66 -2.71 -2.94 -3.38 -3.84 -4.23 -4.26 0.21 0.40 0.54 0.66 0.43 0.24 0.11 -0.05 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.11 1.89 2.36 2.66 1.46 0.69 0.25 -0.13 0.01 0.04 0.08 0.14 0.18 0.20 0.19 0.07 3.32 4.80 5.21 5.40 2.70 1.12 0.30 -0.22 5.00 6.21 7.51 8.45 9.00 9.57 9.06 9.40 14 Thailand 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 0.46 0.80 1.01 1.11 0.49 0.04 -0.22 -0.11 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.48 0.83 1.06 1.21 0.62 0.23 0.00 -0.07 0.05 0.14 0.25 0.37 0.42 0.39 0.31 -0.03 15 16.17 16.81 16.40 15.42 3.80 -2.18 -4.88 -0.85 2.43 3.79 4.56 5.01 4.87 4.87 4.57 4.50 Table 3 The Impact of A Joint Revaluation in the Emerging Asia GDP Price Index Exports Imports Trade Balance Trade Balance on GDP (%) China 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 Malaysia 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 Thailand 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 Philippines 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 USA 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2020 -0.72 -1.37 -1.63 -1.68 -1.63 -1.55 -1.26 -0.06 -0.10 -0.11 -0.12 -0.12 -0.12 -0.12 -1.21 -2.10 -2.35 -2.35 -2.27 -2.19 -1.84 -0.24 -0.70 -1.17 -1.54 -1.77 -1.88 -1.75 -5.87 -9.21 -8.58 -6.84 -5.17 -4.14 -2.62 7.02 6.85 6.91 7.02 7.10 6.91 6.05 -4.99 -7.89 -7.90 -7.29 -6.80 -6.69 -7.77 -0.06 -0.09 -0.10 -0.10 -0.10 -0.10 -0.11 -3.99 -6.56 -7.12 -7.21 -7.26 -7.43 -8.61 -0.78 -2.05 -3.20 -4.01 -4.51 -4.83 -5.81 -16.25 -23.50 -21.81 -19.25 -17.65 -17.55 -20.85 20.45 19.80 20.57 21.37 21.92 21.85 21.30 -1.68 -2.76 -2.93 -2.77 -2.53 -2.37 -2.53 -0.04 -0.07 -0.10 -0.11 -0.12 -0.13 -0.14 -1.76 -2.85 -3.08 -3.06 -2.98 -2.96 -3.34 -0.17 -0.48 -0.82 -1.11 -1.33 -1.48 -1.78 -38.41 -47.55 -41.39 -33.84 -27.92 -26.65 -32.16 2.05 2.13 2.65 3.21 3.68 3.60 3.15 -0.01 -0.03 -0.03 -0.02 -0.01 0.01 0.05 -0.04 -0.07 -0.10 -0.11 -0.12 -0.13 -0.14 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01 -0.04 -0.07 -0.10 -0.12 -0.14 -0.12 -0.16 -0.97 9.92 2.49 1.89 2.10 1.27 -2.63 -1.14 0.26 1.61 2.93 3.31 5.64 -0.16 -0.14 -0.10 -0.08 -0.07 -0.07 -0.05 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.09 0.00 -0.10 -0.17 -0.21 -0.23 -0.22 -0.69 -0.98 -1.02 -0.95 -0.86 -0.78 -0.54 -4.07 -5.31 -4.87 -3.96 -3.19 -2.68 -1.95 -2.63 -2.65 -2.90 -3.32 -3.77 -4.16 -4.15 16 The reasons for this unusual consequence can be explained by examination of the different repercussion effects embodied in the equation systems of the Fail model for the two nations when the RMB is revaluated. After a careful analysis of the figures in the table, and checking the stochastic equations and the coefficients of the regressions in the Fair model, the following explanations are generalized. Firstly, it is found that the partial price elasticity of the Chinese traded good is actually inelastic. This can be verified by comparing the trade volume data with the price data in both exports and imports for both China and the US. While the US price elasticity is somewhere in the elastic range, the Chinese price elasticity is almost trivial. More interestingly, the positive sign of the partial price elasticity of imports for China suggests that when the revaluation is fully incorporated into the price of import in China, the volume of imports actually falls. This is consistent with the observations of the US Department of Labour that when the RMB appreciates 18% against the US dollar between June 2005 and March 2008, the price of Chinese goods imported to the US rose only 2.5% (Goldstein and Lardy, 2009:61). This reveals that there are some factors that have dampened the pass-through of the RMB appreciation. Goldstein and Lardy (2009:61) explain this as a result of sufficient productivity growth in the exporting firms in China over the same period. They thus speculate that the export surge after 2004 is created by increased ability of the Chinese exporting firms to absorb the adverse effect of RMB appreciation, when the growth of productivity in Chinese exports exceeded the pace of nominal appreciation over the same period. Secondly, after examining the specification of the Fair model for the coefficients of import demand functions, it is found that the Chinese imports are dominated mainly by income effect. In the database where the Fair model is constructed, China’s per capita marginal propensity of imports with respect to domestic aggregate demand per capita is as high as 0.81, ranking at the fourth highest in a group of 35 countries (Fair 2009:11). This indicates that the Chinese imports are overwhelmingly determined by domestic wealth or income effect. As a result, when China’s GDP falls 17 from its potential level as a result the drastic revaluation of the RMB, its imports falls with a faster pace. This is consistent with the finding of Baak (2008) that 1% depreciation of the RMB raises the Chinese exports to the US by 1.7%, while 1% depreciation of the US dollar raises the US exports to China by merely around 0.4%. Thirdly, even if the price elasticity of the US traded goods is elastic so the Marshall-Leaner condition may hold, the improvement in its trade balance would still be limited because the large import content in Chinese exports which is believed to be at a range of 30-35 % of the export value (Goldstein and Lardy 2008:21).4 These inputs are primarily imported from China's more advanced East Asian neighbors such as Japan, Korea, and Taiwan (Lemoine and Ünal-Kezenci, 2004, Tong and Zheng, 2008). Should this estimate be accepted, it would indicate that the import content of China’s exports could be as high as 44% in the mid 2000s.5 When the import content is taken into account, RMB appreciation will lead to a smaller export price increase than when exports had no import content. If the import component is extremely large, however, the overall impact of RMB revaluation may be totally neutralized. Perhaps for the some reason, the appreciation of the RMB, no matter if it is with or without the joint appreciations of other Asian currencies, will not boost exports and trade surplus in the other Asian economies. This invalids the hypothesis of Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009). As the second largest economy and largest exporter in the world, China now has unprecedented larger influence on the world economy than it had before. So when its growth rate slows as a result of a drastic appreciation of the RMB, it will also bring negative impact not only to the developed countries such as the US and Japan, but also to its raw materials suppliers such as the other emerging Asian countries and Australia. One of the explanations for the limited impact of RMB appreciation on trade balance refers to the “J curve” effect.6 The implication is that China’s trade surplus should increase immediately after the RMB appreciation due to instant improvement in its 18 terms of trade (Goldstein and Lardy, 2009:52). But the trade surplus will fall after a time lag when the price effect is fully passed if the Marshall-Lerner condition holds. However, the “J-curve” effect has not been found in the simulation results because there is no significant fall in both the surging trade surplus in China and the growing trade deficit in the US for the next decade, after a 25% revaluation of the RMB, both unilaterally and jointly with the other emerging Asian countries. The result seems to support the Stiglitz-McKinnon conjecture that the RMB revaluation affects the Chinese economy adversely, yet it has little impact on the trade imbalance in the rest of the world, particularly in reducing the trade imbalance between China and the US. In a sharp contrast, the result of Table 2 which shows the impact of the fiscal stimulus scenario brings a much more promising consequence in almost every aspect: GDP and trade grow faster in all countries without significant inflation threats for most of the years. When consumption and investment in China and saving rate in the US increased, and the federal government budget deficit in the US reduced, the global trade balance would be improved in such a way that when the China’s trade surplus falls significantly, the US trade deficit is also reduced. Table 3 shows the joint appreciation scenario which does not generate any significant impact to the global trade imbalance and the US trade deficit. When all the four countries revalue their currencies by 20%, the overall impact of the appreciation is generally negative and the falls in the US trade deficit is only marginally larger than the unilateral revaluation of the RMB scenario. This casts doubt on the policy recommendations offered by Goldstein and Lardy (2008, 2009) and Ogawa and Iwatsubo (2009). 5. Conclusion 19 In the basis of a brief review of the current literature, this paper assesses the major impact of a joint appreciation of emerging Asia currencies in general and a unilateral revaluation of the RMB in particular on the global trade imbalance particularly the huge trade deficit in the US. The appreciation scenarios are also compared with a fiscal stimulus policy in China, which is considered as an alternative policy for achieving the same objective. After examining and contrasting the two popular policy recommendations through running simulation experiments in a multi-country macro-econometric model (the Fair Model), this paper casts doubt on the effectiveness of using appreciation or revaluation as an instrument for removing the global trade imbalance, particularly for settling the trade conflicts between China and the US. The results of simulations seem to support the Stiglitz-McKinnon conjecture that a significant revaluation of the RMB brings mainly adverse impact not only for China but also for the rest of the world, yet has no significant impact on the global trade imbalance, particularly on reducing the huge trade deficit in the US. As compared, the fiscal stimulus policy could bring a much better consequence even though the improvement in the trade balance is merely a by-product of the stimulus scheme. In order to generate a more constructive consequence, the fiscal stimulus policy is more preferred than a drastic revaluation of the RMB, no matter if it is with or without a joint appreciation of currencies in the rest of the emerging Asia. Furthermore, through exploring the unusual responses of China’s export surge after the RMB appreciation, this paper discovers some particular features of the Chinese external economy, namely a rigid or sluggish price elasticity for exports and high marginal income elasticity for imports. It reveals that when the terms of trade effect dominates the export growth after the appreciation, the wealth effect of a fall in domestic demand dampens imports. This could be a more plausible source of the ineffectiveness of appreciation of RMB on improving the global trade imbalance. Despite the strong policy implications of the simulation results, the projection generated from the experiments should not be fully accepted unless a certain degree of caution is given. This is because the simulation result is derived from a 20 model where the Chinese economy is constructed in a rather simple way. As a result, some of the changes could have been exaggerated. The projection could be greatly improved if the model is modified to include more dynamic variables and more appropriate equations particularly in approximating the real exchange rate changes. More researches are therefore encouraged toward these directions. To conclude, this paper questions the effectiveness of using either a sustainable drastic appreciation of the RMB, or a joint appreciation of currencies in emerging Asia as a main instrument of restoring the global trade balance, and settling the conflicts in trade between the US and emerging Asia. Instead, it is in favor of some alternative policy measures including an expansionary fiscal policy and/or expansionary supply side policies to be adopted in the emerging Asia to obtain an overall balance. 21 References Aziz, Jahanger and Xiangming Li, 2008. “China’s changing trade elasticities”, China & World Economy, 16(3):1-21. Baak, Saangloon, 2008. “The bilateral real exchange rates and trade between China and the U.S.”, China Economic Review, 19, 117-127. Bagna, Alberto. 2009. “The role of China in global external imbalances: Some further evidence” , China Economic Review, Volume 20, Issue 3, September 2009, Pages 508-526 Bénassy-Quéré , Agnès and Amina lahrèche-Révil Valérie Mignon, 2008, “Is Asia Responsible for exchange rate misalignment within the G20?” Pacific Economic Review, Volume 13, Issue 1, pp46-51 Benhima, Kenza and Olena Havrylchiyk, 2010. “When do long-term imbalances lead to current account reversals”, The World Economy, Bergsten, C. Fred. 2009. “The Dollar and the Deficits: How Washington Can Prevent the Next Crisis”, Foreign Affairs, Volume 88 No. 6, November/December 2009 November 2009 Carbaugh, J. Robert (2009) International Economics (12th edition), South-Western College Publishing, Cincinnati. Web-site: http://carbaugh.swcollege.com Cline, W. and J. Williamson, 2008. “Exchange rate of the RMB, is there a consensus and if not, why not? ” Chapter 4 in Goldstein, M. and N. Lardy (eds) Debating China's Exchange Rate Policy, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Corden, W. Max. 2007.”Those Current Account Imbalances: A Skeptical View”, The World Economy, vol.30: pp.363-82. Corden, W. Max, 2009. “China’s exchange rate policy, its current account surplus and the global imbalance”, Economic Journal, 119(541). Cova, Pietro , Massimiliano Pisani and Alessandro Rebucci, 2009. “Global Imbalances: The Role of Emerging Asia”, Review of International Economics, Volume 17, Issue 4, pages 716–733) Coudert,Virginie Cécile Couharde, Real equilibrium exchange rate in China is the renminbi undervalued?, Journal of Asian Economics, Volume 18, Issue 4, August 2007, Pages 568-594 Dunaway, Steven, Lamen Leich and Xiangming LI, 2009, “How robust are estimates 22 of equilibrium real effective exchange rate: the case of China”. Pacific Economic Review, 14(1), 361-375. Everard, Beniamin and Ternce Tai-Leng Chong, 2007, “The revaluation and future adjustment of the Renminbi”, The Chinese Economy, Vol 40, No. 5, pp6-20. Fair Ray C. 2004, Estimating How The Macroeconomy Works, Harvard University Press, 2004. Also available in http://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog/FAIEST.html , accessed 12 October 2009. Fair Ray C. 2009, “The ROW part of the MCD model”, Appendix B of MCD model workbook, available in http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/mcd/docum/mcdapb.pdf, accessed 12 October 2009. Fair Ray C. 2010, “Estimated Macroeconomic Effects of a Chinese Yuan Appreciation”, see http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/rayfair/pdf/2010A.PDF , accessed on 18 September, 2010 Frenkel, J.A., Gylfason, T., and Helliwell, J.F., 1980. A synthesis of monetary and Keynesian approaches to short-run balance of payments theory. Economic journal, 90, 582–592. Frankel Jeffrey, 2006 “On the Yuan: The Choice Between Adjustment Under a Fixed Exchange Rate and Adjustment under a Flexible Rate,” CESifo Economic Studies, Munich), May 10 2006. Goldstein, M. and N. Lardy, 2006, ‘China’s Exchange Rate Dilemma’, American Economic Review, 96 (2), 422-426. Goldstein, M. and N. Lardy 2008, Debating China's Exchange Rate Policy, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Goldstein, M. and N. Lardy 2009, The Future of China’s Exchange Rate Policy, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Hirezkowski Henryk and Lurong Chen, 2010. “Outsourcing and trade imbalances: the United States – China Case”. Pacific Economic Review15(1):56-70., IMF, 2010. World Economic Outlook (WEO): Rebalancing Growth. April 2010, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2010/01/index.htm accessed on 20 September 2010. Ito, Hiro, 2009. “U.S. current account debate with Japan then, with China now”, Journal of Asian Economics 20 (2009) 294–313. Kaplan, Stephen B. 2006. “The Political Obstacles to Greater Exchange Rate 23 Flexibility in China” World Development Vol. 34, No. 7, pp. 1182–1200, 2006 Krugman, Paul, 2010, “Chinese New Year,” The New York Times, January 1. Krugman, P. and Obstfeld, M. (2009) International Economics: Theory and Policy, 8th edition, HarperCollins Publishers, New York. Kwack, Song Yeung, Choong Ahn, Yeung Lee, and Du Yang, 2007. “Consistent estimate of world trade elasticities and the appreciation of the yuan”, Journal of Asian Economics, 18(2):314-30. Lemoine F. and D. Ünal-Kezenci, “Assembly trade and technology transfer: The case of China”, World Development 32 (5) (2004), pp. 829–850. Liu, Li-gang, and Wenlang Zhang, 2010. “A New Keynesian model for analysing monetary policy in Mainland China”, Journal of Asian Economics In Press, Available online 14 July 2010 Ma, Alyson C. , Ari Van Assche and Chang Hong, 2009, “Global production networks and China's processing trade”, Journal of Asian Economics In Press, Corrected Proof. Marquez, J., Schindler, J., 2006. Exchange rate effects on China's trade: an interim report. Federal Reserve International Finance Discussion Paper, No. 861. Federal Reserve Board, Washington McKinnon, Ronald, 2006. “China’s exchange rate trap: Japan Redux?”, 2006. American Economic Review, 96 (2), 427-431. McKinnon, Ronald, 2007. “Why China should keep its dollar peg”, International Finance, 10(1):43-70. McKinnon, Ronald. 2008. “Fix RMB Rate Against USD Again” China Stakes, http://www.chinastakes.com/story.aspx?id=808 accessed in 1st December 2008. McKinnon, Ronald and Gunther, Schnabi 2006, “Devaluing the dollar: A critical analysis of William Cline's case for a New Plaza Agreement”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Volume 28, Issue 6, September 2006, Pages 683-694 McKinnon, Ronald and Gunther, Schnabi 2009. “The case for stabilizing China exchange rate: Setting the stage for fiscal expansion”, China & World Economy, 17(1):1-33. Mundell, Robert, 2006, “Fast growth in economy, but not RMB appreciation” see http://english.people.com.cn/200602/14/eng20060214_242688.html and People's Daily, Feb. 13, 2006, accessed 22 July 2009 24 National Statistical Bureau of China 2008, Chinese Statistical Yearbook, many issues, see http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/statisticaldata/yearlydata/, accessed on 20 October 2009. Ogawa, Eiji and Kentaro Iwatsubo, 2009, “External adjustments and coordinated exchange rate policy in Asia”, Journal of Asian Economics Volume 20, Issue 3, May 2009, Pages 225-239 Rahman, Mizanur and Willem Thorbreke , “How Would China's Exports be Affected by a Unilateral Appreciation of the RMB and a Joint Appreciation of Countries Supplying Intermediate Imports?” RIETI Discussion Paper Series, March 2007 07-E-012, http://www.rieti.go.jp/jp/publications/dp/07e012.pdf , accessed on 26th September, 2010 Stiglitz, Joseph , July 2005, “Stiglitz on China and Why U.S. Economic Advice is Discounted”. Economists view, http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2005/07/stiglitz_on_chi.html accessed on 10 October 2009. Straub Roland and Christian Thimann, 2007. “The external and domestic side of macroeconomic adjustment in China”, Journal of Asian Economics, 21 (5), Pages 425-444 Sung Yeung Kwack, Choong Y. Ahn, Young S. Lee and Doo Y. Yang, “Consistent estimates of world trade elasticities and an application to the effects of Chinese Yuan (RMB) appreciation “, Journal of Asian Economics, 18(2):314-330. The US-China Business Council, 2009, US-China Trade Statistics and China's World Trade Statistics, see http://www.uschina.org/statistics/tradetable.html Accessed date 20 October 2009. Thorbecke, Willem. 2006. “How Would an Appreciation of the Renminbi Affect the U.S. Trade Deficit with China”, B.E. Journals of Macroeconomics: Topics in Macroeconomics , Vol. 6 [2006], Iss. 3, Art. 3, Thorbecke, W. and G. Smith, 2010, “How would an appreciation of the Renminbi and other East Asian currencies affect China’s exports”. Review of International Economics, 18(1):95-108. Thorbecke, W. and H. Zhang, 2009, “The effect of exchange rate change on Chinese labour intensive manufacturing exports”, Pacific Economic Review, 14(1), 398-409. Tong S. and Y. Zheng, China's trade acceleration and the deepening of an East Asian regional production network, China & the World Economy 16 (1) (2008), pp. 25 66–81 Tung Chen-Yuan and Sam Baker, 2004. “RMB revaluation will serve China’s self-interest”. China Economic Review, Vol. 15, No.3, page 331-5. Wang, Tao. 2004, “Exchange rate dynamics”, in E. Prasad (ed.), China’s Growth and Integration into the World Economy: Prospects and Challenges, IMF Occasional Paper 232, Washington DC. Whalley, John and Li Wang, 2010. “The impacts of Renminbi appreciation on trade flows and reserve accumulation in a monetary trade model” Economic Modelling, In Press, Corrected Proof, Available online 21 August 2010 Willenbockel, Dirk (2006): Structural Effects of a Real Exchange Rate Revaluation in China: A CGE Assessment, MPRA Paper, No. 920. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/920/ accessed on 20 September 2010 Woo, W. T. 2008, ‘Understanding the Sources of Friction in U.S.-China Trade Relations: The Exchange Rate Debate Diverts Attention Away from Optimum Adjustment’, Asian Economic Papers, vol.7: pp.65-99. Zhang, Jian, Hung-Gay Fung, Donald Kummer (2006) “Can Renminbi Appreciation Reduce the US Trade Deficit?”, China and the World Economy, Volume 14 Issue 1 Page 44. Zhang Jian and Hung-Gay Fung, 2006. “Winners and losers: Assessing the impact of Chinese Yuan appreciation”, Journal of Policy Modeling 28 (2006) 995–1009 Zhang Fan and Zuohong Pan, 2004. “Determination of China’s long-run nominal exchange rate and official intervention”, China Economic Review, Vol. 15, No.3, page 360-5. Zhang, Xiaohe, James, 2009. “The impact of the RMB revaluation on China and the world economy”, Chapter 8 in Chunlai Chen (edited) China's Integration with the Global Economy , page 141-160., Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA Endnotes: 1 Despite most commentators believe that the RMB is still undervalued, the estimation on the degree of undervaluation differs from one to another. Among the 18 studies listed in Cline and Williamson (2008), the gap between the equilibrium exchange rate and actual rated varies from an undervaluation of 56% (Frankel, 2006) to an overvaluation of 5% (Wang 2004). Moreover, all these estimations are challenged by Dunaway et al (2009) because they are all too sensitive to pass the sensitivity test, i.e., a small change in model specification, variable definition and time period used in the estimations would lead to very 26 substantial differences in the equilibrium exchange rate reported. 2 According to conventional textbook version of international economics, the Marshall-Learner condition states that if the sum of export elasticity and import elasticity is greater than unit, the current account surplus will decline as a result of currency appreciation (See Carbaugh 2010). 3 Since the proposed increase in national spending is 7.635 trillion yuan in 2009, up 22.1% in 2009, it seems that the increase in government spending by 25% and spend the 4 trillion stimulus package over four years between 2009 and 2012 is a reasonable estimate. 4 It is estimated that about half of Chinese exports were processing activities where the import content was as high as 55% in 2007 (Dunaway et al 2009:364, Ma et al 2009). The share of processing exports (i.e. exports conducted under the processing regime) in China's total exports has risen from 30% in 1988 to 55% in 2005. According to a recent estimation by Koopman et al (2008), only 20% of China's processing export value is produced in China, while the remaining 80% consists of the value of imported inputs. 5 For this reason, Bagna (2009) has argued that any attempt at dampening Chinese exports, to the extent that it proves successful, would also dampen Chinese imports, with an offsetting effect on the Chinese external accounts. Hierzkowski and Chen (2010) estimate that approximately two-third of the US trade deficit would disappear in 2003 should the imports of parts and components by both the US and China be absent. In the basis of value added terms, the US-China ‘true’ trade deficit was about US$30.2 billion, approximately half of what is reported. This would limit the real effectiveness of the RMB revaluation further. 6 The “J-curve” effect refers to the trend of a country’s trade balance following a change in the real exchange rate. An appreciation in exchange rate initially means exports are more expensive, or equivalently imports sell for less domestic currency, making the current account improve (a bigger surplus or smaller deficit). After a while, though, the volume of imports will start to rise because of their lower more competitive prices to domestic buyers, and foreign consumers will buy fewer of the costlier exports. Eventually, the trade imbalance should improve on what it was before the appreciation. 27