Lecture notes March 4 & 17 Chapter 9: Pure Competition We want to understand firm decision making in a perfectly competitive market. Before studying this market, we will first consider the differences among market types. 4 basic Market models: Model # of firms Pure Competition (ex/ agriculture) Monopolistic Competition (ex/ retail trade) Oligopoly (ex/ car companies) Monopoly (ex/ local utilities) Type of Control over product price Standardized None (homogeneous) Conditions of entry Easy Non-price competition None Many Differentiated Some (but not much) Fairly easy A lot (advertising, etc.) Few Standardized or differentiated Unique (no close substitutes) Some, but High mutually obstacles interdependent A lot Blocked Large number of fims One A lot (product differentiation) Public relations and advertising Pure Competition Characteristics: • • • • Large number of firms Standardized product -> consumers indifferent as to which firm they buy from Price taker -> since there are a large number of firms, each selling the same product, if you raise your price, no customer will buy from you. If you lower your price you make less profit. Therefore, you take the price of the industry. Free Entry and Exit -> no significant legal, financial or technical barriers prevent new firms from starting up, or old firms from closing down. Demand for a Purely Competitive Seller: Because the firm is a price taker, demand for its goods is perfectly elastic. Note: market demand for the product is NOT perfectly elastic. Market demand is the standard downward sloping curve. A firm’s individual demand is perfectly elastic only because the firm is a price taker. Demand and Revenue Schedule for 1 perfectly competitive firm Price 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 Quantity demanded 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 TR MR=Demand 0 131 262 393 524 655 786 917 1084 1179 1310 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 AR=P*Q = P Q 0 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 131 What the firm needs to decide is: at the market price of $131, how many units do they want to supply? They decide this by producing quantities which will maximize their profit. Short Run Profit Maximization Recall: in the SR, plant size is fixed. So wee need to look at TC, TVC and TFC to get a picture of what the firms costs are. Q TFC TVC TC TR Profit=TR-TC 5 6 7 8 9 10 100 100 100 100 100 100 370 450 540 650 780 930 470 550 640 750 880 1030 655 786 917 1048 1179 1310 185 236 277 298 299 280 So it appears the firm would maximize profit, and therefore wish to produce at 9 units. Note: TC includes normal profit. So the point where TR=TC is the quantity in which the firm makes a normal profit, but not an economic profit. This is called the break even point. (see text book illustration) Another, easier way to find the quantity at which a firm should produce is to produce that quantity at which MR=MC. MR=MC rule – method of determining the total output at which economic profit is at a maximum. 1. This rule only applies if producing is preferable to shutting down 2. this rule is an accurate guide to profit maximization for ANY type of firm 3. for purely competitive firms MR=P, so the rule is the same as P=MC We can revisit the previous example and look at Average costs to see a clearer picture. Q AFC AVC ATC MC P=MR Profit=Q*MR-Q*TC 5 6 7 8 9 10 20 16.67 14.29 12.50 11.11 10 74 75 77 81 86.67 93 94 91.67 91.43 93.75 97.78 103 70 80 90 110 130 150 131 131 131 131 131 131 185 236 277 298 299 280 Graphically: $ MC Price=131 PROFITS ATC AVC 9 Note that profit = P*Q – ATC*Q, this is the shaded area. Now what would happen if price fell to $81? Quantity Graphically: $ MC ATC Price=81 losses AVC 6 Quantity Should the firm produce at this price if it is making losses? Yes. Because if it didn’t produce, it would still lose it’s fixed cost of $100, here, the loss is only $64. What if the price fell to $71? Graphically: $ MC ATC losses AVC Price=71 Quantity Should the firm produce at this price? No, the Average cost is always above the price. That means, no matter how many units they could produce, they will lose money on every unit they produce. That means, profits (losses) will fall (rise) with each unit. So losing the $100 fixed cost is better than producing and losing more than $100. Any time the price is below the minimum of the AVC, the firm’s best decision is to shut down. We can think of it as the shut down price. So what does a firm’s short run supply curve look like? Well, at any price above the shut down price, the firm will supply quantity where P=MC. Thus, their supply curve is their MC curve. Graphically: $ MC ( supply) ATC AVC Shut down Price Quantity What would cause a firm’s short run supply curve to shift? A change in costs. If costs rise, the supply curve will shift, along with the MC curve, up and to the right. Firm and industry equilibrium price What determines the price of the product in equilibrium? Consider: 1000 firms in the market. All with identical costs. Then we can generate market supply. Q single firm 10 9 8 7 6 0 Q single * 1000 firms 10000 9000 8000 7000 6000 0 Price 150 131 111 91 81 71 Remember, in the market, equilibrium occurs where supply = demand. Quantity Demanded 4000 6000 8000 9000 11000 13000 Here we see total Quantity supplied = Quantity Demanded at a price of $111, so the equilibrium price is $111 and the equilibrium quantity is 8000, or 8 per firm. Price S 111 D 8 Quantity Long Run Profit Maximization In the short run, firms may “shut down” by not producing. They don’t have time to liquidate assets. In the long run, a firm can expand or contract their plant size. ALSO, in the long run, firms may enter or exit the industry, thereby changing the number of firms in the industry, thereby shifting the market supply curve. How do these long run adjustments affect our short run analysis? Before we answer that, we make 3 assumptions: 1. We focus on long run decisions and adjustment (entry/exit) rather than short run decisions 2. All firms have identical costs 3. The industry is a constant cost industry (price of inputs doesn’t change with entry/exit of firms) The basic conclusion of the Long Run analysis: Production will occur at the minimum of the firm’s Long Run ATC curve. Why? 1. Because firms seek profit and avoid losses. 2. Firms can enter and exit the market at will. Visually, we see that if there are profits in an industry, more firms will wish to enter and reap those profits. As more firms enter, the market supply curve shifts out and price falls. If there are losses in an industry, some firms will exit. As firms exit, the market supply curve shifts in and price rises. Equilibrium (no more entry/exit) occurs at the price that equals min ATC. Case of Profits Price $ S1 MC S2 P1 P2 profits ATC D Qlr Quantity Qlr Quantity Case of losses Price $ MC S2 S1 ATC P2 P1 losses D Qlr Quantity Qlr Quantity As we see above, entry eliminates profits, exit eliminates losses. Note that if demand increases, Firms will temporarily (short run) make profits. But in the long run, new firms will enter the industry and profits will disappear. All that competitive firms make in the long run are normal profits (which are included in their cost curves). So, in the long run, there is no economic profit, but there is normal profit. Note that the ATC curves above are long run ATC curves So, given that the long run price is established where P=min ATC, we will have a long run supply that is perfectly elastic. Price S1 S2 S3 P(long run) S (long run –constant cost ind) D1 D2 D3 Quantity Note: this is for a constant cost industry. What would happen if we were in an increasing costs industry? This would mean that as more firms entered, the cost of inputs would be higher. If this is the case, than the LR ATC curve will increase when more firms enter. And we’d have an increasing long run supply curve that looks something like this: Price S1 S2 S3 S(long run- increasing cost ind) D1 D2 D3 Quantity Decreasing cost industry implies that if more firms enter, the costs of production decrease. This would imply a slightly downward sloping supply curve in the long run. Efficiency Is pure competition allocatively and productively efficient? As we saw above, in the long run P=MR=MC=min ATC long run Productive Efficiency- producing a set of goods the least costly way. Since we are producing at min ATC in the long run, then it is clear that Perfect Competition is productively efficient. Allocative Efficiency- producing the set of goods which best satisfies society’s wants. Note that money measures the relative worth of a product compared with other goods. Since MB=P, and P=MC, then MB=MC. This implies that the relative worth of the last unit produced of the good is equal to the marginal cost of producing it. This means, we are allocating as best for society. Hence, perfect competition is allocatively efficient. If we were to reallocate resources and produce less of this good and more of another, then P>MC and we would be under allocating resources to this good. The desire for the good is greater than the cost of the resources which are used elsewhere. Over allocation would occur if P<MC, this means that firms should decrease the number of resources allocated to making this good (decrease quantity), until MC rises to meet P. So, we can conclude that the long run equilibrium in a purely competitive industry is efficient. Note also, purely competitive markets adjust to demand shocks quickly, as seen above, and restore equilibrium, P=MC, in the long run. Pure Monopoly An industry in which only one firm is the sole seller of a product or service. Characteristics of this market are: 1. 2. 3. 4. Single seller No close substitutes High control over price High barriers to entry Barriers to entry include Economies of scale, Legal Barriers, Ownership, and pricing/strategy barriers. Economies of scale: New firms entering the market would have a hard time competing with the older large firm because the large firm will be producing at a lower ATC position. Legal Barriers: Patents –give exclusive rights of production to the inventor for a number of years Liscences-government may limit entry of firms by requiring liscenses Ownership of Resources: one firm/country may own all/most of world’s natural resource Pricing/strategic barriers: one firm may slash prices and up advertising to make it very difficult for a new firm to make a profit and thereby discourage entry. How does a monopolist decide price and quantity? First we make 3 assumtions: 1. firm is the sole producer; 2. firm is not gov’t regulated; 3. firm charges same price to all customers. Because the monopolist is the sole producer, its demand curve IS the market demand curve. 1. Because the market demand curve is downward sloping, the monopolist can increase sales by decreasing price. Therefore, MR<P, unlike in perfect competition. In perfect competition, there is one price and you can sell the quantity you want at that price. If you charge above that price, no one will buy, so MR=0, if you charge below that price, all you will do is lower profit, so why charge below? For a monopolist, if you lower the price, you will sell more. If you raise the price, you will sell less. But the lower price refers to all units, not just the last unit sold, while MR refers only to the last unit sold. As such, MR will always be lower than P for the monopolist. 2. Monopolist is price maker: by changing market supply, the monopolist determines price. 3. The monopolist will always set prices in the elastic portion of the demand curve, because it is in this area when a price decrease will raise TR. Elsewhere, they would only be decreasing TR. Equilibrium: Profit Maximization is found by producing enough quantity such that MR=MC Why? If MR>MC the firm could make more profit by producing more. If MR<MC the firm could make more profit by producing less. Lets look at an example. Keep in mind that Profit= TR-TC, and AR=(P*Q)/Q = P Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 P 172 162 152 142 132 122 112 102 92 82 72 TR 0 162 304 426 528 610 672 714 736 738 720 MR 162 142 122 102 82 62 42 22 -2 -18 ATC Na 190 135 113 100 94 91.67 91.43 93.75 97.78 103.33 TC 100 190 270 340 400 470 550 640 750 880 1030 MC Profit -100 -28 34 86 128 140 122 74 -14 -142 -310 90 80 70 60 70 80 90 110 130 150 Where should the monopolist produce? At 5 units. Then P=$122 Graphically, we can see the monopolist’s decision is at the intersection of the MC and MR curves, and that price is determined by drawing a vertical line up from the MR=MC point. Profit is the geometric area P*Q – ATC*Q. $ MC P=122 Profit ATC ATC D 5 Myths of Monopolist Pricing: 1. Monopolists charge the highest price they can (false) 2. Monopolists want to maximize per unit profits (false) 3. Pure monopoly guarantees profit (false) 8 Quantity MR Monopolists seek to maximize total profits. This implies they likely charge a price lower than the highest possible price. Moreover, if the demand curve is low enough, and costs are high enough, the monopolist may not be able to make a profit no matter what price they charge. Efficiency Is a pure monopolist efficient? Productive efficiency- Monopolist produces at a point where ATC> minATC. This implies that they are not productively efficient. They find it profitable to sell smaller amounts at higher prices than a competitive firm and thus are not at lowest ATC. Price S Pm Pc Qm D = MR(competitive) MR(monopolist) Qc Quantity Allocative Efficiency- since MB=P>MC then there is underallocation of resources to this product (not enough is being produced) Therefore Monopolies are not efficient. It is said that Monopolists are rent seekers. Rent Seeking is action by persons, firms or unions to gain special benefits from the government at tax payers or someone else’s expense. However, some people argue that if a monopolist wishes to keep his/her monopoly power, he/she is more likely than the competitive firm to stay on top of more efficient production techniques and technological advances over time. Therefore the inefficiency of monopolies may be over stated. In the basic model, we assumed that unit costs would be the same for a competitive firm as for a monopolist, but this may not be so. Moreover, the value of the product may differ. These types of complications to the basic model include: 1. Economies of Scale – when there are large economies of scale, market demand may not be sufficient to support large numbers of competing firms. 2. Simultaneous consumption – the firm may be able to satisfy large numbers of customers at the same time with relatively low marginal costs 3. Network effects – the more people use a product, the higher the value of the product, including the existing ones. 4. X-inefficiency- failure to produce on the ATC curve (produce above it) Price Discrimination What would happen if we relaxed the assumption that a monopolist must charge the same price to each consumer? What if the monopolist could charge a higher price to those who were willing to pay more (those who want it more) This behavior is called Price Discrimination – selling a product to different buyers at different prices when the differences are not justified by differences in prices. Ex/ airline tickets (student rates, etc) Consequences of Price Discrimination in our model: Because each unit is sold at a different price (the price the consumer is willing to pay) MR=D=P 1. Higher profit 2. More production (because MR=D, and production occurs where MR=MC) We can see these effects by comparing a single price industry to an industry with Perfect price discrimination: Single Price: $ MC P1 Profits ATC D MR Quantity Perfect Price Discrimination Graphically: $ MC Profits ATC ATC D Quantity Regulated Monopolies Many natural monopolies have been regulated by the government. Ex. Hydro, telephone, etc. The government usually regulates these firms by setting a maximum price which is considered ‘fair’ or ‘optimal’, and the monopolist cannot legally charge more than this price. Fair Return Price: P=ATC This price enables the producer to obtain a normal profit and that price is therefore equal to the average cost of producing the good. Most regulatory agencies in Canada set this kind of price. Socially Optimal Price: P=MC This price results in allocative efficiency. However if this price is below the monopolists ATC, they will not wish to continue producing in the long run, so the government would face a dilemna. It is possible that at P=MC they might still make a normal profit, if MC>=ATC. Below we see a graphical example where P<ATC at the socially optimal price: Graphically: $ MC Pm ATC Pfr Pso D MR Qm Qfr Qso Quantity