Climate Change Policy: Contrasting the U.S. and the European Union Approaches by Margo Thorning, Ph.D. Senior Vice President and Director of Research American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research The American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research prepared this Special Report for the European Commission Conference on EU-United States Relations held July 6, 2000 in Brussels. More detail is available on the economics of climate change policy at the Center’s Web site, www.accf.org. INTRODUCTION In response to the concerns of environmental groups and some in the scientific community about the possibility of large-scale global warming attributable to human activities, a series of international meetings on climate policy were held starting in 1990. These meetings culminated with the Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, which the United States negotiated in December, 1997. The Protocol calls for industrial economies such as the United States, Canada, Europe, and Japan to reduce their collective emissions of six greenhouse gases by an average of 5.2 percent from 1990 levels by 2008–2012. The U.S. target is a 7 percent reduction from 1990 levels. This amounts to a projected 538 million metric ton cutback in carbon emissions relative to the projected amount in 2010, or about a 30 percent reduction in emissions compared to the baseline forecast. The EU target is an 8 percent reduction. Since the negotiation of the Protocol in 1997, differences in the U.S. and EU approaches to the issue have become sharper. The U.S. Senate, which must consent to ratification of any treaty negotiated by a U.S. President before the treaty can become law, has made its objections to the treaty very clear. The passage in 1997 of the bipartisan Byrd-Hagel Resolution in the Senate by a 95 to 0 vote shows the seriousness of congressional opposition to the Kyoto Protocol. The Byrd-Hagel Resolution states that the Senate will not ratify any climate policy treaty that negatively impacts U.S. economic growth or fails to require developing country participation in emission cutbacks in the same time frame as cutbacks for developed countries. In contrast, the EU, through its ruling body, the European Commission, has embraced (in principle) the near-term emission cutbacks required by the Protocol. On June 22, 2000, the EU’s Environmental Council adopted a set of Conclusions on the Community’s strategy on climate change, including setting the rules for the different mechanisms and instruments for cutting greenhouse gas emissions in the Kyoto Protocol. What factors, economic, political, or cultural, can explain the different paths (and timetables) to climate change policy favored by many U.S. policymakers and those of its ally, the European Union? FACTORS CONTRIBUTING TO U.S.-EU DIFFERENCES TOWARD CLIMATE POLICY In recent years there has been a substantial amount of research on the economic impact of the Protocol on the United States. Thus, U.S. policymakers realize the potentially serious impact of near-term emission reductions. In the EU, in contrast, there does not seem to have been many macroeconomic analyses of how domestic CO2 cutbacks would affect economic growth and living standards for the Union as a whole or for the individual member countries. ■ Economic growth Numerous analyses of the impact on the United States of the sharp, near-term CO2 emission cutbacks required under the Kyoto Protocol by climate policy experts in government, academic and consulting firm experts show a significant negative impact on Gross Domestic Product. For example, the U.S. Department of Energy’s Energy Information Administration (EIA) calculates that GDP losses would range from 2 percent to 4.2 percent by 2010, depending upon AMERICAN COUNCIL FOR CAPITAL FORMATION CENTER FOR POLICY RESEARCH 1750 K Street, N.W., Suite 400, Washington, D.C. 20006-2302 202/293-5811; 202/785-8165 fax; info@accf.org e-mail; Web site: www.accf.org Climate Change Policy: Contrasting the U.S. and the European Union Approaches Page 2 2 2 Federal budget surplus Percent change from baseline how much of the United States’ reductions could be obtained by emissions trading abroad (see Figure 1). Other studies by climate policy experts show losses ranging from 1 percent to 3.2 percent of GDP; a major determinant of the “hit” to GDP is the assumption about the amount of emissions trading. The studies show that as CO2 emissions are reduced, economic growth slows Figure 1 Impact of Reducing CO2 Emissions on due to lost output as new energy taxes are U.S. GDP, 2008–2012 imposed and prices rise for carbon-intenCompared to the baseline forecast sive goods—goods that must be produced using less carbon and/or more expensive Manne/ Manne/ Admin. DOE/ CEA Richels CRA DRI Yohe CRA Richels EIA WEFA processes. In addition, the capital stock (T) (NT) (T) (T) (T) (NT) (T) (NT) (NT) 0 accumulates more slowly, reflecting the -0.01% -0.3% premature obsolescence of capital equip-1 -0.9% ment due to the sharp energy price -1.0% -1.3% -1.3% increases required to meet the CO2 emis-1.6% -2 sion reductions mandated under the Protocol. It takes from 20 to 30 years to CO reduction to Kyoto target -3 “turn over” or replace the entire U.S. cap-3.2% CO reduction to 1990 levels ital stock. Thus, meeting the Protocol’s (Clinton pre-Kyoto target) -4 2008–2012 timetable for emission reducT = with trading; NT = no trading -4.2% tions would mean either continuing to -5 utilize plant and equipment designed to use much lower-cost (pre-Kyoto) fuels, or replacing the capital stock much more Figure 2 Reduction in Federal On-Budget Surplus rapidly than its owners had planned. in 2010 Due to Lower GDP Caused by CO2 Emission Reductions ■ Budgetary Impacts Dollars in billions U.S. policymakers, especially those in the U.S. Congress, are mindful of the $341 350 interactions between sharp CO2 emission $295 cutbacks, slower economic growth, and 300 federal budget receipts. Using a simple $249 calculation based on the relationship of 250 increases in GDP to federal tax receipts, if $203 growth falls by 3 percent per year, the pro200 jected federal budget surplus falls from $157 $341 billion dollars in 2010 to only $203 150 billion (see Figure 2). Therefore, implementation of the Kyoto Protocol would 100 make it much more difficult for the 50 United States to sustain tax cuts and promote the retirement security of the “baby 0 boom” generation, and could require Budget surplus Surplus with Surplus with Surplus with Surplus with sharp changes in fiscal policy in order to if no CO2 4% lower 3% lower 2% lower 1% lower reductions growth growth growth growth avoid deficit spending. If the projected federal budget surpluses fail to materialize, Note: “On-budget” surplus excludes Social Security and postal service contributions. the negative growth impact of the Calculations based on “The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update,” Protocol would be even more difficult to Congressional Budget Office, July, 2000. assimilate. Margo Thorning, Ph.D. ACCF Center for Policy Research Climate Change Policy: Contrasting the U.S. and the European Union Approaches Page 3 ■ Impact on Employment, Consumption, Income Distribution, and Living Standards Percent change from baseline Policies to curb emissions to meet the Kyoto target would have a significant impact on U.S. households’ economic well being and living standards, as well as negatively affect the distribution of income. For example, estimates of job losses range from 1.3 million (Dr. Joyce Y. Brinner of DRI) to 2.4 million (Ms. Mary Novak of WEFA) by 2010. Consumption by U.S. households falls by over 2 percent under the Figure 3 Impact of Reducing CO2 Emissions to Kyoto emissions target, according to DRI. 1990 Levels by 2010 on U.S. Household Curbing CO2 emissions would also Income by Quintile reduce wage growth by 5 to 10 percent, according to Professor Gary W. Yohe of 4 Lowest Second Third Fourth Highest Wesleyan University. Moreover, it would Quintile Quintile Quintile Quintile Quintile worsen the distribution of income in the 2 United States, according to the analyses 0 of both Professor Yohe and Ms. Novak. For example, based on a standard measure -2 of the degree of income inequality among a country’s population called the GINI -4 coefficient, Professor Yohe’s analysis of the impact of reducing emissions to 1990 -6 levels shows that carbon taxes, even when recycled through personal income -8 tax reductions, cause relatively large loss-10 es in the poorest quintile (lowest one-fifth of the population). These losses, added to Note: A $260 per ton tax or tradable permit price of that amount would be needmodest losses in the middle quintiles, proed to reduce emissions to 1990 levels by 2010 if emission reductions begin in 1997 vide gains for the richest fifth of the popor 1998. The analysis assumes the tax is rebated through reductions in the personal income tax. ulation (see Figure 3). ■ U.S. Competitiveness for EnergyIntensive Sectors and Agriculture Source: Gary W. Yohe, “Climate Change Policies, the Distribution of Income, and U.S. Living Standards,” in Climate Change Policy, Risk Prioritization, and U.S. Economic Growth (Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research, June 1997), pp. 13–54. Several studies, including those by Dr. Brian Fisher and his colleagues at the Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Colorado’s Professor Thomas Rutherford, DRI’s Dr. Brinner, and WEFA’s Ms. Novak, have concluded that nearterm emission reductions would result in the migration of energy-intensive industry from the United States to non-Annex I countries (sometimes called “carbon leakage”). A 1999 study by Professor Alan S. Manne of Stanford University and Dr. Richard G. Richels of EPRI also analyzed this question. Their model results suggest that the Kyoto Protocol could lead to serious competitive problems for energy-intensive sector (EIS) producers in the United States, Japan, and OECD Europe. Meeting the emissions targets in the Protocol would lead to significant reductions in output and employment among EIS producers, and there would be offsetting increases in countries with low energy costs. U.S. output of energy-intensive products such as autos, steel, paper, and chemicals could be 15 percent less than under the reference case by 2020. In contrast, countries such as China, India, and Mexico would increase their output of energy-intensive products. In its present form, the Protocol could lead to acrimonious conflicts between those who advocate free international trade and those who advocate a low-carbon environment, Professor Manne and Dr. Richels conclude. U.S. agriculture would also lose competitiveness if the United States complied with the Kyoto Protocol. Another study based on the DRI model predicts that implementation of the Protocol would cause higher fuel oil, motor oil, fertilizer, and other farm operating costs. This would mean higher consumer food prices and greater Margo Thorning, Ph.D. ACCF Center for Policy Research Climate Change Policy: Contrasting the U.S. and the European Union Approaches Page 4 demand for public assistance with higher costs. In addition, by increasing the energy costs of farm production in America while leaving them unchanged in developing countries, the Kyoto Protocol would cause U.S. food exports to decline and imports to rise. Reduced efficiency of the world food system could add to a political backlash against free trade policies at home and abroad. IMPORTANCE OF INTERNATIONAL EMISSIONS TRADING Billions of metric tons of carbon The United States and the EU differ in their views on the use of emissions trading to reduce the economic cost of CO2 reductions. Unrestricted global emissions trading is seen as a practical approach in the United States while EU policymakers want to limit the use of this option. Numerous studies show that a major determinant of the cost of curbing emissions is whether the United States can purchase permits from abroad where emissions can be reduced at a lower cost than in the United States. In the absence of an unfettered international trading system, the United States would be forced to curb its own CO2 emissions by about 30 percent within 10 years. Due to population growth and increases in output, the gap between projected emissions and the Kyoto target will continue to grow. This growing gap has not been addressed by Kyoto advocates. If the United States is not able to take advantage of “where” flexibility (reducing emissions wherever it is cheapest globally) by using international emissions trading to meet the Kyoto target, the cost in terms of lost output ranges from about 1 percent of GDP, according to a recent study by Professor Manne and Dr. Richels, to 4.2 percent of GDP as estimated by EIA. Full global trading in emissions, meaning that developing nations such as China, India, and Brazil are participating in a global emissions reduction effort, could reduce costs to 0.3 percent of GDP, according to the Manne/Richels study. (See Figure 4 for a geographic breakdown of emissions Figure 4 Global Carbon Emissions: Reference Case growth.) Most policy experts, including Professor Manne and Dr. Richels, doubt 25 that these developing countries can be Canada, Australia, & New Zealand Rest of World induced to participate in the foreseeable Japan Mexico & OPEC 20 future. Emissions reductions accomWestern Europe India ROW plished through limited trading schemes USA China (involving only Annex I and Eastern 15 E. Europe & former Soviet Union Mex. & OPEC Europe), which most experts believe are India realistic, would cut U.S. GDP growth by 10 between 0.9 percent annually, according China to Dr. W. David Montgomery of CRA and 5 Professor John R. Moroney of Texas Can., Aust., & NZ Japan EEFSU A&M University, and 1.6 percent annuW. Europe USA ally as estimated by Dr. Brinner of DRI. 0 ;; yy ;; yy ;; ;;;;;;;;; ;; yy ;;;;;;;;; yy ;; yyyyyyyyy ;;;;;;;;; yyyyyyyyy ;;;;;;;;; yyyyyyyyy yyyyyyyyy ;;;;;;;;; 1990 CULTURAL AND POLITICAL DIFFERENCES 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070 2080 2090 2100 Source: Alan S. Manne and Richard G. Richels, “The Kyoto Protocol: A Cost-Effective Strategy for Meeting Environmental Objectives?” In Climate Change Policy: Practical Strategies to Promote Economic Growth and Environmental Quality (Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research, 1999), pp. 3–23. Similar as their views are on many economic and political issues, Americans and their allies in the EU differ in their approach to government policymaking as well as the seriousness with which they take legislated environmental or other mandates. First, in the United States there is growing support for the use of cost-benefit analysis to assess the desirability of implementing various policy proposals. Thus, the high cost of implementing the Kyoto Protocol (estimates by numerous climate change modelers show U.S. GDP losses averaging about 2 to 3 percent annually by 2010) Margo Thorning, Ph.D. ACCF Center for Policy Research Climate Change Policy: Contrasting the U.S. and the European Union Approaches Page 5 makes a careful calculation of benefits imperative. For example, Yale University Professor William D. Nordhaus estimates that the costs of even an efficiently designed emission reduction program exceed the value of environmental benefits by a ratio of 7 to 1 and that the United States would bear almost two-thirds of the global cost. Thus, U.S. policymakers and decision makers in the private sector question the wisdom of the Clinton Administration’s signing the Kyoto Protocol. Given that the U.S. Senate must consent to ratification of any treaty before it goes into effect, it seems very unlikely the Protocol will ever become law. Second, Americans believe in the sanctity of the law and thus in the importance of drafting legislation with major economic, social, or political consequences with great care. The U.S. business community has every reason to expect that if it fails to comply with a legislative statute (for CO2 emission rationing, for example) that the government will impose substantial economic penalties or even prison terms for senior management. In the European Union, by contrast, the governments have the reputation for taking a more conciliatory attitude toward regulatory enforcement. Third, Americans tend to be practical and results-oriented. When faced with an impractical, unachievable goal such as reducing U.S. CO2 emissions by 30 percent compared to the baseline forecast by 2010, their natural inclination is to examine the goal and see how to modify it in a cost-effective way. Several studies, including one recently released by the Pew Center on Global Climate Change as well as one by Ms. Novak of WEFA, conclude that the European Union is also unlikely to meet its emission reduction targets by 2010. In fact, Eileen Claussen, former U.S. Assistant Secretary of State for Oceans and International Environmental and Scientific Affairs and one of the original U.S. negotiators for the Kyoto Protocol, has recently stated that the treaty should be renegotiated because the targets and timetables are unachievable. In light of these realities, it seems hypocritical of the European Commission to insist that the United States try to meet the Kyoto Protocol target. CONCLUSIONS: STRATEGIES FOR THE FUTURE If, as knowledge of the climate system increases, policy changes to reduce CO2 emissions become necessary, these changes should be implemented in a way that minimizes damage to the U.S. economy. Above all, experts agree that voluntary measures clearly and cost-effectively reduce the growth in greenhouse gas emissions, as the U.S. Second National Communication to the Framework Convention on Climate Change noted in 1997. Modifications to U.S. tax policy that reduce the cost of capital for energy-efficient investment should be part of the voluntary measures. Reducing global CO2 emissions should be a gradual process, according to Pacific Northwest National Laboratory’s Dr. Jae Edmonds, Mr. James Dooley, and Mr. Marshall Wise. Moreover, a recent study by Dr. Edmonds, Mr. Dooley, and Dr. Sonny Kim concluded that the introduction of carbon capture and sequestration from central power facilities, the introduction of hydrogen fuel cells as an option for both power generation and transport, sequestration of carbon in the soil, and afforestation and reforestation would enable the economy to rely less heavily on sharp near-term emissions reductions to achieve a particular concentration level. For example, carbon sequestration at power plants and fuel cell use for electric power generation and transportation could cut the present discounted cost of satisfying a 550 parts per million by volume atmospheric constraint by more than 60 percent. In short, the consensus of the noted climate policy scholars whose work is discussed above is clear. Given the need to maintain strong U.S. economic growth to address such challenges as a growing population, the retirement of the baby boom generation, and a persistent trade deficit, policymakers need to weigh carefully the Kyoto Protocol’s negative economic impacts and its failure to engage developing nations in full participation. Adopting a thoughtfully timed climate change policy—based on accurate science, improved climate models, global participation, tax incentives to accelerate investment in energy efficiency and sequestration, and new technology—is essential, both to U.S. and global economic growth and to eventual stabilization of the carbon concentration in the atmosphere, if growing scientific understanding indicates such a policy is needed. ❖ Margo Thorning, Ph.D. ACCF Center for Policy Research Climate Change Policy: Contrasting the U.S. and the European Union Approaches Page 6 SOURCES ACCF Center for Policy Research. 2000. The Kyoto Commitments: Can Nations Meet Them With the Help of Technology? Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research. Contains work by Mary Novak and Brian Fisher. ACCF Center for Policy Research. 1999. Climate Change Policy: Practical Strategies to Promote Economic Growth and Environmental Quality. Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research. Contains work by Jae Edmonds, James Dooley, and Sonny Kim; Alan S. Manne and Richard G. Richels; Joyce Y. Brinner; and John R. Moroney. ACCF Center for Policy Research. 1997. Climate Change Policy, Risk Prioritization, and U.S. Economic Growth. Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research. Contains work by Jae Edmonds, James Dooley, and Marshall Wise; and Gary W. Yohe. ACCF Center for Policy Research. 1996. An Economic Perspective on Climate Change Policies. Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research. Contains work by W. David Montgomery and Thomas Rutherford. Bernstein, Paul M., and W. David Montgomery. 1998. How Much Could Kyoto Really Cost? A Reconstruction and Reconciliation of Administration Estimates. Washington, D.C.: Charles River Associates. Council of Economic Advisers. 1998. The Kyoto Protocol and the President’s Policies to Address Climate Change: Administration Economic Analysis. July. Nordhaus, William and Joseph Boyer. 1999. Requiem for Kyoto: An Economic Analysis. In The Costs of the Kyoto Protocol: A Multi-Model Evaluation, ed. John P. Weyant. The Energy Journal, Special Issue. Novak, Mary H. 1998. Global Climate Change, Environmental Quality, and U.S. Living Standards: The Impact on Consumers. In The Impact of Climate Change Policy on Consumers: Can Tradable Permits Reduce the Cost?, 3–18. Washington, D.C.: American Council for Capital Formation Center for Policy Research. Margo Thorning, Ph.D. ACCF Center for Policy Research