THE IMPACT OF ECONOMIC CONDITIONS ON MORTALITY OVER THE LIFETIME David M. Cutler (Harvard University) Wei Huang (Harvard University) Adriana Lleras-Muney (UCLA) December 2014 Abstract Using historical mortality data covering over 100 birth cohorts in over 20 countries, this paper examines the contemporaneous and long-term impacts of the economic conditions on mortality. Both contemporaneous and early-life economic conditions have large but different impact on morality: contemporaneous recessions are good for health but over the longer term recessions in early life reduce life expectancy. Although recessions in utero and childhood affect longevity, economic conditions around the time of graduation (from ages 10 to 30) have the largest impact on lifetime mortality, particularly for men. We also find strong evidence that the impacts of economic conditions on morality are much larger and stronger for those countries with lower government expenditure/GDP rates, suggesting government expenditures can offset the negative effects of economic fluctuations on outcomes. 1. Data and Methodology The data we are using are from The Human Mortality Database (HMD), which was created to provide detailed mortality and population data to researchers, students, journalists, policy analysts, and others interested in the history of human longevity.1 At present the HMD contains detailed population and mortality data for 37 countries or areas, including live births, deaths and death rates by sex-age-year cell. Because of the different availability of the historical data for each country, the starting date for each country varies. Because we are interested in lifetime effects, we restrict attention to 25 countries with data in 1950 or earlier. Because old age mortality rates are measured with substantial error, we restrict the sample to those aged below 90 in this analysis. 1 See http://www.mortality.org/ for more details. The historical GDP data are from the Gapminder website which combines the data from several official international statistics and various historical sources.2 That the initial year for the GDP per capita is 1800 for most of the countries and thus the data cover most of the cohorts we studied since birth. To de-trend the series, we followed the methodology in van den Berg et al. (2006) by using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with smoothing parameter 500 to de-trend logarithm of GDP per capita, by country. Figure 1 shows the case for the United States. The dashed blue line shows the actual logarithm of GDP per capita over time and the red solid line presents the smoothed one. The de-trended GDP per capita or GDP fluctuation is defined as the actual value. We are interested in both the contemporaneous and long-term impacts of the economic conditions measured by detrended GDP, therefore we kept those cohorts aged over 30. For each birth cohort in each country, we match the corresponding contemporaneous detrended log GDP per capita as well as detrended log GDP per capita at age 0 throughout age 30. For simplicity, we aggregate the de-trended log GDP per capita into 5-year categories: detrended log GDP age 0-5, 6-10 etc. 1.1 OLS models To estimate contemporaneous and long-term impacts of the economic cycles, we estimate the following equation: 0−5 6−10 26−30 ππππ‘ππππ‘π¦πππ‘ = π½0 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ‘ + π½1 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ + π½2 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ + β― + π½6 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ + ππππ‘ + ππππ‘ (1) where the dependent variable is the mortality rate for birth cohort b in country c in calendar year t. πΊπ·ππππ’πππ‘ is the contemporaneous GDP fluctuation in year t of country c. The coefficients π½0 on it, capture the impact of contemporaneous GDP fluctuations on mortality. The next few terms in the π₯−π¦ equation, πΊπ·ππππ’πππ in the equation denotes the mean value of the GDP fluctuations from age x to age y for birth cohort b in country c. ππππ‘ captures a set of control variables including the contemporaneous smoothed log GDP as well as the fixed effects for calendar year, age, year of birth and countries. The coefficients on them, π½1 to π½6, capture the long-term impact of the economic conditions in early life on the mortality of those aged over 30. The observations are weighted by population size. 2 See http://www.gapminder.org/downloads/ for more details. 1.2 Fixed effect models Using the multi-country year-cohort level data, we are able to control for the country specific economic conditions for birth cohort when estimating the contemporaneous impacts. Specifically, we can estimate ππππ‘ππππ‘π¦πππ‘ = π½0 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ‘ + πΏππ + ππππ‘ + ππππ‘ (2) where πΏππ captures the country-birth cohort fixed effects. By doing so, we control for the country specific contemporaneous economic conditions. By doing so, we actually control for the specific life experience for the particular birth cohort in each country. The GDP fluctuations in early life are perfectly collinear with this variable so they are dropped in the main equation. Similarly, we can also control for the country specific birth cohort fixed effect when estimating the contemporaneous impact of economic conditions, by estimating the following equation: 0−5 6−10 26−30 ππππ‘ππππ‘π¦πππ‘ = π½1 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ + π½2 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ + β― + π½6 ∗ πΊπ·ππππ’πππ + ππππ‘ + πΏππ‘ + ππππ‘ (3) The difference between equation (2) and equation (1) is the addition of country-calendar year fixed effects, πΏππ‘ . By including these we control for the country specific contemporaneous economic conditions—thus in this specification the contemporaneous economic condition are dropped from the estimation because it is collinear with the newly added dummies. 2. The short term effects of recession 2.1 OLS results Table 1 presents the results from estimating Equation (1) with all standard errors clustered at country level. The square term of contemporaneous GDP fluctuation is added to capture possible non-linearities. First column shows the results for the full sample, and the next two show the results separately by gender. Consistently, we find the square term on the de-trended log GDP is positive and significant. Further examination shows that only large deviations (economic booms or large economic recessions) matter. Between the 5th percentile and 95th percentile of the GDP fluctuation, the relationship between economic fluctuations and mortality is positive, consistent with the findings in Ruhm (2000). For the impact of economic conditions in early life, we find consistent negative associations in all three columns, indicating that the economic booms (recessions) in early life will be negatively (positively) associated with mortality later. These associations are much more significant for men. Specifically, we find the most important period in early life is from age 11 to age 20 given the coefficients on the GDP fluctuations during then are largest in magnitude. The magnitude is large: one point increase in log GDP at age 11-20 is associated with a 0.6 percentage points decrease in mortality rates after 30. 2.2 FE model for the impact of contemporaneous economic conditions Table 2 reports the results from the FE model in Equation (2), with country-specific birth-cohort fixed effects. Panel A show the results for contemporary GDP are consistent with those in Table 1, where we control for the history of economic conditions since birth instead of using fixed effects. Panel B shows the results hold if we drop World War I and World War II periods. Panel C and Panel D show the results by the countries with different level of government expenditures, measured by the ratio of government expenditure to the total GDP. Because the government expenditures data are available only for recent years, we just calculate the ratio of government expenditure to the total GDP from 1998 onwards and use the median level of government expenditure in the sample as the threshold, which is 0.42 to separate countries into high and low expenditure countries. The results in Panel C show an insignificant and small impact of contemporaneous GDP fluctuations among high expenditure countries. But the effects in Panel D (low expenditure countries) are significant and larger magnitude, suggesting that government expenditure is potentially mitigating the effect of fluctuations on health. Furthermore the results in Panels E and F show that the contemporaneous impact of GDP fluctuations is mostly driven by earlier periods also consistent with the increase in expenditure over time in all countries. Finally the comparison between Panels G and H indicates that the main effects are driven by those aged over 60. 3. The impact of economic conditions in early life Table 3 shows the impact of economic conditions in early life on the mortality of adults ages 30 and above, controlling for country-calendar year fixed effects. The coefficients, π½1 to π½6, are reported in the columns with different specifications. All coefficients are negative, suggesting that unfavorable economic conditions between 0 and 30 lower subsequent mortality. However the largest effects are for those ages 10-25, these are the years when individuals enter the labor force. This is particularly true of males for whom all coefficients are negative and statistically significant. For women the coefficients are smaller, and although the follow the same age-pattern, only the coefficients from early childhood conditions are statistically significant. In the next two columns (i.e. column 4 and column 5), we find again that the impact of the early economic conditions is much larger in countries with lower government expenditure level (relative to GDP). Differences between columns 4 and column 5 are large and significant, though results are not reported here. The final two columns, however, we find that the associations are larger for later cohorts, which is puzzling. Analysis in the future will shed some light on these issues and phenomenon. Table 1: Impact of Contemp. And Earlier life GDP fluc. On Mortality rates aged over 30 (1) (2) (3) Dependent var. is Mortality rates in percentage VARIABLES All population Men Women Contemporaneous GDP fluc. GDP Fluc. GDP Fluc. Square GDP Fluc.at ealier life Age 0 Age 1 - 5 Age 6 - 10 Age 11 - 15 Age 16 - 20 Age 21 - 25 Age 26 - 30 Observations R-squared Mean of Y SD of Y 0.0582 (0.113) 1.673** (0.799) -0.100 (0.115) 1.846* (0.998) 0.179 (0.128) 1.607** (0.706) -0.125** (0.0446) -0.247** (0.100) -0.329* (0.161) -0.406* (0.206) -0.393* (0.227) -0.267 (0.158) -0.0767 (0.155) -0.144*** (0.0448) -0.327*** (0.106) -0.466*** (0.156) -0.608*** (0.203) -0.638*** (0.206) -0.490*** (0.139) -0.304** (0.146) -0.105** (0.0429) -0.177* (0.0986) -0.221 (0.171) -0.245 (0.220) -0.170 (0.245) -0.112 (0.180) 0.0644 (0.185) 132,288 0.955 1.570 2.582 132,288 0.964 1.765 2.792 132,288 0.945 1.393 2.488 Contemp. GDP level Yes Yes Smoothed GDP before 30 Yes Yes Calendar Year FE Yes Yes Age in years FE Yes Yes Year of Birth FE Yes Yes Country FE Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses are clustered at country level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Table 2 Contemporaneous Economic Conditions and Death Rates (FE model) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Dependent var. is Mortality rates in percentage VARIABLES All population Men Women All population Men Women Panel A. Full sample Panel B. Drop WW1 and WW2 period Contemporaneous GDP fluc. GDP Fluc. 0.137 0.0146 0.229 0.334 0.307 0.296 (0.177) (0.190) (0.191) (0.268) (0.224) (0.307) GDP Fluc. Square 1.706** 1.509 1.963** 2.282** 2.392* 2.330* (0.737) (0.927) (0.707) (1.071) (1.226) (1.172) Observations 132,288 132,288 132,288 Panel C. Higher Government Expenditure Countries Contemporaneous GDP fluc. GDP Fluc. GDP Fluc. Square Observations Contemporaneous GDP fluc. GDP Fluc. GDP Fluc. Square Observations Contemporaneous GDP fluc. GDP Fluc. GDP Fluc. Square Observations 0.120 (0.197) 1.512 (1.195) 0.0122 (0.217) 1.232 (1.247) 0.207 (0.208) 1.607 (1.204) 67,660 67,660 67,660 Panel E. Earlier Years (Years before meidan in each specific country) 0.425 (0.337) 2.286** (0.996) 93,313 0.425 (0.388) 2.560** (1.101) 122,808 122,808 122,808 Panel D. Lower Government Expenditure Countries 0.479* (0.241) 1.716** (0.609) 0.242 (0.184) 1.427** (0.646) 0.661* (0.309) 1.956** (0.719) 61,124 61,124 61,124 Panel F. Later Years (Years after meidan in each specific country) 0.431 (0.308) 2.029** (0.904) -0.111 (0.191) 0.950 (0.809) -0.158 (0.208) 0.624 (0.937) -0.0692 (0.212) 1.150 (0.818) 93,313 93,313 Panel G. Aged 30 - 60 92,145 92,145 Panel H. Aged 61+ 92,145 -0.0628 (0.0778) 0.577 (0.460) -0.188 (0.139) 0.550 (0.604) 0.0439 (0.0336) 0.620 (0.369) -0.314 (0.571) 5.206*** (1.636) -0.265 (0.592) 5.427*** (1.908) -0.228 (0.615) 5.133*** (1.620) 68,899 68,899 68,899 63,389 63,389 63,389 Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Covariates controlled for Comtemp. smoothed GDP Yes Yes Yes Calendar Year FE Yes Yes Yes Age FE Yes Yes Yes Year of Birth FE Yes Yes Yes Country FE Yes Yes Yes Country*Birth year FE Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses are clustered at Country level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 3 Impact of Economic Conditions on mortality at later ages (30+) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Dependent variable is Death Rates in Percentage Sample Full sample High Gov. exp Ctys Low Gov. exp Ctys VARIABLES All Men Women All All GDP Fluc. at birth GDP Fluc. 1-5 GDP Fluc. 6-10 GDP Fluc. 11-15 GDP Fluc. 16-20 GDP Fluc. 21-25 GDP Fluc. 26-30 Observations R-squared Mean of Y SD of Y (6) (7) Ealier Cohorts All Later Cohorts All -0.129** (0.0616) -0.279* (0.145) -0.414* (0.223) -0.517* (0.285) -0.518 (0.302) -0.363* (0.207) -0.242 (0.217) -0.119* (0.0628) -0.298* (0.150) -0.458** (0.211) -0.613** (0.274) -0.661** (0.275) -0.502** (0.187) -0.432* (0.209) -0.137** (0.0563) -0.267* (0.140) -0.396 (0.234) -0.456 (0.297) -0.390 (0.320) -0.288 (0.230) -0.138 (0.246) -0.108*** (0.0252) -0.250*** (0.0605) -0.257* (0.134) -0.289 (0.167) -0.176 (0.191) -0.0961 (0.174) 0.0505 (0.182) -0.223** (0.0935) -0.484** (0.171) -0.613** (0.208) -0.833** (0.303) -0.824** (0.267) -0.567** (0.252) -0.617 (0.373) -0.0345 (0.0941) -0.198 (0.171) -0.127 (0.212) -0.212 (0.236) -0.151 (0.202) -0.113 (0.156) -0.0891 (0.109) -0.348*** (0.0885) -0.607*** (0.159) -1.042*** (0.315) -1.279*** (0.395) -1.262*** (0.386) -0.954*** (0.322) -0.493 (0.377) 132,288 0.958 1.570 2.582 132,288 0.967 1.765 2.792 132,288 0.948 1.393 2.488 67,660 0.959 1.762 2.811 61,124 0.969 1.419 2.370 66,732 0.972 1.819 2.779 65,556 0.977 1.414 2.438 Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Covariates controlled for Age FE Yes Yes Yes Birth cohort FE Yes Yes Yes Country FE Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Country-Year FE Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses are clustered at Country level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 8 9 10 11 United States 7 GDP per capita Smoothed value 1800 1850 1900 year 1950 2000 Figure 1 Logarithm of GDP per capita and the Smoothed Value, the United States 1800-2012 Notes: GDP Data comes from Gapminder (http://www.gapminder.org/downloads/). The smoothed GDP is derived from Hodrick-Prescott filter with smoothing parameter 500. The de-trended GDP is defined as the actual value (Blue line) subtracting the smoothed value (Red line).