CHAPTER 3 ECONOMIC CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY 3.1 INTRODUCTION The purpose of this chapter is to deal with the economic characteristics of the airline industry. The special nature of the airline industry as a network infrastructure industry will be examined. A number of characteristics in the airline industry will be identified that are indicative of an oligopoly. It will also be demonstrated that certain unique economic network characteristics exist in the airline industry. It will become evident that, as a result of these unique and special characteristics, it may not be advisable to treat the air transport industry on the same basis as other sectors of the economy from a competition perspective. The sources of economies of scale, scope and density in the airline industry will be identified and well as the effect of airline networks on competition. The effect of declining overall volumes on airline competition and the viability network business travel pricing model of the hub-and-spoke airlines as well as the emergence of new low cost carriers and their characteristics will be examined. Price discrimination in the airline industry generally and specifically in South Africa will be examined in this chapter. Specific objectives that will be established are: • The special nature of the airline industry as a network infrastructure industry. • Certain characteristics of the airline industry will be identified, including: o Characteristics that may demonstrate an oligopoly in the airline industry. o Unique economic characteristics of the airline industry. o Competition in the airline industry in comparison with competition in other industries. o Economies of scale, scope and density in the airline industry. o The effect of airline networks on competition. Chapter 3 Page 121 • The operation of a deregulated airline industry that would include: o Yield management and hub-and-spoke route systems of large network airlines and the potentially unfair competitive responses to entry by low cost airlines involving price and capacity which results in a decline in airline competition as a consequence of the market power in airline markets that result from these commercial practices. o The effect of a decline in overall volumes on airline networks and the viability of the network business travel pricing model of the hub-and-spoke airlines which has led to the development of specific characteristics of new low-cost carriers as well as the responses of hub airlines to competition from low-cost carriers. o The occurrence of price (fare) dispersion in the airline industry. Fare restrictions as a means of differential pricing and the use of yield management to be able to discriminate on price o The effect of price discrimination on the economic welfare of consumers in the domestic airline services and in particular in South Africa. 3.2 THE SPECIAL NATURE OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY AS A NETWORK INFRASTRUCTURE INDUSTRY The Competition Commission in South Africa described the airline industry as a network industry. It stated that there were numerous competitive concerns regarding network industries. 1) The OECD described network infrastructure industries as industries that have commonly been subject to government ownership or regulation and have a number of features that make regulatory reform especially attractive, difficult and interesting to competition authorities. 2) The Competition Commission in South Africa stated that these industries are special in that they connect the consumers of their products and services by means of a network of some sort. Examples of network infrastructure industries include the telephone network, the electricity network, and the road, rail, and water supply and airline networks. Chapter 3 Page 122 Although different in the nature of their products, these industries share several features that are reflected in the common occurrence of broadly similar competition concerns: • The bigger the network, the more useful it is. • There are competition problems associated with dominant, integrated firms in network industries. A new entrant is initially able to compete by providing one service. The response by the incumbent, integrated firm might be to cross-subsidise its prices in respect of that service, by raising the prices of its other services where it faces no competition and thus has market power. • The incumbent could refuse access to an essential facility. 3) • The raising of switching costs between one service (offered by the new entrant) and another (offered only by the incumbent). For example, a dominant airline might schedule its feeder flights to arrive immediately before the departure of its connecting flights, whereas a new entrant might only secure a landing slot that feeds too late or too early into the incumbent’s flight. 4) The CAA in the UK stated that: • The airline industry is a network business in which the demand for air services on a particular airport-pair, city-pair, or even country-pair is derived from a multitude of separate origin/destination markets. Consequently, market definition in airline competition cases can sometimes be quite complex. • In addition, the ‘indivisibility’ of capacity can result in extremely low short-run marginal costs, with consequent difficulties in applying competition law to cases involving allegations of predatory pricing. 5) Van Siclen S also identified a number of key characteristics that have a bearing on regulation and competition in network industries: • Provision of an essential service to the economy In many countries these industries have been traditionally state owned. Such companies often have public service obligations (implying requirements to provide some services even where it is not economically viable for them to do so.) The result is that the reform of these sectors is often highly politicised. • Sunk and unrecoverable costs Many of their costs are sunk and unrecoverable once they are committed. In particular, if there is a desire to attract voluntary private investment, the regulatory Chapter 3 Page 123 regime has to be credible and predictable. According to Van Siclen S, creating this credibility and predictability is one of the basic tasks of a regulator. • Natural monopolies Some parts of network industries probably have to be monopolies while other parts can be competitive. Van Siclen S stated that when the least costly way to provide a good or service is by a single entity, it is referred to in economics, as a “natural monopoly”. In her assessment, a co-ordination function would be a natural monopoly. She emphasised that “natural monopoly” is a technical economic concept and the modifier “natural” should not be considered a synonym for “inevitable” or “durable”. The concept is based on costs, with no reference to substitutes, and therefore no reference to markets. In her assessment, many existing monopolies are not “natural monopolies,” but instead exist for reasons unrelated to their current cost features. In addition, many sectors that fall under the economic definition of a natural monopoly are not, or at least should not be organised in the form of an actual monopoly. • Rapid technological change Rapid change in the level of demand is often brought about by technological change in a related market. In the view of Van Siclen S, changes in technology and demand can upset long held beliefs about feasible structures of the industry and optimal regulation. Technological advances change competition in certain sectors of an industry and may eliminate much of a monopoly. This could imply further changes in the regulation. technological change can also reduce the importance for competition. Further common ownership of different modes may threaten competition, according to Van Siclen S. 6) The characteristics of network industries and the unique application of commercial practices as a result of such characteristics in the airline industry have an effect on the capability of Chapter 3 Page 124 competition law, as applied in the economy generally, to address the different issues raised in the airline industry. In this regard, it is recommended that any corrective measures should duly take account of such characteristics of the airline industry, when commercial conduct is considered from a competition perspective. The need to adjust the application of competition policy specifically in the airline industry, as a result of such characteristics, is an important issue that has been considered in Canada especially and is discussed later in the study. 3.3 CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY THAT DEMONSTRATE AN OLIGOPOLY An oligopoly is defined as an industry composed of a few firms producing either similar or differentiated products. According to Wells AT, the airline industry is typically characterised as an oligopolistic industry as a result of the following: • High barriers to entry. • Few sellers in the market. • A product of similar nature. • Substantial economies of scale. • Growth through merger. • Mutual dependence of airlines. • Price rigidity and non-price competition. • Price transparency and collusion. The abovementioned analysis by Wells AT concluded that the airline industry is “closely approximating an oligopolistic market structure”. 7) This conclusion has important implications both for competitive analysis and as regards the remedies that are required in order to increase competitive forces in the air transport market. Chapter 3 Page 125 3.4 OTHER UNIQUE ECONOMIC CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY 3.4.1 GOVERNMENT FINANCIAL ASSISTANCE Unlike other oligopolistic industries, various governmental units have played major roles in financing the growth and development of the airport-airways system. Wells AT concluded that the airline industry has historically benefited from the financing of major cost elements of the industry by various governmental units. 8) 3.4.2 HIGH TECHNOLOGICAL TURNOVER With regard to capital spending by airlines, Wells AT states that technological advances and competition have forced the carriers to undertake a re-equipment cycle on an average of every eight years. Besides requiring huge amounts of capital spending, heavy expenses in hiring and training personnel and in modifying facilities to accommodate the new aircraft and associated equipment are required in the airline industry. 9) 3.4.3 HIGH LABOUR AND FUEL EXPENSES Wells AT also pointed out that airlines require employees with highly developed skills that are expensive. 10) In addition, the airline industry is subjected to the severe increases in fuel prices the air carriers have experienced over the past 15 years. According to Wells AT, labour and fuel costs typically represent around 60 percent of a carrier's operating expenses. 11) 3.4.4 SENSITIVITY TO ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS With regard to the susceptibility of air transportation demand to the business cycle, Wells AT stated that while the impact of a recession is not unique to the airline industry, the airline industry is much slower in recovering as spending on air travel is discretionary and follows general recovery in the economy a year to 18 months afterwards. Chapter 3 Page 126 Wells AT found that airlines experience a high rate of traffic growth during periods of prosperity but when the economy moves into a recessionary period, the carriers normally experience substantial excess capacity. 12) 3.4.5 CLOSE GOVERNMENT INVOLVEMENT AND REGULATION Wells AT stated that unlike other oligopolistic industries, the airlines have a long history of both support and regulation by government (although this has also been the case in other transportation modes). 13) This was clearly demonstrated by the recent financial aid provided by the USA and other countries as a result of the effect of the terrorist attacks of 11 September 2001. 3.4.5.1 Eight industry-specific features of governmental involvement in the air transport industry Havel BF, identified eight industry-specific features that in his view established the structural faults and contradictions of a long prevailing regime that distinguish the air transport industry from other industries and demonstrate the level of government involvement in the air transport industry: • The doctrine of sovereign national airspace, sanctified in the Chicago Convention as the basis for government control of the world airline industry for the past thirty years. • The piecemeal negotiated exchange of fair traffic rights and other conditions of airspace access through bilateral treaties as opposed to free multilateral grant. • The doctrine of cabotage, which has been used to exclude foreign airlines from traffic rights on domestic point-to-point routes. • The nationality principle, by which each state reserves its domestic cabotage routes, and designation under its bilateral treaties designates carriers that are owned and controlled by the state or its citizens to serve international routes. • The practice of public ownership of national "flag carriers”, supported by incidents of state support that include subsidy programmes and protection from market competition. • Government efforts to fine-tune regulatory control of the tremendous power of computerised yield management technology, and to ensure a fair distribution of access to scarce airport slot and gate facilities. Chapter 3 Page 127 • The evolution of levels of strategic co-operation among airlines of different affiliations, including the device of code-sharing, all of which reflect a partial entrepreneurial evasion, with varying levels of official government complicity, of the precepts of cabotage and nationality. • Confinement of authentic multilateral co-operation to technical and logistical matters such as ticket interlining (with the striking exception of the discredited practice of collective price-setting through the tariff conferences of the IATA). 14) These demonstrate the high degree of government involvement that certainly will have a damping effect on the free working of market forces. The above-mentioned features are further discussed in annexure “B”. It is, however, also necessary to take note of governmental intervention in the conduct of airline operations. In this regard, the following are important: • CRSs. • The distribution of scarce airport runway and terminal resources (the slot and gate problem). • Strategic co-operation among airlines of different affiliations, including the device of code-sharing. • Multilateral co-operation in technical and logistical matters. 3.4.5.2 Regulatory intervention by governments in the operation of air transport services (CRS and airport slots and gates) According to Havel BF, there has been a desire by the USA and EU authorities to liberate their aviation industries from prior regulatory supervision but the switch to competition policy is occasionally blocked by unusual regulatory challenges that are unique to the industry being deregulated. Within the USA and EU air transport industries, two recent developments present challenges that have special resonance for the reform of international aviation: the rapid diffusion in the industry of CRS and the distribution of scarce airport runway and terminal resources (the slot and gate problem). Chapter 3 Page 128 The predicate for invasive government regulation of CRSs and airport access, two apparently unrelated aspects of air transport, remains that of competition policy as in the opinion of Havel BF, each is allegedly capable of: • Foreclosing the entry of new airlines, or • Forestalling system expansion by existing carriers, and • Further both CRSs and airport access have been used in a manner detrimental to a competitive marketplace. The solutions proposed, in the main, a return to ex ante regulatory controls to load the market structure in favour of weaker players (non-owners of CRSs or start-up carriers seeking airport space). 15) 3.4.5.3 Strategic co-operation among airlines (including the device of codesharing) Havel BF noted the “evolution of levels of strategic co-operation amongst airlines of different affiliation, including the device of code-sharing”. In his opinion these measures reflect a “partial entrepreneurial evasion (with varying levels of official government complicity) of the precepts of cabotage and nationality”. 16) 3.4.5.4 Multilateral co-operation limited to technical and logistical matters Havel BF also identified bona fide multilateral co-operation in technical and logistical matters such as ticket interlining with the striking exception of the discredited practice of collective price-setting through the tariff conferences of the IATA. 17) 3.5 COMPETITION IN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY 3.5.1 SPECIAL CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY The airline industry can be described as a network industry (a system of links (routes) that connect nodes (airports)). 18) Chapter 3 Page 129 According to the Nordic competition authorities, a number of interesting characteristics exist in the aviation industry in terms of: • Networking. • Cost structure. • Yield management. • Marketing strategies, and • Switching costs and lock-in effects. 19) 3.5.2 COMPETITION IN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY IN COMPARISON WITH COMPETITION IN OTHER INDUSTRIES Competition in the airline industry differs from competition in many other industries because of the following: • Airlines compete using multiple competitive tools, and • Airlines compete over networks (not only on a route to route (city-pair) basis). In this regard, the airline industry can be described as a network industry consisting of a system of links (routes) that connect nodes (airports). 20) 3.5.3 MULTIPLE DIMENSIONS OF AIRLINE COMPETITION Airlines compete over the following multiple dimensions: • Ticket price. • Frequency (number of flights a day) and the timing of those flights. • Characteristics of the flight itinerary (non stop, continuing single-plane service, or connecting service). • In-flight amenities including: o Service level, food, in-flight entertainment o Seat pitch (how closely spaced together) o Ground amenities, including club lounges • Loyalty schemes (rebates to the client and travellers) in the form of: o FFPs. o TACOs. o Corporate discounts. 21) Chapter 3 Page 130 It is therefore essential that in the analysis of competition in the air transport market, due regard should be had to all the dimensions in which airlines compete and not only to the singular dimension of price. 3.5.4 COMPETITION OVER NETWORKS IN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY Differences in competition over networks in the airline industry differs from that in the telecommunications or information technology industries as follows: • Telecommunications and information technology Primary network effects are increasing returns to scale from large fixed costs coupled with extremely low variable costs and externalities, and increasing benefits to each user when a new user is added. • Airlines Principal effects of network competition are the ability to manage flow traffic and compete over alternative routings and the market power that comes with dominant hubs in route networks. 22) A particularly efficient way of organising an aviation network is the hub-and-spoke mode of operation. Rather than operating a large number of point-to-point, non-stop routes, the airline company channels all or most passengers through a hub airport, from which all connections extend like the spokes of a wheel. In this way the number of different non-stop routes needed to serve all possible pairs of destinations is drastically reduced, allowing for quite remarkable cost savings. 23) The FFPs are thus liable to strengthen any dominant position and to reinforce the anticompetitive effects of hub-and-spoke networks. They therefore act as important barriers to entry. 24) The hub airline therefore tends to dominate its hub airport and the area around it. No other airline is able to offer a comparable frequency of service into or out of the hub. Owing to the important network economic effects at play, the hub airline will often be able to crosssubsidise feeder routes into the hub, so as to effectively outdo any smaller rival airline which may want to offer services on just one or a few spokes. 25) Chapter 3 Page 131 The aviation industry exhibits a number of interesting characteristics in terms of networking, cost structure, yield management, and marketing strategies. The ability to manage flow traffic and compete over alternative routings and the market power that comes with dominant hubs in route networks should also be taken into account when analysing competition in the air transport market. 3.6 NETWORK EXTERNALITIES, ECONOMIES OF SCALE, SCOPE AND DENSITY 3.6.1 INTRODUCTION The aviation industry is also characterised by large network externalities, in the sense that the costs and revenues involved in carrying passengers on different, interconnected routes are interdependent. According to the Nordic Task Force on Airline Competition (NTFAC), there are large economies of scale, scope and density present in the aviation industry. These externalities may originate either at: • The supply (production) side, or • The demand (consumption) side. 26) Supply side economies of scale (also called increasing returns to scale) exist when the average production costs decline with the number of units produced. A common source of economies of scale on the supply side is the combination of a large fixed cost and small constant marginal costs. Economies of scope signify that it costs less to produce services jointly by one firm rather than separately by different firms. Economies of density exist if an airline’s unit costs, or the air travellers’ generalised costs, decline when the airline adds flights or seats on existing routes. 27) Other typical characteristics of network industries are switching costs and lock-in effects. High switching costs result in customers being locked in. This limits competition between Chapter 3 Page 132 operators by preventing competition from eroding price differentials from a dominant carrier. 28) Hunnicutt CA stated that network industries may have fundamentally different characteristics than the traditional industries that classic microeconomic models have been based on. As a result, network effects have important public policy implications. Hunnicutt CA was of the opinion that aviation public policy makers of the future would have to take into account not just supply side efficiency that was central in the traditional models, but demand side effects as well. These include many of the strategies that the airlines have perfected such as loyalty programmes including FFPs that have been designed to raise the switching costs for the best customers. 29) As a result, this section will distinguish between the various economies in the airline industry from both the supply (production) side and the demand (consumption) side. 3.6.2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE Table 3.1: Economies of scale Economies of scale on the supply Economies (production) side Average production of scale on the demand (consumption) side costs (cost per Demand for a good increases with the total passenger kilometre) decline with the number of goods sold number of units produced (in batch size). Such economies can be affected by: Such effects are of limited importance in the • Using larger aircraft size (aircraft) airline industry. • Increasing load factor and • Longer stage length. 30) Larger aircraft may appear more comfortable and secure to the traveller and induce a very Economies of scale due to firm size are, limited additional air travel demand. 32) however, quickly exhausted in the airline industry. Chapter 3 Page 133 Large fixed costs and small variable costs give rise to a minimum viable scale, which has to be exceeded in order for the firm to earn a profit in the market. 31) Source: Compiled from: The Nordic task force on airline competition, Report from the Nordic competition authorities, competitive airlines. Towards a more vigorous competition policy in relation to the air travel market no. 1/2002, Copenhagen/Helsinki/Oslo/Stockholm, 18 June 2002. Using a larger aircraft reduces the cost per passenger where certain costs do not rise proportionally with the number of seats. Economies of vehicle size are well known in transport industries, including in airline operations. The estimated economies of aircraft size are, according to the NTFAC, often exaggerated since costs are compared for the different aircraft on their typical routes. Since larger aircraft tend to be used on longer distances, the economies of stage length influence the comparison. Specific estimates of scale economies at vehicle level may therefore be overstated if no adjustment is made for the effects of differences in stage length. 33) Longer stage length reduces the costs per passenger in two ways: • Landing fees, handling cost, and ground manoeuvring cost fall relative to the passenger kilometres flown (produced). • The capacity of the aircraft is better utilised since the aircraft is grounded for a shorter time. Turn-around between flights is reduced with longer stage lengths and fewer landings per period. 34) The optimal aircraft size follows from route characteristics. This implies that the unit cost per revenue passenger kilometre mirrors the network operated by an airline. A large airline operating the network of a medium sized airline will incur similar unit costs on that part of its operations to those incurred by the smaller carrier. There are no significant economies of scale from operating costs at the firm level. 35) Chapter 3 Page 134 3.6.3 ECONOMIES OF SCOPE Table 3.2: Economies of Scope Economies of scope on the supply Economies (production) side of scope on the demand (consumption) side It costs less to produce services jointly by The most important economies of scope are one firm rather than separately by found on the demand side. different firms. Arise when more routes are served within A carrier offering a larger network of services the network of an airline (the size of the will be more attractive to the traveller, since he will have more destinations to choose from and network of routes). 36) a larger probability of finding a suitable By operating several interconnected connection from the particular origin to any routes, the airline is able to utilise aircraft, given destination. 39) crew, reservation systems, marketing devices, and other overhead cost items in Economies of scope on the demand side are various production lines or city-pair intensified by marketing practices: connections. 37) • FFPs. • TACOS. Economies of scope may be particularly • Corporate discount schemes. important when slot capacity at airports is limited. These create synthetic economies of scope on the demand side as they make it more attractive Airlines operating several flights out of for passengers and travel agents to concentrate one airport gain the flexibility to adjust their demand at one airline. 40) their network to changes in the demand pattern. 38) Increase the loyalty of the customers toward the airlines through an artificial increase in the switching costs. Consumer preferences when more routes are served are connected to the concept of switching costs that customers have to pay when they shift Chapter 3 Page 135 from one supplier to another. 41) Source: Compiled from; The Nordic task force on airline competition, report from the Nordic competition authorities, competitive airlines: Towards a more vigorous competition policy in relation to the air travel market no. 1/2002, Copenhagen/Helsinki/Oslo/Stockholm, 18 June 2002. The NTFAC stated that the most important economies of scope from the production side in the aviation industry arise from the complementarily of routes within the network. By operating several interconnected routes, the airline is able to utilise aircraft, crew, reservation systems, marketing devices and other overhead cost items in various production lines (citypair connections). 42) These complementarities are important for several reasons: • An airline that supplies end-to-end trips consisting of at least two legs but only operates on one of the leg routes has to buy a seat on this route from another airline. In contrast, an airline that operates on both legs can supply all parts of the same endto-end flight itself. In general, this difference gives a competitive advantage to the latter airline. If competition on the leg routes is imperfect, the selling airline marks up the price of the seat above marginal costs. This mark-up is a cost to the buying airline, which means that an airline operating on both legs can supply the end-to-end flight at a lower cost than an airline that operates on only one of them. The selling airline is able to raise its rival’s cost. • Operation within a network requires a close coordination at airport nodes. Incoming flights must be co-ordinated with outgoing flights and arrive at gates close to the gates of the relevant outgoing flights. As a result, economies of scope may be particularly important when slot capacity at airports is limited. Airlines operating several flights out of one airport obtain flexibility to adjust their network to changes in the demand pattern. They may switch the use of a slot from one route to another, when demand develops differently in two market segments. Thus an airline will enjoy flexibility by concentrating several routes on a hub airport. 43) Much of this coordination depends on city-pair specific investment at the hub airport. If two legs forming an end-to-end flight are operated by independent airlines, unforeseen events on the first leg may not be accounted for by the airline that operates the second leg. Furthermore, free-rider problems may mean that all the necessary investments are not made, and having made the necessary city-pair specific investments, the airlines are exposed to Chapter 3 Page 136 strategic behaviour by their rivals. Both problems may mean that the transaction costs in the hub airport are higher than if one airline operates all leg routes. 44) Economies of scope emanating from the demand side are even more important, according to the NTFAC. These occur when the demand for a range of goods (routes) is larger than if the same goods were offered individually. The demand for an airline’s services increases with the number of routes that are covered by its network. A carrier offering a larger network of services will be more attractive to the traveller, since he or she will have more destinations to choose from and a larger probability of finding a suitable connection from her particular origin to any given destination. Economies of scope on the demand side of the airline industry are due to two factors: • Consumer preferences, and • Marketing practices. 45) Consumer preferences Economies of scope on the demand side are due to the larger number of routes served and are connected to the concept of switching costs, which customers have to pay when they shift from one supplier to another. Typical switching costs relate to: • Contracts. • Training. • Learning. • Data conversion. • Search costs, and • Loyalty costs. 46) The NTFAC stated that switching costs may appear in the airline industry because many people prefer a trip by a single airline compared to one involving two or more airlines. A high quality end-to-end journey via a connecting airport requires that the passengers be able to go through the connection without delays, baggage handling problems, extra costs, or other unforeseeable events. The NTFAC was, however, of the opinion that the risk of such events is often perceived as higher when two or more airlines are involved. In addition, some Chapter 3 Page 137 passengers think that travelling by one airline is more comfortable than using two or more carriers. Switching costs mean that the airlines realise economies of scale on the demand side by increasing the number of routes. An increase in the number of routes means fewer transfers between aircraft for the passengers. As many passengers prefer fewer shifts, more routes make the airline’s services more attractive to the passenger, and as a consequence, the airline will encounter an increased demand. 47) Marketing practices Economies of scope on the demand side are often intensified by the marketing practices of the airlines. Examples of such marketing practices are FFPs and travel agent agreements. Schemes and programmes such as these create synthetic economies of scope on the demand side because they make it more attractive for passengers and travel agents to concentrate their demand at one or a few airlines. The schemes and programmes increase the loyalty of the customers toward the airlines through an artificial increase in the switching costs. 48) 3.6.4 ECONOMIES OF DENSITY An airline’s unit costs decline when the airline adds flights or seats on existing routes. 49) Table 3.3: Economies of density Economies of density on the supply Economies of density on the demand (production) side (consumption) side In airlines, supply side economies of Even more important are the demand side density exist if an airline’s unit cost economies of density. A higher route declines when the airline adds flights or frequency will decrease the average time cost seats on existing routes, primarily because experienced by the traveller and hence induce of improved utilisation of aircraft capacity a higher demand for air transport, especially and crew. 50) from business travellers. 52) Competitive advantage in a large hub-and- This feedback mechanism, implying that the Chapter 3 Page 138 spoke network. Adding destinations to a demand for travel in a network is in a sense hub-and-spoke network shows decreasing self-reinforcing, is referred to as the Mohring returns to firm or network size. This effect. As the demand for travel increases, a negative effect is dominated by the positive higher frequency of departures can be supported, and the individual user incurs a effect of economies of traffic density. smaller average generalised cost. This in turn Passengers who must travel via a hub also induces a still higher demand, and so on until face an increase in trip duration as equilibrium is reached. 53) compared to a direct point-to-point service. Longer flights increase the airlines’ operating costs and the passenger’s total travel time. As a result, the economies of density involved in hubbing must be considered against the disadvantage of increased trip duration and the inconvenience of passengers having to transfer between flights. 51) Source: Compiled from; The Nordic task force on airline competition, report from the Nordic competition authorities, competitive airlines towards a more vigorous competition policy in relation to the air travel market no. 1/2002, Copenhagen/Helsinki/Oslo/Stockholm, 18 June 2002. Of particular importance for the economies of density involved in aviation networks is the hub-and-spoke mode of operation. According to the NTFAC, a hub airline channels all or most passengers through a hub airport, from which all connections extend like the spokes of a wheel. In this way the number of different non-stop routes needed to serve all possible pairs of destinations is drastically reduced, allowing for quite remarkable cost savings. According to the NTFAC, the most important economies of scope in the aviation industry stem precisely from the carriers’ opportunities to consolidate traffic by employing a hub-andspoke network. This consolidation enables airlines to derive economies of density from directing passengers via hubs, since they may use larger aircraft and/or fly with higher frequencies. The lower number of routes in the hub-and-spoke network means that by Chapter 3 Page 139 transforming its network from a point-to-point network into a hub-and-spoke network, an airline is able to reduce its costs without lowering the number of destinations served. 54) 3.6.5 ECONOMIES OF ALLIANCES Table 3.4: Economies of alliances Economies of alliances on the supply Economies of alliances on the demand (production) side (consumption) side Airlines form alliances in order to exploit More extensive networks are more attractive to each other’s networks and to strengthen customers and offer larger economies of scope the competitive positions of all alliance to the carrier. partners. Establishing an alliance with an “adjacent” Alliances should be treated with the same carrier may also be an efficient way for vigour as traditional mergers. 55) competitors to divide the market between them. 56) Source: Compiled from; The Nordic task force on airline competition, Report from the Nordic competition authorities, Competitive airlines towards a more vigorous competition policy in relation to the air travel market no. 1/2002, Copenhagen/Helsinki/Oslo/Stockholm, 18 June 2002. 3.6.6 SWITCHING COSTS AND LOCK-IN EFFECTS Switching costs limit competition between operators by stopping competition to erode price differentials from a dominant carrier. 57) High switching costs result in customers being locked in. 58) 3.7 THE EFFECT OF AIRLINE NETWORKS ON COMPETITION The increasing returns to scale, scope and density in the airline industry have several anticompetitive implications, according to the NTFAC. These include: • Economies of scale on the supply side set a natural limit to the number of competitors that can operate without economic loss on a given route. The combination of a large fixed cost and small variable cost gives rise to a minimum viable scale, which has to be exceeded in order for the firm to earn a profit in the market. Aircraft can easily be Chapter 3 Page 140 transferred between routes, but each aircraft operating on a given route incurs a fixed cost. • Economies of scope on the demand side may reduce the competition in the airline industry, as they give the airlines an incentive to merge or join alliances with other airlines so as to increase the number of routes offered and the flight frequency on every route. Entry is often not possible on the scale of one or a few products. To be competitive, and exploit the economies of scope, each firm in the industry often has to produce a full range of products. • The hub-and-spoke system of operation, while economically efficient to the individual carrier firm, seems to give rise to strong anti-competitive effects. The economies of scope and density characteristic of these networks are such as to grant the (one and only) hub airline very considerable market power at and around its hub. As a result, different airlines have an incentive to operate hubs at different airports. The hub-and-spoke system as operated among a set of large individual carriers is therefore able to divide the market between the airlines. Although the networks of different carriers overlap, very few origin-destination pairs will exhibit more than two carriers operating non-stop flights. 59) • The competitive advantage of hub-and-spoke networks is effectively reinforced through the loyalty programmes operated by the carriers. A FFP becomes more attractive to the traveller the larger the carrier’s network of destinations, and vice versa. • The competitive advantages allow the hub airline to dominate most routes out of the hub airport. • Most major airlines have joined alliances with other airlines that operate in complementary regions or continents. A few global alliances cover more than fifty percent of the world passenger market. • The development of the airline industry in the years after the liberalisation was influenced by the role of network economics. By building hub-and-spoke networks the large airlines had, however, managed to enhance their competitiveness by exploiting technical economies of scope (or density). • The cost advantages related to network economics are not always reflected in lower airfares. In many cases dominance of a hub-and-spoke network gives rise to market power, which is exploited by the airlines to increase the fares especially on outgoing Chapter 3 Page 141 flights from airports that are highly dominated by the hub airline. Hub airlines have market power on almost all spokes out of the hub airport. • The incremental cost of operating an extra route in a hub-and-spoke network is often smaller than suggested by the average unit cost of the network. An extra route may generate feeder traffic (and associated revenue) to the larger network. It will be relatively inexpensive for an incumbent hub airline to cross-subsidise a single spoke route or a limited set of such routes. This leaves a dominant hub airline with ample opportunity to fight a rival new entrant through increased capacity, disproportionately reduced fares, and/or other predatory strategies. Unless met by timely and resolute interventions on the part of the competition authorities, such strategies could make the market almost incontestable, according to the NTFAC. 60) 3.8 THE OPERATION OF A DEREGULATED AIRLINE INDUSTRY 3.8.1 INTRODUCTION The US DOT concluded that, contrary to the predictions generally made at the time of deregulation, actual experience demonstrated that “deregulated airline markets are not contestable” and that “incumbent airlines can and do obtain market power on certain types of routes”. As a result of the fact that incumbent airlines “can obtain market power on some kinds of routes", the US Administration stated that the DOT should "take action against exclusionary practices that end or deter attempts by competitors to serve such routes”. 61) The US DOT stated that “deregulation overall has been very successful and greatly benefited consumers, since most airline markets are competitive and the vast proportion of airline passengers travel in markets that have competitive service”. The US DOT motivated their conclusion with the following statistics: • More than eighty percent of airline passengers travel in markets that have two or more competitors. • The number of domestic passengers has tripled since 1979. • Traffic in competitive markets has grown even more. Chapter 3 Page 142 • The number of passengers in markets with two or more competitors has almost quadrupled since 1979. • The number of passengers in markets with three or more competitors has eased almost six fold and now accounts for about forty percent of all traffic. • The number of passengers in markets with three or more competitors exceeds the total number of passengers in 1979. • The increased competition is reflected in the fares paid by passengers, since inflation-adjusted fares have declined by about thirty-five percent since deregulation. The US DOT reported, however, that deregulated airline markets functioned differently from the way expected at the time of deregulation. At the time of deregulation, industry analysts assumed that in a deregulated environment: • Any airline could enter any route and that the threat of entry would cause incumbent airlines to maintain low fares to discourage entry (potential competition). • The more nimble airlines able to enter the industry after deregulation would capture a large share of the traffic from the less efficient established airlines. • Airlines were thought likely to offer relatively simple fare structures. 62) According to the US DOT the operation of the deregulated industry has been quite different from the expectations at the time of deregulation: • Industry analysts had not expected every major airline to adopt a hub-and-spoke route system. Airlines generally operated linear route systems during the regulatory era, as did the intrastate airlines operating in California and Texas. 63) After deregulation each of the holdover airlines (airlines that existed prior to the deregulation of the airline industry) established a hub-and-spoke system. Hub-and-spoke systems enable the hubbing airline to operate a more frequent service in spoke markets than could be supported only by local traffic. Hub-and-spoke systems therefore benefit travellers in most markets. However hub-and-spoke route systems make entry in many markets difficult, owing tothe fact that any airline serving a route from one of its hubs will have substantial competitive advantages over an entrant, unless the entrant either serves the route from one of its own hubs or has significantly lower costs than the hubbing airline. 64) • Deregulation did not lead to the simplified fare structure anticipated by many observers. Economists had expected airlines operating under deregulation to offer Chapter 3 Page 143 unrestricted low fares, an expectation based in part on the assumption that firms entering the industry with low costs would keep incumbent airlines from being able to create a complex fare structure. 65) 66) The actual result was quite different from the expected one. The fare structures of airlines became extraordinarily complicated. Airlines offer many different types of fares subject to many different conditions or rules. Airlines use yield management to determine how many seats would be offered at each fare (and limit the number of seats available to each fare class) with the objective of selling as many seats as possible at higher fare classes. This enables airlines to discriminate and charge higher fares to business travellers interested in obtaining frequent service (time sensitive passengers) while offering lower fares to leisure travellers interested in saving money and less interested in the number of flights available in any market or the timing of those flights. 67) 68) 69) The implementation of advances in information technology made it possible for the airlines to implement detailed yield management systems which increased their ability to engage in market segmentation and price discrimination. The technology has enabled each airline to allocate seats among the many different fare classes offered on a flight in accordance with a predicted demand for each type of fare. 70) In addition, CRSs have played an important role in airline distribution. Travel agents, who sell the great majority of airline tickets, rely on the CRSs to determine what airline services and fares are available and to make bookings. The CRSs provide a very efficient method of carrying out these tasks. 71) To enable travel agents to advise their customers effectively, the CRSs contain the publicly available fare classes of almost all airlines and show whether such fare classes are available or sold out on particular flights. An incumbent airline can learn from a CRS what fares are being charged by a new rival and can plan its response especially if such CRS is owned or controlled by such airline. 72) 73) • Contrary to expectations at the time of deregulation, almost all of the current major airlines were major airlines before deregulation. Industry observers had predicted when deregulation began that the major airlines of that time would have trouble adjusting to a deregulated environment, in part because they had relatively high operating costs. Airlines entering the industry after deregulation were expected to become a major segment of the industry since they would be more efficient and not handicapped with the high-cost practices of the airlines doing business before deregulation. 74) Chapter 3 Page 144 • The proponents of deregulation assumed that there were no economies of scale or scope in the airline industry, and they overlooked the physical barriers to entry that became important when the regulatory scheme no longer made entry and route expansion difficult. The unavailability of airport facilities, for example, has hindered expansion efforts by new entrants. 75) 76) An incumbent airline in such a market can effectively prevent entry if it can obtain control of such scarce resources and deny them to entrants, even if it is not using them. Significant economies of scale and scope proved to exist in the deregulated industry, as shown by the importance of travel agent override commissions and FFPs. These economies are particularly important on the revenue side, another development unforeseen at the time of deregulation. Analysts then focused on airline costs, an important factor under regulation, rather than the ability to generate revenues, a factor which has become critical since deregulation. 77) • According to Dutta R, there are far more economies of scale on the revenue side than on the cost side. He stated that “revenue synergy” is derived from the power of huband-spoke networks. If an airline has have fifty flights into a hub as opposed to three flights into a hub that in his view this creates a “huge power” as a result of the frequency of operations. In addition, customers want to go to many destinations and prefer the carrier that serves all their needs, and that creates some economies from a frequent flyer basis. 78) 79) • As was expected, many firms entered the airline industry in the first ten years after deregulation. Contrary to expectations, few survived. Until recent years the industry included only four significant airlines that began scheduled interstate service after deregulation – Southwest, which had operated as an intrastate airline in Texas before deregulation; America West; Midwest Express; and American Trans Air, which began as a charter airline. The other new entrants generally failed, in part because of management mistakes and an inability to cope with recessions. 80) Competitive responses from stronger network airlines intended to eliminate competition may have undermined the ability of some new entrants to remain in business. 81) 82) Some of the major pre-deregulation airlines, of course, like Eastern and Pan American, also failed. 83) Of the nine passenger airlines with current annual operating revenues of more than US $1 billion, all but America West and Southwest started operating interstate scheduled passenger flights long before the airline industry was deregulated (the seven that began operations before deregulation are American, Continental, Chapter 3 Page 145 Delta, Northwest, TWA, United, and AA). The surviving pre-deregulation airlines have become more efficient since deregulation. Their ability to survive despite their higher costs, and the failure of almost all of the new entrant airlines that started up in the early years of deregulation (with substantially lower costs) suggested that the major airlines’ route systems and the scale and scope of their operations gave them important competitive advantages. 84) 85) This is an important aspect of airline competition as it implies that efficiency and lower cost are not determinants of success in the airline industry. • The expected ability of virtually any airline to enter any route proved unrealistic. 86) • A number of economists had assumed that the contestability theory would apply to the deregulated airline industry. Under that theory, as described by Professor Levine M, 87) potential entry by new firms serves to discipline the behaviour of participants in real world markets where a small number of firms (oligopoly) participate. It was thought that firms actually operating in a given market would necessarily reduce their prices to levels consistent with the costs of their potential entrant rivals. Otherwise, entry will occur and they will be replaced. Whether airline markets are contestable is important in determining whether there are threats to airline competition, since few airline markets are likely to have many competitors. If airline markets were contestable, firms outside a market could enter it so easily that the threat of potential entry would make the incumbent firms operate efficiently and charge competitive prices. 88) Contestability could exist only under three conditions: o “Equal access to economies of scale and to technology, whether expressed as access to competitive levels of unit costs or as equivalent access to product quality. o No sunk costs, a firm can enter and exit without entry and exit costs, including operating losses resulting from predation, and o Price sustainability, there is a set of prices that can occur after the entry of at least one firm which will support profitable operation”. 89) Chapter 3 Page 146 • The Secretary of the DOT concluded that “contestability has proven inapplicable in the airline industry”. 90) 91) for the following reasons: o An airline entering a market incurs certain sunk costs that cannot be recovered if it exits, for example, advertising costs and the cost of setting up facilities at the new airport. o Travellers will be reluctant to book an airline that exits and re-enters a market, moreover, given the significant possibility that the airline may again leave the market before the date of their planned flight and the loss of pre-payment for such flight. As a result, airlines cannot freely enter routes due to expected initial lack of support by clients. o An incumbent airline does not need to lower fares to discourage entry before it happens – an incumbent airline can immediately change its fare structure if another airline announces plans to enter one of its markets. The threat of entry thus puts little pressure on incumbent airlines to reduce fares. 92) 93) o Airlines developed marketing programmes designed to gain the loyalty of their customers and travel agents. Airlines, for example, created travel agent override commission programmes to encourage travel agents to book the airline offering the incentive commissions. These commission programmes are usually structured so that the airline with the largest market share in a travel agent’s area will have the most attractive commission programme. These programmes are attractive to many travel agents. FFPs purchase passenger loyalty in order to attract repeat business. 94) 95) o The US DOT nevertheless found that “nonetheless, deregulation has been very successful despite the inaccuracy of many predictions on how the deregulated industry would operate. And while competition in some markets may be less vigorous than predicted, all airlines, both those operating before deregulation and those created since, have had to reshape their operations to become efficient and cope with the competitive demands of the deregulated environment”. 96) Two of the unexpected results of deregulation, hub-and-spoke route systems and yield management, were crucial to the analysis of competitive issues in the proceedings regarding unfair or exclusionary competitive practices by the US DOT. The major findings and Chapter 3 Page 147 conclusions of the Secretary of the DOT in this regard as well as those pertaining to the development of a new generation of low cost airlines are set out in 3.8.4 below. Johannesburg International Airport in South Africa has to a great extent developed into the hub of larger airlines in the private sector in South Africa. As a result, many of the characteristics of hub-airports in the USA are also be applicable to South Africa. Yield management is practiced by SAA and some of the airlines in the private sector. It may well be that yield management systems unfairly discriminate against members of the public by limiting the availability of the number of seats per fare class (especially the availability of cheaper fare classes) and at the same time promoting such tariffs without disclosing the limited extent of seat availability to the public. This also results in confusion relating to what the “going rate” for a particular flight will be. 3.8.2 YIELD MANAGEMENT According to the US DOT, yield management has enabled the airlines, especially the network airlines, to develop complex fare structures designed to maximises revenues on each flight through price discrimination. Airlines attempt to sell as many seats as possible at the highest fares, those charged for unrestricted travel, and as few seats as possible at the lowest discount fares. Passengers paying the highest fares obtain the advantages of flexibility and last-minute access to seats. They can book seats just before the flight, change their reservation without penalty, and obtain a full refund if they do not to use the booking. Passengers travelling on most discount fares, in contrast, typically have to book seats several days or more before the flight, have to pay in advance for their seats, cannot change a reservation without paying a penalty, and cannot obtain a cash refund if they cancel their trip. Although business travellers can use some discount fares, the cheapest discount fares frequently have a Saturday night stay requirement to discourage business travellers from using them. To save seats for passengers willing to pay for unrestricted fares bought shortly or immediately before the flight, airlines limit the number of seats made available at the lower fare levels. 97) 98) Unlike the low cost airlines, the network airlines have relatively little interest in attracting travellers who insist on paying low fares for air travel, even though the network airlines do Chapter 3 Page 148 sell many discount-fare seats. They have structured their operations so as to attract travellers willing to pay more for better and more frequent service. If an airline charges higher fares to those travellers, it may be able “to generate sufficient revenue to provide the product, but no more than that if competition is effective”. 99) 100) The airlines’ yield management systems mean that passengers on the same flight will have paid different fares, depending on how far in advance they made their booking and how many restrictions they were willing to accept in return for a lower fare. No airline has been able to maintain a simple fare structure. The discrimination in fares also reflects the willingness of business travellers, but not leisure travellers, to pay for frequent and convenient flights. 101) 102) 103) Low cost airlines have less complex fare structures than the network airlines. Although network airlines serving a market allocate different numbers of seats to each fare level, they tend to charge similar amounts for each type of fare offered in a market (for example, 21-day advance-purchase fares and unrestricted economy fares). Each network airline usually matches the fare levels offered by its network competitors in a market, although not necessarily the number of seats made available at each fare. An airline that has a competitive advantage in a non stop market will be able to sell more seats at unrestricted fares and so can afford to make fewer seats available for discount fare passengers. A hubbing carrier is able to offer a service advantage relative to a non-hubbing carrier, which permits it to attract a relatively larger portion of time-sensitive (primarily business) travellers, serving to raise its average yield. Even if both airlines serving a route have a hub at one of the endpoints, the airline with a competitive advantage can obtain significantly higher yields. 104) 3.8.3 HUB-AND-SPOKE ROUTE SYSTEMS Airlines with hub-and-spoke route systems carry most travellers in long haul markets by flying them from their origin point to a hub, where the passengers transfer to other flights bound for their destination. This enables a hubbing airline to attract both local traffic (passengers flying between the hub and another point) and flow traffic (passengers travelling from one point to another over the hub). Chapter 3 Page 149 The network airlines’ hub-and-spoke systems give flow passengers more connection options for travel from their point of origin to their destination. Travellers in the long-haul markets benefit from increased service options, since several airlines compete for flow traffic with connections over their hubs. 105) A network airline will have a large share of the traffic and flights at its hub. It typically will carry at least half of the local traffic at each of its hub airports. 106) 107) While hub-and-spoke systems benefit travellers in the flow markets (and make possible more frequent service for travellers in the local markets), they also create substantial competitive advantages for a network airline in its hub markets. Those advantages make it difficult for other airlines to compete in those markets and enable the incumbent hub airline to charge higher fares for the following reasons: • The combination of local and flow traffic enables the hubbing airline to offer more flights in all of the markets at its hub, providing a substantial competitive edge. Nonhubbing competitors will capture little flow traffic and so cannot operate as many flights. The airline that offers the most flights in a market typically obtains a disproportionate share of the traffic in that market, so the inability of a competitor to operate as many flights will likely reduce its ability to attract passengers for the few flights that it does operate. 108) 109) • The hubbing airline serves the most destinations from the hub and offers the most flights in all or almost all its hub markets, so the hub city’s residents will find its FFP more attractive than programmes offered by competing airlines that serve fewer destinations and operate fewer flights from the city. Residents flying on the hub airline will accumulate award miles more quickly and have a better choice of destinations for awards. 110) but since award benefits are non-linear, residents will prefer the hub airline since they will obtain awards more quickly. 111) • The hub airline’s travel agent override commission programme will be the most attractive programme for travel agents in the hub city. An airline that dominates a city will typically structure its override commission programme to leverage its dominant share of the local airline market. The airline that is most often booked by the agent will offer the most remunerative override commission programme for the travel agents in the area and thereby gain a larger share of their bookings. 112) 113) Chapter 3 Page 150 • The hub airline’s dominance of the local market at the hub city gives it greater name recognition. Travellers will be more likely to call that airline when they wish to book airline seats. 114) In addition, the hub airline can spread advertising costs over a greater number of markets, so it will have lower advertising expenses than will an airline serving fewer markets at the hub city. 115) Because a hubbing airline obtains the above-mentioned competitive advantages, its hub markets tend to have little competition. The virtual disappearance of hubs with two hubbing network airlines suggests that the competitive advantages possessed by the larger hubbing airline make it difficult for a second airline to operate a hub at the same city. However, since a hub airline can operate most efficiently in its hub markets, it will likely add new routes from its hub, not from cities that are not hubs. Each network airline focuses on routes that have one of its hubs as an endpoint, and it rarely serves a competitor’s non-stop hub markets. 116) Where a network airline entered a competitor’s total hub route system it seems to represent signalling that the airline entering is doing so in retaliation against the competing airline’s increased competition in one of the first airline’s major markets. Generally the competitive advantages enjoyed by a network airline at its hub preclude other network airlines from operating as efficiently or profitably as the first hubbing airline. 117) Hub airlines therefore usually have market power at their hubs, as shown by hub premiums – average fares in most hub markets are substantially higher than in comparable non-hub markets. Professors Oster and Strong cited figures presented by Professors Borenstein S to the Transportation Research Board on January 21, 1999, that show hub premiums in the USA as high as 62 percent at Charlotte, 51 percent at Cincinnati and Pittsburgh, and 41 percent at Minneapolis-St. Paul. 118) On the other hand, little or no hub premium exists at network airline hubs that receive a significant amount of service from the low cost carrier Southwest, such as St. Louis and Salt Lake City. 119) 120) 121) Hub premiums have persisted over time. Hubs without a significant level of low cost carrier service had larger fare premiums in 1997 than they did in 1988. 122). Travellers in markets with low cost carrier competition, on the other hand, obtain both the low fares offered by low cost airlines and the more frequent service and wider range of destinations offered by a Chapter 3 Page 151 hubbing airline. While hubs give travellers better service, the ability of network airlines to continue operating hubs after entry by a low cost carrier indicates that the higher fares charged by network airlines in hub markets without competition reflect in part market power, not costs, demand characteristics, or service features. A network airline with market power at a hub can obtain higher yields in the hub markets largely by limiting the capacity of its flights, with the result that business travellers who are willing to accept high fares will fill up most of the relatively limited number of seats offered by the network airline. The limited number of seats offered means that the network airline has little incentive to make seats available to passengers willing to fly only if they can obtain low fares. Hub markets, of course, still have frequent service, since frequent connecting banks of flights are a necessary part of hub-and-spoke operations, but they would have even more service in a competitive environment. 123) The operation of hub-and-spoke networks is one of the many commercial practices adopted by airlines following deregulation to exploit the economies of scope that exist in the air transport industry, as analysed in 4.3 of chapter 4. Recently, the viability of the network business travel pricing model of the hub-and-spoke airlines has undergone a fundamental shift with respect to levels of business travel to support such operations, as identified in 3.9 below. 3.8.4 THE DEVELOPMENT OF A NEW GENERATION OF LOW COST AIRLINES In this section, the importance for consumers of establishing low fare competition especially in hub-markets that are dominated by large network airlines is demonstrated on the basis of conclusions arrived on in the USA. Low cost carriers, both in the USA (like SWA, JetBlue, AirTran Airways, American Trans Air, Frontier and Spirit Airlines) and in Europe (like Ryanair, easyJet, Airline Co, Virgin Express, Buzz) have recently achieved tremendous growth while financial difficulties are being experienced by full-service network airlines (like American, Continental, Delta, Northwest and American Airways as well as Air Canada) that have experienced a reduction of volumes of traffic. This issue is further discussed in 3.9 below. Chapter 3 Page 152 While the low cost airlines generally use yield management, they offer a smaller range of fares than the network airlines and impose fewer restrictions on their lowest fares. 124) The more recently established low cost airlines have more limited route systems than Southwest and do not have Southwest’s financial strength or as much of a brand reputation. While Southwest enters new routes with frequent flights, the newer low cost airlines often enter markets by operating relatively few daily flights. Some of the newer low cost airlines, unlike Southwest, rely on hub-and-spoke route systems. The low cost airlines have lower operating costs than the network airlines, except for America West and possibly the network airlines’ low fare subsidiaries. 125) Every low cost carrier had adjusted costs per available seat-mile that were significantly below the costs of any network airline (except America West). While the network airlines do not focus on carrying low fare traffic, several of them have developed low cost subsidiaries that seek to compete with Southwest and other low cost airlines for price-sensitive travellers (e.g. Shuttle by United, Delta Express and American Airways’ MetroJet). 126) The services offered by Southwest and the newer low cost airlines greatly benefit many consumers: they both give travellers access to substantially lower fares and greatly increase the size of the market by stimulating traffic. In 1997, short-haul markets (markets under 750 miles, 1200 kilometres) with low fare service had a nominal average fare of $84, while shorthaul markets without such service had a nominal average fare of $175. Traffic in short-haul markets with low fare service has quadrupled since 1979, while traffic in short-haul markets without such service has grown by only 48 percent since 1979. 127) The Secretary for Transportation of the USA concluded that low cost airlines provide important service and competitive benefits in that fare levels are much lower and traffic levels are much higher on routes served by low cost airlines. He also noted that whilst competition by the low cost airlines provides obvious benefits, especially for cost-sensitive consumers, consumers benefit from all forms of airline competition. In this regard, he noted that Midwest Express chose to compete by offering service features not matched by other airlines and considered attractive by many travellers. As such, Midwest Express has operated successfully by offering premium service at fares comparable to those charged by other airlines. While network airlines cannot practicably compete effectively at another network Chapter 3 Page 153 airline’s hub, a low cost carrier with lower costs than network airlines and effective management can compete effectively in such hub markets, which typically have relatively high fares. The Secretary for Transportation of the USA concluded that a new service by a low cost carrier is likely to be the only way that many hub markets will ever benefit from competitive airline service. 128) 3.8.5 POTENTIALLY UNFAIR COMPETITIVE RESPONSES TO ENTRY BY LOW COST AIRLINES Since a hubbing airline will most likely have only limited competition in most of its hub markets if it can deter entry by low cost airlines, Oster and Strong regarded it as profitable for an incumbent airline to attempt to eliminate actual competition if it can. The low cost carrier’s presence in a hub market takes away the hubbing airline’s ability to charge fares above competitive levels. 129) If the low cost carrier becomes established in one hub market, it may well expand into other markets at the hub. 130) Several low cost airlines, often supported by communities and airports, have complained to the US DOT that a low cost carrier’s entry into a network airline’s market, typically a hub market, has led the incumbent to sharply cut its fares and increase the number of seats sold at low fares (and often its capacity on the route) with the intention of making the route unprofitable for the entrant. Complaints were also received by the US DOT about other behaviour, not just pricing and capacity strategies, seemingly designed to make entry impossible or at least unprofitable as airlines compete in multiple ways, not just on price and schedules. 131) Such complaints included allegation that incumbent airlines: • Awarded bonus override commissions to travel agents that book the incumbent airline rather than the airline entering the market, thereby making it more difficult for the entrant to obtain bookings from those agents’ customers. • Took other steps that prejudiced the competitive position of an entrant airline, for example, refusals to sign joint baggage and ticketing agreements with the entrant, even though airlines typically have such agreements with most other airlines. Chapter 3 Page 154 • Refused to sublease gates and other airport facilities to entrants, even though they are not being fully used, when comparable facilities are not available from any other source. • Allegedly purchased the slots that come on the market to keep entrants from obtaining slots at slot-restricted airports. • Used slots for relatively unprofitable markets in order to prevent losing such slots to a potential entrant (“baby sitting” of slots). 132) The Secretary agreed with the TRB panel that incumbents could use such tactics as “limiting access to airports by restricting the availability of slots and gates; influencing CRS listings; and offering special travel agent incentives” “to the detriment of smaller rivals, possibly denying the opportunity to compete fully on the basis of relative costs and the attractiveness of their offerings”. 133) The panel also stated that the DOT “has an important role in preserving and enhancing opportunities for competitive entry in the airline industry”. It stated that the DOT “should ensure that airlines are not exploiting their relationships with airports, air traffic control access, CRSs, and travel agents to hinder competition and to limit entry opportunities”. 134) 135) 3.8.6 QUESTIONABLE RESPONSES INVOLVING PRICE AND CAPACITY The Secretary of the US DOT stated that the most controversial competitive responses to entry involved sharp fare cuts, a large increase in the number of seats sold at low fares, and often an increase in total capacity. An incumbent airline will often need to cut its fares when a competitor enters the market. He was of the opinion that a low cost carrier’s entry should not usually require the incumbent airline to match the new entrant’s fare levels and make large numbers of seats available at those levels or to eliminate restrictions on its discount fares owing to the fact that network airlines typically offer service features unmatched by most low cost airlines. In some cases the incumbent network airline has nonetheless responded to entry in ways that appear to him to be economically irrational, unless the entrant exits the market or reduces its service. In these cases, the hubbing airline cuts its fares and increases the availability of its lowest fares by so much that it obtains much lower revenues and profits than it would have Chapter 3 Page 155 obtained if it had chosen a more moderate response. In extreme cases the incumbent airline cuts its fares to match the new entrant’s fare levels, eliminates all or most of its restrictions on discount fares, and greatly expands the availability of discount-fare seats. 136) The incumbent airline often adds flights as well and increases traffic as a result of the wide availability of low fares. The incumbent airline, however, incurs a substantial amount of self-diversion – it sells so many seats at low fares with minimal restrictions that it no longer sells significant numbers of higher fare seats (self-diversion means a reduction in revenues caused by the airline’s own actions, not by its competitor’s actions). As a result, although the incumbent carries many more passengers, its total revenues are well below the revenues realisable through a more moderate response to entry. When the incumbent airline responds to entry by slashing fares and making low discount fares much more available, the new entrant airline usually cannot obtain enough traffic to sustain its service. The readily availability of low fares on the incumbent airline, which offers service features not offered by the new entrant airline and has an established reputation, dries up the traffic available to the entrant. The new entrant exits the market owing to the financial impact, and the incumbent airline then increases its fares and sharply reduces the availability of its lowest discount fares. The entrant’s exit can occur within several months of entry. 137) An incumbent airline, like any firm, would normally prefer to obtain as much revenue as possible for the services it has chosen to provide. The airline would be unlikely to voluntarily reduce its own revenues by charging lower fares than it could have charged unless it intended to keep travellers from booking the entrant airline. 138) The Secretary of the DOT concluded that the investigation into competitive responses by network airlines to entry by a low cost carrier has shown that network airlines can and sometimes do respond to entry with the apparent intent of eliminating or reducing competition. He referred to one airline’s internal documents that indicated its intent to eliminate new competition through fare reductions, a greatly increased availability of low fare seats, and some added capacity. The network airline expected that it would then attract almost all discount fare travellers away from the new entrant and compel its exit. According to the Secretary, the network airline knew that it would thereby reduce its short-term Chapter 3 Page 156 revenues more than was necessary to meet the new competition, but it accepted those losses as the price to pay for regaining its market power in its hub markets. 139) The Secretary of the DOT stated that this kind of competitive response harms consumers over the long term. In the short run the public benefits – fares are much lower and discountfare seats are easily obtained from both airlines. Travellers can enjoy both low fares and the service features offered by the hub airline, such as more frequent flights and more attractive FFP benefits. In the long run, however, the public loses – the new entrant’s competition is eliminated and fares go up to their previous levels or even higher. 140) It was the view of the Secretary of the DOT that a hubbing airline would not need to respond so aggressively if its objective was to maximise its revenues rather than eliminate competition, as a hubbing airline has substantial competitive advantages that should enable it to retain higher-yield traffic due to the fact that airlines compete on many service features, not just price. Some of the many service features of network airlines are: • They operate more frequent services and have an established brand. • They offer more attractive FFPs and TACOs. • Business travellers often choose an airline in order to obtain frequent flyer miles. • Incumbents are likely to have the advantage of a reputation for reliable service, whereas a new entrant would not have such a reputation. 141). • The hub airline’s flow traffic attracted by its network operations will support its service even if it loses some local passengers to an entrant. • The entrant could not capture the flow passengers unless it also operated a hub at the same city. 142) 143) The Secretary of the DOT stated that experience in other markets demonstrated that network airlines could compete with low cost airlines without flooding the market with low fare seats. Network airlines have found ways of coexisting with low fare competitors like the toleration of Southwest’s major presence in local markets has been tolerated by major carriers not competing aggressively for local passengers, but focussing on carrying flow traffic to feed their networks. There are cases where the hubbing airline did not try to deny Southwest a significant share of the market by offering a large number of discount-fare seats at low fares. 144) Chapter 3 Page 157 In addition, the Secretary found examples where network airlines did not invariably respond to entry by low cost airlines other than Southwest by sharply cutting fares and making the low fares available on large numbers of seats. Even an airline as successful as Southwest cannot necessarily expect to obtain large profits from competing with the network airlines in their hub markets, which indicates that network airlines have substantial competitive strengths of their own in competing against a successful low cost carrier. Southwest “deliberately avoids” confrontations with the major airlines. Southwest itself stated that barriers to entry remain high at many concentrated airports because of the competitive advantages of the incumbent carriers that potential new entrants cannot begin to match, and that these barriers to competition are overwhelmingly the result of powerful marketing advantages and tactics used by dominant incumbent carriers to protect their concentrated markets from low cost competitors. 145) The conclusion of the Secretary of the DOT that an incumbent airline can effectively eliminate competition through predatory-type behaviour is consistent with recent economic thinking. He formed the view that while economists for some time viewed predation as an ineffective strategy, they have re-examined the question of predation and concluded that predation is more likely to occur and to be more rational than was thought earlier. He stated that “it is now the consensus view in modern economics that predatory pricing can be a successful and fully rational business strategy. Sound empirical and experimental studies, as well as modern economic theory, have shown that predation is not rare”. 146) The Secretary of the DOT stated that predatory-type behaviour might be effective in the airline industry precisely because of the fact that aircraft are so mobile and can be moved from one route to another. The mobility of aircraft was originally thought to be a guarantee that airline markets would be competitive. However, as shown, airlines incur significant sunk costs in entering a new airport, a factor which can discourage entry. On the other hand, when entry occurs, the incumbent hub airline can easily shift aircraft from other markets to increase capacity in the market served by the new competitor. An airline that dominates a market thus can quickly expand its capacity on a route without making an irretrievable investment, since it can easily re-deploy the aircraft to other markets when the entrant has been forced to exit or reduce service. In addition, the ready availability of fare and Chapter 3 Page 158 availability information on competing airlines through the CRS facilitates an airline’s ability to engage in anti-competitive conduct. The CRSs, moreover, generally sell route-by-route booking data on individual airlines to airlines participating in a system, which enables each airline buying the data to learn how many seats are being sold on its competitors, for each travel agent using the system. 147) As a result, the Secretary of the US DOT stated that the Administration has concluded that the potential for predatory-type behaviour by incumbent airlines is great enough that the Department to implement strategies, such as enforcement action, that will effectively prevent such conduct (and other conduct intended to eliminate or reduce competition). 148 3.8.7 THE DECLINE IN AIRLINE COMPETITION The Secretary of the US DOT stated that there are signs that competition has declined in recent years, even though most markets remain very competitive. The number of routes with competition between airlines having a significant presence in the market has declined. In addition, travellers in some markets have benefited significantly less from deregulation. Inflation-adjusted fares have declined substantially since deregulation in long-haul markets (markets over 750 miles, 1,200 kilometres in length) and in short-haul markets that have low cost carrier service. When adjusted for inflation, average fares in short-haul markets with low cost carrier service have fallen by 36 percent since 1979 and have increased by 26 percent in other short-haul markets over the same period. Passengers in the short-haul markets without low cost carrier service make up almost one fourth of all domestic passengers. 149) The TRB panel also found signs indicating that the US airline industry has become somewhat less competitive in recent years. 150) After the May 1996 ValuJet crash, new entry into the airline industry virtually stopped until the US DOT proposed its enforcement policy. No firm applied for the authority needed to operate scheduled passenger service with jet aircraft in 1997 or 1998 and actually began service (save for National Airlines, which applied after the proposed enforcement policy’s publication). Chapter 3 Page 159 The Secretary of the DOT stated that entry ceased around the time when, according to the low cost airlines, network airlines became much more aggressive in responding to competition by the low cost airlines. Following the publication of the proposed policy, several low cost airlines began operating, including Access Air, Sun Country (Sun Country had been operating only charter service until 1999), and Jet Blue. He was of the opinion that the publication of the proposed policy and the DOJ’s suit against American may have encouraged the renewed interest in entering the industry. The number of passengers in markets with low cost carrier service declined in 1997 for the first time in recent years, but in 1999 both the absolute and relative number of such passengers reached record highs. The Secretary of the DOT suggested that the proposed guidelines of the DOT and the DOJ suit against AA have benefited competition. 151) 3.8.8 MARKET POWER IN AIRLINE MARKETS The Secretary of the DOT concluded that successful past predation could itself operate as an entry and re-entry barrier, particularly where reputation effects are present. As such, the would-be entrant would anticipate that any attempt to enter the market would evoke a predatory response from the incumbent. Anticipating that response, the would-be entrant would decline to enter the particular market. 152) 3.8.9 FREQUENCY OF APPARENT UNFAIR EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT The US DOT claimed to have seen a number of cases where an incumbent airline crafted its response to entry with the apparent goal of eliminating competition, since the response appears to be economically irrational unless it forces the entrant to end or reduce its service. 153) The network airlines contended that there was no systemic problem in the airline industry as in their view such conduct rarely occurs and that there was no need to adopt enforcement standards on airline competition under section 411. The Secretary of the DOT concluded that unfair exclusionary conduct seems to be more common than claimed by network airlines and that the Department would be justified in Chapter 3 Page 160 taking action against competitive responses designed to eliminate competition and create market power, even if incumbent airlines rarely engaged in such conduct. Professor Kahn A also endorsed the approach of the US DOT. The Secretary also stated that if the network airlines are correct in claiming that this type of conduct hardly ever occurs, enforcement action like that the US DOT had proposed would have little impact on the industry and would only have an effect on the network airlines’ scheduling and fare decisions in rare cases. 154) According to the Secretary, the network airlines understated the seriousness of unreasonably aggressive competitive responses for the following reasons: • Driving a new entrant from one market deters entry in other markets (or causes entry to occur on a smaller scale). • The network airlines concluded that potentially exclusionary competitive responses hardly ever occur, but the US DOT identified several such instances. • The DOJ’s complaint against American alleged, on the basis of internal American documents, that American had adopted a strategy of using responses to low cost carrier entry at Dallas Fort Worth (DFW) that would eliminate such competition and that American carried out that strategy against several such airlines. • The low cost airlines have repeatedly maintained that unfair competitive responses by major airlines are a substantial barrier to their growth and success. 155) Levine M stated that “apparent predation attempts have been plentiful”. 156) The findings of the analysis of the US DOT were consistent with the view of Levine M who described the salient features of an incumbent’s predation strategy as follows: • Match, or better yet, beat the new entrant’s lowest fare with a low fare restricted to confine its attractiveness to the leisure-oriented, price-sensitive sector of the market. • Match business-oriented fares and offer extra benefits to retain the loyalties of travel agents and frequent flyers. • Add frequency where possible, to “sandwich” the new entrant’s departures between one’s own departures. Chapter 3 Page 161 • Make sure enough seats are available on your flights in the market to accommodate increases in traffic caused by the fare war. In short, leave no traveller with either a price or a schedule incentive to fly the new entrant. • If the new entrant attempts to lower prices, the incumbent matches the prices of the new entrant, no matter how low the fare. The objective of matching is to subject the new entrant to a prolonged period of operation at low load factors. • This strategy saps the entrant’s working capital while inhibiting trials that would disseminate favourable information about the new entrant. 157) This Administration’s conclusion that predatory-type behaviour occurred often enough in the airline industry to justify Department action on the issue is consistent with the most recent studies and analyses conducted by economists, that believe that predatory behaviour is a successful and rational business strategy that is more common than believed in earlier years. 158) 3.9 THE EFFECT OF A DECLINE IN OVERALL VOLUMES ON AIRLINE NETWORKS 3.9.1 VIABILITY OF THE NETWORK BUSINESS TRAVEL PRICING MODEL OF THE HUB-AND-SPOKE AIRLINES The operation of hub-and-spoke networks is one of the many commercial practices adopted by airlines following deregulation to exploit the economies of scope that exist in the air transport industry as identified in 3.8.3 above and analysed in 4.3 of chapter 4. Some practical aspects are also highlighted in 4.11.5.2 of chapter 4. According to Davidowitch G, the economics of the airline industry have recently undergone a fundamental shift with respect to levels of business travel and the viability of the hub-andspoke model, with the effect that strategic responses will take time to develop and implement. 159) Chapter 3 Page 162 In response to the early development of the discount airline sector the old-line carriers adopted hub-and-spoke systems, discounted fares, FFPs and similar marketing techniques. 160) According to Levine ME, the airlines expanded rapidly during the late 1990s, when the economy of the USA was vibrant and growing. Unions took advantage of the growth to negotiate favourable contracts that raised labour costs in the airline industry to unprecedented levels. In order to afford these higher costs, airlines attempted to raise fares. As leisure travellers do not buy expensive tickets, airlines focused on business travellers booking tickets on short notice, who valued the convenience of frequent service at nearby airports. Levine ME noted that business fares rose almost 50 percent between 1999 and 2001. In addition, walk-up business fares often were 10 times more than leisure fares booked in advance. 161) According to O’Toole K and Field D, size really did matter in the past. In the days of limited competition, the champions were those that could dominate their home markets and take a powerful hold of the distribution chain. Sub-scale competitors were simply “killed or acquired”. This relates to aggressive actions by hub airlines that involved a combination of increase in capacity and lowering of fares in order to eliminate competitors and new entrants. 162) Recently, measures were adopted by the US DOT to prevent such anti-competitive behaviour. This aspect is fully discussed in chapter 7. There was plenty of growth to conceal the worst of any structural flaws in the cost base. In the assessment of Levine ME, this strategy by network carriers of focusing on business travellers for high yield tickets has backfired for the following reasons: • Business travellers looked to travel on leisure fares even if it meant advance purchases and Saturday night stays, and • Business travellers started to use airlines with cheaper fares. 163) O’Toole K and Field D stated that the United Airlines bankruptcy filing added fuel to the doomsayers' predictions of the impending failure of the full-service network model. O’Toole Chapter 3 Page 163 K and Field D concluded, however, that the root cause of the current “malaise” may have more to do with a lack of market focus than with too much “hubbing”. 164) As a result, the discount sector flourished again. SWA grew rapidly and is now the most profitable airline in the industry. Soon other discount airlines appeared which resulted in a quarter of tickets sold in the USA being on a discount airline, compared to less than a tenth four years ago. 165) The terrorist attacks of 11 September 2001 had the following results: • Initially many business travellers stayed home. • When they finally did start to fly again, more alternatives were available than ever before and it was not necessary to pay the exorbitant prices of the late 1990's. Business travellers could fly on a discount airline or find a cheap Internet fare on one of the traditional airlines. • Even when business improved, the old high fare structure did not come back. Business travellers found other airlines that charges much less, even if they had to drive to alternative airports. The implication was that the hub-and-spoke airlines would have to offer more competitive fares to all customers. • The very same hub-and-spoke system that the airlines created in response to deregulation is now being exploited by the discount airlines, which operate on its fringes. According to Levine ME, the established airlines need not abandon the hub-and-spoke system, which has served both airlines and passengers well, but need to operate it more efficiently. In his assessment, airlines have to do the restructuring that they have been putting off for the better part of a decade. This restructuring can be done under the protection of bankruptcy or outside it. But in the assessment of Levine ME, it will succeed only if bankruptcy is a threat, which would mean no more federal loan guarantees. If they can reduce labour, equipment and other costs to more reasonable levels, these airlines will find that the hub-and-spoke system will allow them to prosper. By concentrating their flights at a hub, they can offer more frequent service to more destinations than the discount Chapter 3 Page 164 airlines, which would enable them to offer reasonable fares on many seats by using the Internet or other technologies. Only this kind of restructuring will enable airlines like United, American, Delta and Northwest to run their businesses profitably. 166) According to Levine ME, most airlines have a business model that was created against a background of high traffic and high fares. Following 11 September 2001, he was of the opinion that the overall market had changed substantially and was further of the opinion that the airline industry would have to begin the painful process of restructuring. Levine ME stated that the plight of United Airlines in having its application for state financial aid (in the form of $1.8 billion in federal loan guarantees) turned down by the Air Transportation Stabilisation Board was not unique as its precarious financial situation was shared by all of the large hub-and-spoke airlines that survived deregulation (American, Continental, Delta, Northwest and American Airways (which is already in bankruptcy)) to a greater or lesser degree. In his assessment these airlines are competing for customers with a greatly expanded discount airline sector, and they all have contractual commitments (in terms of labour, fleet and infrastructure) that they can no longer meet. Discount airlines like, SWA, JetBlue, AirTran Airways, American Trans Air, Frontier and Spirit Airlines provide the competitive spur that would ensure that deregulation benefited the public by offering customers more choice by exploiting the fringes of the hub-and-spoke systems. As such, they are forcing the established airlines to become more nimble. 167) 168) In Europe, Ryanair, easyJet, Airline Co, Virgin Express, Buzz are moving more deeply into competing with the flag carriers. 169) 170) Coy P and Zellner W reported that Carty DJ, the Chief Executive of AA had stated that the airline industry's pricing model was badly broken and that “many of our customers feel as though they're being cheated. It's clear that something dramatic needs to be done.” The critical problem was the economics of the carriers' far-flung networks, in which dozens of "spoke" cities are served through a handful of "hub" airports. In good times, hubs enable the airlines to provide frequent service to many cities with short layovers. But the hub-and-spoke Chapter 3 Page 165 networks of big carriers are enormously expensive to run and business travellers seem no longer willing to pay the high-ticket prices that make them viable. 171) According to Belobaba PP, it's very difficult to incrementally dismantle a hub. The risk for hub airlines is that if they cut back too much, they will surrender the one advantage (frequency of service) they have over discount point-to-point carriers, such as SWA. 172) The hub-and-spoke system feeds a carrier's passengers from its smaller markets into larger ones, from which it operates banks of flights to more lucrative destinations. McCartney S stated that until lately, hubs generated enough revenue to make up for the high cost of staffing multiple gates and of keeping aircraft and baggage handlers there idle between waves of connecting flights. 173) The blanket coverage of a large network airline is aimed at minimising layover times, by scheduling lots of flights to arrive and depart within narrow windows of time called “banks”. This requires leasing many gates and having lots of ground crew, who are idle between different arriving and departing banks of flights. In addition, aircraft and their expensive flight crews spend more time on the ground than point-to-point crews do because they have to wait for connecting flights. Coy P and Zellner W stated that hub airlines' labour costs would not seem so high if they got more hours of useful work out of their employees. The necessity of charging high fares makes hub carriers vulnerable to attack from both above and below. Some high-paid business travellers are turning to private jets, while the budgetconscious are switching to low cost airlines, including point-to-point carriers. Coy P and Zellner W observed that hubbing, which was a competitive advantage in the '90s, is becoming a competitive disadvantage, but also stated that hub-and-spoke systems will never disappear entirely, because only they can provide frequent flights to many cities with short layovers. In order to save money, hubbing airlines were likely to spread their flights out instead of concentrating them in banks, thus lengthening layovers. In the longer run, airlines will merge and close hubs. Coy P and Zellner W reported that Crandall R, the ex-chief of AA, who created some of the first hubs stated that “there will be less service, and it will be less convenient to travel" in future as airlines would schedule flights more evenly, cutting congestion by building in longer layovers. 174) Chapter 3 Page 166 According to Stieghorst T, the plunge in demand after September 11 exposed the high level of fixed costs of the hub system, which are hard to scale back rapidly. A legacy of higher labour costs compounds the problem. As long as the big carriers kept lucrative business flyers, however, they could rationalise losing some leisure customers. The big carriers offset cheap vacation (leisure) fares by hiking business fares, on the theory that corporations would absorb the difference as a cost of doing business. But when the economy stalled and full-fare tickets remained, 10 times the cost of more restricted ones, business flyers balked and passengers were lost to low cost carriers. Neither business nor leisure fares could be raised and cost cutting risked labour unrest, which no mainline carrier seemed eager to add to its list of troubles. Losses are however forcing them to respond. AA is modifying its hub-and-spoke system to make flights less bunched together in its Chicago and Dallas hubs. For passengers it means more waiting between flights, but American will improve its efficiency. 175) In summary, the effects of the terrorist attacks of 11 September 2001 on the network business travel pricing model were as follows: • The network business travel-pricing model was created against a background of high traffic and high fares. 176) • The network business travel pricing model exploited network size for scope advantages and enabled customers to be locked in by means of artificial switching costs. Hub airlines may have over-expanded in attempting to gain scope advantages. 177) • Circumstances changed in that growth is no longer assured and corporate clients are cutting back on travel costs. 178) • Corporate business flyers are becoming price sensitive and getting smarter in identifying lower cost flights. More companies are requiring employees to travel on restricted airfares to save on corporate travel costs (less expensive but less flexible). 179) 180) • The Web and Internet have put the distribution chain beyond CRS control in certain countries. Internet websites provide powerful tools for finding and taking advantage of deeply discounted fares (for travellers, travel agents and corporate travel managers). 181) 182) • The big airlines (full-service retailers of flights) have massive fixed costs that are not easy to scale back. They built expensive hub-and-spoke route systems and signed Chapter 3 Page 167 costly labour contracts that they had hoped to finance by charging high-margin business fares. 183) • There appears to be an optimum size for network airlines beyond which the financial risk of a downturn in the economy needs to be managed. • Airlines need to be acutely focused on just what they are selling. 184) • Financial difficulties are shared by all of the large hub-and-spoke airlines that survived deregulation as a result of the difficulties of scaling down operations. 185) 3.9.2 NEW LOW COST CARRIER CHARACTERISTICS Low cost carriers enjoyed tremendous growth while financial difficulties were experienced by full-service network airlines. Some advantages that low cost carriers have over fullservice network airlines are: • Businesses are acutely focused on just what they are selling. • Fast-paced schedules with minimal downtime between flights. 186) • Consumers have freer access to fare-price information. Web sites list all the fares available between any two airports. 187) • Low cost carriers have younger fleets, which require less maintenance. 188) • Low cost carriers have younger labour forces that aren't tied to complicated, inefficient labour contracts. Labour costs at most of the discount airlines are lower than the bigger, unionised competitors. 189) • Low cost carriers stick to one model of aircraft thus minimising maintenance, operating and training costs and spare parts. This also simplifies processes. 190) 191) • Selective route structures that minimise competition. 192) • Instead of having aircraft and crews sit around and wait for passengers at hub airports, low cost carriers maintain fast-paced schedules with minimal downtime between flights. 193) • Focus on going after the leisure traveller. Most of the low cost airlines left the majority of business travellers to the major airlines. This requires a simple marketing plan and lower marketing costs. 194) • Low cost carriers had difficulties to obtain access to travel agents or corporate travel departments but are now easy to find on the Internet. 195) Chapter 3 Page 168 • Downscaling hub-and-spoke systems to make flights less bunched together which would mean more waiting between flights for passengers at hubs to improve efficiency in comparison to high frequency shuttle services of low cost carriers. 196) 3.9.3 RESPONSES OF HUB AIRLINES TO COMPETITION BY LOWCOST CARRIERS The responses of hub airlines (as identified in 3.8.3 above and analysed in 4.3 of chapter 4) in the changed circumstances identified in 3.9.1 above, to competition by low cost airlines in the USA and in Europe were to: • Selectively match fares, (but now the hub airlines are confronted with low fare competition on about three quarters of their routes). 197) • Set up copycat subsidiaries to attract price-sensitive passengers (but without lowenough costs, those carriers have failed). 198) • Quote prices on a flight-by-flight basis based on timing of departure (and not pricing). 199) • Reduce the six or seven different types of aircraft that are used in operations. 200) • Reduce capacity by downsizing aircraft and eliminating unprofitable flights and routes, retiring older aircraft, deferring major new purchases. 201) • Obtain a major airline partner. 202) • Seek major concessions from unions and management. 203) • Fundamentally reform the pricing structure in order to stay competitive in this environment. 204) • Seek state aid and upon refusal seek bankruptcy protection under Chapter 11. 205) • Focus on productivity and efficiency. 206) • Sell assets and raise cash. 207) According to Grossman D, downsizing to smaller jets may eliminate empty seats and reduce operating costs but that strategy can backfire too as much of the airline industry's profit comes from last-minute business travellers who pay full fare. Selling out all a particular flight’s seats in advance and losing last minute, full-fare business travellers would leave a “lot of money on the table for competitors with larger jets to grab". 208) Chapter 3 Page 169 3.9.4 SUMMARY AND IMPLICATIONS FOR SOUTH AFRICA It is evident that the airline industry has undergone a fundamental shift with respect to levels of business travel and the viability of the hub-and-spoke model in the USA and Europe. Higher cost airlines attempted to raise fares relying on marketing techniques which gave them a powerful hold of the distribution chain. Some examples were FFPs, corporate discount agreements and TACOs and discriminatory pricing practice utilising CRS applications. As leisure travellers do not buy expensive tickets, airlines focused on business travellers booking tickets on short notice, who value the convenience of frequent service at nearby airports. A number of factors contributed to changed circumstances that affected the network model, inter alia: • Economic conditions forced customers that travel for business reasons to seek cheaper alternatives. This need to economise became more important than the lock-in (binding) effect of a number of the marketing techniques referred to above. • A serious drop in volumes of passengers making use of air travel highlighted the difficulty network airlines experience in reducing costs. This resulted in extreme financial difficulties for the large network airlines. • New entrant airlines had to focus on what exactly the product comprises that is offered. • A framework of prevention of anti-competitive behaviour and the abuse of dominance prevented larger airlines from targeted action against new low cost carriers especially with regard to a combination of pricing and capacity actions. • CRS codes of conduct and Internet applications made it possible to restrict and bypass CRS practices that were discriminatory against smaller airlines and favoured large airlines. Chapter 3 Page 170 With regard to South Africa, the writer is of the opinion that South Africa may have been sheltered from the severity of such market factors in the USA and Europe for the following reasons: • The downturn in passenger volumes was not as severe as in the USA and Europe while the number of international visitors to South Africa increased and the Rand/US Dollar exchange rate improved substantially. • SAA is a fully owned state airline. • No CRS code of conduct has been implemented and SAA controls the dominant CRS system. • The exclusionary effect of marketing techniques, which provide a powerful hold on the distribution chain in this industry, has not been eroded substantially. • No effective framework of prevention of anti-competitive behaviour exists and the abuse of dominance cases seem to be bogged down by review procedures. As a result, the dominant airline is not effectively prevented from targeted action against new low cost carriers, especially with regard to a combination of pricing and capacity actions. As a result, due regard should be had to on the extremity of these developments in the USA and Europe as these factors will eventually affect competition in South Africa. The most important lesson is that the size of a network airline would have to managed very carefully. This would be in contrast to a focus is based on maximisation of a dominant airline’s size through the marketing techniques that were referred to above and that offer scope advantages. Overall, the writer recommends the following: • The government should ensure that the size of operations of SAA is limited in competitive markets and its increases in capacity is not excessive in relation to the growth expectations in the market, which might lead to difficulties in adjusting in periods of an overall market decline. In this regard, there is a risk of the continued existence of one large dominant network airline in circumstances of sudden decline in overall traffic volumes, as has been seen in the case of Sabena, Swissair and United Airlines. It is evident that there is an optimum limit to the size of an airline as is the case in other industries. • The government should implement an adequate framework to prevent anticompetitive behaviour and prevent the abuse of dominance. In addition, measures Chapter 3 Page 171 should be introduced that would ensure that the process of remedial intervention would not be bogged down by review procedures. 3.10 DEVELOPMENTS RELATING TO AIR FARES 3.10.1 INTRODUCTION The findings of the Committee for a Study of Competition in the US airline industry of the Transportation Research Board of the National Academy of Sciences (TRB) with regard to general economic development and trends relating to fares and airline competition were published in July 1999 as Special Report 255 Entry and competition in the United States airline industry: issues and opportunities. The trends in fares charged by airlines are discussed in this chapter, and include • Price (fare) dispersion in the airline industry. • Ramsey pricing within the airline industry. • Fare restrictions as a means of differential pricing. • Trends in fare dispersion. • Using yield management systems to discriminate between prices and allocate capacity. 209) The TRB found that dominant airlines had gained too much market power and were exploiting it by raising fares well above the cost of service. Although the industry’s average fares declined during the1990s, the widening in the range of fares became a more prominent issue. Fares varied greatly by market and even among individual travellers seated side-byside on the same flights. As travel demand recovered in the early 1990s, airlines began experimenting with higher fares and new low cost airlines emerged. Many of these start up carriers used the equipment and labour shed by the large airlines during the recession and earlier failures. However, in 1996, the highly publicised crash of a ValuJet airliner damaged the reputation of low cost carriers, contributing to the financial failure of some and discouraging start-ups in general. 210) The TRB observed that even before the ValuJet crash, some start-up airlines had complained about what they perceived as intentionally injurious, or “predatory,” tactics by incumbents. Chapter 3 Page 172 By the mid-1990s, alarm over the major airlines’ financial condition was superseded by concern that financially strengthened incumbents were actively seeking the demise of startups and systematically suppressing competition. Meanwhile, public discontent with airline service and pricing practices particularly the higher fares charged to business passengers travelling on unrestricted tickets, was rising. Enjoying dramatic growth in travel demand, the airlines were increasingly viewed as being uninterested in their main customers. Despite these concerns, the TRB stated that consumers continued to benefit overall from a deregulated industry, which is still characterised by significant price competition, including frequent "fare wars" that attract many bargain-seeking travellers. Adjusted for inflation, it found that average fares decreased 25 percent from 1990 to 1998. However, the industry’s operating costs, as well as fares, were largely stable after the middle of the decade, perhaps drifting slightly upward. Most of the reductions in fares during the 1990s occurred early in the decade. Since 1995, trends have been relatively flat. 211) 3.10.2 COMPARISON OF THE CHANGES IN AVERAGE FARES WITH CHANGES IN UNDERLYING PRODUCTION COSTS The US DOTs Standard Industry Fare Level (SIFL) depicts changes in airline operating costs on a seat-mile basis. Changes in the SIFL indicated that much of the overall decline in average fares (or yield) during the 1990s was actually caused by declining jet fuel costs. The trends also indicated that fare levels did not increase in relation to costs, which suggested that the gains from deregulation have not been eroding over time. The competitive pressures brought about by deregulation have compelled cost reductions, which were regarded as further evidence of the continuing benefits of deregulation. As the decade of the 1990s progressed, airlines refined their ability to charge different fares to different groups of travellers. This widened the spread in fares paid. Unable to take advantage of the heavily restricted low-price tickets, time-sensitive business travellers increasingly expressed concern that the fares they were being charged were far above the cost of providing the service in an efficient manner. 212) As in most other studies in the USA, reference was often made to “average fares,” and average fare data are used in many of the data analyses. The airlines, however, served two distinct types of customers - business and leisure travellers. Airlines have become skilled at Chapter 3 Page 173 distinguishing these passengers and charging them widely differing fares by imposing purchase restrictions. As a result, in addition to average fares, actual fares paid, sorted by restriction type, would be meaningful in examining trends in fares. It was not apparent for the TRB, how such data could be gathered and analysed in a meaningful way, because “restricted” or “discounted” fares were terms that could not easily or uniformly be defined. 213) The TRB concluded, however, that, although imperfect, in an industry in which buyers are paying widely differing prices, market averages still remain the most informative and reliable price measure available when considering trends in fares. 214) 3.10.3 PRICE (FARE) DISPERSION IN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY Fare dispersion has grown since deregulation. According to the TRB, there were two general reasons why buyers, in any industry, may be charged different prices for products that appear to be the same or nearly the same for reasons that are “both efficiency-and welfareenhancing.“ These were: • That the direct costs of supplying different prices to different groups of customers are in fact different, such as the costs associated with delivering the product to the point of sale. • That costs are incurred in circumstances in which, while the products and costs of supplying them are effectively similar significant economies of scale and scope were operating in the supply of the different airline products. When a firm sells the same product or almost identical products at different prices to different buyers (or at different mark-ups on marginal cost), price discrimination is said to have occurred. Under the latter circumstance, prices set uniformly at their marginal costs would not recover the total costs of supplying them, including fixed and overhead expenses, and it becomes necessary to charge buyers collectively prices in excess of incremental cost if the products are to continue to be supplied. In this situation, if the seller can take advantage of the fact that buyers attach widely different values to the same product and segment buyers on the basis of their different product valuations, an airline can charge prices that are above marginal cost to those who are least sensitive to price. The seller may then generate sufficient revenue to provide all the different Chapter 3 Page 174 products. Excessive overall price exploitation would be avoided if effective competition is at a sufficient level. 215) The major airlines claimed that fare differentials (that is, variations in fares between business and leisure travellers) are caused in large measure by direct differences in cost, such as those associated with flying during peak or congested periods. Unfortunately, the TRB noted that too little empirical evidence was submitted by the airlines to support this main assertion. The TRB considered the possibility that too many common or shared costs may exist in the airline industry, making the allocation of cost among different classes of services arbitrary. 216) 3.10.4 RAMSEY PRICING WITHIN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY The TRB stated that generally economists have maintained that prices set at a level equal to the marginal costs of producing goods or services are optimal (that is, welfare maximising). Problems can arise, however, if marginal costs are less than average costs at levels of output that would prevail if prices had been set uniformly to all buyers. In this situation the revenue raised by marginal cost pricing will not cover total costs and the producer will not be able to continue to provide the product as it will not be economic to replace equipment and other capital in the long term. The loss of the product may create welfare losses, particularly among those consumers who valued it highly. 217) A well-known theorem in economics, known as Ramsey pricing (named after one of its earliest proponents), holds that the welfare losses created by deviating from marginal cost pricing are minimised if the buyers with inelastic demands are charged the highest prices or mark-ups above the marginal cost. Including the overhead, fixed, and other costs that comprise total costs (that are otherwise excluded from marginal costs) in the prices charged these buyers with inelastic demand results in the least deviation of consumption patterns from the patterns that would be achieved if uniform prices were set at marginal cost. 218) The TRB stated that something akin to Ramsey pricing might be practised in the airline industry. Leisure travellers who are sensitive to price (price-elastic) are charged fares roughly equal to the marginal cost of serving them, but which are apparently insufficient in the aggregate to cover the full cost of maintaining the airline networks as they are now Chapter 3 Page 175 constituted. US airlines must cover their total costs by competing for capital in private financial markets. As Ramsey pricing would suggest, they apparently cover any shortfall in revenues from leisure travellers by charging higher prices, or whatever the traffic will bear, to price-inelastic business travellers. In the process, moreover, the airlines may have been able to finance a more extensive network than would have been possible otherwise. 219) The TRB also stated that those who make the extra contributions are seldom content with this role. Some may believe they are being held captive to their inelastic demands as a result of various actions taken by the airlines, such as possible exclusionary behaviour to hold back new entrants or technologies such as smaller, “regional” jets. A traditional role of economic regulation, particularly in telecommunications and transportation, has been to smooth out these surcharges by making them uniform over broad classes of customers, and in the process making them more politically acceptable. This was usually achieved, with some sacrifice in welfare (by attenuating the mark-ups on the most inelastic buyers while increasing them on buyers who are somewhat more sensitive to price). The TRB was of the opinion that the politically acceptable solution usually led to greater deviation in consumption patterns (from the marginal cost optimum) than would a strict Ramsey pricing solution. 220) The TRB stated that, while “a Ramsey pricing scheme can be beneficial in the short-term, it may be less desirable in the long-term. The Ramsey pricing optimum is strictly static in character, unless prices adjust quickly or producers have considerable foresight. Ramsey pricing optimality will be undermined by any changes in the demand elasticity and other conditions on which it is defined. Indeed, Ramsey pricing creates its own strong incentives for change. Buyers paying the highest prices, or mark-ups, have incentives to seek alternatives to the high-priced service. Over time, they will be increasingly successful in finding such alternatives, or in otherwise adjusting their circumstances to become less reliant on the product, thus making much of the existing capacity redundant for some period of time or until industry capacity can be properly adjusted. New technology and other changes and alternatives (including new competitors) that undermine an established Ramsey pricing pattern will be unwelcome to incumbent producers”. The TRB was of the view that in the long term, sustaining such a pricing scheme will usually require government regulation or monopoly power to bar entry and producers pricing under a Ramsey pricing scheme would be likely to be hostile to change, even if the change would be otherwise beneficial to consumers. The Committee’s view was that some of the most counterproductive experiences Chapter 3 Page 176 with industry economic regulation have been associated with regulatory regimes to maintain highly discriminatory pricing by delaying technological changes that would otherwise have been desirable. As such, they were of the opinion that any price discrimination should sustain itself only if tested by open entry and competition. 221) The TRB stated that “evidence of growing fare dispersion has not been supported by evidence of growing cost dispersion”. Nevertheless a very substantial portion of the fare differences is explicable in terms of the direct costs of the two kinds of services. The economies gained from density (e.g., denser routes permit larger planes, with correspondingly lower costs per seat mile) suggest that fares will typically be lower in dense markets than in thin ones. Differing constraints on airport and airway capacity, including terminal charges, can also contribute to differentials in costs, and therefore variations in fares across markets. Likewise, fares paid by travellers in the same markets can vary widely as a result of differences in the cost of travelling at different times of the day and week. One would, for instance, expect higher fares for travel during peak times when demand is greatest and resources are tight. Travellers booking early are less costly to serve than travellers booking much later, as holding unsold seats in anticipation of late-booking travellers increases the risk that the seat will fly empty. Business travellers pay higher fares in part because they tend to be late bookers, whereas leisure travellers, who pay the lowest fares, tend to be early bookers. When demand for seats is high, the cost of holding a seat empty in anticipation of late-booking or “walk-up” travellers, that is, the opportunity cost incurred if the seat is not eventually sold, may be high. This cost may be reflected in higher fares for travellers who book late or make last-minute itinerary changes. 222) The TRB observed that much of the spread in airline fares may be explained by cost differences, but not all the spread can be so explained, and some is the result of price discrimination. It noted that airlines have long been able to sort travellers according to their relative price elasticity by imposing various ticket restrictions. The TRB concluded that the general ability of airlines to price discriminate might be advantageous to travellers on balance, at least in the short run. The argument that some price discrimination in the airline industry can be desirable rests to a large degree on the recognition that the type of product demanded by schedule-sensitive business travellers differs significantly from the product demanded by price-sensitive leisure travellers. On short-haul flights, the difference in preferences between the two kinds of travellers may be the greatest. Leisure travellers in Chapter 3 Page 177 these markets are especially sensitive to price owing to the substitutability of driving as a travel option. Flight frequency may be especially important to business travellers, since saving relatively small amounts of time is, after all, one of the main reasons for their decision to fly (rather than drive) in the first place. By being able to identify leisure travellers through ticket restrictions, the price-discriminating airline can offer discounted fares to fill unsold seats on flights that might otherwise fly partially empty, but at the same time not permit business travellers to routinely take advantage of these lower fares. The TRB were of the opinion that should an airline not have the ability to restrict access to low fare tickets by time-sensitive travellers, the airline might not be able to cover the total cost of providing the frequent and extensive service. Where airline operations entail large economies of both scale and scope (and thus, declining average costs), as in hubs (where the number of routes that can be served from the hub increases disproportionately with an increase in the number of scheduled flights) it is possible that fares set uniformly at marginal cost would generate insufficient revenue to recover total costs, necessitating discriminatory pricing if the hub airline is to maintain the service. Price discrimination allows carriers to cover both the operating and capital costs of providing the schedule-intensive service desired by business travellers, while filling empty seats with leisure travellers whose low fares at least cover their incremental, or marginal, cost. 223) The possibility that airlines have become too skilled at identifying price-inelastic travellers and charge them excessive fares, above the level necessary to efficiently provide the service, can be identified if the price discriminating airline is reaping monopoly profits (excessive returns on capital). Such determinations are difficult, involving projections of airline profits and the effects of the business cycle. A protection against such exploitation is free entry. Where entry is not artificially impeded, competing services will ensure that the fares charged to price-inelastic travellers are, in the long-run, reflective of the full (or stand-alone) cost of efficiently providing the type of service desired. 224) Some uniformly low cost carriers, such as SWA, have discovered that business travellers are not completely insensitive to price and are sometimes willing to accept fewer schedule options in return for substantial fare reductions. In dense markets where airlines charge excessive fares to price-inelastic travellers, competition from non-network, point-to-point, and low cost airlines can be expected, especially in the light of the high overhead and fixed costs associated with creating a brand new, competing hub-and-spoke system. As a result, Chapter 3 Page 178 new low fare services tend to focus on dense markets only, where point-to-point service can be economical. Airline service in many thinner markets (often important to business travellers) generally remains the domain of the larger carriers with their larger (and higher fixed cost) networks. The introduction of smaller regional jets, and other new technologies, may, however, change this situation. 225) 3.10.5 FARE RESTRICTIONS AS A MEANS OF DIFFERENTIAL PRICING Before deregulation, airlines concentrated on business travellers. Unscheduled charter service was permitted for some low fare travel (e.g., tour packages), but in general, the pricesensitive market was neglected. But by the mid-1960s, regulated airlines were increasing their use of discount economy fares to attract more leisure passengers to fill seats on their new larger-capacity jet aircraft. Senior citizens, students, and relatives of travellers flying on full fares were offered discounts of up to 25 percent. Using such differential methods of pricing, airlines could identify and attract price-sensitive traffic without marking down the fares charged to regular business travellers. The airlines maintained, and the CAB regulators presumed, that such discriminatory pricing was needed to ensure the long-run profitability of the service. Though seldom able to purchase the discounted fares, business travellers were thought to have benefited owing to the more frequent flights that were available from these larger aircraft. 226) Some economists predicted that deregulation would diminish airlines’ ability to differentiate among types of travellers, because of a general belief that monopoly power (or regulatory protection) was required for discrimination and a lack of understanding of the economies of scale and scope that would come to characterise a post-deregulation industry. According to this view, new and incumbent airlines would tailor their services to particular kinds of travellers. For example, single-class, service-intensive airlines would cater to business travellers by providing more spacious seating, frequent departure times, and generous inflight amenities, but charging uniformly high fares to cover the cost of premium service. Meanwhile, “no-frills” airlines would emerge, offering off-peak, low fare services for mostly leisure passengers. Under these scenarios, the variation in fares paid by travellers seated sideby side on the same flight would be small. 227) Chapter 3 Page 179 Although some new single-class carriers did emerge after deregulation, the incumbent airlines quickly realised that they could efficiently serve both business and leisure travellers on the same flights. Through hub-and-spoke networks and the economies of consolidating traffic at central hub airports, airlines could increase the number of scheduled flights from previous point-to-point schedules. The large increase in flight destinations and frequencies (i.e. the scope economies) were a boon to business travellers, particularly those travelling to cities with hub airports. Hub cities such as Charlotte, Cincinnati, and Detroit have experienced a 50 percent or more increase in scheduled jet departures since 1985. 228) Airlines also recognises that leisure travellers - self-identified by their willingness to accept booking restrictions - could be accommodated on many of the same flights as time-sensitive travellers. Seats that otherwise would fly empty could be sold at a significant discount, yet still cover incremental, or marginal, costs. Start-up airlines focusing on leisure traffic - but unable to attract business travellers seeking frequent and convenient flights to numerous points - were at a significant disadvantage. Many failed within the first few years after deregulation. Moreover, it soon became evident that certain service amenities could be offered selectively to high-fare business travellers. These included accrual of free vacation trips, access to airport club lounges, upgrades to first class, and special boarding privileges. 229) Since deregulation, airlines have fine-tuned their fares using a complex combination of purchase terms such as Saturday-night stay-over restrictions, advance purchase requirements, and penalties for cancellations and exchanges. Yield management practices in which airlines reassess on a flight-by-flight basis how many seats are to be offered at a discount, by how much, and when have proliferated and become more sophisticated with experience and advances in information technology. At any one time, an airline may be offering a dozen or more different economy fares on a given flight. FFPs, now offered by nearly all airlines; also identify the most loyal customers who generally are the most price-inelastic. These travellers receive additional bonus miles and other benefits, particularly when purchasing high-fare tickets. Airport security requirements that travellers must present personal identification before boarding have also enhanced the ability of airlines to price discriminate, as low fare travellers cannot resell their heavily restricted advance-purchase tickets (e.g. through intermediaries) to late-booking travellers, who must then pay the higher fares. 230) Chapter 3 Page 180 3.10.6 TRENDS IN FARE DISPERSION The TRB compared the median fare paid by passengers in short, medium, and long haul markets in the USA for 1992, 1995, and 1998 in order to gauge more recent trends in fare dispersion. The median fare, declined by about 15 to 20 percent over this 6-year period in three aggregate market groupings, based on market distance. The lowest fares (that is, the 10th percentile fares) fell by about 5 percent in real terms. The higher fare travellers (the 90th percentile), however, were paying 5 to 25 percent more at the end of the period. It is also evident that these travellers are paying fares much higher than the median, at least in comparison with earlier periods (1995 and 1992). 231) Travellers who paid the highest fares in 1992 paid 2 to 2,1 times the median fare. In 1998, these high-fare travellers paid 2,7 to 2,9 times the median. The highest fares have risen in real terms and the medians have declined. The top-fare travellers (95th percentile and above) accounted for 17 to 18 percent of airline revenue in 1998, compared with 8 to 13 percent in 1992. 232) Although Southwest charges different fares to travellers based on certain demand and cost characteristics, by offering discounts for advance purchases it does not vary fares to the same extent as most other large airlines. High fare travellers (90th percentile) on short-haul Southwest flights pay about twice the median fare for all Southwest passengers in those markets. By contrast, high-fare travellers paid three times the median on other larger incumbent carriers (American, Continental, Delta, Northwest, TWA, United, and AA) examined collectively. A marked difference in the fare structure of two carriers of similar size and scope (SWA and AA) was identified. While most short-haul travellers on SWA pay fares close to the average, the differential between low and high fare travellers on American Airways was much greater. 233) A more precise means of measuring trends in fare dispersion is to use the Gini coefficient, which encompasses the entire distribution of fares, rather than specific percentiles. A Gini coefficient of zero indicates that all fares are the same; as it moves closer to 1, the fare distribution is more dispersed. Studies done by the Committee indicated that the Gini coefficients are much higher today than in 1978, when the CAB limited the amount of fare variation generally and on individual routes. 234) A comparison of 1990 and 1998 levels Chapter 3 Page 181 shows that the Gini coefficient has not changed significantly. Although there was a move upward from 1995 to 1997, these data do not, by themselves, offer evidence of airlines' enjoying greater ability to price discriminate during the 1990s. 235) 3.10.7 THE USE OF YIELD MANAGEMENT AS A MEANS OF DISCRIMINATING ON PRICE Yield management (identified in 3.8.2 above) has enabled the airlines, especially the network airlines, to develop complex fare structures designed to maximise revenues on each flight through price discrimination. Airlines try to sell as many seats as possible at the highest fares, those charged for unrestricted travel, and as few seats as possible at the lowest discount fares. Passengers paying the highest fares obtain the advantages of flexibility and last-minute access to seats. Passengers can book seats just before the flight, change their reservation without penalty, and obtain a full refund if they do not use the booking. Passengers travelling on most discount fares, in contrast, typically have to book seats several days or more before the flight, have to pay in advance for their seats, cannot change a reservation without paying a penalty, and cannot obtain a cash refund if they cancel their trip. Although business travellers can use some discount fares, the cheapest discount fares frequently have a Saturday night stay requirement to discourage business travellers from using them. To save seats for passengers willing to pay for unrestricted fares bought shortly or immediately before the flight, airlines limit the number of seats made available at the lower fare levels. 236) 237) According to Levine ME, unlike the low cost airlines, the network airlines have relatively little interest in attracting travellers who insist on paying low fares for air travel, even though the network airlines do sell many discount-fare seats. Network airlines structured their operations so as to attract travellers willing to pay more for better and more frequent service. If an airline charges higher fares to those travellers, it may be able “to generate sufficient revenue to provide the product, but no more than that if competition is effective”. 238) The airlines’ yield management systems mean that passengers on the same flight will have paid different fares, depending on how far in advance they made their booking and how many restrictions they were willing to accept in return for a lower fare. No airline has been able to maintain a simple fare structure. The discrimination in fares also reflects the willingness of business travellers, but not leisure travellers, to pay for frequent and convenient flights. 239) Low cost airlines, however, have less complex fare structures than the network airlines. 240) Chapter 3 Page 182 Although network airlines serving a market allocate different numbers of seats to each fare level, they tend to charge similar amounts for each type of fare offered in a market (for example, 21-day advance-purchase fares and unrestricted economy fares). Each network airline usually matches the fare levels offered by its network competitors in a market, although not necessarily the number of seats made available at each fare. 241) An airline that has a competitive advantage in a non-stop market will be able to sell more seats at unrestricted fares and so can afford to make fewer seats available for discount fare passengers. A hubbing carrier is able to offer a service advantage relative to a non-hubbing carrier that permits it to attract a relatively larger portion of time-sensitive (primarily business) travellers, serving to raise its average yield. Even if both airlines serving a route have a hub at one of the endpoints, the airline with a competitive advantage can obtain significantly higher yields. As a result, even if two airlines charge the same fares in the same non-stop markets, one airline can obtain higher average fares owing to the fact that it has a better mix of traffic. 242) 3.10.8 OTHER FACTORS CONTRIBUTING TO FARE DISPERSION The TRB stated that the airline industry has been prone to wide cyclical swings. Excess capacity has been a recurrent problem for the industry during recessions and shortly afterwards. Excess seat capacity has declined during the decade, as indicated by average load factors, which rose from 60 percent in 1990 to nearly 70 percent in 1998. Low load factors early in the decade reflect the drop-off in demand during the 1990 to 1991 recession, coupled with expanded capacity. More recently, higher load factors reflect an industry with high demand and intensive use of capacity. In the past (notably in the early 1990s) whenever failing airlines attempted to generate revenues from underused capacity by sharply lowering fares, other airlines followed suit by matching their fares. The resulting fare wars benefited travellers in the short term. However in order for well-run private airlines to survive and prosper, fares must eventually rise to levels sufficient to recover long-term costs and keep capital in the industry. Incumbent carriers experienced large losses during the recession of the early 1990s, but have since experienced positive operating profits, often at record levels. 243) Chapter 3 Page 183 The TRB concluded that the increases in unrestricted fares observed in recent years have been at least partly justified as a means of restoring the industry’s total returns after the large losses it suffered in the early 1990s. 244) As a result, while observed increases in the fares charged price-inelastic travellers may be a manifestation of airlines exercising their market power, the extent to which these fare increases have been excessive is unclear; that is, the extent to which increases have reflected the exploitation of this market power. The TRB in the USA stated that the only sure check against such exploitation is to ensure that opportunities for competitive entry are made available and not impeded. 245) From the conclusions of the TRB in the USA it would appear, however, that the only sure check against exploitation is to ensure that opportunities for competition exist. In the absence of such fare analysis in the domestic market in South Africa, the focus should be on the promotion of competition to serve as an automatic check against the exploitation of passengers. Further study would be necessary in South Africa to identify the overall trends with regard to fares and yield of air travel in South Africa as well as the determination of the factors that influence such trends. 3.11 THE EFFECT OF PRICE DISCRIMINATION ON ECONOMIC WELFARE OF CONSUMERS IN THE DOMESTIC AIRLINE SERVICES 3.11.1 INTRODUCTION According to the NTFAC it is well known that the airline industry has been practising price discrimination for many years. Price discrimination implies that firms are charging different prices to different customers, and that the price difference cannot be explained by cost differences. 246) Chapter 3 Page 184 The following types of price discrimination practices are practiced in the airline industry according to the NTFAC: • Versioning One can buy an expensive, flexible ticket, which can be changed or even cancelled without costs. Or one can buy a cheaper ticket, with more or less severe restrictions: Saturday night stay-over, advance-purchase, etc. These different versions are, in principle, all available to each and every passenger. • Corporate discount schemes Large customers use their buying power to obtain special fare contracts with an airline, whereby a certain discount is given on every ticket bought. • FFPs The bonus points earned by frequent flyers can later be exchanged for extra flights, hotel visits, car rental, etc. 247) The NTFAC also identified three different degrees of price discrimination: • First degree of price discrimination The seller charges a different price for each unit, so that the price of each unit equals maximum willingness to pay. • Second degree of price discrimination Each consumer faces the same price schedule, but the schedule involves different prices for different amounts of the good purchased. • Third degree of price discrimination Different consumers are charged different prices, but each consumer pays a constant price for each unit of the good bought. 248) 3.11.2 VERSIONING According to the NTFAC, versioning implies that the same price schedule is available to all consumers. The consumers can choose to buy an expensive, high quality version or a cheap, low quality version. Technically, this was regarded by the NTFAC as an example of second degree price discrimination as the consumers pay different prices for different amounts of a different quality of the good purchased. 249) Chapter 3 Page 185 Versioning usually implies that one version of the product is deliberately made less attractive. The consumer with a low willingness to pay is offered this inferior version, while a full quality version remains available to those with a high willingness to pay. 250) The inferior version must be sufficiently unattractive to the customers with a high willingness to pay, so that they choose to adhere to rules applicable to the superior quality version. Otherwise the seller will only be able to charge the same low price to (almost) every customer. Typically, an airline would offer the leisure traveller a “damaged” or inflexible ticket (that has more restrictions or penalties as part of the conditions of sale or use) in order to make the inexpensive version unattractive to the less price elastic business traveller segment. 251) In practice, airlines charge different travellers different prices depending on their demand characteristics: • Higher prices are charged to those travellers with more inelastic demand and lower prices to those travellers with a more elastic demand. The ability to discriminate in pricing depends on an airline's having market power. • Prices based on demand characteristics rather than on the cost of providing the products are characteristic of a market in which the seller has a degree of market power. • Airlines offer different fares on a given flight, attaching restrictions or conditions of travel to some fares and, most importantly, offering only a limited number of seats in some fare categories. 252) Yield management makes it possible for airlines to charge different travellers different prices, depending on their demand characteristics. Using computerised yield management systems, airlines can do the following: • Offer seats at multiple prices with varying conditions or restrictions. • Manage the number of seats in price categories or classes to charge each individual passenger as close as possible to the maximum he would be willing to pay. • Effectively change its fare offerings by changing the number of seats offered in each fare category without ever changing any of its published posted prices. Chapter 3 Page 186 • Match fares of the new entrant by simply offering a large number of seats in an existing or new fare category that match the new entrant’s fare offering in response to entry by a new low fare carrier. Such matching of fares does not need to be across all seats on all flights. Instead, such matching would more likely be targeted at those flights that most closely matched the new entrant’s offering of flights. 253) 254) The NTFAC identified three conditions that may contribute to welfare improving versioning: • The fraction of consumers with high willingness to pay is large. • Their valuation of extra quality is high, and • The other group’s valuation of quality degradation is limited. 255) The NTFAC did however question whether willingness to pay is based on consumer choice determined by loyalty schemes like membership of FFPs as opposed to an actual willingness to pay for the service or conditions of sale. 256) It is submitted that the working of FFPs, corporate discount schemes and TACO schemes may substantially affect the working of market forces and also affect the analysis of whether versioning is actually improving welfare. These factors may actually be more important in the chain of decisions of purchasing a ticket than the valuation of extra quality of airline service or conditions of sale by consumers. These factors may have a restrictive effect on competition. Versioning may imply that a large part of an aircraft’s capacity may be allocated to fares that may be set uniformly at marginal cost and would generate insufficient revenue to recover total costs of its flight, necessitating discriminatory pricing providing the schedule-intensive service desired by business travellers, while filling empty seats with leisure travellers whose low fares at least cover their incremental, or marginal, cost. In 3.10.4 above, it was established that leisure travellers who are sensitive to price (price-elastic) are charged fares roughly equal to the marginal cost of serving them, but apparently insufficient in the aggregate to cover the full cost of maintaining the airline networks as they are now constituted. As Ramsey pricing would suggest, US airlines apparently cover any shortfall in revenues from leisure travellers by charging higher prices, or whatever the traffic will bear, to priceChapter 3 Page 187 inelastic business travellers. The TRB was of the opinion that some business travellers believed they were being held captive to their inelastic demands as a result of various actions taken by the airlines, such as possible exclusionary behaviour to hold back new entrants or technologies such as smaller, “regional” jets. 257) As a result, the writer is of the opinion that versioning may not be in the interest of competition if the average pricing level of the larger portion of flights results in an economic barrier to entry by low cost airlines. The NTFAC stated that a large part of the market is made up of business travellers, whose willingness to pay for quality of service is high. It also questioned whether an alternative to versioning might be that no low quality version would be offered. Without the ability to price discriminate, certain routes could in their assessment become unprofitable to the airline and hence not be served at all. 258) As stated above, the willingness of business travellers to pay a higher tariff may not be related to the quality of service but due to airline practices that distort the normal working of market forces. The include FFPs, corporate discount schemes and TACO schemes. It is submitted that the entry and survival of low cost carriers could play an important role in developing new routes and expansion of markets in preference to extensive versioning and Ramsey pricing. This alternative, to increase the competition in terms of number of airlines would, in the writer’s opinion, be an important objective to achieve. As a result, the competitive conditions, frequency of service, the volume of business travel demand and the willingness to pay would be important when assessing the effect of versioning. Versioning also reduce price transparency. The more versions are offered in the market, at different prices, the harder it becomes for a consumer to compare prices and quality between suppliers. An incumbent supplier may exploit this to reduce a new entrant’s potential for attracting customers through price rivalry, thus easing the competitive pressure according to the NTFAC. 259) A comparison between fares charged by different airlines and the restrictions imposed on such fares, which are displayed in CRS in South Africa, is contained in annexure “C1” and “C2”. These fares do not include directly negotiated tariffs. It is evident that price discrimination based on the concept of versioning as set out above has generally been Chapter 3 Page 188 adopted by domestic airlines in South Africa. Whether such pricing resulted from the price leadership of the dominant airline or as a result of matching of fares disclosed in CRS by the different airlines is not clear. It may be the result of both. Within the South African context with a history of discrimination and legislation prohibiting discrimination, the question is whether price discrimination in the airline industry based on the restrictions contained in the conditions of sale by a dominant airline is per sé acceptable from a consumer or competition point of view or whether it should be considered from the perspective of overall economic welfare enhancement of growing the overall market. 3.11.3 CORPORATE DISCOUNT SCHEMES The NTFAC stated that large private and public customers (segment A) may be able to exploit buying power by triggering competition between the producers for an exclusive contract involving large discounts. Such price discrimination may actually trigger intense price rivalry in the affected segment, depending on the number of large private and public customers in the market. 260) The NTFAC concluded that such price discrimination may be detrimental to welfare, for the following reasons: • Among other customers (say, segment B) there may be no buying power present and hence no discounts available. The price setting in this segment is no longer constrained by the competition for large corporate consumers. The company may therefore increase the price in segment B, without losing business in segment A. • The net welfare effect of the price discrimination scheme will depend on the respective price elasticities of demand in the two segments. If segment A is comparatively inelastic, even a limited price increase in segment B may lead to a loss of output and welfare that outweighs the welfare gain in the segment with intense price rivalry. 261) Unlike versioning, corporate discount schemes usually discriminate between customers not on the basis of price elasticity, but on the basis of buying power under competition. Thus there is no guarantee that the more price-elastic segment receives the lower price; in fact the Chapter 3 Page 189 opposite may be more likely. This increases the risk that the welfare gain in the large customer segment A will be more than outweighed by the loss affecting all other clients in segment B. 262) The NTFAC stated that such discrimination may jeopardise profits among the firms involved in price rivalry, resulting in competition no longer being viable, and suggested the following alternatives: • Competition without price discrimination, and • Monopoly. The NTFAC concluded that in most cases welfare will be higher under effective competition than under monopoly, implying that society as a whole is better off with no third degree price discrimination in a competitive environment. 263) The NTFAC concluded that corporate discount schemes are agreements that imply third degree price discrimination that has ambiguous effects on welfare. Discounts may tend to be large in segments with quite inelastic demand, and this is regarded as a less than optimal way for the airlines to cover their fixed costs. Moreover, selective discounts may lead to intense price rivalry between suppliers. Large customer discounts may therefore lead to exits from the market, because not all the airlines are able to cover their fixed costs. In a similar manner, potential entrants might be deterred, knowing that the incumbent airline is able to meet any challenger by offering selective discounts to large, attractive clients. Since these discounts are secret and therefore difficult to detect for competition authorities, such price discrimination may make predation a more credible threat. This suggests that corporate discount schemes are anti-competitive, especially in a setting with a dominant, incumbent carrier and smaller potential entrants. 264) The NTFAC stated that many of these corporate discount schemes take forms that engender important lock-in effects, as when the rebate is in some way progressive (the percentage discount given depends on the total volume of sales through a certain period of time on a certain air travel network). The NTFAC concluded that such agreements provide an incentive for the buyer to channel his demand to one or a few carriers. 265) As larger carriers would obtain an inherent advantage compared to smaller ones, such corporate discount schemes have clear anti-competitive effects. Chapter 3 Page 190 The NTFAC also stated that corporate discounts may conceivably have the effect of raising the price for all those companies that do not benefit from them. To compensate for the dilution effect of corporate discounts on yield, airlines increase their nominal fares. 266) The NTFAC also concluded that price discrimination through corporate discounts may actually trigger intense price rivalry in the affected segment of large attractive corporate clients. As these corporate discounts are directed exclusively to a small set of customers, without affecting market prices in general, such price discrimination serves to make predation much less expensive to the dominant supplier, and hence a more credible threat to potential entrants. As a result, the NTFAC concluded that corporate discount schemes are anti-competitive, especially in a setting with a dominant, incumbent carrier and smaller potential entrants. 267) 3.11.4 FFPs The NTFAC regarded FFPs as second degree price discrimination. The consumers are rewarded for large purchases, and they receive a special kind of quantity discount. The discount is, however, given in the form of added quantity and not in the form of a reduced price. The extra service provided (for free) is not necessarily of the same type or quality as the good purchased. Most bonus trips are generally available only on certain flights. Moreover, although the customer may have earned his or her frequent flyer points buying fully flexible tickets, the bonus tickets are generally inflexible from the time they are issued. A bonus trip is, in other words, no ordinary rebate. FFPs are, according to the NTFAC, more appropriately analysed within the framework of loyalty or fidelity inducing marketing strategies, which are discussed in 4.7 of chapter 4. 268) Chapter 3 Page 191 3.12 CONCLUSIONS 3.12.1 PURPOSE The purpose of this chapter was to deal with the economic characteristics of the airline industry. The special nature of the airline industry as a network infrastructure industry was examined. A number of characteristics were identified in the airline industry that are indicative of oligopoly; further, certain unique economic network characteristics exist in the airline industry. The sources of economies of scale, scope and density in the airline industry were identified as well as the effect of airline networks on competition. The effect of declining overall volumes on airline competition, the viability network business travel pricing model (of hub-and-spoke airlines) as well as the emergence of new low cost carriers and their characteristics were examined. Price discrimination in the airline industry in general was also examined in this chapter. 3.12.2 SPECIFIC OBJECTIVES: CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY Certain economic network characteristics of the airline industry that are a concern from a competition point of view, were identified in 3.2, including: • A number of competitive concerns regarding the airline industry and other network industries were identified that have an effect on the desirability and ability of the application of competition law, applicable in the economy in general, in addressing certain concerns relating to competition in the airline industry. These competitive concerns include the following: o Network infrastructure industries have commonly been subject to government ownership or regulation. o These industries are special in that they connect consumers of their products and services by means of a network of some sort. o Several economic features exist in network infrastructure industries that are reflected in the common occurrence of broadly similar competition concern: The bigger the network, the more useful it is. Chapter 3 Page 192 Competition problems are associated with dominant, integrated firms in network industries. - A new entrant is initially able to compete by providing a limited service. - The response by the incumbent, integrated firm might be to cross-subsidise its prices in respect of that service, by raising the prices of its other services where it faces no competition and thus has market power. - The incumbent could refuse access to an essential facility. - Switching costs could be raised between one service (offered by the new entrant) and another (offered only by the incumbent). The demand for air services on a particular airport-pair, city-pair, or even country-pair is derived from a multitude of separate origin/destination markets. This gives rise to complex market definitions in airline competition. The "indivisibility" of capacity can result in extremely low short-run marginal costs, with consequent difficulties in applying competition law to cases involving allegations of predatory pricing. Some public service obligations may exist (requirements to provide some services even where it is not economic for them to do so) with the result that the reform may be highly politicised. Many of the costs are sunk and unrecoverable once they are committed. Rapid change in the level of demand is often brought about by technological change in a related market. • The factors that demonstrate that the airline industry represents an oligopoly were identified in 3.3: o High barriers to entry. o Few sellers in the market. o A product of similar nature. o Substantial economies of scale. o Growth through merger. o Mutual dependence. Chapter 3 Page 193 o Price rigidity and non-price competition. o Price transparency and collusion. • The unique economic characteristics of the airline industry were identified in 3.4. These include: o Government financial assistance. o High technological turnover. o High labour and fuel expenses. o Sensitivity to economic fluctuations. o Close government involvement and regulation, including: Eight industry-specific features of governmental involvement in the air transport market, discussed in 3.4.5.1. Regulatory intervention by governments in the operation of air transport services (CRS airport slots and gates), discussed in 3.4.5.2. Strategic co-operation amongst airlines (including the device of codesharing) in 3.4.5.3. Multilateral co-operation limited to technical and logistical matters in 3.4.5.4. • In 3.5.2 it was established that competition in the airline industry differs from that in other industries in the following respects: o Airlines compete using multiple competitive tools as identified in 3.5.3, and o Airlines compete over networks in that airlines manage flow traffic and compete over alternative routings and the market power that comes with dominant hubs in route networks, as identified in 3.5.4. • The multiple competitive tools of airlines identified in 3.5.3 includes: o Ticket price. o Frequency (number of flights a day) and the timing of those flights. o Characteristics of the flight itinerary (non stop, continuing single-plane service, or connecting service). o In-flight amenities including: Service level, food, in-flight entertainment. Seat pitch (how closely spaced together). Ground amenities including club lounges. Chapter 3 Page 194 • Loyalty schemes (rebates to the client and traveller) in the form of: - FFPs. - TACOs. - Corporate discounts. Economies of scale, scope and density on both the supply side and demand side were identified and tabulated in 3.6. In 3.6.2 it was established that few economies of scale exist from a competitive point of view. In 3.6.3, economies of scope on the supply (production) side are evident from an increase in the number of routes served within the network of an airline. These arise from the complementary routes within the network. Economies of scope on the demand (consumption) side are more important and are intensified by marketing practices, including: o FFPs. o TACOs. o Corporate discount schemes. Such airline marketing practices create synthetic economies of scope on the demand (consumption) side in that they make it more attractive for passengers and travel agents to concentrate their demand on one airline and as such increase the loyalty of the customers toward such airline through an artificial increase in the switching costs. In 3.6.4, it was established that supply side economies of density exist if an airline’s unit cost declines when the airline adds flights or seats on existing routes, primarily as a result of improved utilisation of aircraft capacity and crew. Adding destinations to a hub-and-spoke network create economies of traffic density. Demand side economies of density results from a higher route frequency that induces a higher demand for air transport. This feedback mechanism, which implies that the demand for travel in a network is in a sense self-reinforcing, is referred to as the Mohring effect. As the demand for travel increases, a higher frequency of departures can be supported, and the individual user incurs a smaller average generalised cost. In 3.6.5 it was established that economies of alliances on the supply (production) side result from airlines exploiting each other’s networks to strengthen the competitive positions of all alliance partners. On the demand (consumption) side, economies of alliances result from the fact that more extensive networks are more attractive to customers and offer larger economies of scope to the carrier. Chapter 3 Page 195 • The effect of airline networks on competition is discussed in 3.7. The increasing returns to scale, scope and density in the airline industry have several anticompetitive implications that include the following: o Economies of scale on the supply side set a natural limit to the number of competitors that can operate without economic loss on a given route. The combination of a large fixed cost and small variable cost gives rise to a minimum viable scale, which has to be exceeded in order for the firm to earn a profit in the market. Aircraft can easily be transferred between routes, but each aircraft operating on a given route invokes additional fixed costs. o Economies of scope on the demand side may reduce the competition in the airline industry, as they give the airlines an incentive to merge or enter into alliances with other airlines so as to increase the number of routes offered and the flight frequency on every route. o The hub-and-spoke system of operation, although economically efficient to the individual carrier, seems to give rise to strong anti-competitive effects by providing the hub airline with considerable market power at and around its hub. The competitive advantage of hub-and-spoke networks is effectively reinforced through the loyalty programmes operated by the carriers. o Most major airlines have joined alliances with other airlines operating in complementary regions or continents. A few global alliances cover more than fifty percent of the world passenger market. o The cost advantages related to network economics are not always reflected in lower airfares but in market power which is exploited by the airlines to increase the fares, especially on outgoing flights from airports that are highly dominated by the hub airline. Hub airlines have market power on almost all spokes out of the hub airport. o The ability of an incumbent hub airline to cross-subsidise a single spoke route or a limited set of such routes that enables a dominant hub airline with ample opportunity to fight a rival new entrant through increased capacity, disproportionately reduced fares, and/or other predatory strategies with ease and moreover at lower cost than in other industries. Chapter 3 Page 196 • The actual operation of a deregulated airline industry was examined in 3.8. The development of the following was studied: o Yield management. o Hub-and-spoke route systems. o A new generation of low cost airlines. o Potentially unfair competitive responses to entry by low cost airlines involving price and capacity. o The decline in airline competition. o Market power in airline markets. o Frequency of apparent unfair exclusionary conduct. • The effect of declining overall volumes on competition and networks as a result of the 11 September 2001 events were dealt with in 3.9. The viability of the network business travel pricing model of the hub-and-spoke airlines was considered in the light of severe financial difficulties experienced by some of the world’s major airlines. The development of a new generation of low cost carriers and the responses of hub airlines to competition by low cost carriers were identified. It was evident that there is an optimum limit to the size of an airline in the event of a turndown in volumes where it would be very difficult to scale down a large network airline. A risk of having one large dominant airline in South Africa was identified. • The occurrence of price discrimination in the airline industry was discussed in 3.10. Fare restrictions as a means of differential pricing result in something akin to Ramsey in that yield management is used to discriminate prices and conditions. The effect of price discrimination on the economic welfare of consumers in the domestic airline services was set out in 3.11. This includes: o Versioning, set out in 3.11.2 (in which one version of the product is deliberately made less attractive by exploiting the willingness to pay of customers) using yield management techniques in CRS. o Corporate discount schemes set out in 3.11.3. o FFPs set out in 3.11.4. Chapter 3 Page 197 3.12.3 SUMMARY OF RECOMMENDATIONS In 3.12.3 it was recommended that the Competition Commission should investigate price discrimination in the airline industry in South Africa. As identified in 3.5.3, it is essential that in analysing competition in the air transport market, due regard should be had to all the dimensions in which airlines compete and not only the singular dimension of price. It is also recommended that a competition analysis bearing on the airline industry should take aspects like the characteristics of networking, cost structure, yield management and marketing strategies into account. The ability to manage flow traffic and compete over alternative routings and the market power that comes with dominant hubs in route networks should also be taken into account when analysing competition in the air transport market as identified in 3.5.4. 3.13 SPECIFIC ASPECTS IDENTIFIED IN THE STUDY THAT ARE RELEVANT TO SOUTH AFRICA 3.13.1 THE SPECIAL NATURE OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY AS A NETWORK INFRASTRUCTURE INDUSTRY Network infrastructure industries are special in that they connect consumers of their products and services by means of a network of some sort. The characteristics of network industries and the unique application of commercial practices as a result of such characteristics in the airline industry affect the capability of competition law, as applied in the economy generally, to address the different issues raised in the airline industry. In this regard, it was established that any corrective measures should duly take account of such characteristics of the airline industry, when commercial conduct is considered from a competition perspective. Chapter 3 Page 198 The airline industry shares several features with other network infrastructure industries that are reflected in the common occurrence of broadly similar competition concerns: • The bigger the network, the more useful it is. • There are competition problems associated with dominant, integrated firms in network industries. A new entrant is initially able to compete by providing a limited service. The response by the incumbent, integrated firm might be to cross-subsidise its prices in respect of that service, by raising the prices of its other services where it faces no competition and thus has market power. • The incumbent could refuse access to an essential facility. • The raising of switching costs between one service (offered by the new entrant) and another (offered only by the incumbent). A dominant airline might schedule its feeder flights to arrive immediately before the departure of its connecting flights, whereas a new entrant might only secure a landing slot that feeds too late or too early into the incumbent’s flight. • Market definition in airline competition cases can sometimes be quite complex in the airline industry as the demand for air services on a particular airport-pair, city-pair, or even country-pair is derived from a multitude of separate origin/destination markets. • The "indivisibility" of capacity can result in extremely low short-run marginal costs, with consequent difficulties in applying competition law to cases involving allegations of predatory pricing. • In many countries these industries have been traditionally state owned. Such companies often have public service obligations (implying requirements to provide some services even where it is not economic for them to do so). The result is that the reform of these sectors is often highly politicised. • Many of their costs are sunk and unrecoverable once they are committed. In particular, if there is a desire to attract voluntary private investment, the regulatory regime has to be credible and predictable. Creating this credibility and predictability was one of the basic tasks of a regulator. • Rapid change in the level of demand is often brought about by technological change, which can upset long held beliefs about feasible structures of the industry and optimal regulation. Chapter 3 Page 199 3.13.2 CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY THAT DEMONSTRATE AN OLIGOPOLY It was established that the airline industry is typically characterised as an oligopolistic industry. This would require remedies that will increase competitive forces in the air transport market. 3.13.3 OTHER UNIQUE ECONOMIC CHARACTERISTICS OF THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY • Governments have played major roles in financing the growth and development of the airways system. • Airlines require employees with highly developed skills that are expensive. In addition the airline industry is very hard hit by increases in fuel prices. • Air transportation demand is susceptible to the business cycle. While the impact of a recession is not unique to the airline industry, the airline industry is much slower in recovering as spending on air travel is discretionary and follows general recovery in the economy a year to 18 months afterwards. • Features of governmental involvement in the air transport industry include: o The doctrine of sovereign national airspace o The doctrine of cabotage, which has been used to exclude foreign airlines from traffic rights on domestic point-to-point routes. o The nationality principle, by which each state reserves its domestic cabotage routes, and designation under its bilateral treaties to serve international routes, to carriers that are owned and controlled by the state or its citizens. o The practice of public ownership of national "flag carriers”, supported by incidents of state support that include subsidy programmes and protection from market competition. o Government efforts to control the tremendous power of computerised yield management technology, and to ensure a fair distribution of access to scarce airport slot and gate facilities. o The evolution of levels of strategic co-operation among airlines of different affiliation, including the device of cod -sharing, all of which reflect a partial Chapter 3 Page 200 entrepreneurial evasion, with varying levels of official government complicity of the precepts of cabotage and nationality. o Confinement of authentic multilateral co-operation to technical and logistical matters such as ticket interlining. 3.13.4 COMPETITION IN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY 3.13.4.1 Airline competition in comparison to other industries Competition in the airline industry differs from competition in many other industries because of the following: • Airlines compete using multiple competitive tools, and • Airlines compete over networks (not only on a route-to-route [city-pair] basis). In this regard, the airline industry can be described as a network industry consisting of a system of links (routes) that connect nodes (airports). 3.13.4.2 Multiple dimensions of airline competition Airlines compete over the following multiple dimensions: • Ticket price. • Frequency (number of flights a day) and the timing of those flights. • Characteristics of the flight itinerary (non stop, continuing single-plane service, or connecting service). • In-flight amenities including: o Service level, food, in-flight entertainment. o Seat pitch (how closely spaced together), and o Ground amenities including club lounges. • Loyalty schemes (rebates to the client and traveller) in the form of: o FFPs. o TACOs. o Corporate discounts. Chapter 3 Page 201 It is therefore essential that in the analysis of competition in the air transport market due regard should be had to all the dimensions in which airlines compete and not only to the singular dimension of price. The aviation industry exhibits a number of interesting characteristics in terms of networking, cost structure, yield management, and marketing strategies. The ability to manage flow traffic and compete over alternative routings and the market power that comes with dominant hubs in route networks should also be taken into account when analysing competition in the air transport market. 3.13.5 ECONOMIES OF SCALE, SCOPE AND DENSITY Network industries may have fundamentally different characteristics from the traditional industries that classic microeconomic models have been based on. As a result it is necessary to take into account not just supply side efficiency that was central in the traditional models, but demand side effects as well. These include many of the strategies that the airlines have perfected like loyalty programmes, including FFPs, that have been designed to raise the switching costs for the best customers, 3.13.5.1 Economies of scale The optimal aircraft size follows from route characteristics. This implies that the unit cost per revenue passenger kilometre mirrors the network operated by an airline. A large airline operating the network of a medium sized airline will incur similar unit costs on that part of its operations to those faced by the smaller carrier. As a result there are no significant economies of scale from operating costs at the firm level. 3.13.5.2 Economies of scope Economies of scope that emerge from the demand side are, according to the NTFAC, even more important than economies of scope that emerge from the supply side. Chapter 3 Page 202 Economies of scope on the demand side of the airline industry are due to two factors: • Consumer preferences (due to more routes served and more destinations to choose from resulting in a larger probability of finding a suitable connection as well as the concept of switching costs, which customers have to pay when they shift from one supplier to another), and • Marketing practices (economies of scope on the demand side are intensified by the marketing practices of the airlines like FFPs, TACOs and corporate discount programmes). Such airline marketing practices create synthetic economies of scope on the demand side because they make it more attractive for passengers and travel agents to concentrate their demand at one or a few airlines. The schemes and programmes increase the loyalty of the customers toward the airlines through an artificial increase in the switching costs. 48) The loyalty of customers toward airlines is increased through an artificial increase in switching costs. 3.13.5.3 Economies of ensity Supply side economies of density exist if an airline’s unit cost declines when the airline adds flights or seats on existing routes. These are competitive advantages in a large hub-andspoke networks. The demand side economies of density are even more important. A higher route frequency will decrease the average time cost experienced by the traveller and hence induce a higher demand for air transport, especially from business travellers. 3.13.5.4 Economics of alliances Airlines form alliances in order to exploit each other’s networks and to strengthen the competitive positions of all alliance partners. More extensive networks are more attractive to customers and offer larger economies of scope to the carrier. 3.13.6 THE OPERATION OF A DEREGULATED AIRLINE INDUSTRY Contrary to the predictions generally made at the time of deregulation, actual experience has demonstrated that deregulated airline markets are not contestable and that incumbent airlines Chapter 3 Page 203 can and do obtain market power on certain types of routes. Under the contestability theory, potential entry by new firms serves to discipline the behaviour of participants in real world markets where a small number of firms (oligopoly) participate. It was concluded, however. that contestability has proven inapplicable in the airline industry. The operation of the deregulated industry has been quite different from the expectations at the time of deregulation: • Industry analysts had not expected every major airline to adopt a hub-and-spoke route system. Airlines generally operated linear route systems during the regulatory era. After deregulation each of the holdover airlines (airlines that existed prior to the deregulation of the airline industry) established a hub-and-spoke system that enabled the hubbing airline to operate a more frequent service in spoke markets than could be supported only by local traffic. • Deregulation did not lead to the simplified fare structure anticipated by many observers. The fare structures of airlines became extraordinarily complicated. Airlines offer many different types of fares subject to many different conditions or rules. Airlines use yield management to determine how many seats would be offered at each fare (and limit the number of seats available to each fare class) with the objective of selling as many seats as possible at higher fare classes. This enables airlines to discriminate and charge higher fares to business travellers interested in obtaining frequent service (time sensitive passengers) while offering lower fares to leisure travellers interested in saving money and less interested in the number of flights available in any market or the timing of those flights. The implementation of advances in information technology made it possible for the airlines to implement detailed yield management systems, which increased their ability to engage in market segmentation and price discrimination. The technology has enabled each airline to allocate seats among the many different fares classes offered on a flight in accordance with a predicted demand for each type of fare. In addition, CRSs have played an important role in airline distribution. • Contrary to expectations at the time of deregulation, almost all of the current major US airlines were major airlines before deregulation. The surviving pre-deregulation airlines have become more efficient since deregulation. Their ability to survive despite their higher costs, and the failure of almost all of the new entrant airlines that started up in the early years of deregulation (with substantially lower costs) suggested Chapter 3 Page 204 that the major airlines’ route systems and the scale and scope of their operations gave them important competitive advantages. • The proponents of deregulation assumed that there were no economies of scale or scope in the airline industry, and overlooked the physical barriers to entry that became important when the regulatory scheme no longer made entry and route expansion difficult. • Competitive responses from stronger network airlines intended to eliminate competition may have undermined the ability of some new entrants to remain in business. 3.13.7 POTENTIALLY UNFAIR COMPETITIVE RESPONSES TO ENTRY BY LOW COST AIRLINES It was established that a new service by a low cost carrier is likely to be the only way that many hub markets will ever benefit from competitive airline service. Since a hubbing airline will likely have only limited competition in most of its hub markets if it can deter entry by low cost airlines, it is profitable for an incumbent airline to attempt to eliminate actual competition if it can. The following complaints were noted relating to other behaviour, not just pricing and capacity strategies, seemingly designed to make entry impossible or at least unprofitable: • Award bonus override commissions to travel agents that book the incumbent airline rather than the airline entering the market, thereby making it more difficult for the entrant to obtain bookings from those agents’ customers. • Other steps that prejudice a new entrant airline like refusals to sign joint baggage and ticketing agreements with the entrant. Refusals to sublease gates and other airport facilities to entrants (even though they are not being fully used), when comparable facilities are not available from any other source. Purchasing slots to keep entrants from obtaining such slots at slot-restricted airports. “Baby sitting” slots use the slots in relatively unprofitable markets in order to keep from losing them to a potential entrant. Chapter 3 Page 205 3.13.8 PREDATION IN THE AIRLINE INDUSTRY DUE TO ACTIONS RELATING TO CAPACITY AND PRICING The most controversial competitive responses to entry in deregulated air transport markets involve steep fare cuts combined with a large increase in the number of seats sold at low fares, and often an increase in total capacity. The incumbent airline matches the new entrant’s fare levels and makes large numbers of seats available at those levels or eliminates restrictions on its discount fares despite the fact that network airlines typically offer service features unmatched by most low cost airlines. Such action by an incumbent network airline would appear to be economically irrational, unless the entrant exits the market or reduces its service. In extreme cases the incumbent airline cuts its fares to match the new entrant’s fare levels, eliminates all or most of its restrictions on discount fares, and greatly expands the availability of discount-fare seats. In the short run the public benefits from much lower fares and discount-fare seats are easily obtained from both airlines. Travellers can enjoy both low fares and the service features offered by the hub airline, such as more frequent flights and more attractive FFP benefits. In the long run, however, the public loses because the new entrant’s competition is eliminated and fares go up to their previous levels or even higher. 3.13.9 THE NATURE OF THE AIR TRANSPORTATION MARKET IS CONDU-SIVE TO UNFAIR EXCLUSIONARY AND PREDATORY PRACTICES Compared to firms in other industries a major air carrier can: • Price-discriminate to a much greater extent (makes predation much less expensive to the dominant supplier, and hence a more credible threat to potential entrants). • Adjust prices much faster. • Shift resources between markets much more readily (mobility of aircraft) to allow an increased service frequency and number of seats to capture a disproportionate share of traffic, and • Gain access to comprehensive, “real time” information on their competitors’ activities through booking and other data generated by CRS. This enables airlines to respond to competitive initiatives more precisely and swiftly than firms in other industries, and to respond in advance. Chapter 3 Page 206 As a result, specific measures should be taken in the competition policy applicable in particular to the air transport market. 3.13.10 THE DECLINE IN AIRLINE COMPETITION There are signs that competition has declined in recent years, even though most markets remain very competitive. The number of routes with competition between airlines having a significant presence in the market has declined. 3.13.11 THE EFFECT OF A DECLINE IN OVERALL VOLUMES ON AIRLINE NETWORKS The airline industry has undergone a fundamental shift with respect to levels of business travel and the viability of the hub-and-spoke model in the USA and Europe. Higher cost airlines attempted to raise fares relying on marketing techniques which provided a powerful hold on the distribution chain; some examples are FFPs, corporate discount agreements and TACOs and discriminatory pricing practice utilising CRS applications. As leisure travellers do not buy expensive tickets, airlines focused on business travellers booking tickets at short notice, who value the convenience of frequent service at nearby airports. A number of factors contributed to changed circumstances that affected the network model. These included the following: • The network business travel pricing model exploited network size for scope advantages and made it possible to lock customers in by means of artificial switching costs. Hub airlines over-expanded in attempting to gain scope advantages. This implies that there is an optimum size for airlines beyond which the financial risk of a downturn in the economy needs to be managed. • Circumstances have changed in that growth is no longer assured and corporate clients are cutting back on travel cost. A serious drop in volumes of passengers making use of air travel highlighted the difficulty network airlines experience in reducing costs. This resulted in extreme financial difficulties for the large network airlines. • Economic conditions have forced customers to seek cheaper alternatives. This need to economise has to some extent rivalled the binding effect of a number of the marketing Chapter 3 Page 207 techniques. In particular corporate business flyers have become price sensitive and are getting smarter about identifying lower cost flights. More companies are requiring employees to travel on restricted airfares to save on corporate travel costs (less expensive but less flexible). • New entrant airlines had to focus on exactly what the product they are offering comprises. • A framework of prevention of anti-competitive behaviour and the abuse of dominance prevented larger airlines from targeted action against new low cost carriers, especially with regard to a combination of pricing and capacity actions. • CRS codes of conduct and Internet applications made it possible to restrict and bypass CRS practices that were discriminatory against smaller airlines and favoured large airlines. 3.13.12 DEVELOPMENTS RELATING TO AIR FARES In practice, airlines charge different travellers different prices, depending on their demand characteristics: • Charging higher prices for those with more inelastic demand and lower prices for those with more elastic demand discriminate in pricing depends on having market power. • Prices based on demand characteristics rather than on the cost of providing the product are characteristic of a market in which the seller has a degree of market power. Airlines offer different fares on a given flight, attaching restrictions or conditions of travel to some fares and, most importantly, offering only a limited number of seats in some fare categories. 3.13.13 YIELD MANAGEMENT AND PRICE MATCHING Yield management (by means of CRS) offers seats at multiple prices with varying conditions or restrictions and manages the number of seats in each price category or class to charge each individual passenger an amount as close as possible to the maximum he would be willing to pay. Chapter 3 Page 208 An airline can effectively change its fare offerings by changing the number of seats offered in each fare category without ever changing any of its published posted prices. In response to new entry by a low fare carrier, the airline could match fares by simply offering a large number of seats in an existing or new fare category that matches the new entrant’s fare offering. Such matching need not be across all seats on all flights. Instead, such matching would more likely be targeted at those flights that most closely matched the new entrant’s offering of flights. Chapter 3 Page 209