H OMO LEGISLATIVUS : MISSING LINK IN THE EVOLUTION OF ‘BEHAVIOUR MODIFICATION’?✝ JOHN C. KLEEFELD✵ Introduction .......................................................................................................................................... 1 ‘Behaviour Modification’—Poor Cousin of ‘Access to Justice’? .................................................. 3 Towards a Typology of Legislative- or Regulatory-Seeking Behaviour....................................... 5 Enacting ‘Private Legislation’ to Preclude Large-Scale Claims............................................................................. 5 Legislatively Eliminating or Reducing Liability (Proactive or Preemptive Approach) .......................................... 16 Legislatively Eliminating or Reducing Liability (Reactive or Retaliatory Approach) ........................................... 18 Legalizing or Regulating Previously Illegal or Unlawful Conduct........................................................................ 22 Frustrating the Ability of the Class to Collect a Remedy or Counsel to Collect a Fee .......................................... 30 Allowing Recovery of Settlements, Judgments, Penalties or Other Costs............................................................... 33 Whither Behaviour Modification? ................................................................................................... 35 Introduction In the decade since the Supreme Court of Canada’s class certification trilogy,1 it has become de rigueur to assert that class actions have three goals or advantages: judicial economy, access to justice, and behaviour modification.2 But as I will argue, in thinking about behavioral responses to class actions, Canadian scholars and practitioners—this writer included—have failed to adequately account for Homo legislativus.3 This species, closely related ✝ Presented at “Accessing Justice: Appraising Class Actions Ten Years After Dutton, Hollick & Rumley” (University of Windsor, March 28-29, 2011). ✵ Assistant Professor, University of Saskatchewan College of Law and member of the British Columbia and Saskatchewan bars. 1 Western Canadian Shopping Centres Inc. v. Dutton, [2000] S.C.J. No. 63 (QL), 2001 SCC 46, [2001] 2 S.C.R. 534, 286 A.R. 201, 201 D.L.R. (4th) 385, [2002] 1 W.W.R. 1, 4 Alta. L.R. (3d) 1 [Dutton]; Hollick v. Toronto (City), [2001] S.C.J. No. 67 (QL), 2001 SCC 68, [2001] 3 S.C.R. 158, 56 O.R. (3d) 214, 205 D.L.R. (4th) 19 [Hollick]; Rumley v. British Columbia, [2001] S.C.J. No. 39 (QL), 2001 SCC 69, [2001] 3 S.C.R. 184, [2001] 11 W.W.R. 207, 95 B.C.L.R. (3d) 1. For a summary , see John C. Kleefeld, “Class Actions in Canada” (2002) 44:3 For the Defense 60, rep’d as “Top of the Class: The Supreme Court of Canada’s Endorsement of Class Actions” (Continuing Legal Education Society of British Columbia: May 24, 2002) online: <http://www.cle.bc.ca>. 2 Dutton, ibid. at paras. 27-29; Hollick, ibid. at para. 15. 3 I had hoped to be the first to classify Homo legislativus, but the term appears to have been coined 70 years ago. See Max Radin, “Fair, Feasible and in the Public Interest” (1941) 29 Cal. L. Rev. 451. Radin’s Homo legislativus “always acted reasonably, always meant different things when he used different words, always acted for the public interest, rarely or never contradicted himself, was always aware of other statutes passed on the same subject matter, and knew and took account of decisions and administrative practice about previous enactments of this character” (at 456-457). My H. legislativus, in contrast, unabashedly acts out of self-interest. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 2 to Homo economicus,4 responds to actual or perceived threats of class actions or other largescale claims,5 not by modifying the wrongful behaviour itself, but by seeking legislative or regulatory relief for class action pain. Included here is such ‘private legislation’ as the anticlass-action clauses that defendants write into consumer contracts—clauses that mandate private arbitration, prohibit joinder of claims, or even require customers to opt out of class actions. In other cases, defendants may seek to legislatively cap or eliminate liability, or to legalize or regulate conduct that was previously illegal or unlawful, or under the threat of being found so. But Homo legislativus is found in claimants as well as defendants. So, for example, if consumers are sufficiently represented, they too can effect legislative change— e.g., in the form of anti-arbitration provisions in consumer protection legislation—as they have done in some provinces. Likewise, they can influence the legislative process to make illegal or unlawful conduct that was previously legal or lawful, or to restrict or regulate the lawful ambit within which business, government or institutions operate. To make sense of what is going on, then, we need a framework that better takes legislative- or regulatoryseeking behaviour into account in the context of large-scale claims. I aim to sketch out such a framework or schema here. First, I review the “behaviour modification” role of class proceedings legislation, a role related to, but distinct from “judicial economy” or “access to justice.” Second, I categorize types of legislative-seeking behaviour, illustrating each with examples from the Canadian experience with large-scale claims. At least two types of schemata are possible. One characterizes legislative intervention as falling, roughly speaking, into pre- and post-dispute phases. Another characterizes it by the degree of intervention sought; i.e., from less interventionist to more. Neither of these schemata are perfect. For instance, an arbitration clause imposed in a consumer contract before any dispute has arisen may be seen as less interventionist than a legislative enactment that reverses a judicial decision. But the arbitration clause may affect many more individuals than the legislative reversal of a judgment, so that, practically, the pre-dispute behaviour has a more widespread impact. Recognizing the limitations of both schemata, I pick the first, because I find it convenient to think in terms of the chronological unfolding of a dispute. The typology will, I hope, be a fruitful starting point and be refined in future scholarship. Third, I join a growing call for change, including legislative change, apparently make me a member of H. legislativus too. I conclude that without such change, all the promises of class proceedings—judicial economy, access to justice and, especially, behaviour modification— will go unfulfilled. 4 On which, see, e.g., Joseph Persky, “Retrospectives: The Ethology of Homo Economicus” (1995) 9 Journal of Economic Perspectives 221. 5 I use the term large-scale claims as it includes other proceedings besides class actions, such as multi-plaintiff lawsuits, class arbitrations (which have so far had little impact in Canada), shareholder derivative actions and, potentially, administrative proceedings. See Jamie Cassels and Craig Jones, The Law of Large-Scale Claims: Product Liability, Mass Torts, and Complex Litigation in Canada (Toronto: Irwin Law, 2005). Similarly, I adopt the term claimant to refer to members of a class who have an actual or potential claim—typically against a government, corporate or institutional actor—whether or not it has crystallized into a class proceeding. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 3 ‘Behaviour Modification’—Poor Cousin of ‘Access to Justice’? Craig Jones notes that when the U.S. class action rule, Rule 23, was adopted for federal courts, it was seen as little more than a mechanism to benefit those who would otherwise lack court access.6 Jones also notes that despite the ensuing decades of class action experience, it is not uncommon to find class actions and other aggregative techniques discussed in essentially those terms. Behaviour modification or deterrence—the expressions are used interchangeably—tend to be viewed as byproducts of access to justice or as related to their effects on the ability to aggregate low-value claims. If you like, access to justice and judicial economy are the elder siblings; behaviour modification, the junior one—or even the poor cousin. This can be seen in the third-place ranking of deterrence when courts list class action goals, and in comments such as these in Dutton: Third, class actions serve efficiency and justice by ensuring that actual and potential wrongdoers do not ignore their obligations to the public. Without class actions, those who cause widespread but individually minimal harm might not take into account the full costs of their conduct, because for any one plaintiff the expense of bringing suit would far exceed the likely recovery. Cost-sharing decreases the expense of pursuing legal recourse and accordingly deters potential defendants who might otherwise assume that minor wrongs would not result in litigation.7 I agree with this statement, and so does Jones. But as Jones explains, the corollary sometimes advanced—that the deterrence advantage of class actions disappears when some or all of the claims are individually viable—is “misconceived.”8 Indeed, much of Jones’s thesis is that from a public policy perspective, deterrence is more important than compensation in furthering the goals of class action legislation, and is a foundation for a public-law view of class proceedings. Certainly, the heralding of a public- or policy-oriented approach was apparent in Dutton, the first of the trilogy decisions. The case arose in Alberta, a province that had no class action statute as the time. That didn’t deter McLachlin C.J.C., though, who declared that judges “must fill the void under their inherent power to settle the rules of practice and procedure as to disputes brought before them.”9 The Court went out of its way to note the change in the law and public attitude since its decision in Naken,10 where it had rejected the notion of a common-law class action. Jones also notes that compensation, often used synonymously with “access to justice,” isn’t necessarily co-dependent with deterrence. As victims often learn to their chagrin, the prosecution of criminal or quasi-criminal offences may be a way to access justice, and the associated fines or imprisonment may even act as behavioral deterrents; but barring remedies such as civil restitution orders, victims must seek compensation in another forum. In civil proceedings, though, there is a confluence of the two ideas, and in class proceedings, a further confluence with the idea of judicial economy. Though the ideas are 6 Craig Jones, Theory of Class Actions (Toronto: Irwin Law, 2003). This section is drawn in part from pp 27-37. 7 Dutton, supra note 1 at para. 29, cited ibid. at 28 (emphasis added by Jones). 8 Jones, supra note 6 at 29. 9 Dutton, supra note 1 at para. 34. 10 Naken v. General Motors of Canada Ltd., [1983] S.C.J. No. 9 (QL), [1983] 1 S.C.R. 72, 144 D.L.R. (3d) 385, 32 C.P.C. 138. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 4 distinct, they interact in important ways. Perhaps, rather than thinking of them as an ordered list, or as siblings or cousins, it would be useful to imagine an equilateral triangle—with compensation, deterrence and judicial economy poised at its corners, constantly acting on and interacting with each other. The other point I will make here is that behaviour modification or deterrence—pick your term—has multiple meanings. The meanings are important in litigation generally, but in class proceedings especially. We can think of specific deterrence as those incentives that encourage the same legal actor not to repeat certain past behaviour. And we can think of general deterrence as signals or incentives that attempt to modify the future behaviour of other legal actors. These are well known concepts and are sometimes referred to, respectively, as ex post and ex ante attempts at behaviour modification. But there is another form of ex post behaviour that Jones discusses in detail in the class action context, and that is the behaviour of parties in resolving their disputes. Examples include the speed with which a dispute is processed, the relative willingness to disclose information material to the dispute, and relative preferences for settlement over trial. If one studies the rules of court and the reforms thereto, it is evident that they aim to modify such ex post behaviour in particular ways. Class action regimes (regime encompassing the rules, the ways in which parties use them, and the interpretation courts give to them)11 are no different. Thus a regime in which either party can appeal a class certification evinces a different stance towards this ex post litigation behaviour than one in which only the plaintiff can appeal, as in Quebec.12 The first regime tolerates a higher level of investment in fighting certification and takes a neutral stance on who will do the investing; the second evinces a lower tolerance for certification battles, but where it lets them go past the motion stage, tilts the balance to plaintiffs. Similarly, a regime that takes a loser-pay or full indemnity approach to costs differs from one in which parties bear their own costs on a partial-indemnity or lower (i.e., tariff-based) approach. Depending on how these factors combine (i.e., whether costs are shifted and, if so, at what amounts), there can be a huge range in the risk associated with the costs of a class proceeding. And so regimes that allow cost awards against representative plaintiffs— i.e., Ontario’s—are problematic because the economies of scale are “grotesquely reversed.”13 That is, a defendant’s litigation costs, incurred to fend itself off against the whole class, “can be exacted from a single representative plaintiff whose own interest in the claim might be minimal.”14 Absent indemnification agreements from class counsel or funding guarantees from organizations like the Class Proceedings Fund, this creates very different risk profiles for ex post disputing behaviour and, potentially, for the types of claim brought. A similar analysis applies to whether a class action regime is opt-in or opt-out; in Canada, that effectively devolves into a question as to whether class proceedings will be national or 11 On the ‘regime’ or ‘system design’ aspects of class actions, see, e.g., John C. Kleefeld and Anila Srivastava, “Resolving Mass Wrongs: A Command-Consensus Perspective” (2005) 30 Queen’s L.J. 449. 12 See Code of Civil Procedure, R.S.Q. c. C-25, art. 1010. 13 Jamie Cassels and Craig Jones, The Law of Large-Scale Claims: Product Liability, Mass Torts, and Complex Litigation in Canada (Toronto: Irwin Law, 2005) at 370. 14 Ibid. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 5 proceed province-by-province.15 Cassels and Jones make a compelling case for why national—even international—class actions are preferable to provincial ones, noting the benefits to access to justice, judicial economy and, particularly, deterrence.16 The corollary is that defendants can generally be expected to do whatever they can to avoid national classes,17 so if courts are concerned with promoting the policies behind class actions, it is crucial that they take into account what effects their decisions may have on such policies. I return to this point when considering judicial reactions in different provinces to the question of whether an arbitration clause can be used to stay a class proceeding. Towards a Typology of Legislative- or Regulatory-Seeking Behaviour Enacting ‘Private Legislation’ to Preclude Large-Scale Claims The first type of behaviour I will consider is that in which a legal actor, typically a corporation, ‘enacts’ its own ‘private legislation’ to preclude the threat of court action generally, and large-scale claims in particular.18 Its salient form is a standard-form agreement to arbitrate, typically entered into at the time of contracting, or at least before a dispute has arisen. When the larger contract of which it is a part is for consumer goods or services, this type of agreement is called a “pre-dispute consumer arbitration clause.”19 What we have here is a carefully crafted internal legal system whose operation depends on an ability to use the external legal system to induce compliance.20 In this case, the external legal mechanism is an especially potent one—the provisions in arbitration legislation that let a party seek a stay of proceedings if a court action is launched against it. The potency was illustrated most notoriously in the 2002 decision in Kanitz v. Rogers Cable Inc.21 Through its brand Rogers@Home, Rogers provided Internet service under a 15 I exclude actions brought in Federal Court, which are national by definition. 16 Cassels and Jones, supra note 13, c. 10. 17 But not always. In two cases in which I have been involved, the defendants consented to certification, and in one of those cases, to a national class—and was able to extract some concessions for doing so. 18 The term private legislation draws on a tradition that recognizes the crucial role of private law-making in society. See, e.g., the influential manuscript of Henry M. Hart, Jr. and Albert M. Sacks, The Legal Process: Basic Problems in the Making and Application of Law (Cambridge MA: Tentative Edition, 1958). Hart and Sacks, though chiefly concerned with a theory of adjudication, said that “private law makers, the courts, and administrative agencies are . . . the regularly available, continuously functioning agencies of growth in the legal system” (at 187, emphasis added). Other terms conveying this concept include “private ordering,” “indigenous law” and “legal pluralism.” See, e.g., Marc Galanter, “Justice in Many Rooms: Courts, Private Ordering and Indigenous Law” (1981) 19 J. Legal Pluralism 1, and Roderick A. MacDonald, “Metaphors of Multiplicity: Civil Society, Regimes and Legal Pluralism” (1998) 15 Ariz. J. Int’l & Comp. L. 69. 19 See Jonnette Watson Hamilton, “Pre-Dispute Consumer Arbitration Clauses: Denying Access to Justice?” (2006) 51 McGill L.J. 693 and Shelley McGill, “The Conflict Between Consumer Class Actions and Contractual Arbitration Clauses” (2006) 43 Can. Bus. L.J. 359. 20 See Galanter, supra note 18 at 24-25 on the interface between external and internal (indigenous) systems. 21 Kanitz v. Rogers Cable Inc., [2002] O.J. No. 665; 58 O.R. (3d) 299; 21 B.L.R. (3d) 104; 16 C.P.C. (5th) 84 (S.C.J.) [Kanitz]. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 6 contract that let Rogers “change, modify, add or remove portions of this Agreement at any time,” with the proviso that it would tell subscribers “by posting notice . . . on the Rogers@Home web site, or sending notice via email or postal mail.”22 In late 2000, Rogers amended the contract, adding a clause that read in part as follows: Arbitration. Any claim, dispute or controversy (whether in contract or tort, pursuant to statute or regulation, or otherwise, and whether pre-existing, present or future) arising out of or relating to: (a) this Agreement; (b) Rogers@Home; (c) oral or written statements, advertisements or promotions relating to this Agreement or to Rogers@Home or (d) the relationships which result from this Agreement (including relationships with third parties who are not signatories to this Agreement) (collectively the “Claim”), will be referred to and determined by arbitration (to the exclusion of the courts). You agree to waive any right you may have to commence or participate in any class action against us related to any Claim and, where applicable, you also agree to opt out of any class proceedings against us.23 Relying on the web update option in its original contract, Rogers posted the amended contract with the arbitration clause on its website in January 2001, noting this in the site’s “News and Highlights” section for about a two-week period.24 When a class action was launched for refunds due to Internet service interruptions—alleged to have occurred over a six-month period before addition of the arbitration clause25—Rogers successfully moved to stay the action. Characterizing the motion as involving the interplay between Ontario’s Arbitration Act26 and its Class Proceedings Act,27 Nordheimer J. held that Rogers had adequately notified subscribers of the change, and concluded that the mandatory stay provisions of the AA trumped the CPA unless the plaintiffs could successfully invoke one of the legislated exceptions in the AA.28 The most obvious exception, and the one most vigorously argued, was that the arbitration agreement was invalid on grounds of unconscionability. This required proving three elements: (i) inequality of bargaining power; (ii) a preying upon or 22 Ibid. at para. 7. 23 Ibid. at para. 8 (emphasis added). 24 Ibid. at para. 9. 25 Ibid. at para. 48. 26 Arbitration Act, 1991, S.O. 1991, c. 17 [AA]. 27 Class Proceedings Act, 1992, S.O. 1992, c. 6 [CPA]. 28 Kanitz, supra note 21 at para. 33. Subsections 1 and 2 of AA s. 7 read as follows: (1) If a party to an arbitration agreement commences a proceeding in respect of a matter to be submitted to arbitration under the agreement, the court in which the proceeding is commenced shall, on the motion of another party to the arbitration agreement, stay the proceeding. 1991, c. 17, s. 7 (1). (2) However, the court may refuse to stay the proceeding in any of the following cases: 1. A party entered into the arbitration agreement while under a legal incapacity. 2. The arbitration agreement is invalid. 3. The subject-matter of the dispute is not capable of being the subject of arbitration under Ontario law. 4. The motion was brought with undue delay. 5. The matter is a proper one for default or summary judgment. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 7 taking advantage of the weaker party by the stronger party; and (iii) a resulting improvident bargain.29 While the result in Kanitz has been frequently criticized, what is sometimes overlooked is Nordheimer J.’s holding for the plaintiffs on the first of these elements: The defendant contends that there is no inequality of bargaining power in this case because there is no evidence that any of the plaintiffs was in a disadvantaged bargaining position regarding any aspect of the lesser agreement. With respect, that submission simply ignores reality. There is clearly an inequality of bargaining power between a single consumer and a corporation the size of the defendant here. The reality is that there is no bargaining at all. The defendant decides on the terms of the agreement and the consumer’s sole choice is either to accept the agreement if he or she wants the service or to reject the agreement and forgo the defendant’s service as a consequence. It is very much a “take it or leave it” form of contract. The first element for a finding of unconscionability is therefore met.30 To put it in the framework of this paper, if such private law can be said to be ‘enacted,’ it is done so without any meaningful consent of the governed. But Nordheimer J., despite his reality-testing on the first element of the unconscionability test, held that Rogers hadn’t taken advantage of its subscribers to form an improvident bargain—noting that no evidence had been led that subscribers would not arbitrate for a maximum refund of about $240.31 With respect, that conclusion, as well as the accompanying suggestion that an arbitrator might be able to consolidate arbitrations raising the same issue,32 also “simply ignores reality.” The potential claims were small, even by small-claims standards, especially as the maximum refund assumed 100% service unavailability for six months at $40 per month, and there was no suggestion that subscribers had experienced that much interruption. And the plaintiffs had proposed class-wide arbitration but Rogers had rejected their overture.33 From the defendant’s perspective, that made economic sense. The well-documented realpolitik is that clauses like Rogers’ are added by corporations “to insulate the corporation from the punishing effects of class actions and not as a serious choice of forum.”34 Agreeing to class arbitration would negate that effect, as evidenced by arbitration clauses that corporations have since drafted to preclude class arbitrations as well as class actions.35 29 Kanitz, supra note 21 at para. 37. 30 Ibid. at para. 38 (emphasis added). 31 Kanitz, supra note 21 at para. 41. 32 Ibid. at para. 55. 33 Ibid. at para. 41. 34 Shelley McGill, “Consumer Arbitration Clause Enforcement: A Balanced Legislative Response” (2010) 47 Am. Bus. L.J. 361 at 361; see note 1 of McGill’s article for supporting citations and evidence. 35 “Most arbitration provisions today contain class action waivers and there is no question that the interest of those companies would be severely prejudiced by an order compelling class-wide arbitration, particularly if the arbitration provision specifies that the class action waiver may not be severed from the rest of the arbitration provision if the class action waiver is invalidated.” Alan S. Kaplinsky, “The Use of Pre-Dispute Arbitration Agreements by Consumer Financial Services Providers” in American Bar Association, “The State of Consumer Credit Arbitration: Assessing Developments Regarding NAF, AAA and Proposed Federal Legislation” presented at a meeting of the American Bar Association Committee on Consumer Financial Services (Park City, Utah: January 11, 2010) at 35. This document, which provides a detailed Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 8 Legislative reaction was swift. An overhaul of Ontario consumer law was already underway via schedules to an omnibus amending statute.36 Schedule A enacted the new Consumer Protection Act,37 and to it was added, among other things, a provision that “any term or acknowledgment in a consumer agreement or a related agreement that requires . . . that disputes . . . be submitted to arbitration is invalid insofar as it prevents a consumer from exercising a right to commence an action in the Superior Court of Justice given under this Act.”38 Since the Small Claims Court is a branch of the Superior Court of Justice,39 the protection was automatically extended to consumer claims brought in that Court. A similar provision was added in respect of class proceedings.40 In both cases, an exception was added to preserve the ability of consumers and suppliers to agree to arbitrate after a dispute had arisen.41 The statute was assented to on December 13, 2002, but due to the time it took to draft the regulations, the legislation did not come into force until July 30, 2005.42 In the meantime, several other developments were unfolding that were to launch pre-dispute consumer arbitration clauses onto the national scene. The first development was the profuse payday loan litigation, especially in British Columbia and Ontario. I will return to it later, but suffice it to say here that in the two leading cases, MacKinnon and Smith,43 the courts rejected the Kanitz approach in favour of agenda for avoiding consumer credit class actions, is available through the ABA Business Law Section, online: <http://apps.americanbar.org/buslaw/committees/CL230000pub/materials.shtml>. 36 Consumer Protection Statute Law Amendment Act, 2002, S.O. 2002, c. 30. 37 Consumer Protection Act, 2002, being Schedule A to the Consumer Protection Statute Law Amendment Act, 2002, ibid. 38 Ibid., s. 7(2). The terms consumer and consumer agreement are defined in s. 1 of the statute. 39 Courts of Justice Act, R.S.O. 1990, c. 43, s. 22. 40 Consumer Protection Act, 2002, supra note 37, s. 8(1). 41 Ibid., ss. 7(5) and 8(4). 42 Ontario Legislature, Table of Proclamations, online: <http://www.e-laws.gov.on.ca/html/tables/ publicstatutes/elaws_t_pu_st_tprocs.htm>. 43 In Ontario, see Smith v. National Money Mart Co., [2005] O.J. No. 2660 (QL), 8 B.L.R. (4th) 159, 18 C.P.C. (6th) 1 (S.C.J.) (dismissing motions to set aside ex juris service of statement of claim on Money Mart’s parent company and to stay uncertified class proceeding in favour of arbitration), [2005] O.J. No. 4269 (QL), 258 D.L.R. (4th) 453, 12 B.L.R. (4th) 29, 20 C.P.C. (6th) 345 (C.A.) (quashing appeal on the basis that legality of the arbitration provision should be determined at the certification hearing), [2005] S.C.C.A. No. 528 (QL), 261 D.L.R. (4th) vi (leave to appeal dismissed), [2006] O.J. No. 1807 (QL), 80 O.R. (3d) 81, 266 D.L.R. (4th) 275, 209 O.A.C. 190, 18 B.L.R. (4th) 22, 28 C.P.C. (6th) 34 (dismissing appeal on ex juris service of statement of claim), [2006] S.C.C.A. No. 267 (QL) (leave to appeal dismissed), [2007] O.J. No. 46 (QL) 37 C.P.C. (6th) 171, 29 E.T.R. (3d) 199 (S.C.J.) (granting certification), [2007] O.J. No. 2160, 30 E.T.R. (3d) 163 (Div. Ct.) (dismissing leave to appeal), [2007] O.J. No. 1507 (QL) (S.C.J.) (motion to permit defendant to advise class members during opt-out period that it might not make further loans unless customer opted-out of class action), [2008] O.J. No. 2248 (QL), 57 C.P.C. (6th) 99 (S.C.J.) (application to stay class proceeding pending arbitration, based on a change in the law resulting from Supreme Court of Canada’s decisions in Dell Computer and Rogers Wireless), [2008] O.J. No. 3497 (QL), 92 O.R. (3d) 224 (S.C.J.) (costs), [2008] O.J. No. 4327 (QL), 2008 ONCA 746, 61 C.P.C. (6th) 72, 243 O.A.C. 173 (refusing appeal based on issue estoppel), [2008] S.C.C.A. No. 535 (QL) (leave to appeal dismissed), [2008] O.J. No. 4474 (QL), 67 C.P.C. (6th) 260 (S.C.J.) (costs), [2009] O.J. No. 2217 (QL), 2009 ONCA 455 (costs), [2010] O.J. No. 873 (QL), 2010 ONSC 1334, 94 C.P.C. (6th) 126 (approving settlement and fees) [Smith]. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 9 requiring certification judges to consider arbitration clauses in the context of the preferability criterion for class proceedings. In other words, only if arbitration was a “preferable procedure”44 for resolving the common issues would an action be stayed; otherwise, it would be certified as a class action. Here the behavioral realpolitik is entirely in the other direction: as Shelley McGill has commented, “[i]t is hard to imagine how individual arbitration could ever be preferable over an otherwise certifiable class action if deterrence is used as a criterion.”45 The second development was two Quebec cases that went to the Supreme Court of Canada, with arbitration policy prevailing over class action policy in the judicial arena—only to be reversed in the legislative arena. In first, Dell Computer,46 the Court set out the law and applied it to enforce an arbitration clause in the context of online computer purchases; in the second, Rogers Wireless,47 the Court applied the newly announced law to enforce an arbitration clause in the context of roaming charges for wireless phone service. Dell Computer arose out of a pricing error for two handheld computers on Dell’s website ($89 and $118 rather than $379 and $549, respectively). The day after Dell learned of the error, it blocked the ability to access the order page through its website, though without actually removing the page. But some intrepid consumers—one Olivier Dumoulin in particular—accessed the page through ‘deep links’ and ordered the computers. Dell responded by posting a correction and announcing that it wouldn’t process the orders. Dumoulin retaliated by instituting a class action with the aid of the Consumers Union of Quebec.48 Dell applied to have the claim referred to arbitration based on a clause accessible In British Columbia, see MacKinnon v. National Money Mart Co., [2004] B.C.J. No. 175 (QL), 2004 BCSC 136, 26 B.C.L.R. (4th) 172, 41 B.L.R. (3d) 198, 46 C.P.C. (5th) 80 (dismissing motion to stay uncertified class proceeding in favour of arbitration), [2004] B.C.J. No. 1961 (QL), 2004 BCCA 473, 50 B.L.R. (3d) 291 (allowing appeal and remitting case back to case management judge to complete analysis of the certification application), [2005] B.C.J. No. 399 (QL), 2005 BCSC 271 (denying certification on basis that individual issues overwhelmed common issues), unreported, Vancouver Registry No. S030527, June 16, 2005 (allowing action to be continued as several separate proceedings), [2006] B.C.J. No. 635 (QL), 2006 BCCA 148, 265 D.L.R. (4th) 214, [2006] 5 W.W.R. 601 (allowing appeal and adjourning certification application for a reconstituted proceeding), [2007] B.C.J. No. 520 (QL), 2007 BCSC 348 (certifying reconstituted proceeding), [2008] B.C.J. No. 1026 (QL), 2008 BCSC 710, 293 D.L.R. (4th) 478, 84 B.C.L.R. (4th) 369, [2009] 1 W.W.R. 129 (refusing application to stay class proceeding pending arbitration, based on a change in the law resulting from Supreme Court of Canada’s decisions in Dell Computer and Rogers Wireless), [2008] B.C.J. No. 1285 (QL), 2008 BCCA 292, 295 D.L.R. (4th) 304 (granting leave to appeal), [2009] B.C.J. No. 468 (QL), 2009 BCCA 103, 68 C.P.C. (6th) 241, 89 B.C.L.R. (4th) 1, 304 D.L.R. (4th) 331, [2009] 5 W.W.R. 418 (refusing appeal based on issue estoppel), [2010] B.C.J. No. 1436 (QL), 2010 BCSC 1008 (approving settlement and fees) [MacKinnon]. 44 CPA, supra note 27, s. 5(1)(d) and Class Proceedings Act, R.S.B.C. 1996, c. 50 [BCCPA], s. 4(1)(d). 45 McGill, supra note 19 at 370. 46 Dell Computer Corp. v. Union des des consommateurs, [2004] J.Q. No. 155 (QL) (S.C.) (QL) (authorizing class action), [2005] J.Q. no 7011, 2005 QCCA 570 (affirming result on different grounds), [2005] S.C.C.A. No. 370 (QL) (granting leave to appeal and granting intervention applications for several intervenors), [2007] S.C.J. No. 34 (QL), 2007 SCC 34, 284 D.L.R. (4th) 577, 34 B.L.R. (4th) 155, 44 C.P.C. (6th) 205 (reversing lower courts and referring matter to arbitration) [Dell Computer]. 47 Rogers Wireless Inc. v. Muroff, [2007] S.C.J. No. 35 (QL), 2007 SCC 35, [2007] 2 S.C.R. 921, 284 D.L.R. (4th) 675, 36 B.L.R. (4th) 79, 44 C.P.C. (6th) 373 [Rogers Wireless]. 48 The Consumers Union of Quebec-Union des consommateurs is an affiliate of Consumers International (CI). The Union’s mission “is to represent and protect the rights of consumers, especially from poor and Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 10 through a hyperlink, and for dismissal of the motion to authorize a class action. The clause specified that arbitration was to be administered by National Arbitration Forum (NAF), a U.S. organization.49 The Union contended that the arbitration clause was null and, in any event, couldn’t be used against Dumoulin. The Quebec Superior Court and the Court of Appeal refused to uphold the clause, though for different reasons. In a 6:3 decision the Supreme Court reversed both courts, stayed the class action, and upheld the arbitration clause. Both the majority and minority relied on textual interpretation of Quebec’s Civil Code,50 without referring to class action policy, to the MacKinnon and Smith decisions in the British Columbia and Ontario Courts of Appeal, or to the Court’s own class action trilogy.51 Deschamps J., writing for the majority, thought that art. 3149 CCQ posed the key issue: as an exception to the general deference to arbitration in art. 3148 CCQ, it gives “Quebec authorities” jurisdiction to hear an action involving a consumer or employment contract if the consumer or worker resides in or is domiciled in Quebec, and says that “the waiver of such jurisdiction by the consumer or worker may not be set up against him.”52 This required considering whether the arbitration clause gave rise to a “foreign element,” since art. 3149 is under the Code title Private International Law. This couldn’t be, thought Deschamps J., since arbitration is an institution characterized by “neutrality [and is] without a forum [or] geographic basis.”53 That the arbitration clause invoked NAF and its procedural rules was seen as irrelevant, for “[t]he rules become those of the parties, regardless of where they are taken from.”54 The majority also considered irrelevant the fact that the NAF arbitrations would be governed by a U.S. statute55 and conducted in English. In the majority’s view, these were not foreign elements for purposes of Quebec’s private international law. The minority, comprising Bastarache, LeBel and Fish JJ., thought that this was reading too much into the Code’s titles and taxonomic structure, and that, in any case, the word international in ‘private international law,’ or what the common law calls ‘conflicts of law,’ is something of a misnomer.56 They thought that both forum selection clauses and arbitration clauses constitute on their own the requisite foreign element. As to forum selection clauses, disadvantaged households.” See the Union’s website: <http://www.consommateur.qc.ca/union-desconsommateurs or its page on the CI website: <http://www.consumersinternational.org/our-members/ member-directory/Consumers%20Union%20of%20Quebec%20-%20Union%20des%20consommateurs>. 49 NAF says its mission is “to provide a fair, efficient, and effective system for the resolution of commercial and civil disputes in the United States and worldwide.” NAF, online: <http://www.adrforum.com>. But see infra, notes 60 to 62 and accompanying text. 50 Civil Code of Québec, S.Q. 1991, c. 64 [CCQ]. 51 For a critique, see Shelley McGill, “Consumer Arbitration and Class Actions: The Impact of Dell Computer Corp. v. Union des consommateurs” (2007) 45 Can. Bus. L.J. 334. 52 Dell Computer, supra note 46 at paras. 11-12, citing art. 3149 CCQ. 53 Ibid. at para. 51. 54 Ibid. at para. 52; see also paras. 55-60 for the majority’s analysis of the specific elements that might be argued to be “foreign.” 55 That is, the Federal Arbitration Act, 9 U.S.C. §§ 1-16. 56 Dell Computer, supra note 46 at para. 202. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 11 the minority said that their effect is to divest Quebec authorities of jurisdiction so the dispute can be heard in another country or province; similarly, the effect of arbitration clauses is to create “private jurisdiction” in place of the jurisdiction of state-appointed authorities like domestic courts and administrative tribunals.57 The minority thought that this alone triggered art. 3149. They also questioned NAF’s reliance on the U.S. Federal Arbitration Act, concluding that an arbitrator bound by U.S. law couldn’t be a “Québec authority.”58 And they thought that a “Québec authority” would have to provide arbitration services in French, finding it “completely incongruous” that “to begin the process attributing to the purported ‘Québec authority’ power to hear the dispute, the consumer must first contact an American institution, located in Minneapolis, who is in charge of organizing the arbitration.”59 As it turns out, the minority’s suspicions were not unfounded: NAF was subsequently prosecuted by Minnesota’s Attorney General for being anything but “neutral,” due in part to financial ties to the very firms whose cases came before it and in part to its alleged advice to business on drafting arbitration clauses, helping them make arbitration claims, and counselling them on legal trends affecting arbitration.60 Three days after the action was filed, NAF signed a consent decree under which it agreed to stop doing credit card and consumer arbitrations altogether.61 In an ironic twist, NAF, once a bulwark against class actions, is now defending itself in a class action brought to recover the allegedly improper arbitration awards.62 Dell Computer also posed a question of arbitral jurisdiction that was to prove important in cases outside Quebec. The majority said that any challenge to the arbitrator’s jurisdiction must first be resolved by the arbitrator in accordance with the competence-competence principle,63 which recognizes that an arbitral tribunal is generally competent to decide on its own competence or jurisdiction to resolve a dispute.64 A court should depart from the rule of systematic referral to arbitration only if the jurisdictional challenge is based solely on a question of law—an exception justified by judicial expertise in resolving such questions, by 57 Ibid. at paras. 200-201. 58 Ibid. at para. 212. 59 Ibid. 60 See Deepak Gupta, “Minnesota Attorney General Sues National Arbitration Forum” (July 14, 2009) Public Citizen Consumer Law and Policy Blog online: <http://pubcit.typepad.com/clpblog/2009/07/minnesotaattorney-general-sues-national-arbitration-forum.html>. For the Attorney General’s complaint, see <http://pubcit.typepad.com/files/2009-07-14-signed-complaint-with-exhibits.pdf>. 61 Public Citizen Consumer Law and Policy Blog online: <http://pubcit.typepad.com/files/nafconsentdecree.pdf>. 62 In re: National Arbitration Forum Trade Practices Litigation, 682 F. Supp. 2d 1343; 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 10380 (J.P.M.L.) (transferring multi-district actions to Minnesota), 704 F. Supp. 2d 832; 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 15178 (D. Minn. 2010) (motions to dismiss granted in part and denied in part), 2010 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 35655 (D. Minn. April 12, 2010) (stay pending appeal denied). Apart from this, California is suing NAF and other defendants in litigation that is ongoing. See People of the State of California v. National Arbitration Forum, Inc. (Calif. Sup. Ct., San Francisco No. CGC-08-473569) online: “http://www.sfsuperiorcourt.org> (enter case number 473569 in Case Number Query field for a list of all court documents, some of which are viewable). 63 Ibid. at para. 84. 64 Ibid. at para. 87. For a good summary of this principle and other related points , see Andrew Little, “Canadian Arbitration Law after Dell Computer Corp. v. Union des consommateurs” (2007) 45 Can. Bus. L.J. 356. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 12 the fact that parties apply to the court when requesting referral, and by the rule that an arbitrator’s decision on jurisdiction can be judicially reviewed.65 If the challenge requires reviewing facts, the court should normally refer the case to arbitration, because arbitrators have, for this purpose, the same expertise as courts.66 In the result, the majority thought that there was a need to analyze facts, such as those relating to the existence or non-existence of a foreign element, so the matter should have been referred to arbitration.67 In contrast, the minority favoured an approach in which jurisdictional questions would typically be decided by the arbitrator, especially if possible to do so on documents and pleadings, but that judges should retain discretion to answer such questions when an arbitration agreement’s validity is challenged.68 The minority thought that this would best promote arbitration policy, while preserving the Superior Court’s supervisory jurisdiction. In the result, the minority thought that the courts below had been correct to consider the challenge to the arbitration clause.69 One of the Union’s validity arguments was that hyperlinking the arbitration clause made it “external” within the meaning of art. 1435 CCQ. That article says that an external clause in a consumer or adhesion contract is null “if, at the time of formation of the contract, it was not expressly brought to the attention of the consumer or adhering party, unless the other party proves that the consumer or adhering party otherwise knew of it.” Neither the majority nor the minority accepted this argument: the clause was accessible by a single click, making it no harder to access than a paper contract on which the terms and conditions of sale appeared on the back; this ease of accessibility meant that the clause wasn’t even “external” for the purposes of art. 1435.70 The majority and minority agreed on two other points. On December 14, 2006, the day after Dell Computer was heard and the day that Rogers Wireless was heard, Quebec enacted Bill 48,71 which, among other things, amended its Consumer Protection Act72 by adding s. 11.1: Any stipulation that obliges the consumer to refer a dispute to arbitration, that restricts the consumer’s right to go before a court, in particular by prohibiting the consumer from bringing a class action, or that deprives the consumer of the right to be a member of a group bringing a class action is prohibited.73 Section 11.1 was therefore like the post-Kanitz amendment to Ontario’s Consumer Protection Act, and like it, balanced the legislative response by adding an exception to allow 65 Dell Computer, supra note 46 at para. 84. 66 Ibid. at para. 85. 67 Ibid. at para. 88. 68 Ibid. at paras. 176-178. 69 Ibid. at para. 178. 70 Ibid. at paras. 100-101, 237-240. 71 An act to amend the consumer protection act and the Act respecting the collection of certain debts, S.Q. 2006, c. 56. 72 R.S.Q. c. P-40.1. 73 S.Q. 2006, c. 56, supra note 71, s. 2 (emphasis added). Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 13 post-dispute arbitration clauses.74 The Court sought submissions from the parties in both cases on the effect of this change,75 but concluded, unsurprisingly, that because the facts triggering application of the arbitration clause occurred before s. 11.1 came into force and there was no obvious legislative intent to make its effect retroactive, s. 11.1 did not apply.76 The other point of agreement, and the one perhaps most discouraging for a public-law vision of class actions, centred on art. 2639 CCQ, which says that “[d]isputes over the status and capacity of persons, family matters or other matters of public order may not be submitted to arbitration.” The Court held that while class actions have a social dimension, that doesn’t make them “matters of public order,” a substantive concept. The Court repeated what has become a sort of juristic bromide—viz., a class action “is only a ‘procedural vehicle whose use neither modifies nor creates substantive rights’ and can generally be waived. It is the legislature, and not the courts, that can create exceptions to this.”77 One might have thought that s. 11.1 would have been some evidence of a legislative move away from this narrow understanding of class actions, such as to make them “matters of public order” quite apart from whether s. 11.1 applied retroactively. The Dell Computer facts were sympathetic to the defendant, in that Dumoulin’s order had all the flavour of taking advantage of a sudden vulnerability in Dell’s system. In Rogers Wireless, the facts were rather the other way. There, the Court applied Dell Computer to a class action brought by Dr. Frederick Muroff, a Quebec resident and subscriber to Rogers’ mobile phone service. Canadian subscribers could use their phones in the U.S., subject to roaming charges that, in most states, were 95¢ a minute but in certain “excluded areas” were $4 per minute. The excluded areas included Rhode Island and Maine, where Muroff had made calls for which Rogers had billed him at the $4 rate. The service agreement had an arbitration clause that also expressly prohibited a customer from starting or participating in a class action. Muroff alleged that the arbitration clause was abusive, relying on various evidence, including transcripts of oral examinations of Rogers’ representatives. Without addressing the issue, the trial judge held that the clause deprived her of jurisdiction and referred the matter to arbitration. The Court of Appeal set aside that decision and returned the matter to the Superior Court to first decide the issue of the clause’s validity. From that decision, Rogers appealed to the Supreme Court, where this time, a seven-member panel78 unanimously allowed the appeal. The Court held that, “[f]aced with a challenge to the validity of an arbitration clause that would have required a detailed factual inquiry on a mixed question of law and fact,”79 the trial judge had correctly referred the matter to arbitration. 74 Ibid. (providing that “[i]f a dispute arises after a contract has been entered into, the consumer may then agree to refer the dispute to arbitration”). 75 See the case dockets at <http://www.scc-csc.gc.ca/case-dossier/cms-sgd/dock-regi-eng.aspx?cas=31067> (Dell Computer) and <http://www.scc-csc.gc.ca/case-dossier/cms-sgd/dock-regi-eng.aspx?cas=31383> (Rogers Wireless). 76 Dell Computer, supra note 46 at paras. 116-120, 161-162. 77 Ibid. at paras. 105-110, 226, citing Bisaillon v. Concordia University, [2006] 1 S.C.R. 666, 2006 SCC 19 at par. 17. 78 McLachlin C.J. and Binnie, LeBel, Fish, Abella, Charron and Rothstein JJ. At para. 25, LeBel J. agreed that this was the right result, whether one were to apply the majority or minority judgment in Dell Computer. 79 Rogers Wireless, supra note 47 at para. 20. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 14 Although Dell Computer revolved chiefly on the “architectonics”80 of Civil Code interpretation, it had a swift impact outside Quebec. First, in Frey,81 an action against several mobile phone companies brought under Saskatchewan’s class proceedings statute,82 certain defendants brought stay motions based on Dell Computer and Rogers Wireless. Without actually going through the Dell Computer analysis, Gerein J. concluded that Saskatchewan was bound by these decisions, and amended the certification order to exclude class members who had arbitration clauses in their contracts.83 Customers with contracts lacking arbitration clauses or predating their inclusion were allowed to remain in the certified class. This, comments McGill, “was absurd for all concerned,”84 as it created a multiplicity of proceedings with possibly inconsistent rulings, as well as increased litigation costs (assuming that any of the excluded class members would actually arbitrate). Then, in MacKinnon and Smith, the primary defendant, National Money Mart Co., returned to court to argue that the previously certified actions should now be stayed based on the change in law announced by Dell Computer. In MacKinnon, Brown J. refused the application. Noting the Quebec-specific reasoning in Dell Computer, she also reasoned that she had already decided the issue, and that, while she had a discretion under the doctrine of issue estoppel to reopen the question and stay the action, she found it “difficult to perceive an injustice to Money Mart in having matters determined by the court in one proceeding as opposed to several proceedings before an arbitrator.”85 On appeal, a five-member panel of the British Columbia Court of Appeal disagreed with the first of these conclusions, saying that “the law of British Columbia is not so different from that of Quebec as to justify a departure from Dell in this province.”86 However, it agreed with Brown J.’s reasoning and exercise of discretion on the grounds of issue estoppel.87 In Smith, Perell J. also concluded that the “short answer” was that Dell Computer and Rogers Wireless had not changed the law in Ontario,88 while the “longer answer” is that courts have discretion “to employ or not employ the doctrine of issue estoppel in the interests of justice.”89 In exercising that discretion, any alleged unfairness to defendants must be balanced against potential unfairness to plaintiffs. 80 J.E.C. Brierley and R.A. Macdonald, Quebec Civil Law: An Introduction to Quebec Private Law (Toronto: Edmond Montgomery, 1993) at 102-4 cited in Dell Computer, supra note 46 at para. 14. 81 Frey v. Bell Mobility Inc., [2007] S.J. No. 476 (QL), 2007 SKQB 328, 312 Sask. R. 4 (granting certification on reapplication, with different representative plaintiffs), [2008] S.J. No. 105 (QL), 2008 SKQB 79, 329 Sask. R. 42 (amending certification order to remove class members with arbitration clauses in their agreements), [2010] S.J. Nos. 157-165 (QL), 2010 SKCA 30-38, 83 C.P.C. (6th) 349 (granting partial leave to appeal, but not of the orders removing class members with arbitration agreements) [Frey]. 82 The Class Actions Act, S.S., c. C-12.01. 83 Frey, supra note 81 at 2008 SKQB 79, para. 11 (concluding that “[a] binding arbitration clause removes a dispute from the jurisdiction of a superior court and of necessity precludes participation in a class action”). 84 McGill, supra note 34 at 378. 85 MacKinnon, supra note 43, [2008] B.C.J. No. 1026 at para. 42. 86 Ibid., [2009] B.C.J. No. 468 at para. 72. 87 Ibid. at para. 81. 88 Smith, supra note 43, [2008] O.J. No. 2248 at para. 174. 89 Ibid. at paras. 175-177. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 15 Taking a number of factors into account,90 Perell J., like Brown J., found no unfairness in allowing the class action to continue.91 On appeal, Sharpe J.A., writing for a five-member panel of the Ontario Court of Appeal, concluded that “the loss of the appellants’ right to arbitrate pales into insignificance when measured against the impact that a contrary ruling would have on the respondents.”92 Justice Sharpe also considered: . . . the fact that the appellants appear to lack a genuine interest in arbitration. As the certification judge found, they never seek arbitration when enforcing their own rights and routinely bring court actions against borrowers to enforce the loan agreements. It is difficult to avoid the inference that the appellants insist upon arbitration, not with any serious intention of arbitrating, but simply as a way to defeat the respondents’ class proceeding.93 Accordingly, the Court held that Perell J. had not erred in exercising his discretion in applying issue estoppel, and the class action could continue. The question of whether Dell Computer and Rogers Wireless applied in Ontario was discussed, but not definitively answered.94 Of course, on a go-forward basis, that question is now moot for disputes that fall under the Consumer Protection Act, 2002, as well as those covered by certain other Ontario statutes. But as I will argue in the final section of this paper, these post-Dell Computer decisions have ramifications for the longer-term effects on Canadian class action practice.95 90 Ibid. at para. 181. 91 Perell J.’s reasons comprise 364 paragraphs and cover many issues, including whether ss. 7 and 8 of the Consumer Protection Act, 2002 (see notes 37 to 42, supra and accompanying text) had retroactive effect. I have hardly done justice to them here, but space constraints dictate sending the reader to the decision itself for more information. 92 Smith, supra note 43, [2008] O.J. No. 4327 at para. 49. 93 Ibid. at para. 52. 94 As was the question of the retroactivity of ss. 7 and 8 of the Consumer Protection Act, 2002. 95 As I was nearing the final stages of writing this paper, the Supreme Court of Canada released Seidel v. TELUS Communications Inc., [2011] S.C.J. No. 15 (QL), 2011 SCC 15 [Seidel]. In a 5:4 decision, the Court partially lifted a stay that the B.C. Court of Appeal had imposed on Ms. Seidel’s claim, based on a predispute arbitration clause in her mobile phone contract. Like the Rogers clause, the arbitration clause had a customer purporting to waive rights to participate in a class action and to agree to opt out of any class action commenced against TELUS. Binnie J., writing for the majority, decided that this waiver fell under the umbrella of s. 3 of the Business Practices and Consumer Protection Act, S.B.C. 2004, c. 2 [BPCPA], which said that “any waiver or release by a person of the person’s rights, benefits or protections under this Act is void except to the extent that the waiver or release is expressly permitted by this Act.” Since Seidel had brought some claims under BPCPA s. 172 (e.g., for an injunction against certain practices and for restitution), the stay was lifted in relation to those claims. However, Binnie J. did not depart from the Dell Computer principle that, absent legislation, any challenge to arbitral jurisdiction should first be determined by the arbitrator, unless the challenge involves a pure question of law, or one of mixed fact and law that requires only superficial review of the record: see particularly paras. 29, 42. What he decided was that the question about BPCPA s. 172 was a question of law to be determined on undisputed facts, and therefore properly entertainable by the courts. This meant that Seidel’s other claims (based on common-law or other statutory causes of action) would have to be referred to arbitration. Binnie J. acknowledged that this would lead to bifurcated proceedings, but that this was “consistent with the legislative choice made by British Columbia in drawing the boundaries of s. 172 as narrowly as it did” (para. 50). Lebel and Deschamps J.J., writing for the minority, would have dismissed the appeal altogether and upheld the stay of proceedings. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 16 Legislatively Eliminating or Reducing Liability (Proactive or Preemptive Approach) The next behaviour I will consider is the pursuit of legislation to forestall, eliminate or cap liability. When sought to preclude or frustrate the possibility of a lawsuit, I will call such behaviour proactive or preemptive; when the goal is to reverse a decision in a lawsuit, I will call it reactive or retaliatory. I am deliberately avoiding the words prospective, retrospective or retroactive, which describe the intended legal effect of enactments—the actual effect often being a contested question of statutory interpretation.96 That is because here, I am focusing more on behaviour than effect, though the two are necessarily intertwined. This section addresses proactive or preemptive behaviour; the following section, reactive or retaliatory behaviour. An example of preemptive behaviour in large-scale claims arose in the case of disabled war veterans, for whom the Department of Veterans Affairs (DVA) administered pensions when the veterans were incapable of managing their own money. Instead of investing the money in interest-bearing accounts, the DVA simply cashed the veterans’ cheques and held the money in some 10,000 notional accounts in the Consolidated Revenue Fund. Despite warnings from its own officials and the Auditor General, the government did nothing about the situation until 1990. By then, passage of time and the transfer of some accounts to third party administrators had reduced the number of DVA-managed accounts to about a thousand. At this time, the practice was changed so that the remaining veterans in this group started receiving interest. One of them, Joseph Authorson, disabled by combatrelated mental illness during World War II, became able to manage his money again in 1991 and learned of the non-payment of interest. He sued the government, alleging breach of fiduciary duty and seeking payment of the lost interest. The action was certified with Authorson as class representative. In the Ontario courts, Authorson succeeded on all issues, including the question of whether a fiduciary duty existed and whether it had been breached. But he ultimately lost at the Supreme Court of Canada due to a legislative intervention that had eliminated pre-1990 claims for interest.97 The intervention was s. 5.1(4) of the Department of Veterans Affairs Act,98 added in 1990 as part of an omnibus amending statute.99 With respect to pension monies, it provided 96 There is a presumption that statutes only operate prospectively or immediately; that is, from when they come into force. The Romans phrased this as lex prospicit, non respicit—the law looks forward, not backward. Both retrospectivity and retroactivity derogate from that presumption. A retrospective statute can: (i) impose new results regarding past events; (ii) attach new future consequences to an event occurring before the statute’s enactment; or (iii) create new rights or duties regarding past events. A retroactive statute can: (i) invalidate what was previously valid or vice versa; (ii) affect transactions completed before the statute took force; or (iii) decree that as at a past date the law is deemed to have been that which it was not. In any given statute, it is possible to find all three types of temporal application—prospective, retrospective and retroactive—but clear language is needed to overcome the presumption of prospectivity. For an in-depth treatment, see Ruth Sullivan, Sullivan on the Construction of Statutes, 5th ed. (Markham: LexisNexis, 2008), c. 24. 97 Authorson v. Canada (Attorney General), [2000] O.J. No. 3768 (QL), 53 O.R. (3d) 221 (S.C.J.) (granting plaintiffs’ summary judgment motion and dismissing defendant’s dismissal motion), [2002] O.J. No. 962 (QL), 157 O.A.C. 278, 58 O.R. (3d) 417, 215 D.L.R. (4th) 496, 33 C.C.P.B. 1 (affirming summary judgment), [2003] S.C.J. No. 40 (QL), 2003 SCC 39, [2003] 2 S.C.R. 40 (granting appeal) [Authorson]. 98 Department of Veterans Affairs Act, R.S.C. 1985, c. V-1. 99 An Act to amend the statute law in relation to war veterans, S.C. 1990, c. 43, s. 2 [Bill C-87]. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 17 that “[n]o claim shall be made after this subsection comes into force for or on account of interest on moneys held or administered by the Minister . . . prior to January 1, 1990.”100 The amendment’s brevity belies its long gestation period. The evidence showed that from the 1970s, “group after group of bureaucrats looked at the ‘problem’ of non-payment of interest and potential liability therefor” and that “the senior levels of the DVA must have felt there was a problem, and . . . a potential of liability arising from it.”101 A 1988 internal document had recommended a new system and listed five options to address “old liability”: 1. Let courts settle each case if and when it arises. 2. Keep quiet. Settle case out of court if and when it arises. 3. Devise standard settlement formula, to be used in lieu of old liability, if client agrees. 4. Devise standard settlement formula, to replace old liability, whether client chooses or not (ex post facto). 5. Eliminate old liability (ex post facto).102 For reasons that were never disclosed, but which might be guessed at, ex post facto elimination of liability was the option chosen, resulting in s. 5.1(4). On a motion for judgment, Authorson’s counsel challenged s. 5.1(4) as inoperative under the Canadian Bill of Rights,103 which recognizes, among other things, “the right of the individual to . . . enjoyment of property, and the right not to be deprived thereof except by due process of law” as well as “the right to a fair hearing, in accordance with the principles of fundamental justice for the determination of his rights and obligations.”104 The Bill applies to federal laws, and if a federal statutory provision cannot be interpreted so as not to infringe one of the rights in the Bill, the provision is rendered inoperative unless “expressly declared by an Act of the Parliament of Canada that it shall operate notwithstanding the Canadian Bill of Rights.”105 Both parties agreed that the foregone interest was “property” for the purposes of the Bill, but disagreed on the applicability of the Bill. While there was plenty of argument about what constituted “due process,” Brockenshire J. said it didn’t mean “no process.”106 In 100 Bill C-87 was assented to on December 17, 1990, with s. 64(2) deeming s. 5.1(4) to have come into force on October 12, 1990. Thus “not only [was] the statutory bar made retroactive by 11½ months, the passage of it [was] made retroactive more than a month from the date of the assent to the statute.” Authorson, supra note 97, [2000] O.J. No. 3768 at para. 44. Why October 12, 1990? That was when Bill C-87 was introduced for first reading. See House of Commons Debates, 34th Parliament, 2nd Session, vol. 10 (October 12, 1990) at 14110. Thus retroactive passage precluded anyone from bringing an action between the date the government’s intention became known and the date of assent (that being the default date that statutes come into force). On this rationale for retroactivity, see Beetz J.’s comment in Venne v. Quebec (Commission de la protection du territoire agricole), [1989] S.C.J. No. 32, [1989] 1 S.C.R. 880, 4 R.P.R. (2d) 1 at para. 99. 101 Authorson, ibid. at para. 53. 102 Ibid. at para. 61. 103 Canadian Bill of Rights, S.C. 1960, c. 44, reproduced in R.S.C. 1985, App. III. 104 Ibid., ss. 1(a), 2(e). 105 Ibid., s. 2. 106 Authorson, supra note 97, per Brockenshire J., [2000] O.J. No. 3768 at para. 99. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 18 concluding that there had been neither due process nor a fair hearing, Brockenshire J. was influenced by the Minister’s characterization of the legislation as comprising “housekeeping measures”107 and to his comments when introducing the legislation for second reading: For decades veterans’ affairs has followed ordinary banking practices with regard to administered accounts. The assumption has been that the accounts were like checking accounts. A service was received and the costs of this service was provided through waiving interest on the account. Well times have changed. Financial institutions pay interest on virtually every type of account and Bill C-87 will permit veterans’ affairs to fall into line with modern practice. With the passage of this legislation, veterans’ affairs will pay interest on administered accounts effective January 1, 1990. The interest this year will amount to approximately $3.5 million. That Mr. Speaker, is the type of change I had in mind when I said we want veterans and their dependants to receive 1990’s service and treatment.108 Brockenshire J. thought that what was more important about this statement was what was not said: in particular, no mention was made of the fact that authority had always existed to pay interest but had not previously been used, leading him to conclude that the only purpose of s. 5.1(4) was to bar claims for interest before 1990.109 The Ontario Court of Appeal unanimously agreed and upheld the conclusion that s. 5.1(4) was inoperative,110 as well as Brockenshire J.’s other holdings. By the time Authorson reached the Supreme Court, s. 5.1(4) had crystallized as the issue, with the Crown finally conceding that it had breached its fiduciary duty, but saying that the amendment nevertheless saved it from “old liability.” In a bit of a nose-holding exercise, a seven-member panel111 of the Court agreed, concluding that “s. 5.1(4) takes a property claim from a vulnerable group, in disregard of the Crown’s fiduciary duty to disabled veterans [but] that taking is within the power of Parliament.”112 In particular, “the Bill of Rights does not impose . . . the duty to provide a hearing before the enactment of legislation [and operates] only in the application of law to individual circumstances in a proceeding before a court, tribunal or similar body.”113 Legislatively Eliminating or Reducing Liability (Reactive or Retaliatory Approach) In contrast to preemptive behaviour, which aims to bar claims before they crystallize, retaliatory behaviour aims at shutting claims down after they have already been commenced, and in some cases, reversing liability that has already been adjudged to arise from such claims. One of the most notable Canadian examples of legislative retaliatory behaviour arose in the 1940s, well before modern class actions. But the KVP case—“KVP” stands for 107 Ibid. at para. 65. 108 Ibid. at para. 64 (citing House of Commons Debates, 34th Parliament, 2nd Session, vol. 11 (October 12, 1990) at 15340. 109 Ibid. at paras. 64-66. 110 Authorson, supra note 97, [2002] O.J. No. 962 (QL), paras. 96-124. 111 McLachlin C.J. and Gonthier, Major, Bastarache, Binnie, Arbour and LeBel JJ. 112 Authorson, supra note 97, [2003] S.C.J. No. 40, para. 15. 113 Ibid. at para. 61. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 19 Kalamazoo Vegetable Parchment Company—was certainly a large-scale claim.114 From 1946, KVP made kraft paper in the Ontario town of Espanola, 35 miles upstream from the mouth of the Spanish River, which empties into Lake Huron’s northern channel. In doing so, KVP discharged tons of noxious effluent into the river, permeating the air with a stench of rotting cabbage and killing fish and wild rice that had been habitat for ducks. Downstream riparian owners sued in five actions heard together by McRuer C.J.H.C. They obtained damages and an injunction, which was stayed for six months to give KVP time to implement abatement measures, all of which was upheld by the Supreme Court of Canada in the fall of 1949.115 Although Chief Justice McRuer had rejected KVP’s argument that the jobs it provided justified the pollution, KVP mobilized a major lobbying effort to dissolve the injunction on precisely those grounds. Premier Leslie Frost listened, and five days before the injunction was to take effect, his government passed the requisite legislation with little opposition.116 Its first section read: Whether or not its operation is now stayed, every injunction heretofore granted against the KVP Company, herein called “the Company”, restraining the Company from polluting the waters of the Spanish River, is dissolved.117 Wisely, KVP had not sought to overrule the damages awards against it or to bar future damage claims; it had also agreed to an optional arbitration scheme and to subsidize the Research Council of Ontario for costs of developing methods that might abate the pollution, if implemented. All these features created sufficient political capital for dissolving the injunction and made their way into the statute.118 In essence, the legislative intervention gave KVP a limited licence to pollute, while allowing riparian owners (some of whom had tourist businesses that had been ruined) to “collect the small damage awards the Courts had given them and dutifully apply them to pay part of their legal bills.”119 The pollution continued until the International Joint Commission declared the Lower Spanish River to be an Area of Concern in the mid-1980s, at which point cleanup began in earnest.120 Elizabeth 114 The KVP story is ably told by Elizabeth Brubaker, Property Rights in the Defence of Nature (London and Toronto: Earthscan, 1995), c. 4, “In the Name of the Public Good.” Available through Environment Probe online: <http://www.e-b-i.net/enviroprobe/pridon/>. This section relies on part on Brubaker’s account. 115 McKie v. K.V.P. Co. Ltd. (sub nom K.V.P. Co. Ltd. v. McKie, [1948] O.J. No. 471 (QL), [1948] O.R. 398, [1948] 3 D.L.R. 201 (H.C.J.) (ordering injunction, stay and reference for damages), [1949] 1 D.L.R. 39; [1948] O.W.N. 812 (C.A.) (affirming with variation), [1949] S.C.J. No. 37 (QL), [1949] S.C.R. 698, [1949] 4 D.L.R. 497 (affirming and upholding injunction with six-month stay). 116 The KVP Company Limited Act, 1950, S.O. 1950, c. 33. 117 Ibid., s. 1. 118 Ibid., ss.1(2), 2 (preserving damages claims); s. 3 (arbitration scheme); s. 4 (research costs to be “deemed a debt due by the Company to the Research Council of Ontario”). 119 Friends of the Spanish River, reproducing three articles by Peter Best published in the Mid-North Monitor, online: <http://www.friendsofthespanishriver.ca/KVP%20Trial%20History/kvptrialhistory.htm>. 120 See Brubaker, supra note 114 and 1987 Report on Great Lakes Water Quality, Appendix A: Progress in Developing Remedial Action Plans for Areas of Concern in the Great Lakes Basin (Toledo, Ohio: International Joint Commission) online: <www.ijc.org/php/publications/pdf/ID642.pdf>. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 20 Brubaker, commenting on the KVP saga, adds a postscript: Frost went on to enjoy 11 more years as Ontario’s premier, and on retiring, was appointed to KVP’s board of directors.121 In modern class action experience, a case more remarkable than the KVP saga in terms of legislative intervention is Barbour v. University of British Columbia.122 Since the start of the 1990 academic year, UBC had collected over $4 million in fines and related towing, storage and administrative charges for breaches of UBC’s Parking Regulations. However, these fines and charges had apparently been imposed without legislative authority, and neither the Parking Regulations nor any other UBC policy provided an opportunity for alleged violators to be heard before being deemed guilty or being required to pay fines or fees. In March 2004, chartered accountant Daniel Barbour parked his car at UBC to visit a campus dental clinic. Although the car was legally parked, enforcement officials ordered it towed in an attempt to recover outstanding fines for previous parking violations. Barbour brought a class action in January 2005, seeking restitution of unlawfully collected fines, estimated to average about $40 per class member. Barbour did not challenge UBC’s right to regulate parking on campus or to charge for it, only the associated fines and penalties. The action was certified as a class proceeding in late 2006, and after some preliminary skirmishing over the common issues in 2007, went to trial in 2008.123 In its statement of defence and during the certification process, UBC had contended that its fines were intra vires—that is, within the powers of UBC’s board of governors in the University Act, the governing statute.124 At the start of the trial, though, UBC abandoned that position, and conceded that imposing fines was ultra vires the board’s public-law powers. This concession was hardly surprising, given the similarity of the facts to a Newfoundland case decided some 20 years earlier.125 Instead, UBC argued an alternative submission—that it had private-law justifications for enforcing the Parking Regulations and for collecting and keeping the fines. It also claimed a set-off for unpaid parking services.126 In March 2009, Goepel J. rendered judgment in Barbour’s favour. Regarding UBC’s submissions, Goepel J. agreed that, as a private landowner, UBC could invoke the doctrine 121 Brubaker, ibid. 122 Barbour v. University of British Columbia, [2006] B.C.J. No. 3278 (QL), 2006 BCSC 1897 (granting certification), [2007] B.C.J. No. 1216 (QL), 2007 BCSC 800 (dismissing decertification application and allowing reframing of common issues), [2009] B.C.J. No. 617 (QL), 2009 BCSC 425, 310 D.L.R. (4th) 130, [2009] 10 W.W.R. 323; 94 B.C.L.R. (4th) 139 (allowing action in part), [2009] B.C.J. No. 1572 (QL), 2009 BCCA 334 (granting stay pending appeal and ordering parking fines collected during the stay to be held in trust), [2010] B.C.J. No. 219 (QL), 2010 BCCA 63, 83 C.P.C. (6th) 1, 2 B.C.L.R. (5th) 240 (reversing, based on post-trial legislation), [2010] S.C.C.A. No. 135 (QL) (refusing leave to appeal) [Barbour]. 123 This paragraph’s facts are from the statement of claim (online: <http://www.cfmlawyers.ca/class_actions/ UBCWritofSummonsaandStatementofClaim.htm>); Barbour, ibid., [2006] B.C.J. No. 3278; and Brett Wittmeier, “UBC to appeal parking fines decision” The Globe and Mail (April 1, 2009) online: <www.theglobeandmail.com/news/national/ubc-to-appeal-parking-fines-decision/article764379/print>. 124 University Act, R.S.B.C. 1996, c. 468. 125 Keough v. Memorial University of Newfoundland, [1980] N.J. No. 185 (QL); 26 Nfld. & P.E.I.R. 386 (Nfld. S.C.T.D.) 126 The facts in this paragraph are from Barbour, supra note 122, [2009] B.C.J. No. 617 at paras. 8, 25-26. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 21 of distress damage feasant to impound and hold vehicles parked in contravention of the Parking Regulations; he also acknowledged that a liberal interpretation could be given to “damage,” including impeding or obstructing traffic, parking in a prohibited area, or even parking in an allowed area but without having paid a parking fee. This meant that UBC could charge reasonable fees for towing and storage and hold vehicles until payment of such fees. But it did not mean that UBC could also levy a fine, nor could it tow a lawfully parked vehicle because of a past offence or refuse to release an impounded vehicle until past fines had been paid. In the result, Goepel J. held the Parking Regulation fines ultra vires and ordered restitution, subject to appropriate deductions for towing and storage fees.127 After the trial judgment, a stay was granted pending an expedited appeal. Meanwhile, the BC Legislature moved with sudden expedition, amending the section of the University Act dealing with a board’s powers, repealing and replacing another section, and enacting transitional provisions.128 The transitional provisions defined the term pre-amendment provision to mean any of the previously suspect provisions—e.g., the power “to impose and collect penalties, including fines, in relation to a contravention of a rule or other instrument made in the exercise of a power”129—and decreed as follows: Despite any pre-amendment provision and despite any decision of a court to the contrary made before or after the coming into force of this section, if a rule, bylaw or other instrument made under a preamendment provision is authorized under [the relevant sections of the amended University Act]: (a) the rule, bylaw or other instrument is conclusively deemed to be valid for all purposes, (b) all actions taken under the rule, bylaw or other instrument are conclusively deemed to be valid including, without limitation, (i) the collection of a fee, (ii) the removal, immobilization or impoundment of a vehicle in contravention of the rule, including for failure to pay a fee levied under the rule, bylaw or other instrument, and (iii) the imposition of a penalty, including a fine, for failure to pay a fee levied under the rule, bylaw or other instrument, and (c) no refund, restitution or other compensation may be paid in respect of fees or penalties, including fines, collected under the rule, bylaw or other instrument.130 In other words, the amendments retroactively gave UBC lawful authority to collect the fines and prohibited it from making the restitution ordered by Goepel J. Lest any doubt be left as to the intended effect, the legislation also stipulated that it was “retroactive to the extent necessary to give full force and effect to its provisions and must not be construed as lacking retroactive effect in relation to any matter by reason that it makes no specific reference to that matter.”131 127 Ibid. at paras. 53-56, 80. 128 Miscellaneous Statutes Amendment Act, 2009, S.B.C. 2009, c. 22. 129 Ibid., s. 12 (repealing and substituting s. 27(2)(t) of the University Act with new provisions). 130 Ibid., s. 16(2) (emphasis added). 131 Ibid., s. 16(3) (emphasis added). Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 22 The legislation came into force on October 29, 2009,132 a month before the appeal hearing. At that hearing, class counsel put on a brave face, arguing that UBC ought not to be able to withdraw its concession made at the outset of trial. Counsel also argued that the amendments: (i) could not resurrect the Parking Regulations, which, having been declared ultra vires, no longer existed when the amendments came into force; (ii) should be interpreted so as not to violate the principle of judicial independence; and (iii) could not breach rules of natural justice.133 Counsel called in aid a number of authorities, including the International Bar Association’s Minimum Standards of Judicial Independence, which provides that “the Legislature shall not pass legislation which retroactively reverses specific court decisions.”134 However, the Court of Appeal said that, in Canada, examples of precisely this sort of thing “abound,”135 and that “[w]hile a Legislature may not interfere with the Court’s adjudicative role, it may amend the law which the court is required to apply in its adjudication.”136 The Court allowed the appeal and set aside Goepel J.’s order; an application for leave to appeal to the Supreme Court of Canada was dismissed with costs.137 The postscript: in June 2010, pursuant to the new legislation, UBC’s board of governors approved new parking rules.138 Legalizing or Regulating Previously Illegal or Unlawful Conduct In Barbour, the amending legislation had both retroactive and prospective effect: it operated backwards to legalize behaviour that a court had declared illegal, but also operated forwards to give universities powers to do what they had previously lacked authority to do. In this section, I will focus on behaviour specifically targeted to the second effect. Notwithstanding the B.C. Court of Appeal’s assurance that instances of retroactive legislation “abound,” prospective legislation is, of course, the more common form. In particular, I will refer to federal and provincial legislative changes prompted by the litigation against payday lenders. Both the litigation and the legislation raise compelling questions as to whether any meaningful behaviour modification has been achieved in the area of payday lending. A payday loan is a short-term loan for a small sum (on average, about $300), secured only by a post-dated cheque, pre-authorized debit or similar future payment, to be repaid with interest and fees on the borrower’s next payday.139 Historically, the effective annual 132 Ibid., s. 99 (row 1 of table, date of Royal Assent specified as the coming-into-force date). 133 Barbour, supra note 122, [2010] B.C.J. No. 219 at para. 10. 134 Ibid. at para. 28, citing IBA Minimum Standards for Judicial Independence (International Bar Association, 1982) online: <http://www.ibanet.org/Document/Default.aspx?DocumentUid=BB019013-52B1-427C-AD25A6409B49FE29> at para. 19. 135 Ibid. at para. 30 (noting its use in tax cases in particular). 136 Ibid. at para. 32. 137 Barbour, supra note 122, [2010] S.C.C.A. No. 135. 138 UBC Traffic and Parking Rules, online: <http://www.universitycounsel.ubc.ca/guidelines/ UBC_Traffic_and_Parking_Rules.pdf>. 139 Capping Borrowing Costs: A Balanced Approach to Payday Loans in Ontario—Report of the Maximum Total Cost of Borrowing Advisory Board for the Ontario Payday Lending Industry (Ontario Ministry of Consumer Services, February 2009) [Ontario Advisory Board Report] online: <http://www.sse.gov.on.ca/mcs/Documents/ 264305.pdf> at 7. For a similar definition, see Andrew Kitching and Sheena Starky, Payday Loan Companies in Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 23 interest rate for these loans was capped at 60% by s. 347 of the Criminal Code.140 To avoid s. 347, payday lenders often set interest rates at 59%,141 but charged fees (e.g., for cheque cashing, non-sufficient funds on the post-dated cheque, or extending the loan when not repaid on time) that took effective annual percentage rates (APRs) well beyond that, even into the three- or four-digit range and higher.142 For instance, in one case, for a $100 loan, the lender purported to charge a $21 late fee, a $200 returned items fee, and a $400 administrative fee, resulting in a 782% annual interest rate,143 assuming the aggregate of these charges count as “interest,” an assumption that payday lenders would contest. The lenders, who operate both in storefronts and online and go by names like Money Mart, Cash Store and Cash Now, are considered ‘non-traditional,’ ‘alternative’ or ‘fringe’ lenders—in contrast with ‘mainstream’ lenders such as banks, trust companies and credit unions. On one view, payday lending is predatory and “feeds off poverty and financial exclusion.”144 On another view, it provides a service to consumers who would not otherwise be able to get credit.145 There may be elements of truth to both views. Payday lending has been likened to taking a taxi between cities: convenient in an emergency, but prohibitively expensive if done over the long term.146 The long-term effects are discussed in one panCanadian study on insolvency filings, in which the researchers found that some borrowers owed as much as $22,000 to payday lenders (often as a result of “rollovers,” the extending of Canada: Determining the Public Interest (Ottawa: Library of Parliament, January 2006) online: <http:// www2.parl.gc.ca/content/lop/researchpublications/prb0581-e.html> [Payday Loan Companies in Canada]. 140 The Criminal Code, R.S.C. 1985, c. C-46, creates two offences: s. 347(1)(a) makes it an indictable offence to enter an agreement to receive a criminal rate of interest; s. 347(1)(b) makes it a summary offence to receive such interest. Section 347(2) defines a criminal rate as one exceeding 60% per annum and interest as the “aggregate of all charges and expenses . . . paid or payable for the advancing of credit under an agreement or arrangement . . . but does not include any repayment of credit advanced or any insurance charge, official fee, overdraft charge, required deposit balance . . .” 141 See, e.g., Orangehen.com v. Collins, [2009] O.J. No. 5160 (Sm. Cl. Ct.), RC Recyling Inc. (c.o.b. Cash 4001) v. Sawicki, [2010] O.J. No. 71 (Sm. Cl. Ct.), Loans Till Payday v. Brereton, [2010] O.J. No. 5176, 2010 ONSC 6610, Loans Till Payday v. Brown, [2010] O.J. No. 5184, 2010 ONSC 6639. See also Ontario Advisory Board Report, supra note 139 at 9 (noting Money Mart’s practice of charging 59% plus $9.99 per transaction, plus a cheque-cashing fee of 7.99% of the principal plus interest). 142 See, e.g., Stephanie Ben-Ishai, “Regulating Payday Lenders in Canada: Drawing on American Lessons” (2008) 23 B.F.L.R. 323 at 326 and CanPayday.ca, “That will be 1132% Interest Please” and accompanying payday loan calculator, online: <http://www.canpayday.ca/payday-loan-canada.aspx>. 143 Orangehen.com v. Collins, supra note 141. See also Payday Loan Companies in Canada, supra note 139, Tables 1, 2. 144 Henry Palmer, Profiting from Poverty: Why Debt is Big Business in Britain (London: New Economics Foundation, 2002) online: <http://www.neweconomics.org/sites/neweconomics.org/files/ Profiting_from_Poverty.pdf>. at 1, cited in Ben-Ishai, supra note 142 at 327. 145 Both arguments are canvassed by Ben-Ishai, supra, note 142 at 325-330. 146 On the taxi metaphor, see Ruth E. Berry and Karen A. Duncan, “The Importance of Payday Loans in Canadian Consumer Insolvency” (Ottawa: Office of the Superintendent of Bankruptcy, October 2007) online: <http://www.ic.gc.ca/eic/site/bsf-osb.nsf/eng/h_br01667.html> at 16. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 24 a loan when not repaid on time) and some held up to 12 payday loans, making the situation “severe for many consumers who choose to use this financial alternative.”147 This situation went unchecked for many years, though not without alarms being sounded and not without some abortive attempts at regulation having been taken.148 The advent of class proceedings legislation, though, brought the matter to the fore: where it could be shown that s. 347 had been violated, there was a classic access-to-justice scenario in the sense of allowing plaintiffs’ lawyers to aggregate claims that were too small to litigate individually. Class actions could also promote judicial economy; perhaps they could even modify lender behaviour! But the class action momentum also prompted threats of a bankruptcy backlash, as evidenced by this comment in a 2006 parliamentary research report: Should the payday loans industry not be regulated, the future of payday lenders may ultimately be determined not by governments but by a number of class action suits currently proceeding through Canadian courts. These lawsuits claim that consumers were charged in excess of the Criminal Code rate, and seek to recover hundreds of millions of dollars’ worth of interest. Should these civil lawsuits succeed, they could potentially bankrupt the payday loans industry.149 The report was apparently influenced by submissions of the Canadian Payday Loan Association (CPLA), a payday lender group.150 In 2005, the CPLA had updated its Code of Best Business Practices to oblige its members to follow guidelines regarding such things as rollovers, multiple loans and complaints; however, the only recourse for non-compliance was loss of CPLA membership, leading the CPLA itself to call for government regulation.151 The payday loan story, then, followed a familiar path for beleaguered businesses: first, deflect criticism with alternative accounts of the criticized activity (e.g., ‘service provider’ versus ‘predator’); second, if that fails, self-regulate; third, when that doesn’t work and government regulation seems inevitable, embrace regulation and turn it to one’s advantage.152 147 Ibid. For a recent study in the U.S. based on one lender’s data, see Paige Marta Skiba and Jeremy Tobacman, “Do Payday Loans Cause Bankruptcy?” Vanderbilt Law and Economics Research Paper No. 11-13 (February 23, 2011) online: <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1266215>. Using a discontinuity in the lender’s data between barely approved and barely rejected loan applications, and matching that data with publicly available bankruptcy filings, the researchers concluded that Chapter 13 bankruptcy petitions doubled within two years of a successful first-time payday loan application, with the effects stronger among minorities, women and homeowners. Skiba and Tobacman also found that getting approved for one payday loan resulted in extended further use of such loans—on average, 5.1 more loans than rejected first-time applicants over the next 12 months. 148 For a summary, see Ben-Ishai, supra, note 142. 149 Payday Loan Companies in Canada, supra note 139 at note 19. 150 The submissions appear to have been made in the context of consultations by the Consumer Measures Committee (CMC) Working Group on the Alternative Consumer Credit Market, a consortium of federal and provincial departments responsible for consumer affairs: ibid., note 15 and accompanying text. 151 Ibid., notes 10-13 and accompanying text. 152 See, e.g., M. David Ermann and Richard J. Lundman, Corporate and Governmental Deviance: Problems of Organizational Behavior in Contemporary Society, 6th ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002) at 27-36 (on such reactions generally) and David R. Simon, Elite Deviance, 9th ed. (Boston: Pearson, 2008) at 32-33 (on embracing regulation particularly, e.g., when it eliminates marginal firms or helps block entry of new ones). Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 25 And so it was that payday lenders were “rescued”153 from criminalization and bankruptcy by a now-familiar process of cooperative federalism. The first step in that process was the addition of s. 347.1 to the Criminal Code. Subsection 347.1(1) preserved the definition of interest in s. 347154 and also defined “payday loan,”155 while s. 347.1(2) provided that: Section 347 and section 2 of the Interest Act do not apply to a person, other than a financial institution within the meaning of paragraphs (a) to (d) of the definition ‘financial institution’ in section 2 of the Bank Act, in respect of a payday loan agreement entered into by the person to receive interest, or in respect of interest received by that person under the agreement, if (a) the amount of money advanced under the agreement is $1,500 or less and the term of the agreement is 62 days or less; (b) the person is licensed or otherwise specifically authorized under the laws of a province to enter into the agreement; and (c) the province is designated under subsection (3).156 Subsections 347.1(3) and (4) provided for the governor-in-council to work with lieutenant governors-in-council to designate provinces that have legislation to protect payday loan recipients, and to revoke such designations where the legislation is no longer in force. Although s. 347.1 was not made retroactive, it immediately created a protected niche market for loans up to $1500 and less than two months duration. All that remained was to secure the necessary provincial legislation and to settle the class actions for past claims. The provincial legislation contemplated by s. 347.1 was introduced and gradually came into force over the next three years, with two notable exceptions which I will come to below. The legislative initiatives, as of 2008, are summarized by Stephanie Ben-Ishai in a comprehensive article on payday lending regulation.157 Of greater interest here, though, is the lobbying behind that effort. One of the most contentious points was the information that lenders would have to disclose on the cost of borrowing. PIAC, the Public Interest Advocacy Centre, was a vociferous proponent of requiring disclosure of the effective annual percentage rate (APR),158 as were a number of other organizations. Lenders, on the other hand, favoured a total-cost-of-borrowing approach, on the basis that this was easier for consumers to understand and was already the approach taken for credit agreements in certain consumer protection laws.159 In the end, this was the approach that prevailed in Ontario. The board charged with advising the provincial government put it this way: 153 John D. McCamus, “Liquidated Damages and the Criminal Rate of Interest: More Unintended Consequences of Section 347” (2010) 25 B.F.L.R. 229 at 231. 154 For a synopsized version of the definition, see note 140, supra. 155 Viz., “an advancement of money in exchange for a post-dated cheque, a pre-authorized debit or a future payment of a similar nature but not for any guarantee, suretyship, overdraft protection or security on property and not through a margin loan, pawnbroking, a line of credit or a credit card.” 156 An Act to amend the Criminal Code (criminal interest rate), S.C. 2007, c. 9, s. 2. 157 Ben-Ishai, supra, note 142. 158 See the many documents available on PIAC’s website, online: <http://www.piac.ca/financial>. 159 See, e.g., Consumer Protection Act, 2002, supra note 37, O. Reg. 17/05, s. 56. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 26 The media often report that the industry charges astronomical interest rates. For example, a $100 loan for a fee of $20 would represent an annual percentage rate of 20 per cent if the term is one year. But the annual percentage rate balloons to 520 per cent, uncompounded, when the term is two weeks, as is normally the case with payday loans. Expressing the cost of a small, short-term loan on an annualized basis makes no more sense than expressing the cost of a night in a hotel on a yearly basis. At $200 per night, a hotel room would cost more than $73,000 for a full year – a sum no one would ever pay because no one would take a room at the nightly rate for a full year – which is the point.160 Relying on a report by Ernst & Young and on StatsCan data, the board concluded that the average cost of a payday loan for a lender was $21.50161 and that the industry was “not making exorbitant profits.”162 Hence the board recommended an upper limit on the total cost of borrowing at $21 per $100 borrowed.163 PIAC responded by calling the report “a gift to payday lenders at the expense of Ontario’s most vulnerable consumers” and noted that “[a] $300 loan [i.e., the average size loan] at this rate would cost $63 and if it were payable in 10 days, that would be an annual percentage rate of over 766%.”164 Ontario accepted the recommendation, though, and implemented the $21 cap in regulations under its new payday loan legislation.165 Alberta adopted a $23 cap but also required APR disclosure.166 160 Ontario Advisory Board Report, supra note 139 at 14. 161 Ibid. at 15-16. 162 Ibid. at 17. Compare Smith, supra note 43, [2010] O.J. No. 873 at para. 64 (finding Money Mart, the market leader, to be “highly profitable,” with a 2007 net income in Ontario alone of $64.34 million). 163 Ibid. at 19. 164 PIAC, “Proposed Ontario Payday Loan Rate Astronomically High” (February 6, 2009) online: <http://www.piac.ca/financial/proposed_ontario_payday_loan_rate_astronomically_high>. 165 See Payday Loans Act, 2008, S.O. 2008, c. 9 s. 1 (defining “cost of borrowing”), s. 32(2) (requiring that payday loan agreement not exceed the cost of borrowing) and O. Reg. 98/09, s. 15(2) (capping cost of borrowing at $21 per $100 advanced). 166 Payday Loans Regulation, Alta. Reg. 157/2009, ss. 17 and 20(2). This regulation was enacted pursuant to Alberta’s Fair Trading Act, R.S.A. 2000, c. F-2. Both provinces require advertising the information for a twoweek, $300 loan, such that on one national payday lender’s website, the information reads as follows: Repayment Disclosures Alberta: Maximum charges permitted in Alberta for a payday loan: $23 per $100 lent National Money Mart Company charges $23 per $100 lent For a $300 loan for 14 days: Total Cost of Borrowing = $69 Annual Percentage Rate = 599.64% Ontario: The Maximum Allowable Cost per $100 Borrowed: $21 Our Cost per $100 Borrowed: $21 For a $300 loan for 14 days: Amount Advanced: $300 Total Cost of Borrowing: $63 Total to Repay: $363 Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 27 Most other provinces followed suit. However, Quebec will grant licences to payday lenders only if they charge less than a 35% APR,167 meaning that none now legally operate in the province. And Newfoundland and Labrador decided, “[a]fter significant research and careful consideration,” not to regulate payday lenders, but to rely on the 60% cap in the Criminal Code.168 Said Kevin O’Brien, Minister of Government Services: [W]e could not in good conscience implement regulations that potentially could result in annual interest rates equating to nearly 550 per cent being charged to consumers in our province . . . . We do not want individuals being gouged or putting themselves more in debt and having a hard time catching up because of high interest rates for these types of short-term loans. We have reviewed . . . the Criminal Code of Canada, as well as regulations of other provinces and territories for payday lenders, and have decided that payday loan companies in this province will continue to be subject to section 347 of the Criminal Code of Canada.169 The next step in the process was to settle the payday lending litigation, most of which was accomplished last year. The basic settlement structure has been to provide: (i) debt forgiveness for unpaid loans; (ii) transaction credits, or vouchers, for future business; and (iii) fees to class counsel. I will focus on the Money Mart settlement, particularly the decision of Ontario’s Perell J., in which the two types of class members are called the “Debt Forgiveness Group” and the “Transaction Credit Group.”170 Justice Perell’s 142-paragraph judgment is a tour-de-force review of settlement approval law and a candid account of the difficult task that judges face in this area. He approved the settlement, but not without a muted sense of outrage over certain aspects of the case, particularly relating to behaviour modification, and not without making a variation in the settlement terms that significantly improved benefits to class members at the expense of class counsel. Justice Perell began by noting the extensive pre-settlement litigation, commenting that “[i]t is to do injustice to the notion of understatement to say that [the case] has been hard fought.”171 Indeed, it was not until the case had already gone halfway through trial See National Money Mart Company, online: https://loans.moneymart.ca/repayment-disclosures.aspx. This is a secure web page that cannot be accessed directly, but can be reached by through the Pricing tab on Money Mart’s website, then clicking on the Disclosure hyperlink at the bottom of the page. 167 Ben-Ishai, supra, note 142, explains that this arises from court interpretations of Quebec’s Consumer Protection Act, supra note 72, s. 8 (nullity of unconscionable contracts) and s. 325 (ability of the president of the Office de la protection du consommateur to refuse a permit to a merchant who contracts to lend money). 168 Government of Newfoundland and Labrador, “Provincial Government Will Not Regulate Payday Loan Companies” (June 16, 2010) online: <http://www.releases.gov.nl.ca/releases/2010/gs/0616n11.htm>. 169 Ibid. This press release was issued just three weeks after a settlement reached with Money Mart in Newfoundland and Labrador, New Brunswick and Nova Scotia (apparently, a simultaneous settlement and certification, which, though unreported, is summarized in the class action notice on Money Mart’s website: http://www.moneymart.ca/paydayloans/Notice%20of%20Settlement.pdf). 170 Smith, supra note 43, [2010] O.J. No. 873. 171 Ibid. at para. 11. “Among other things, there were two motions to stay the action, a certification motion, a decertification motion, and a motion for summary judgment. Many issues were litigated, and some were relitigated. There was one leave application to the Divisional Court, four appeals to the Court of Appeal, and three leave applications to the Supreme Court of Canada. There were 39 orders, 12 endorsements, and 4 judgments. Eventually, the action was called to trial in April 2009, and there were 17 days of trial before Justice Spies. That trial has been adjourned pending the outcome of the motion now before the court.” Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 28 before Spies J. when intensive mediation sessions finally resulted in a settlement.172 The coming into force of Ontario’s payday loans legislation173 at the time was purportedly crucial: class counsel said that until then, they couldn’t recommend any settlement that would let Money Mart continue marketing allegedly illegal contracts, while Money Mart’s counsel said their client wouldn’t settle on any basis that barred it from carrying on business as usual.174 Justice Perell could not help but observe the irony in this. He noted that the allegedly illegal fees had been the class action’s “rallying point,”175 and that counsel had put forth one of the plaintiffs’ transactions as an example: a $100 cash advance, secured by a postdated cheque for $119.18, comprising the principal ($100), a 59% finance charge for 9 days ($1.14), a cheque-cashing fee ($5.05), and an item fee ($12.99). Assuming all of this to be “interest” per s. 347 of the Criminal Code, it yielded a typically astronomical APR.176 Yet as Justice Perell commented, this business model “is apparently now legal in the Province of Ontario and indeed Money Mart can charge . . . an additional $2.”177 It was “interesting and informative,” he thought, “that, unlike most settlement approval and certification motions, there was not a peep about behaviour modification, and there was little about access to justice.”178 Indeed, despite counsel asserting that the settlement was excellent, he found it “hard to paint [it] as a success” and concluded that “there is no behaviour modification in this class action.”179 There were, though, factors favouring approval, not the least of which was that in the event of a large judgment, Money Mart and its parent, Dollar Financial Group, could have instituted insolvency proceedings in Canada and the U.S.; indeed, as I will note in the next section, such legislatively assisted “reorganizations” are always a backdrop to highstakes litigation, and in this case, were not only possible, but likely, due to the terms on which the defendants had secured financing.180 This factor, plus the risk associated with litigation of this magnitude and the recommendation of a respected mediator who was apprised of each side’s risks and the hard-fought negotiations,181 led Perell J. to approve the settlement. However, he was concerned with the Transaction Credit Group—class members who had repaid their loans and had no debt to “forgive.” Under the proposal, they would have received prorated shares of $30 million worth of transaction credits, each worth $5, and 172 Ibid. at para. 58. The mediator was former Supreme Court of Canada Justice Frank Iacobucci. 173 Supra note 165. 174 Smith, supra note 43, [2010] O.J. No. 873 at para. 56. 175 Ibid. at para. 94. 176 Ibid. at paras. 37-38. According to the case, this yielded an APR of 123,060%, if all charges were classified as “interest.” But the payday loan calculator, supra note 142, calculates the APR as (merely?) 778%. 177 Ibid. at para. 55. 178 Ibid. at para. 98. 179 Ibid. at para. 98-99. 180 Ibid. at paras. 60-63. 181 See note 172. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 29 a prorated share of whatever cash might be left after paying class counsel’s fee.182 One of the two registered objectors to the settlement, Guy Laporte, commented on these credits: [The defendants] still get away with a lot of money that they do not have to repay and with a maximum credit of $5 per transaction how long is it going to take me to use up all my credit that they will owe me!? This does not make sense. I do not want to use Money Mart services ever again. I do not want credits! I want an apology, and I want a refund of some of the money that they stole from us by overcharging us interest. That would be justice!183 Justice Perell agreed, concluding that the transaction credits were “a business promotion for more payday loans,”184 though he doubted there would be much take-up.185 But a problem, not always appreciated commentators, is that judges have little or no power, beyond their ability to exert moral suasion, to impose a change in the terms of a civil settlement. Settlements between private parties are heavily negotiated and carefully crafted, and the general rule is that courts will give a settlement a yea or a nay, but won’t rewrite the parties’ bargain. Here, though, Perell J. saw a window for variation because of the way counsel fees had been worked into the settlement. Unlike other terms, counsel fees are not only reviewable, but must be reviewed in cases that require settlement approval, such as class actions. The proposed class counsel fee, $27.5 million, was to be a first charge on settlement proceeds, the balance to be distributed as cash credits to the Transaction Credit Group.186 But the likelihood of there being any cash to distribute after paying this fee was very low.187 Justice Perell therefore looked closely at the fee—as he was bound to do anyway—and concluded there was room to shave it back. A $13 million shave, in fact. That brought the approved counsel fee to $14.5 million, “all-inclusive,”188 which Perell J. still thought sufficed for the risk taken, and still provided a healthy incentive over the “not bargain-basement hourly rates” of the counsel involved.189 By this means, Perell J. was able to respond to Mr. Laporte’s objection and direct some cash to the Debt Forgiveness Group. I would be remiss if I did not mention a field study done while the payday lending litigation was ongoing. In March 2008, Osgoode Hall law professor Stephanie Ben-Ishai sent two research students incognito into the stores of payday lenders in Toronto. The timing was such that cost-of-borrowing disclosure requirements were already in place under prior consumer legislation,190 and the Ontario legislation specific to payday lenders was about to 182 Smith, supra note 43, [2010] O.J. No. 873 at para. 14. 183 Ibid. at para. 72 (excerpt of email from Guy Laporte). 184 Ibid. at para. 196. 185 Ibid. at para. 105. 186 Ibid. at para. 90. 187 Ibid. at para. 94. 188 There had been some significant costs orders for the plaintiffs on prior motions in the litigation, which had already been paid and which Perell J. took into account. 189 Ibid. at para. 129. Counsel’s regular rates came to about $10 million. The “not bargain-basement rates” ranged from $261 to $808 per hour: ibid. at para. 78. Costs awards on prior motions were about $1 million. Therefore, the risk premium (approved fees minus costs and regular counsel hours) was about $3.5 million. 190 See note 159, supra and accompanying text. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 30 be introduced. The researchers posed as would-be borrowers wanting to get information about loan costs, as well as such things as whether rollovers were permitted. They asked their questions in a way that an actual borrower might ask—e.g., “How much does it cost to borrow?” “What if I can’t pay the loan back?”—and recorded the results of their enquiries.191 The researchers concluded that the lenders generally complied with the statutory disclosure obligations, though they differed greatly in how they explained them, in some cases, exhibiting much adroitness, using terms like “optional” or “convenience” fees for loans repaid on one’s payday, as opposed to the day before.192 In two cases, the researchers were able to get loan applications; one of these included a wage assignment that appeared to violate Ontario law. Two of the lenders expressly said on their websites that rollovers weren’t permitted (one of the CPLA stipulations in its Code of Best Business Practices), but in the storefront settings, the same lenders told the researchers they could get back-to-back loans or that something could be worked out if they couldn’t repay in time. One of the students concluded that, by the end of the study, she “found it very difficult to determine how much the loan would ultimately cost me” and that her confusion would likely be compounded for a person faced with “getting the money now” to pay for groceries or avoid eviction.193 Given the importance of this topic, and given that payday-specific legislation has now been in existence for some time, it might be fruitful for a similar study to be redone to see whether payday lender behaviour has changed in any meaningful way since 2008. Frustrating the Ability of the Class to Collect a Remedy or Counsel to Collect a Fee In addition to enacting private legislation such as pre-dispute arbitration clauses or seeking post-dispute legislative solutions to liability, defendants can use existing legislation to frustrate plaintiffs’ ability to collect a remedy. Again, just as successful use of a private-law measure like arbitration depends on an external mechanism like a statutory stay provision, so do private-law arrangements interact with existing legislation in complex ways. Such is the case with insolvency proceedings generally, and with the Money Mart case in particular. The defendants, National Money Mart Company and Dollar Financial Group Inc., were related, with Dollar Financial effectively controlling Money Mart.194 The evidence was that the enterprise had long-term debt of US$574 million and current liabilities of US$105 million, and that this debt was secured by the enterprise’s assets under agreements stipulating that if there was a final judgment over US$15 million against either of the companies that remained unpaid after 30 days, creditors could seize assets, cut off credit, and demand repayment.195 Thus, the practical result of a judgment in the expected range of 191 Ben-Ishai, supra note 142 at 344-350. 192 Ibid. at 348. 193 Ibid. at 350. 194 Dollar Financial Group Inc. is affiliated with publicly traded Dollar Financial Corp (DLLR: NASDAQ:GS). It is the sole shareholder of DFG International, Inc., which is the sole shareholder of National Money Mart Company: Smith, supra note 43, [2010] O.J. No. 873 at para. 7. 195 Ibid. at paras. 62-63. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 31 $150 million would have been to prompt proceedings under the CCAA196 in Canada and bankruptcy proceedings in the U.S.—with any recovery occurring far into the future and for a fraction of the judgment.197 Not only was this a powerful extra incentive to settle, but the settlement was structured largely to avoid the kind of default events that could trigger creditors’ rights. Hence the settlement’s use of transaction credits, which can be treated under accounting rules as future incentives rather than current liabilities.198 The point here is that a target’s ability to invoke insolvency legislation may tend to defeat both access to justice and behaviour modification in a specific case, as well as giving class counsel cause for sober second thought when deciding to take on cases in a more general sense. If the prospect of a defendant’s insolvency is likely to dampen the ardour of plaintiffs’ lawyers to take on a class action, the possibility of not earning a fee after a successful outcome is likely to kill it entirely. This is not usually an issue, because class proceedings legislation creates a statutory first charge for counsel fees on a settlement or judgment. For example, Ontario’s CPA says in s. 32(3) that “[a]mounts owing under an enforceable agreement are a first charge on any settlement funds or monetary award.” But in Hislop v. Canada (Attorney General),199 the first successful class action under the Charter,200 this same provision was defeated by a federal provision that was determined to be paramount. The essential facts of the case were that under various provisions of the Canada Pension Plan (“CPP”),201 the Hislop class had been denied survivors’ pensions because they were the same sex as their deceased partners. The plaintiffs successfully challenged this discrimination under s. 15(1) of the Charter, but in creating a remedy, the Supreme Court of Canada decided not to interfere with a CPP section of general application that limits pension benefit arrears to the 12 months preceding a survivor’s application. Thus eligible class members became prospectively entitled to the full pension, but retroactively entitled to a maximum of only 12 months’ benefits. After succeeding at trial, the plaintiff’s counsel group (“PCG”), seven law firms across the country who had taken on the case, had applied for approval of their retainer agreement, on notice to the class. Justice Ellen Macdonald, the trial judge, approved the fee with a 4.8 multiplier for all hours in connection with the action, other than time spent on administrative issues, subject to undertakings that PCG had given about amounts they would seek to charge; in particular, PCG undertook not to pursue its statutory first charge for post- 196 Companies’ Creditors Arrangement Act, R.S.C. 1985, c. C-36. 197 Ibid. at paras. 63-64. 198 Ibid. at para. 66. 199 Hislop v. Canada (Attorney General), [2007] S.C.J. No. 10 (QL), 2007 SCC 10, [2007] 1 S.C.R. 429, 278 D.L.R. (4th) 385 (merits), [2008] O.J. No. 793 (QL), 2008 CanLII 8248 (determining interest rates and deciding on class counsel’s entitlement to a first charge on arrears), [2009] O.J. No. 1756 (QL), 2009 ONCA 354, 95 O.R. (3d) 81, 248 O.A.C. 205 (affirmed), [2009] S.C.C.A. No. 264 (leave to appeal refused) [Hislop]. 200 Canadian Charter of Rights and Freedoms, Part I, Constitution Act, 1982, enacted as Schedule B to the Canada Act 1982, (U.K.) 1982, c. 11. 201 Canada Pension Plan, R.S.C. 1985, c. C-8. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 32 judgment arrears, and to seek a maximum of 50% of pre-judgment arrears.202 PCG considered this a voluntary limit on its statutory first charge, and the approval was supported by the representative plaintiffs, with no objections from class members. After the conclusion of appeals at the Supreme Court, the case went back to Macdonald J. on two issues: calculation of interest and PCG’s entitlement to a first charge. Most of the judgment is taken up with the interest rates to be charged and the manner of calculation; my focus here, though, is on the portion of the decision dealing with the first charge on counsel fees. Based on docketed hours, PCG’s base fees had by then totaled some $5.3 million. PCG had also obtained a $2 million costs award that it was able to apply to unpaid fees, and the government had agreed to pay PCG a further $2 million by deducting it from the interest owing to the class. But the government took the position that CPP s. 65, which says that “[a] benefit shall not be assigned, charged, attached, anticipated or given as security,” barred the government from deducting the balance of PCG’s fees at source. PCG estimated that, under the approved multiplier, counsel would therefore still face a $15 million shortfall if this position were correct. PCG distinguished amounts that are “normally payable” under the CPP from the sums netted by the class members because of the Charter violation, and argued that s. 65 is only intended to shelter these “normally payable” benefits.203 The government contended that CPP s. 65 conflicts with CPA s. 32(3), and had to be resolved in favour of CPP s. 65 on paramountcy grounds. Justice Macdonald accepted the government’s argument based on s. 94A of the Constitution Act, 1867,204 which gives Parliament legislative authority over “old age pensions and supplementary benefits, including survivors’ and disability benefits . . . but no such law shall affect the operation of any law . . . of a provincial legislature in relation to any such matter.”205 The question for Macdonald J. thus became whether CPA s. 32(3) legislated in relation to “any such matter,” and that question was easy to decide: it didn’t. Consequently, the CPP assignment-barring provision was seen as trumping the statutory first charge on monetary awards in the CPA. The result was upheld on appeal, with leave to appeal to the Supreme Court of Canada denied. The decision cast a pall over the plaintiffs’ bar. “It’s the death knell for constitutional class actions,” declared Douglas Elliott, lead counsel in Hislop.206 While Elliot’s reaction may have been an overstatement, similar sentiments were echoed across Canada. Vancouver class action practitioner and commentator Ward Branch also found it “interesting” that Canada, and not the class members, had fought the issue, and asked whether it had done so to “preserve the integrity of the statute” or “based on a tactical appreciation that the result would create access to justice problems in relation to CPP issues, by negating the ability of 202 Hislop, supra note 199, [2008] O.J. No. 793 at para. 47-48. 203 Ibid. at para. 55. 204 Constitution Act, 1867 (U.K.), 30 & 31 Vic., c. 3. 205 Section 94A was a mid-20th century constitutional compromise that let provincial pension laws co-exist with federal programs such as CPP and Old Age Security. See British North America Act, 1951 (U.K.), 14 & 15 Geo. VI, c. 32 and Constitution Act, 1964 (adding and amending s. 94A of the Constitution Act, 1867). 206 Cristin Schmitz, “Counsel denied millions for Charter class action” The Lawyers Weekly (15 May 2009) online: <http://www.lawyersweekly.ca/index.php?section=article&articleid=917>. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 33 any class counsel to be paid.”207 PCG had made much the same point, but its arguments had been summarily dismissed, with an admonition that “future class counsel confirm that the [first] charge is available and not negated by other legislation.”208 In the absence of further court rulings, this may be easier said than done: while the matter has now been decided with respect to the CPP, most pension schemes are provincial, and it is common for them to have some sort of anti-assignment provision. In such cases, resort cannot be had to paramountcy arguments, leaving the matter to be fought on a case-by-case or province-by-province basis. The question will be whether any counsel will take on such cases on a contingent basis— class actions or otherwise—after the ruling in Hislop. Allowing Recovery of Settlements, Judgments, Penalties or Other Costs Let us assume now that we are truly at the end of the case in a large-scale claim, and that our notional defendant has settled with the plaintiffs or had judgment declared against it, has paid the plaintiffs their damages, restitution or other costs, and plaintiffs’ counsel have received their fees. What now? Well, there is relatively little to say here, because our system generally facilitates recovering such amounts through markets. In other words, this area is typified more by the absence of regulation than its presence. The general bias is to let market mechanisms deal with cost recovery, subject to certain exceptions and limitations.209 This has implications for behaviour modification. In a perfectly competitive market—that is, one in which all firms are price-takers—there is no ability to pass on costs of settlements or awards through price increases. Instead, the extra costs will go straight to the firm’s bottom line, and the best it can do to survive is try to sell more of its product. In such a setting, the repeat wrongdoer will be out of business in the long run, and maybe even the short run. But the farther we travel from the model of perfect competition, the less apt is this concept of market discipline. Or to put it another way, the easier it is for firms to pass on costs to consumers, with a corresponding disincentive to modify future behaviour. In an oligopolistic market—that is, one with few firms in which the decisions of one influence, and are influenced by, the decisions of others, but in any case, where the market is characterized more by price-setting than price-taking—the market penalty associated with having to pay for wrongful behaviour may be very small. Add other layers of complexity, such as chained markets, with some firms making raw materials, others incorporating them into their products, these firms selling to wholesalers, the wholesalers selling to retailers and the retailers selling to the final customer, and the market effect can be spread through the 207 Branch MacMaster LLP, July 2009 Class Actions blog, online: <http://www.branchmacmaster.com/classactions-blog/2009/7/26/july-2009.html>. My view is that in a situation like this, the government’s position is more akin to that of a trustee seeking the court’s direction on a matter. To link the analogy to Branch’s point, the trustee will naturally be concerned with the interpretation of trust terms on future cases, and will make those concerns known. But that can be done without taking the kind of adversarial stance evident in Hislop. Had there been concerns with an encroachment on CPP s. 65, they could have been addressed with a suitably narrow ruling as to the nature of a solicitor’s charge or lien. After all, it was the solicitors who obtained the remedy, which, as the Court recognized, would not have been obtained otherwise. 208 Hislop, supra note 199, [2008] O.J. No. 793 at para. 65. 209 Exceptions may include rules relating to tax or accounting treatment of certain types of awards, or limits on the ability of a company to indemnify corporate directors for wrongdoing. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 34 system, each player experiencing only a portion of the cost increase.210 In the limiting case, that of monopoly, special considerations arise. The theory here is that in some industries, economies of scale are so large compared to the market served that a single firm will eventually dominate, and so it is better to recognize this fact and regulate the prices charged by the monopoly as a quid pro quo for granting it monopoly status. Transportation networks tend to fall in this category, as do most public utilities. That brings me to Garland v. Consumers’ Gas Co.,211 which Jeff Berryman has written about in his paper for this conference.212 Consumers’ Gas was, and in its current incarnation as Enbridge is, a gas distribution utility regulated by the Ontario Energy Board (“OEB”). The OEB had approved a tariff for Consumers’ that allowed it to charge a late payment penalty for customers who didn’t pay their gas bills on time. The penalty was 5% of the bill, but if it were paid promptly, this would amount to a very high APR—thus potentially engaging s. 347 of the Criminal Code, the same provision at stake in the payday lending litigation.213 Indeed, in two separate rulings from the Supreme Court of Canada, it was held that the late payment penalty was “interest” for the purposes of s. 347 and that Consumers’ had been unjustly enriched thereby. Both rulings came as a surprise to public utility lawyers, because as a matter of utility law, the late payment penalty had already been determined, by virtue of the OEB ruling, to be a just and reasonable rate, as that term is understood in utility law. Moreover, the notion that a utility could be enriched by a late payment penalty does not fit well with a scheme in which prices and rates of return are set by a regulator. In such a scheme, the most one could say is that a cross-subsidy existed between customers— with the late payment penalties having the effect of reducing costs for other customers, albeit by a miniscule amount when spread across the entire rate base. In any case, as Berryman explains, the dispute was ultimately settled for $22 million after the second Supreme Court ruling, leaving a number of questions about the cy-près aspects of the settlement that he discusses in his paper. My purpose here is simply to note what happened next. In a move that might have been perfectly predictable from a regulatedmonopoly or public-utility-law perspective, Enbridge applied to the OEB recover the $22 million from its customers. The Board concluded that all costs—settlement, legal fees 210 This phenomenon also creates problems in price-fixing cases, when trying to tell who has been harmed. See Margaret Sanderson and Michael Trebilcock, “Competition Class Actions: An Evaluation of Deterrence and Corrective Justice Rationales” (2006) 3 Canadian Class Action Review 15, particularly at 23-32. 211 Garland v. Consumers’ Gas Co., [1998] S.C.J. No. 76 (QL) [1998] 3 S.C.R. 112, 40 O.R. (3d) 479, 165 D.L.R. (4th) 385 (ruling that late payment penalty constituted “interest” under Criminal Code s. 347), [2004] S.C.J. No. 21 (QL), [2004] 1 S.C.R. 629, 237 D.L.R. (4th) 385 (finding unjust enrichment and ordering restitution in an amount to be determined), Garland v. Enbridge Gas Distribution Inc., [2006] O.J. No. 4273 (QL), 38 C.P.C. (6th) 70 (S.C.J.) (refusing settlement and certification, with leave to amend), [2006] O.J. No. 4907, 56 C.P.C. (6th) 357 (S.C.J.) (certifying and approving amended settlement pending determination of amount to be paid to representative plaintiff) [Garland]. 212 Jeff Berryman, “Nudge, Nudge, Wink, Wink: Behavioural Modification, Cy-Pres Distributions and Class Actions” presented at “Accessing Justice: Appraising Class Actions Ten Years After Dutton, Hollick & Rumley” (University of Windsor, March 28-29, 2011) at 25-26. 213 In fact, Garland predated and presaged the payday lending litigation, and the ruling on the legality of Consumers’ late payment penalty was litigated as a question of law, before Garland was even certified. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 35 and interest—had been reasonably incurred and were recoverable from ratepayers.214 Over the five-year recovery period allowed by the Board, this works out to about $2.70 per year for each residential customer.215 Berryman concludes that under this settlement, the lawyers got $10 million, [Garland] got $95,000, and the victims got to pay twice, once when they paid the late payment fee, and . . . now through the OEB’s rate order.”216 Whither Behaviour Modification? My primary purpose in this paper has been to raise awareness of legislative- and regulatory-seeking behaviour in response to large-scale claims, actual or threatened. I have tried to do that through examples that illustrate a typology of behaviour which can be thought of on a timeline (from pre-dispute to post-dispute) or a behavioral spectrum (from lesser to greater intervention). From the examples, it will be obvious that I think class actions have done little to promote behaviour modification. Indeed, regarding the form of behaviour discussed by Jones—that of defendants in resolving disputes—I have tried to show that class actions and other large-scale claims have spurred a great deal of legislative intervention, both private and public, aimed at defeating claims rather than responding to them on their merits. Having said that, I still see behaviour modification as a laudable goal, and the legislative news is not all bad. Consumer interests have not been totally disregarded, and in some cases, class actions have spurred regulatory change that favour consumers—witness Ontario’s post-Kanitz amendments to its consumer legislation, which have already held up in the context of another class action.217 Therefore, my secondary purpose is to make some preliminary recommendations for change to promote the stated goals of class proceedings. First, as to arbitration clauses, Shelley McGill has done such a thorough job of setting out the rationale and need for change in this area that I can do little better than refer to her recent article.218 Her reform agenda is set out at pp. 394-412. And, yes, it is largely an agenda for legislative reform that includes a more expansive definition of consumer, so as to bring mixed-use goods and services under the aegis of consumer law; invalidation of class claim waivers (for actions or arbitrations); restriction of consumer arbitration clauses to postdispute agreements; regulation of such post-dispute agreements; and legislative priority— placing the provisions in statutes that are seen as providing substantive, not merely procedural, rights. Given the recent Seidel decision,219 in which both the majority and the minority endorsed arbitration’s primacy absent legislative intent, there is little room left for judicial innovation in this area. Legislatures need to step in. I would also refer to the 214 Re Application by Enbridge Gas Distribution Inc. for an order or orders approving the balance and clearance of the Class Action Suit Deferral Account, EB-2007-0731 (4 February 2008), online: http://www.ontarioenergyboard.ca/ documents/cases/EB-2007-0731/Decision_Enbridge_CASDA_20080204.pdf. 215 Ibid. at 13. 216 Berryman, supra note 212 at 26. 217 Griffin v. Dell Canada Inc., 2010 ONSC 2384 (granting certification, refusing stay), 2010 ONCA 29 (affirming and saying Dell Computer now “academic” in Ontario), 2010 CanLII 27725 (SCC) (refusing leave to appeal). 218 McGill, supra note 34. 219 See Seidel, supra note 95 and the synopsis of the decision in that footnote. Homo legislativus: Missing Link in the Evolution of ‘Behaviour Modification’? (John Kleefeld) 36 proposed U.S. Arbitration Fairness Act: this law, whose preamble reflects a growing populist rant about “forced arbitration,” would render unenforceable arbitration agreements in consumer, employment and franchise disputes.220 My purpose is not to endorse the bill, but to point to one way in which public legislation is responding to the perceived excesses of private legislation. In Canada, the legislative initiative should be implemented in a coordinated fashion; for example, by the Uniform Law Conference of Canada or an interprovincial government committee. If this is not done, I predict that we will see more cases with multiple proceedings, forum shopping, and fragmentation of national classes—all of which defeat the aims of class action policy. I also believe there is scope for adding more substantive heft to class proceedings legislation. For example, while I would be naïve to think that there will be any federal legislation to undo the conflict that surfaced in Hislop, with class counsel being denied most of its fees because of the non-assignment provision in the CPP, such a result could be avoided with provincial pension plans and other benefits legislation. So, for example, if legislatures wanted to make clear that in a dispute over such benefits, counsel fees could be deducted from awards or settlements, they could say so by adding a subsection to the CPA provisions dealing with solicitor’s charges. Alternatively, this could be done by defining what does and doesn’t count as an “assignment” (or other terminology) in the relevant benefits legislation. Class proceedings statutes could also be amended, for example, to adopt the MacKinnon and Smith tests, or something like them, for whether to stay a class action in the face of an arbitration clause, thereby overriding Dell Computer and requiring the question of arbitrability to be decided by the certification judge as part of the preferability analysis. Regarding retroactive legislation, I can only resort to the exhortations of class counsel in Barbour, to the effect that this kind of behaviour is a draconian incursion on the rule of law, particularly when retroactivity is used to validate previously invalid acts or reverse court rulings. Indeed, such legislation has been characterized as “a high watermark of political expediency, if not cynicism.”221 And the more that instances of such legislation abound, the higher and higher will be the watermarks that are established—with what effect on regard for the rule of law? It is also unfair for governments, who are uniquely poised to implement legislative solutions, to take a wait-and-see attitude when considering legislation—i.e., legislatively ‘fix’ a decision that is lost; breathe a sigh of relief when it is won. Even if there are good public policy reasons in favour of the ‘fix’—as there may well be—it is, at a minimum, a waste of legal and judicial resources to wait until after a trial is over—or, as in the KVP case, until after it has gone through all possible appeal processes. In closing, I would like to be able to predict that when we come together again to celebrate the trilogy’s twentieth anniversary, we will be able look back and laugh at some of the concerns raised here. That’s because I’m also hoping that we’ll then be able to say that yes, we finally have access to justice, judicial economy and behaviour modification. 220 Arbitration Fairness Act of 2009, H.R. 1020, 111th Cong. § 4 (2009-2010), online: http://www.gpo.gov/ fdsys/pkg/ BILLS-111hr1020ih/pdf/BILLS-111hr1020ih.pdf. 221 Nanaimo Immigrant Settlement Society v. British Columbia, 2001 BCCA 75, 84 B.C.L.R. (3d) 208 at para. 11 (referring to Woodward Estate v. Minister of Finance, [1973] S.C.R. 120).