First motivation: spending 07-09 The Role of Automatic Stabilizers in the U.S. Business Cycle Alisdair McKay and Ricardo Reis � In the 1930s, purchases were 78% of spending. In the 2000s, they were 25%-52%. � 2007-09 saw the largest increase in government spending / GDP since the Korean war. But 75% was an increase in transfers, and only 25% were purchases. (Oh, Reis, 2011) � Of the $494bn spent 2007-09 in the ARRA, only $37bn were spent in purchases (CBO, 2012) � The United States is not special in both of these facts. (Oh, Reis, 2011) � The times of Keynes are long gone: the money is in ∆Y = (∂Y /∂T ) ∆T now, not in ∆Y = (∂Y /∂G) ∆G anymore. Boston University and Columbia University June 18th Sciences Po Second motivation: automatic stabilizers � Big: CBO (2011) estimates that automatic stabilizers in 2012 will account for $343bn, or 35% of the federal deficit. � Less controversial: Auerbach (2009), Feldstein (2009): disagree on countercyclical fiscal policy, agree that automatic stabilizers are valuable. � Policy: IMF (2009) recommendation for every country. � Virtue of rule: Solow (2004): “The advantage of automatic stabilization is precisely that it is automatic. It is not vulnerable to the perversities that arise when a discretionary “stimulus package” (or “cooling-off package”) is up for grabs in a democratic government.” � Ignorance: Blanchard (2006): “...very little work has been done on automatic stabilization in the last 20 years.” What this paper does � The question: By how much do the automatic stabilizers in the U.S. tax-and-transfer system lower the volatility of aggregate activity? � The approach: Quantitative business-cycle model, with a role for aggregate demand, incentives, and redistribution. � Existing literature: 1. Single stabilizer, single mechanism (Christiano, 1984, Gali, 1994, Andres Domnech, 2006, Dromel, Pintus, 2007); 2. Discretionary policy changes (Oh Reis, 2011, Huntley Michelangeli, 2011, Kaplan Violante, 2012); 3. Public finance perspective (Auerbach Feenberg, 2000, Auerbach, 2009, Dolls, Fuest Peichl, 2011); 4. Steady state effect (Floden, 2001, Alonso-Ortiz Rogerson, 2010, Horvath Nolan, 2011). Outline for today 1. Introduction 2. What are the automatic stabilizers and what is their role? 3. A model 2. The automatic stabilizers: what they are and what is their role 6$(106-215%!10!$;1.$%2?!-0!23$!0$%0121;127!5=!2->$0!25!1%:54$!./'1%(!23$!<$'15.!*++@AB!C-0!65C$'! #$$%&$'(!)*+++,!-%.!/01%(!23$!0-4$!4$235.565(78*!!93$!:/4/6-21;$!14<-:2!5=!:3-%($0!1%!2->! 4. First result: neutrality 23-%!-2!-%7!214$!01%:$!23$!DEF+08!!G0214-2$0!=5'!*++H!-%.!23$'$-=2$'!.5!035C!-%!1%:'$-0$.! 5. Second result: complete markets '$0<5%01;$%$00?!&/2!23$0$!$0214-2$0!'$=6$:2!2->!6-C!-0!1%!$==$:2!41.C-7!23'5/(3!*++H!-%.! 23$'$=5'$!-!02'5%($'!&12$!='54!23$!I62$'%-21;$!J1%14/4!9->!)IJ9,?!23$!$%:'5-:34$%2!5=!C31:3! 6. Third result: redistribution 7. Conclusion 3-0!&$$%!:5%21%/-667!.$6-7$.!&7!-%%/-6!6$(106-215%!1%!'$:$%2!7$-'0?!-%.!$;$%2/-6!'$<$-6!5=! $00$%21-667!-66!5=!23$!K/03!2->!:/20!$%-:2$.!1%!*++D!-%.!*++@8!!L%$!41(32!231%M!23-2!23$!('5C1%(! 14<5'2-%:$!5=!02-2$!-%.!65:-6!2->$0!5;$'!2310!<$'15.!C5/6.!3-;$!<-'21-667!5==0$2!23$!.$:61%$!1%! =$.$'-6!4-'(1%-6!2->!'-2$0?!&/2!C123!$00$%21-667!-66!02-2$0!=-:1%(!054$!=5'4!5=!&-6-%:$.A&/.($2! '$N/1'$4$%20?!23$!%$:$00-'7!2->!1%:'$-0$0!-%.!0<$%.1%(!:/20!C5/6.!3-;$!/%.5%$!2310!<52$%21-6! What are the stabilizers? � � :/0315%1%(!$==$:28! Auerbach et al, ∆Taxes / ∆Income !"#$%&'()'*$+,-.+"/'0&12,31"4&3&11',5'!&6&%.7'8.9&1'+,':3/,-& Definition: Rules in tax and transfer systems that lead to automatic adjustments in revenues and outlays in response to business cycle fluctuations. +8O+ How can they affect fluctuations? +8@" 2. By changing relative benefits and costs. 3. Deficit-financing and crowd out or in of capital. 4. Redistribution and consumption (Oh-Reis Keynesian channel). 5. Redistribution and labor supply (Oh-Reis neoclassical channel). � Examples: personal income tax, safety net transfers, corporate income tax, unemployment benefits... .9Q.P 1. By lowering the volatility of cash on hand, X̂ = (1 − τ )X. +8@+ +8*" +8*+ DEF+ DEF" DEB+ DEB" DEH+ DEH" DEE+ DEE" *+++ *++" *+D+ P$-' ! �� StDev(Y (·, τ ) ≈ � � i=1 A new measure of stabilization � � ��� N �� �� ∂T ∂Y ∂X ∂Y ∂P � � i i i i StDev(Y (·, τ ) ≈ � 1− + � StDev(Z). � ∂Xi ∂ X̂i ∂Z ∂P ∂Z � i=1 In a simple model � with one good, N consumers, aggregate output is: Y = N i=1 Yi (P, X̂i , τ ), net income is: X̂i (Xi , τ ) = Xi − Ti (Xi , τ ), gross income is Xi (Z, τ ) and prices in equilibrium are: P (Z, τ ) then: V ar(Y (·, τ )) ≈ N � � i=1 ∂Yi ∂Xi ∂Yi ∂P � + � StDev(Z). ∂P ∂Z � ∂ X̂i ∂Z !""#$%&%'()#*(+,,(-.-"/0( V ar(Y (·, 0)) − 1. V ar(Y (·, 1)) � ∂Ti ∂Xi Accounting for all the effects The fraction by which the volatility of aggregate activity Y (·, τ ) would increase if we removed automatic stabilizers (τ = 1 to τ = 0): S= 1− ∂Ti 1− ∂Xi � ∂Yi ∂Xi ∂Yi ∂P + ∂P ∂Z ∂ X̂i ∂Z �2 1-/2'*#00(-.-"/( Preferences: E0 ∞ � t=0 V ar(Z). βt � 3.-"/(#%(+"&#%0( �1−σ ψ c3.-"/(#%(4%"-%&5-0(/#(-+*%( t (1 − nt ) !"#$%$"&'% (#()*%+*&,-'% $.%$")%$#+/)% (1 − σ) 3.-"/(#%(4%"-%&5-0(/#("#%0$6-( 3.-"/(/7*#$'7('-%-*+,(-8$4,49*4$6(( Wealth evolution: p̂t ct + bt+1 − bt = pt [xt − τ̄ x (xt )] Preliminaries Income � Time is discrete, agents live forever, aggregate shocks to xt = (it /pt )bt +productivity wt s̄nt + dand t . monetary policy. 3. A quantitative business-cycle model � First automatic � x τ̄ (x) = Population: measure 1 of capital-owners, measure ν of other households, measure 1income of intermediate-good firms, stabilizer is the personal tax : representative final-goods firm, representative capital firms. x x � � τ (x )dx . 0 � Government collects taxes τ̄ at rates τ , gives transfers T and spends resources g. where τ x is weakly increasing. � Capture as many possible stabilizers as can, with three omissions: closed economy, no health care, no retirement. 2 Capital owners Insure within, preferences of representative agent: � � ∞ 2 � n1+ψ t t E0 β ln(ct ) − ψ1 1 + ψ2 t=0 Wealth evolution: p̂t ct + bt+1 − bt = pt [xt − τ̄ x (xt )] + Tte Income: xt = (it /pt )bt + wt s̄nt + dt . First stabilizer: personal income tax with τ x weakly increasing: � x x τ̄ (x) = τ x (x� )dx� . Other households Same preferences, but can be more impatient β̂ ≤ β. Income subject to idiosyncratic shocks: xt (i) = (it /pt )bt (i)+I(et (i) = 2)st (i)wt nt (i)+T u (et (i), st (i)). The st (i) are skill shocks, which generate a wage distribution. Progressive taxation then implies redistribution. Law of motion for wealth: p̂t ct (i) + bt+1 (i) − bt (i) = pt [xt (i) − τ̄ x (xt (i))] + pt T n (et (i)) 0 Safety-net payments � et ∈ {0, 1, 2} is employment status, Markov process. Probabilities depend on exogenous shock, so have a business cycle in aggregate unemployment. � If et (i) = 2 then employed, earn wage st (i)wt nt (i) as part of taxable income, and no social benefits: T u = T n = 0. � If et (i) = 1 then unemployed collecting benefits, which are taxable. Unemployment benefits � � receive T u (et (i), st (i)) = min T̄ u st (i), T̄ u s̄u if et (i) = 0. Zero otherwise. Final goods’ firms Technology: �� yt = 1 yt (j)1/µ dj 0 �µ . By cost minimization and zero profits: � If et (i) = 0 then out of the labor force collecting food stamps, which are not taxable. SNAP / food stamps receive T¯n (et (i)) if et (i) = 0. Zero otherwise. pt = �� 1 pt (j) 0 1/(1−µ) dj �1−µ . Sales tax After-tax prices p̂t = (1 + τ c )pt so consume 1/(1 + τ c ) fraction of spending. Intermediate goods’ firms Capital goods’ firms Continuum of monopolists with production function: yt (j) = at kt (j)α �t (j)1−α . Maximize after-tax nominal profits dit (j): � � 1 − τ k [pt (j)yt (j)/pt − wt �t (j) − (rt + δ)kt (j) − ξ] . Representative firm, maximize after-tax profits dkt : (1 − τ k )rt kt − ∆kt+1 − Υ(∆kt+1 )kt . Value of the firm is vt = dkt − τ p vt + β Et [λt,t+1 Vt+1 ] Nominal rigidities a la Calvo (1983) with parameter θ. Corporate income tax Flat rate τ k attenuates fluctuations in dividends and in after-tax interest rate. Property income tax Rate τ p on vt = qt kt and qt = 1 + Υ� (.) is procyclical. The last stabilizer: budget constraint The government budget constraint is: �ν �ν τ c 0 (ct (i)dh + ct )di + τ p qt kt + 0 τ̄ x (xt (i))dh + τ̄ x (xt ) + � � τ k ω dˆi (j)di + rt kt − γ∆kt+1 = �ν �ν Tte + 0 (1 − eht )Ttuh dh + 0 Tt (xt (i), st (i), et (i))di + gt + (it /pt )Bt − (Bt+1 − Bt ) /pt Need a fiscal rule to cover deficits. Tax on entrepreneurs is closest to being separated from other effects: � �φ Bt e Tt = log B̄ But also consider alternative with purchases: � � gt yt Bt /pt φ = g ȳ B̄ Market clearing � Government bonds are the only asset in positive net supply: � ν Bt = bt (i)di + bt . 0 � Capital goods: � 1 kt = kt (j)dj. 0 � Labor market: � 1 � lt = �t (j)dj = 0 � ν et (i)st (i)nt (i)dh + s̄nt . 0 Taylor rule for monetary policy: it = ī + φp ∆ log(pt ) + φy log(yt /y) + εt Equilibrium � Aggregate shocks to log(at ) and εt are independent AR(1). Individual shocks to et (i) and st (i) are Markov processes. � Employment varies exogenously with aggregate shocks: probabilities depend on composite shock log(at ), εt . � Our measure of real activity is log output and its variance is evaluated at the ergodic distribution of this economy. � Crucial is that we have four groups of stabilizers: 4. First result: neutrality 1. Proportional taxes τ c , τ k , τ p ; 2. Progressive personal tax system τ x (x� ); 3. Safety-net transfers T u (et (i), st (i)), T n (et (i), st (i)); 4. Deficits, via adjustment rate φ. Neutrality proposition Assumption 1: The following set of conditions holds: Implications � Intuition for the result with separable preferences (σ = 1) 1. With flexible prices, there is an aggregate production function: yt = at ktα lt1−α . 2. k is fixed so proposition holds if labor supply is fixed. 3. Because g/y is fixed, resource constraint says c/y is fixed. Because production function is Cobb-Douglas, wages are proportional to y/l. Therefore, c/w is proportional to l. 4. Because of complete markets, consumption same for all. 5. Labor supply condition for employed household: 1. Households trade a complete set of Arrow securities. 2. The personal income tax is proportional. 3. Probability of employment is fixed over time. 4. Capital is fixed (infinite adjustment costs). 5. Prices are flexible (Calvo frequency is infinity). 6. Government purchases are a fixed fraction of GDP. Proposition Under the conditions of assumption 1, the variance of the log of output is equal to the variance of the log of productivity. Therefore, S = 0 for any combination of taxes and transfers. nt (i) = 1 − � p̂t ψct (i) . pt (1 − τ )wt st (i) Implications: � � � Public finance measures would have led you astray. Net income affects volatility of the level but not log income. Proportional taxes are weak stabilizers. Aggregation result 5. Second result: complete markets Proposition If all households can trade a complete set of Arrow securities, there is a representative agent. Her preferences are: � � ∞ 2 � n1+ψ t t max E0 β log(ct ) − (1 + Et ) ψ1 1 + ψ2 t=0 and her constraints are: p̂t ct + bt+1 − bt = pt [xt − τ̄ (xt )] + Ttn it xt = bt + wt st (1 + Et )nt + dt + Ttu pt � � 1 � ν 1+1/ψ2 1 Et 1+1/ψ2 1+1/ψ2 st = s̄t + si,t di , 1 + Et 1 + Et 0 where 1 + Et is total employment, including capital-owners and households. More aggregation results The United States welfare state Table 1. The government's use and source of funds, average 1997-2007 Lemma The solution to the capital firm’s problem is represented by a standard Euler equation, taking into account the adjustment costs. Lemma The solution to the final- and intermediate-goods problems is represented by a standard NK Phillips curve. Revenues Outlays Automatic stabilizers Automatic stabilizers Personal Income Taxes Corporate Income Taxes Sales and excise taxes Property Taxes Others Public deficit So, overall, very standard macro model augmented to have many taxes along many margins. 11.22% 2.59% 3.80% 2.75% Sum 0.29% 0.91% 0.20% 0.17% 0.35% 0.19% Others -1.12% Out of the model Customs taxes Licenses, fines, fees Payroll taxes Unemployment benefits Safety net programs Supplemental nutrition assistance Family assistance under PRWORA Security income to the disabled Others Government purchases Net interest income 15.14% 2.25% Out of the model 0.21% 1.79% 6.26% 27.49% Notes 28.61% Retirement-related transfers Others (esp. rest of the world) Health benefits (non-retirement) Sum 7.27% 1.92% 1.74% 27.49% Calibration of stabilizers Simulate TaxSim, 88-07, federal plus state, weight states by population, years equally. Fit a truncated cubic to it, plus an intercept to match table 1. Get: Table 1: Parameter Values Explanation Value Panel A. Tax bases and rates τc Tax rate on consumption 0.054 β Discount factor of stock owners 0.989 τp Tax rate on property 0.003 α Coefficient on labor in production 0.296 τk Tax rate on corporate income 0.282 ξ Fixed costs of production 1.32 µ Desired gross markup 1.1 Panel B. Government outlays and debt Tu Unemployment benefits 0.185 To Safety-net transfers 0.169 G/Y Steady-state purchases / output 0.130 φ Fiscal adjustment speed 1.33 B/Y Steady-state debt / output 1.66 Panel C. Labor-force status πeu Steady-state transition probability E-U 0.026 πue Steady-state transition probability U-E 0.571 Table 1: Parameter πup Steady-state transition probability U-P Values 0.297 πpu Steady-state transition probability P-E 0.087 y πeu Cyclical transition probability E-U -1.20 y Parameter Explanation Value πue Cyclical transition probability U-E 3.477 y πupA. TaxCyclical transition 1.55 Panel bases and rates probability U-P Panel distribution τc D. Income Tax rateand on wealth consumption 0.054 ν Non-participants / stock owners 4 β h Discount factor of stock owners 0.989 Discount of non-participants 0.983 τpβ Tax rate onfactor property 0.003 s̄ Skill level of stock owners 4.66 α Coefficient on labor in production 0.296 E(s) Mean of non-participants skill 1.08 τk Tax rate on corporate income 0.282 Panel E. Business-cycle parameters ξ Fixed costs of production 1.32 γ Coefficient of relative risk aversion 1 µ Desired gross markup 1.1 θ Calvo parameter for price stickiness 0.286 Panel B. Government outlays and debt ψ Labor supply 21.6 Tu 1 Unemployment benefits 0.185 ψ Labor supply 2 To 2 Safety-net transfers 0.169 δ Depreciation rate 0.114 G/Y Steady-state purchases / output 0.130 φ Adjustment costs for investment 17.2 φ Fiscal adjustment speed 1.33 ρz Autocorrelation of productivity shock 0.923 B/Y Steady-state debt / output 1.66 σz St. dev. of productivity shock 0.003 Panel C. Labor-force status ρm Autocorrelation of monetary shock 0.500 πeu Steady-state transition probability E-U 0.026 σm St. dev. of monetary shock 0.005 πue Steady-state transition probability U-E 0.571 φp Interest-rate rule coefficient on inflation 1.50 πupφ Steady-state probability U-P 0.297 Interest-ratetransition rule coefficient on output 0.010 y πpu Steady-state transition probability P-E 0.087 y πeu Cyclical transition probability E-U -1.20 y πue Cyclical transition probability U-E 3.477 2 y πup Cyclical transition probability U-P 1.55 Panel D. Income and wealth distribution ν Non-participants / stock owners 4 βh Discount factor of non-participants 0.983 s̄ Skill level of stock owners 4.66 E(s) Mean of non-participants skill 1.08 Panel E. Business-cycle parameters γ Coefficient of relative risk aversion 1 θ Calvo parameter for price stickiness 0.286 ψ1 Labor supply 21.6 ψ2 Labor supply 2 δ Depreciation rate 0.114 φ Adjustment costs for investment 17.2 ρz Autocorrelation of productivity shock 0.923 σz St. dev. of productivity shock 0.003 ρm Autocorrelation of monetary shock 0.500 σm St. dev. of monetary shock 0.005 φp Interest-rate rule coefficient on inflation 1.50 φy Interest-rate rule coefficient on output 0.010 0.4 Target (Source) Avg. revenue from sales taxes (Table 1) Consumption-income ratio = 0.689 (NIPA) Avg. revenue from property taxes (Table 1) Capital income share = 0.36 (NIPA) Avg. revenue from corporate income tax (Table 1) Corporate profits / GDP = 9.13% (NIPA) Avg. U.S. markup (Basu, Fernald, 1997) Avg. outlays on unemp. benefits (Table 1) Avg. outlays on safety-net benefits (Table 1) Avg. outlays on purchases (Table 1) Autocorrelation of net government savings / GDP = 0.966 (NIPA) Avg. interest expenses (Table 1) Avg. insured unemp. rate = 0.023 (BLS) Avg. UE flow quarterly = 0.813 (Shimer, 2007) Avg. SNAP ratio = 0.077 (USDA) SNAP exit hazard = 0.03 monthly (Mabli et al., 2011) St. dev. of unemp. rate = 0.009 (BLS) Target (Source) St. dev. of UE flows = 0.053 (Shimer) St. dev. of SNAP ratio = 0.020 (USDA) Avg. revenue from sales taxes (Table 1) Consumption-income ratio = 0.689 (NIPA) Wealth of topfrom 20% property by wealthtaxes (Table 1) Avg. revenue Income of top 20% by wealth (SCF) Capital income share = 0.36 (NIPA) Avg. income in economy normalized to 1 Avg. revenue from corporate income tax (Table 1) Corporate profits / GDP = 9.13% (NIPA) Avg. U.S. markup (Basu, Fernald, 1997) Avg. price spell duration = 3.5 (Klenow, Malin, 2011) Avg. hours worked = 0.31 (Cooley, Prescott, 1995) Avg. outlays on unemp. benefits (Table 1) Frisch elasticity = 1/2 Avg. outlays on safety-net benefits (Table 1) Annual depreciation expenses / GDP = 0.046 (NIPA) Avg. outlays on purchases (Table 1) Corr. of Y and C = 0.88 (NIPA) Autocorrelation of net government savings / GDP = 0.966 (NIPA) Autocorrelation of log GDP = 0.864 (NIPA) Avg. interest expenses (Table 1) St. dev. of log GDP = 1.539 (NIPA) Largest autoregressive root of inflation = 0.85 (Pivetta, Reis, 2006) Avg. insured unemp. rate = 0.023 (BLS) Share of output variance due to m shock = 0.8 Avg. UE flow quarterly = 0.813 (Shimer, 2007) St. dev. of inflation = 0.638 (NIPA) Avg. SNAP of ratio = 0.077 (USDA) Correlation inflation with log GDP = 0.198 (NIPA) SNAP exit hazard = 0.03 monthly (Mabli et al., 2011) St. dev. of unemp. rate = 0.009 (BLS) St. dev. of UE flows = 0.053 (Shimer) St. dev. of SNAP ratio = 0.020 (USDA) Calibration of inequality Wealth of top 20% by wealth Income of top 20% by wealth (SCF) Avg. income in economy normalized to 1 Avg. price spell duration = 3.5 (Klenow, Malin, 2011) Avg. hours worked = 0.31 (Cooley, Prescott, 1995) Frisch elasticity = 1/2 Annual depreciation expenses / GDP = 0.046 (NIPA) Corr. of Y and C = 0.88 (NIPA) Autocorrelation of log GDP = 0.864 (NIPA) St. dev. of log GDP = 1.539 (NIPA) Largest autoregressive root of inflation = 0.85 (Pivetta, Reis, 2006) Share of output variance due to m shock = 0.8 St. dev. of inflation = 0.638 (NIPA) Correlation of inflation with log GDP = 0.198 (NIPA) 0.35 0.3 Table 1: Parameter Values 0.25 Parameter marginal tax rate Parameter Calibration of personal income tax Explanation 0.2 Value Target (Source) Panel A. Tax bases and rates 0.15on consumption τc Tax rate 0.054 Avg. revenue from sales taxes (Table 1) β Discount factor of stock owners 0.989 Consumption-income ratio = 0.689 (NIPA) 0.1on property τp Tax rate 0.003 Avg. revenue from property taxes (Table 1) α Coefficient on labor in production 0.296 Capital income share = 0.36 (NIPA) τk Tax rate 0.282 Avg. revenue from corporate income tax (Table 1) 0.05on corporate income ξ Fixed costs of production 1.32 Corporate profits / GDP = 9.13% (NIPA) µ Desired gross markup 1.1 Avg. U.S. markup (Basu, Fernald, 1997) 0 Panel B. Government outlays and debt u T Unemployment benefits 0.185 Avg. outlays on unemp. benefits (Table 1) −0.05 To Safety-net transfers 0.169 Avg. outlays on safety-net benefits (Table 1) G/Y Steady-state purchases / output 0.130 Avg. outlays on purchases (Table 1) −0.1 φ Fiscal adjustment speed savings / GDP = 0.966 (NIPA) 0 1 2 31.33 Autocorrelation 4 5 of net government 6 7 income B/Y Steady-state debt / output multiples of average 1.66 household Avg. interest expenses (Table 1) Panel C. Labor-force status πeu Steady-state transition probability E-U 0.026 Avg. insured unemp. rate = 0.023 (BLS) πue Steady-state transition probability U-E 0.571 Avg. UE flow quarterly = 0.813 (Shimer, 2007) πup Steady-state transition probability U-P 0.297 Avg. SNAP ratio = 0.077 (USDA) πpu Steady-state transition probability P-E 0.087 SNAP exit hazard = 0.03 monthly (Mabli et al., 2011) y πeu Cyclical transition probability E-U -1.20 St. dev. of unemp. rate = 0.009 (BLS) y πue Cyclical transition probability U-E 3.477 St. dev. of UE flows = 0.053 (Shimer) y πup Cyclical transition probability U-P 1.55 St. dev. of SNAP ratio = 0.020 (USDA) Panel D. Income and wealth distribution ν Non-participants / stock owners 4 βh Discount factor of non-participants 0.983 Wealth of top 20% by wealth s̄ Skill level of stock owners 4.66 Income of top 20% by wealth (SCF) E(s) Mean of non-participants skill 1.08 Avg. income in economy normalized to 1 Panel E. Business-cycle parameters γ Coefficient of relative risk aversion 1 θ Calvo parameter for price stickiness 0.286 Avg. price spell duration = 3.5 (Klenow, Malin, 2011) ψ1 Labor supply 21.6 Avg. hours worked = 0.31 (Cooley, Prescott, 1995) ψ2 Labor supply 2 Frisch elasticity = 1/2 δ Depreciation rate 0.114 Annual depreciation expenses / GDP = 0.046 (NIPA) φ Adjustment costs for investment 17.2 Corr. of Y and C = 0.88 (NIPA) ρz Autocorrelation of productivity shock 0.923 Autocorrelation of log GDP = 0.864 (NIPA) σz St. dev. of productivity shock 0.003 St. dev. of log GDP = 1.539 (NIPA) ρm Autocorrelation of monetary shock 0.500 Largest autoregressive root of inflation = 0.85 (Pivetta, Reis, 2006) σm St. dev. of monetary shock 0.005 Share of output variance due to m shock = 0.8 φp Interest-rate rule coefficient on inflation 1.50 St. dev. of inflation = 0.638 (NIPA) φy Interest-rate rule coefficient on output 0.010 Correlation of inflation with log GDP = 0.198 (NIPA) Calibration of other parameters 2 resulting government budget surplus is rebated lump-sum to capital owners. investment more volatile. The policy changes would generally raise the steady state level of output because they reduce 4. small government: no government spending, transfers are reduced to 20% of their baseline distortions. The high marginal tax rates associated with progressive taxation have quite large C K P level, income taxes are eliminated, τ , τ , and τ are reduced by 10%. Steady state goveffects on steady state levels. The elimination of government spending in the small government ernment debt remains at itsThe baseline level. A lump-sum tax on capital owners balances the experiments Results for S experiment has a large, if mechanical, effect on consumption. budget period by period. 3 1. lower proportional taxes: tax rates τ C , τ P and τ K are 10%. Lost revenue of 0.6% of GDP is replaced Resultsreduced for thebyrepresentative agent economy by increased lump-sum tax on the capital owners. In the representative agent economy, the effects of these policies for fluctuations are modest. In 2. without progressive taxes: the slightly progressive incomebut tax particular, lowering transfers would make the economy more stable, in essence has no effect on volatilities. Progressive has veryincome little effect output or the labor input, but does is replaced by ataxation proportional tax on that raises contribute to the stability of consumption. My understanding of this result is that it is driven same revenue in steady state. by intertemporal substitution in the timing of dividends: in a recession, marginal tax rates are lower and it 3. is an attractive time to pay out dividends. Thistomakes more stable and low transfers: transfers are reduced lowerconsumption spending by investment more0.8/5 volatile. of GDP. In steady state, the resulting government The policy changes would generally raise the steady state level of output because they reduce budget surplus is rebated lump-sum to capital owners. distortions. The high marginal tax rates associated with progressive taxation have quite large effects on steady state levels. The elimination of government spending in the small government 4. small no on government spending, income experiment has a large, government: if mechanical, effect consumption. taxes are eliminated, all other taxes and transfers fall by amounts equal to above experiments. Steady state Table 1: S statistic for representative agent economy government debt remains at its baseline level. A lump-sum tax capital owners balances the budget every period. low on propor. taxes w/o progressive taxes low transfers small gov. Y N C (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.0047 0.0078 -0.0254 -0.0119 0.0019 0.0746 -0.0059 -0.0056 -0.0168 -0.0147 -0.0080 0.0721 Effect on steady state Table 1: S statistic for representative agent economy Y N C low propor. taxes (1) w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) 0.0047 0.0078 -0.0254 -0.0119 0.0019 0.0746 -0.0059 -0.0056 -0.0168 -0.0147 -0.0080 0.0721 Progressive income tax only stabilizes C because of timing of Table 2: Effects on steady state levels for representative agent economy dividends by capital-goods firm. Transfers not exactly zero because taxable, but very close to Ricardian equivalence. low propor. taxes w/o progressive taxes low transfers small gov. Y N C (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.0159 0.0007 0.0147 0.0369 0.0369 0.0487 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0321 0.0167 0.2655 2 Table 2: Effects on steady state levels for representative agent economy Y N C low propor. taxes (1) w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) 0.0159 0.0007 0.0147 0.0369 0.0369 0.0487 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0321 0.0167 0.2655 Progressive taxation comes with much lower output though 2 because of its high marginal tax rates. 6. Third result: heterogeneity Solving the full model � � 4 Need to solve a model with: � Heterogeneity: must keep track of distributions, as in Krusell and Smith (1997). � Nominal rigidities: as in Oh and Reis (2011) and Guerrieri and Lorenzoni (2011). � Solve for aggregate dynamics: as in Reiter (2009) We have just finished refining our grids (so no draft yet but very soon). How the model works: household savings employed 1.5 the model works: capital Results forHow the heterogeneous agent economy i The steady state effects are similar to the representative agent economy, but the impact on volatilities are now more substantial. Transfers in particular have a substantially larger effect here and the h −1 variance of log output is 13% higher when transfers are reduced. However, aggregate consumption is more stable when transfers are reduced. This result is driven by the additional accumulation of precautionary savings in the stationary economy. Lowering /01"#20*.% transfers increases the precautionary 3'4)-5"% savings motive of households, which means that they have more savings with which to smooth aggregate as well as idiosyncratic shocks. To confirm this intuition, we conducted an additional −1 e experiment in which we lower the households’ discount factor at the same time that we eliminate transfers. This experiment is just meant to illustrate the role678,%9'()$'*%"$09:% of precautionary savings in the model and is not intended as a true policy experiment because it is not clear how one might achieve this reduction in discount factor. We choose the new discount factor so that the aggregate assets of 678,% economy despite the fact that transfers are lower. In the households is the same as in the baseline 201"#20*.% this alternative economy with low transfers and a low discount &'()$'*%+#,'-.% factor, the volatility of consumption is higher than in the baseline economy"'4)-5"% by 22% (i.e. S = 0.22). This makes sense as in this case the households have little private insurance in the form of precautionary savings and little public insurance in the form of transfers. Therefore, the reduction in employment in a recession has a strong impact on consumption. The impact of progressive taxation on the volatility of output is now substantially larger than in !""#$"% the representative agent economy. However, while progressive taxation stabilized consumption in the representative agent economy, it now destabilizes log consumption. This result also arises out of the impact of the policy on the steady state. The change to proportional taxes makes the level of consumption more volatile and larger in steady state. These two effects have opposite effects on the variance of log consumption. The impact on steady state consumption is stronger in the Results S increase in the volatility of the level heterogeneous agent economy and this is enough tofor offset the of consumption. � β � (β ) 1 Table 3: S statistic for heterogeneous agent economy 0.5 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 unemployed 1 Y N C 0.5 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 low propor. taxes (1) w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) 0.0036 0.0125 0.0424 0.1454 0.1348 -0.0663 0.1317 0.0640 -0.2270 0.1278 0.1364 -0.0716 1 out of the labor force 5 1 baseline low transfers Proportional taxes still mostly irrelevant. Our first extreme Alternative Financing Mechanisms result is still a good approximation. 1. Baseline: lump-sum tax adjusts gradually to government debt outstanding. 0.5 2. No deficits: lump-sum tax immediately to clear government budget. 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 assets (1 = avg income) 0.8 1 3. Spending: G adjusts gradually to debt outstanding. 3 of the impact of the policy on the steady state. The change to proportional taxes makes the level of consumption more volatile and larger in steady state. These two effects have opposite effects on the variance of log consumption. The impact on steady state consumption is stronger in the heterogeneous agent economy and this is enough to offset the increase in the volatility of the level Results for S of consumption. of consumption more volatile and larger in steady state. These two effects have opposite effects on the variance of log consumption. The impact on steady state consumption is stronger in the heterogeneous agent economy and this is enough to offset the increase in the volatility of the level of consumption. Results for S Table 3: S statistic for heterogeneous agent economy Table 3: S statistic for heterogeneous agent economy Y N C low propor. taxes (1) w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) 0.0036 0.0125 0.0424 0.1454 0.1348 -0.0663 0.1317 0.0640 -0.2270 0.1278 0.1364 -0.0716 Progressive taxes much more effective at stabilizing output and 5 Alternative Financing Mechanisms employment, but now destabilize consumption. Actually C is more stable in levels, but steady-state level much so log 1. Baseline: lump-sum tax adjusts gradually to government debtlower, outstanding. C is more volatile. 2. No deficits: lump-sum tax immediately to clear government budget. Y N C 5 low propor. taxes (1) w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) 0.0036 0.0125 0.0424 0.1454 0.1348 -0.0663 0.1317 0.0640 -0.2270 0.1278 0.1364 -0.0716 Transfers are hugely effective on Y, N but destabilize C. With Alternative Financing Mechanisms low transfers, precautionary savings rise allowing for better smoothing of shocks. 1. Baseline: lump-sum tax adjusts gradually to government debt outstanding. 2. No deficits: lump-sum taxhousehold immediatelydiscount to clear government budget. Experiment: lower factor. Now S for consumption +22%. to debt outstanding. 3. Spending: G adjustsisgradually 3. Spending: G adjusts gradually to debt outstanding. 3 3 Wealth distribution Results for steady state employed 0.015 0.01 Table 4: Effects on steady state levels for heterogeneous agent economy 0.005 0 0 2 −4 4 4 6 8 10 unemployed x 10 Y N C 3 2 1 0 0 2 4 6 8 w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) 0.0164 0.0012 0.0153 0.0413 0.0413 0.0543 0.0017 0.0017 0.0024 0.0347 0.0192 0.2696 10 out of the labor force 0.015 baseline low transfers 0.01 0.005 0 low propor. taxes (1) 0 2 4 6 assets (1 = avg income) 8 10 Keynesian effect on bottom group, stabilizes Y,N. Precautionary effect on other households, C destabilized. The timing of the lump-sum tax hasimpacts very littleoninfluence the dynamics Transfers have minimal steady on state, unlike of the economy, which reflects a near Ricardian equivalence. The reason that Ricardian equivalence does not hold exactly progressive taxes. is that the interest payments on government debt alters taxable income. A fiscal adjustment rule that has government spending adjust to stabilize government debt leads output and hours to be more volatile, but consumption to be less volatile. The reason that hours are more volatile is because of a wealth effect: in a boom, government revenues rise as the tax base increases and government outlays fall as transfers fall. These forces lead to a reduction in government debt, which is offset by increased government spending, which generates a wealth effect that increases labor supply thus reinforcing the boom. This wealth effect also leads consumption to respond less in a boom making it more stable. The same pattern arises in the representative agent economy. because of a wealth effect: in a boom, government revenues rise as the tax base increases and government outlays fall as transfers fall. These forces lead to a reduction in government debt, which is offset by increased government spending, which generates a wealth effect that increases labor supply thus reinforcing the boom. This wealth effect also leads consumption to respond less in a boom making Alternative it more stable. The same pattern arises mechanisms in the representative agent economy. financing Keynes or Precautionary? Table 6: S statistic for hand-to-mouth economy Table 5: Variance of logs for heterogeneous agent economy Y N C 6 baseline no deficits spending 0.0166 0.0135 0.0190 0.0166 0.0135 0.0188 0.0185 0.0156 0.0122 Running deficits is almost irrelevant. Ricardian equivalence not Results for hand-to-mouth economy such a bad approximation. In this version of the model we assume that the households do not save and consume their after-tax Government leads to calibration large wealth effects. incomes immediately. I didpurchases not changeadjusting any features of the except that I increased the because in booms, surplus, This leadschange to rises coefficients inIncreases the Taylorvolatility rule to resolve an issue of non-existence. mayinalter the overall dynamics in G, response a shock, I hope it will not effect the impact of the experiments too whichtoare furtherbut expansionary. much. It is still the case that lowering proportional taxes has close to no effect on volatility. Progressive taxes also have very limited impact, which is more similar to the representative agent economy than the heterogeneous agent economy. Reducing transfers now makes consumption more volatile, which is not surprising as a large part of consumption tracks income mechanically. In this economy, transfers stabilize labor supply more than in the heterogeneous agent economy. The behavior of labor supply in the transfer experiment depends in part on the way the transfers are financed. If we conduct the same experiment under the assumption that government spending adjusts to 4 Y N C low propor. taxes (1) w/o progressive taxes (2) low transfers (3) small gov. (4) -0.0002 0.0091 -0.0074 -0.0052 0.0217 0.0210 0.0280 0.0950 0.1518 0.0481 0.1362 0.1043 maintain long-run budget balance, then the volatility hourshouseholds is nearly unchanged by the change Mankiw’s savers-spenders, just assumeof that live in transfers.hand-to-mouth. One effect of transfers under lump-sum financing is that a positive shock leads to a positive wealth effect for the capital-owners since they will pay fewer taxes for the transfers. This is stabilizing since the positive wealth effect leads them to work less. When government spending Transfers now mechanically stabilize consumption, and because is used to balance the budget, the positive shock leads to an increase in government spending to in recession, lump-sum tax on entrepreneurs rises, they work absorb the budget surplus so there is not the same wealth effect. more, which is also stabilizing. Conclusion � Follow the money: transfers, tax changes. Focus on automatic stabilizers. Contributions / results 7. Conclusion � Propose a new measure of stabilization. New method to solve incomplete-market models with nominal rigidities. � Redistribution is the crucial stabilizing force. � Progressive taxation and safety-net transfers stabilize output and hours, but not consumption. � Transfers cause small reductions in steady-state wealth.