Swimming with the sharks? Understanding the competitive structure of primary-demand level product-markets. Introduction The issue of product-market definition is complex, but demands consideration by marketing strategists who need to look further than a simple category definition of closely substitutable competitors if they are to understand the full extent of the competition they face. As Shocker (2005 p.107) points out, “competition is a matter of degree rather than a simple dichotomy”. Consumers choose not just between competing brands in the same product category, but also from other categories that might meet the same generic need. As Lehmann and Winer’s conceptualisation (2005) defines it, this demand-oriented competition occurs at four different levels: product form, product category, generic and budget. At the product-form level, competition is between brands serving the same customers with closely substitutable products, offering largely similar attributes, as it might be two similar brands of instant coffee granules, or of laundry detergent. At the product category level, the competitive set is extended to include not just close substitutes, but all product forms in a wider market. For example, while Walkers crisps may compete closely with Seabrook crisps, both brands may also be competing with premium offerings such as Kettle Chips. The biggest suppliers or retailers in the channel often define this broader category definition, in consultation with their research providers. At the generic level (primary demand), products compete with anything that meets the same broad need so for example, potato crisps are part of a wider salty snacks category that may include corn and potato-starch based chips as well as nuts and varieties of pork scratching. Lastly, Lehmann and Winer define budget competition as anything that may have a stronger call on limited discretionary income, although they point out that the competitive effects of this are hard to determine. Market structure at both the product form and the category level can be estimated on the basis of brand choice (selective demand). Shocker (2005) outlines three common approaches. The first, derived from cross-elasticity calculations, considers the impact of one brand’s marketing activities on sales of others. When a substantial impact is identified the conclusion is that the affected brands are competing. One difficulty in this approach is that it can only be applied to existing brands, and so it is of limited use in planning for new products. Furthermore, marketing impacts on smaller brands such as those in limited distribution are not easily tracked. A second approach, substitutability-in-use (substitutability)is more useful here, as it highlights a rationale for the existence of the competition, usually through qualitative research. For managers this offers the chance to assess the proposed benefits of new products, and to explore market segmentation, where products may need to meet more varied consumer needs. This type of research leads to a complex categorisation of markets and submarkets based on benefits sought (Shocker, Stewart and Zahorik, 1990a) to which, in practice, it may be impossible to respond. Results from such a deterministic approach are also likely to be misinterpreted because of the gulf between consumer attitude and consumer behaviour (Dall’Olmo-Riley, Ehrenberg, Castleberry, Barwise & Barnard, 1997). The third alternative is the analysis of brand switching from panel or other aggregated choice data (Colombo and Morrison, 1989; Erdem, 1996). This approach describes existing competitive intensity through analysis of switching probabilities and by extension through duplication of purchase analysis (Ehrenberg & Goodhardt, 1970), the technique we employ here. At the selective demand level, the marketing strategy literature has long championed the benefits of loyalty, and the sustainable competitive advantage of brand equity and retention (Aaker, 2002; Keller, 1993; Keller & Lehmann, 2006; Reichheld, 2003). However, as Reinartz and Kumar (2002) and East, Hammond and Gendall (2006) both show, this view is not supported by the empirical evidence. Instead, the repeat buying of competing brands falls into regular and predictable patterns and can be summarised in a single model, the NBD-Dirichlet (Goodhardt, Ehrenberg and Chatfield, 1984). The main brand metrics are all described in this model; how many people buy each brand, how often they do so, and which other brands they buy. The fundamental pattern observed is that all brand performance measures vary together according to brand size. This is reflected in loyalty measures such as repeat purchase and brand switching that are dependent upon market share rather than on any particular brand or customer attribute. Big brands tend to score higher and small brands lower on these metrics (Ehrenberg, 1988; Ehrenberg, Uncles and Goodhardt, 2004). The model and the empirical generalisations it describes therefore lead to simple performance benchmarks and norms that capture market structure accurately between competing brands. The aim of this research is to extend these empirical generalisations to the level of primary demand, in order to describe and benchmark patterns of buying behaviour between, rather than within, categories. Findings will be of use to brand marketers who are seeking expansion opportunities in new, but related categories (Bang & Joshi, 2008), those who wish to identify or explain current threats at a higher competitive level (Levitt,1960; Lehmann & Winer, 2005), and to marketers at trade associations who seek to understand the relationship between, and the relative importance of, the connected categories they support. In this exploratory study we report the generic-level consumer purchasing of different categories of seafood using data from an Australian diary panel. These empirical generalisations in repeat buying will next be described, followed by the objectives, methodology, data and findings. For competing brands in established markets, in a period such as a month or quarter: Brand share is defined by the Law of Double Jeopardy. Small brands suffer twice. Compared with bigger brands they have fewer buyers who buy that brand slightly less often. Market shares and penetrations are closely correlated, but vary considerably. This implies that penetration accounts for brand size far more than loyalty, which is quite similar between brands. 100% brand loyal customers do exist but they are light buyers. A large proportion of any brand’s buyers only buy the category once in a period, and therefore cannot switch by definition. Your buyers are the buyers of other brands who occasionally buy you. Loyalty is polygamous; most consumers select from a limited repertoire of familiar brands. Duplication is in line with brand penetration. The proportion of the buyers of brand x who also bought brand y in the period is related to the penetration of brand y. This law is normally expressed as: by|x = Dby . Any deviation indicates a greater or lesser degree of competition between pairs of brands, and this can indicate market partitioning, for example between diet and regular colas. The main finding here has been that brand-level segmentation does not exist: simply a higher than expected level of duplication between partitioned brands (Kennedy & Ehrenberg, 2001). Buyers of diet colas usually buy both main brands, but also buy regular colas occasionally. Objectives Our focus is on the patterns of consumer purchase between competing categories of seafood - generic competition. We expect that the established patterns of buying behaviour commonly seen between existing brands will replicate at the higher primary-demand level of category buying. In particular we seek to: Extend the application of the duplication of purchase law in order to describe generic level purchasing. Describe the intensity and extent of inter-category competition Test for evidence of category-level segmentation Methodology A small consumer shopping-panel consisting initially of 132 respondents was recruited from a larger existing online consumer database. Screening questions stipulated that respondents should at least have bought seafood in the past month, to identify all but the lightest buyers. A total of 113 respondents completed the survey, collecting receipts for all purchases from supermarkets, grocery stores, convenience stores, fishmongers, restaurants, pubs and takeaways over four weeks through November 2009. Purchases without receipts were also recorded in order to capture whole-of-customer buying. From this data, all generic seafood purchases could be extracted by category (eg frozen, fresh etc) and by channel (eg supermarket, fishmonger, foodservice…). Of the 113 respondents, 7% (n=8) bought no seafood in the period, while the remainder of the panel bought an average of 4.4 times, just over once per week. Seafood purchases were identified to establish frequencies, and then tabulated to observe and describe any patterns of repeat buying at the generic level. Findings Our first finding is that the stability seen in buying behaviour at the category level was repeated at the generic level. Purchasing was split polygamously between consumer marketing channels, just as it is between competing brands. Table 1 shows the proportion of the total purchasing in each of the four weeks through the three main outlet types reported in the survey. Each week, around half the panel bought some type of seafood from one or more of the channels (average of 58%), most from a supermarket, although 21% ate seafood in a restaurant and just under10% bought from a fishmonger. Although these proportions remained in approximate equilibrium from week to week, individual consumers had different purchasing propensities, a few repeating each week, and about half buying only once or twice in four weeks. Evidence of buying from multiple sources in the same week was also seen (total purchasing across three channels is greater than 58%). These are typical brand-level buying patterns and were clearly identified between categories at the generic level. Table 1. Stability in generic seafood purchases by week. É of those who bought seafood (n=105) Anywhere Supermarket Restaurant Fishmonger % % % % Week 1 Week 2 Week 3 Week 4 57 58 60 57 38 35 38 36 18 19 22 25 11 11 4 5 Average 58 37 21 8 Table 1 also shows a seasonal fluctuation in buying. In weeks three and four purchasing through restaurants increased by a few points, with a corresponding decrease in fishmonger purchasing. The data was collected in the run-up to Christmas, and this pattern reflects the temporary upward trend in eating out. The between– category pattern is similar to that seen at the product-form level where price promotions attract buyers in one period, who then switch to another acceptable brand at the next purchase. Here the generic need was being met by one channel on one occasion, but met equally well by another at another time. As with brands, such a trend is only temporary, although here it indicates a heightened substitutability between two of the three channels, as supermarket sales remained almost steady. The competitive intensity of multiple category purchasing seen in Table 1 was next examined using a duplication of purchase analysis. The level of detail was extended to incorporate the six largest seafood categories bought in the data, namely Shelf (largely tinned and jars), Restaurant (restaurants, pubs and takeaways), Delicatessen, Frozen, Fishmonger and Fridge (chilled portions and ready meals). Penetrations for each these categories were established, and cross purchasing set out as in Table 2. From this, a duplication coefficient was calculated according to the DoP law (average penetration divided by average duplication for the period), and a benchmark established for each category. As expected, the average duplications shown in Table 2 declined in line with the category penetrations, and were also a reasonable fit to the predicted values. It thus became clear that satisfying the generic need for any seafood between categories resulted in buying behaviour similar to that seen between competing brands within a category. Buyers of one category were also buyers of other categories, simply in line with penetration. For example, 48% of consumers who bought from a fishmonger also bought from a deli (predicted duplication 46%), while only a quarter also bought from the freezer (predicted 27%). Comparison with the benchmark also revealed some partitions in buying. First, restaurant customers bought seafood from every category, but shopped a little less than expected everywhere except the fishmonger, where they purchased a little more. This may indicate a small quality-seeking partition. There is also a convenience partition. Freezer and fridge buyers purchased more heavily than expected from the shelf, and shelf buyers purchased less than expected from the fishmonger, but these are only slight variations around the benchmark, rather than deeply carved segmentation. The generality of purchasing is across multiple complementary categories, a finding that has important implications for strategy as we discuss next. Table 2: Duplication of purchase by seafood category Pen. % 60 55 39 23 22 8 Of those buying from: Éproportion (%) also buying from: Shelf Rest'rant Deli Freezer F'monger Fridge Shelf Restaurants Deli Freezer Fishmonger Fridge 58 57 73 52 78 53 55 54 76 67 37 39 42 48 78 28 23 25 24 67 19 31 27 23 22 10 10 16 23 8 - Avg. Duplication D x Penetration 64 71 61 65 49 46 34 27 24 26 13 9 Coefficient D = 1.18 Conclusions and further research The duplication of purchase technique, even from a small diary panel, is a useful measure of competition at the generic level where data may not be comparable or easy to find. For example, while retail panel data is in plentiful supply, equivalent foodservice purchasing is far harder to track. This technique captures whole-ofcustomer purchasing, which can therefore be aggregated for analysis. We have shown that many of the normal patterns of repeat buying seen within categories replicate at the wider generic-level of competition, between categories. In the same way that competing brands are substitutable, so are all categories that meet the generic need. The duplication of purchase law can thus be extended to primary level competition, which will be useful in understanding the characteristics of a wider competitive set. The dynamics of such competition, and exceptions to the law, offer insight for new product development, brand growth and brand extension strategies. The marketing response to generic-level competition is different from the category level. In the latter, brand marketers look inward at near competitors. Keller (1993) suggests that managers must identify and act upon points of parity and points of difference to market the best version of the product form. In responding to genericlevel competition though, marketers must look outside in order to promote both category benefits and the brand offer to build penetration from users of other related categories. Over four weeks only 8% of this sample bought seafood from the fridge, a category with closely competing brands. While it is nearly impossible to grow brands by taking share permanently from category competitors (Graham, 2009) our findings suggest a better strategy; to build category penetration by attracting new buyers to the brand from related markets, here perhaps from the fishmonger or the freezer. Lehmann and Winer (2005) have suggested that at the level of primary demand customers buy for a wider variety of reasons (eg frozen is more convenient than fresh). This might suggest that a more pronounced partitioning between categories would become apparent. We didn’t see this clearly. Seafood however is a narrow generic. At the level of protein it competes with meat, and perhaps also cheese and tofu products, so here perhaps a clearer segmentation would emerge. Further research is now needed at such broader generic levels with more categories and bigger samples, to explore this idea, and further extend these findings. References Aaker, D. (2002). Building strong brands. London: Simon and Schuster. Bang, V. and Joshi, S. (2008) Conceptualization of market expansion strategies in emerging economies. Academy of Marketing Science Review, 12, 4,1-26. Colombo, R. and Morrison (1989) A Brand Switching Model with Implications for Marketing Strategies. Marketing Science. 8, 1, 89-99. Dall'Olmo Riley, F., Ehrenberg, A., Castleberry, S., Barwise, P and Barnard, N. (1997), The Variability of Attitudinal Repeat-Rates, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 14, 5, pp 437-50. Goodhardt, G., Ehrenberg, A., and Chatfield, C. (1984). The Dirichlet: a comprehensive model of buying behaviour. Journal of the Statistical Society, A, 147, 621-655. Graham, C. (2009) What’s the point of marketing anyway. Journal of Marketing Management, 25, 9-10, 867-874. East, R., Hammond, K., & Gendall, P. (2006). Fact and fallacy in retention marketing. Journal of Marketing Management, 22,1/2, pp5-23. Ehrenberg, A. (1988). Repeat buying, (2nd ed.). London: Charles Griffin. Ehrenberg & Goodhardt, (1970). A Model of Multi-Brand Buying. Journal of Marketing Research. VII, (February) pp 77-84 Ehrenberg, A., Uncles, M., & Goodhardt, G. (2004). Understanding brand performance measures: using Dirichlet benchmarks, Journal of Business Research, 57, 1307-1325. Erdem, Tulin (1996) A Dynamic Analysis of Market Structure Based on Panel Data. Marketing Science. 15,4. 359-378. Kennedy, R., & Ehrenberg, A. (2001). There is no brand segmentation. Marketing Research, 13(1), 4-7. Keller, Kevin (1993) Conceptualizing, Measuring, and Managing Customer-Based Brand Equity. Journal of Marketing, 57, (Jan) 1-22. Keller, K and Lehmann, D. (2006) Brands and Branding: Research Findings and Future Priorities. Marketing Science. 25,6, 740-759 Lehmann, D and Winer, R. (2005). Product Management. 4th International edition. New York, NY; McGraw-Hill. Levitt, T (1960) “Marketing Myopia”. Harvard Business Review, July-August, 45-56 Reicheld, F, (2003) The One Number You Need. Harvard Business Review. December, 46-54. Reinartz, W. and Kumar, V. (2002) The Mismanagement of Customer Loyalty. Harvard Business Review, July, 86 – 94. Shocker, A. (2005) Determining the competitive structure of product markets: practices, issues and suggestions. In B.Weitz and R. Wensley (Eds.) Handbook of Marketing, (pp 106-125) London; Sage Publications. Shocker, A., Stewart, D., and Zahorik, A. (1990a). Determining the competitive structure of product markets: practices, issues and suggestions. Journal of Managerial Issues. 11, 127-159. Acknowledgement The authors would like to thank Simplot Seafood Australia Pty Ltd. for their generous permission to use the data quoted in this study.