MANAGING INTERORGANIZATIONAL RELATIONS IN INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY INTENSIVE ENVIRONMENTS A Proposal by: Eric A. Walden Information and Decision Sciences Carlson School of Management University of Minnesota Room 3-365 321 19th Avenue South Minneapolis, MN 55455 Phone: (612) 624-3816 Fax: (612) 626-1316 ewalden@csom.umn.edu http://eric.akindofmagic.com COMMITTEE: Gordon Davis (IS) Management Information Systems Mani Subramani (IS) Organizational Theory and Governance Baba Prasad (IS) Information Systems Management George John (Marketing) Interorganizational Relationships Thomas J. Holmes (ECON) Industrial Organization ABSTRACT Interorganizational systems (IOSs) are proving to be a necessity for firm performance and even survival in an increasingly complex technological environment. To enable such systems to be successful requires not only technological expertise, but also an ability to manage the interorganizational relationship (IOR). This dissertation proposes three essays to investigate how to manage the relationships necessary to enable superior performance from these systems. These essays examine the knowledge resources, the contractual bond, and the performance outcomes, of information technology (IT) based relationships, in order to generate a strong theoretical contribution to the state of the art of information system (IS) research. Key Words: Inter-Organizational Systems, Economic Theory, Organizational Value Chain, Contract, Transaction Cost Economics, Economics, Information In Organizations, Issues In Organizing IS, Organizational Behavior Word Count: 4176 – 204 = 3972 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments BACKGROUND AND OBJECTIVES On February 26, 2001, after the close of the New York stock exchange, Nike, Inc announced that its third quarter earnings would be between $0.34 and $0.38 per share rather than the previous estimate of $0.50 to $0.55 per share. This was in great part blamed on “complications arising from the impact of implementing our new demand and supply planning systems and processes which resulted in product shortages and excesses as well as late deliveries” according to Nike CEO Philip H. Knight (PRNewswire 2001). This supply chain mistake, originating in the forecasting software of partner firm i2 Technologies, left retailers without the styles that consumers desired, and created an excess inventory that will take nearly a year to liquidate (Siberia, Girard and Robinson 2001). Nike was not the only firm damaged. I2 was awarded the dubious honor of Forbes.com dog of the day (Murphy 2001), it has lowered its earning estimates and is considering laying off 10% of its workforce. Between the two firms, almost $5 billion in value was lost in one day (see Table 1). Not only has this value failed to returned, but also the egregious error has spawned a number of class action law suits (for example Cauley Geller Bowman & Coates, LLP at http://biz.yahoo.com/prnews/010405/dath031.html). i2 (ITWO) Close 2-26-01 Close 2-27-01 Loss Price per share $ 35.50 $ 27.56 $ 7.94 Shares 410,736,060 410,736,060 Market Cap $ 14,581,130,130 $ 11,320,912,654 $ 3,260,217,476 Price per share $ 49.17 $ 39.60 $ 9.57 Shares 170,863,000 170,863,000 Market Cap $ 8,401,333,710 $ 6,766,174,800 $ 1,635,158,910 Nike (NKE) Close 2-26-01 Close 2-27-01 Loss Overall 1-day loss $ 4,895,376,386 Table 1: Market Capitalization for Nike and i2 Technologies The important point from an information systems (IS) perspective is that this fiasco was not the result of failed technology—i2’s technology did not crash or fail to perform—but the result of poor relationship management (Siberia, et al. 2001). The difficulties arose because Nike and i2 technologies failed to work together to make the system responsive to the environment in 1 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments which it was expected to perform. This type of problem is not, by any means, unique. For example, in 1999 problems with the SAP system software caused Hershey to under deliver during the important Halloween season (Farmer and Luening 2001). W.L. Gore has filed suit against PeopleSoft for problems in its supply chain, FoxMeyer filed a $500 million suit in 2000 against Andersen Consulting for problems with its SAP system, and Whirlpool has cited its SAP system for shipping delays (Farmer and Luening 2001). Increasingly, the problem in information technology (IT) is not a technology problem or an individual organization problem, but a relationship problem. Because IOSs have taken on heightened importance in electronic business environments the management of interorganizational relationships (IORs) has become a key success factor in the development and implementation of IT. The competitive environment is extensively shaped by developments in hardware, software and networking technologies, and therefore inextricably linked to the rapid cycles of change in these enabling technologies. Not only must tasks be executed at a frenetic pace, but also the total number and variety of electronically enabled tasks is increasing. This requires firms’ IT infrastructure to be both highly reliable and extremely flexible. Be it for outsourcing, building an interorganizational system (IOS) or for development of business to business (B2B) electronic marketplace, firms that need technology solutions must interact with other firms in order to build a joint solution that combines technology with business practices. Success, and even survival, in such an environment requires the ability to manage relationships between an organization and its partners. Research indicates that executives spend fully one-third of their budgets on the management of external relationships. This tremendous need to coordinate with outside entities has even prompted some industrial analysts to call for a new executive officer, the Chief Relationship Officer (Mayor 2000), to manage firm relationships. Furthermore, as firms move away from simply outsourcing the development of software into more complex infrastructure projects the nature of the relationship becomes more complex. However, the evidence on the value of relational business models is far from equivocal. It is estimated that outsourcing clients spend 15% of their IT budget on litigation with erstwhile partners. To be sure, the management of relationships will be one of the fundamental research agendas for the next several decades. 2 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments Both IS practitioners and academics have long recognized the importance of considering the human factors in systems development (Mason and Mitroff 1973). Likewise, the impacts of human interaction on systems have also been recognized in the literature (DeSanctis and Poole 1994, Orlikowski 1992). However, there has yet to be a systematic research stream focused on understanding the impacts of firm-to-firm interactions in IS development, use, and value. The IS research focused on understanding IORs has focused predominantly on the impact of IT on the ability of firms to engage in relationships (Bakos and Brynjolfsson 1993, Clemons, Reddi and Row 1993, Gurbuxani and Whang 1991, Malone, Yates and Benjamin 1987). A notable exception is the work of Lacity and colleges (Lacity and Hirschheim 1993, Lacity and Hirschheim 1995, Lacity and Willcocks 1998, Willcocks, Lacity and Kern 1999), which attempts to explain outsourcing relationships through managerial interviews. An array of insightful observations is presented, but the authors do not offer a rigorous model of IORs. While a complete understanding of IORs is a laudable goal, this thesis pursues a more modest ambition. This thesis is aimed at simply beginning a research stream directed toward understanding how inter-firm relationships impact IT, and how those relationships can be managed to leverage a whole range of revolutionary advances in IT as well as to maximize the effectiveness of IT currently deployed by firms. This groundwork proceeds by laying the framework for understanding three important aspects of IORs in IT environments. First, the thesis examines the basic value propositions behind such relationships. Second, it examines how firms understand and structure a relationship through the contracting process. Third, it tests how the number and type of relationships impacts firm performance. While this is not the definitive word on the subject of firm relationships, it is certainly a good foundation for a productive research agenda. RESEARCH QUESTIONS As the above discussion illustrates, the management of IORs is, and will be a fundamental issue in IS for many years to come. There is a fundamental need for reconciliation between the relational approach’s shinning triumphs and its glairing failures. Prior research on IT relationships has been largely exploratory, focused mainly on offering a descriptive assessment of a specific relationship. The goal of my dissertation is to provide a rigorous theoretical basis for understanding how to manage IT intensive relationships in order to promote superior 3 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments business performance. To accomplish this, I propose a three-essay approach that examines each of three important steps in establishing a successful business relationship. The first essay, entitled “Organizational Form And Information Flows: How Infrastructure Providers Deliver Value,” is a look into the value propositions of IT outsourcing. One of the primary theoretical tools for examining relationships in IS is transaction costs economics. This research has been focused primarily on explaining how IT mitigates relational problems, thus leading firms away from hierarchy. However, very little IS research focuses on why a firm would be willing to enter into a relationship in the first place. Previous literature has simply assumed that partner firms are better at a specific aspect of business than the focal firm is. My goal is to push theory forward by explaining why some firms may systematically be better at specific IT processes than other firms. The thesis of this essay is that an IT partner firm, by virtue of the fact that it manages the IT function for multiple focal firms, is privileged to information not available to the individual focal firms. In a series of propositions based on the work of Maskin, Qian and Xu (Maskin, Qian and Xu 2000), I derive the conditions under which this privileged information allows the partner firm to construct superior incentives for its employees, resulting in superior IT performance. Further, I detail the circumstances under which relational sourcing will not provide additional benefit, and what sorts of partners are likely to provide the greatest benefit. The main result is that an IT partner can emulate any incentive for the IT employees that a traditional firm can, provided that the variance of the outsourced employee’s output conditional on the output of other IT employees, is less than the variance of the same employee’s output conditional on the output of non-IT employees within the traditional firm. The intuition is simply that the IT partner can compare an employee’s output to the output of other IT employees, while the traditional firm must compare the output of its IT employees to the output of employees from other functional areas such as marketing or R&D. Even ignoring all of the problems with comparing lines of code to number of patents, it seems intuitive that knowing that the R&D department produced 10% more patents this year, while the IT department produced 20% more lines of code this year, does not form the basis for a reasonable comparison. One of the corollaries to this is that an IT partner that is not engaged in the specific aspect of IT being considered for a relationship will not provide any additional value. Consequently, an IT partner specializing in data center management will not offer any value proposition as a partner for web 4 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments sight development. These are very powerful results because they can explain not only the source of the advantage IT partners possess, but also when there is likely to be no advantage. This allows practitioners to more accurately assess their partnership possibilities. Another satisfying result of the analysis is that as overall variance decreases in the business environment, the value of forming partnerships over unaided development decreases to zero. On the flip side, this indicates that as environmental variance increases the value of partnerships over unaided development increases (see Figure 1). This feature of the model helps explain why recent years have seen a greater level of IT based relationships than occurred in the past. This ability to explain observed phenomena lends validity to the model. Figure 1: Effects of Variance on Value of Relational Management Value ($) Effects of Increased Variance on Value Variance Value from Partnership Value from Unaided Development After establishing that the partner firm has something additional to bring to the alliance, the firms must construct and elucidate the relationship. This inter-firm sense making process exhibits itself in the contract between the two parties. The contract represents the best effort on behalf of both firms to design a device to overcome the problems inherent in relationships among profit maximizing entities. The second essay, entitled “On The Structure and Function of Outsourcing Contracts: An Interpretive Assessment Based on Property Rights,” introduces the incomplete contracting model of Grossman and Hart (Grossman and Hart 1986) as a model of firm behavior. This model posits that because each firm must share the fruits of its labor with the partner firm, 5 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments both members of the alliance underinvest in quality of production. The innovation is in understanding a contract is an artifact, which arises in response to incomplete contracting problems, that provides guarantees to each alliance partner in order to encourage optimal investment. By examining actual contracts, one can develop an understanding of the incomplete contracting problems that the contract is designed to solve. From this framework, I provide an interpretive analysis of the contracts. This examination of outsourcing contracts makes a number of valuable contributions to the IS literature. First, it uses the integrative approach to link both positivist and interpretive research to build greater understanding of an important IS issue. As such, it adds another brick to the foundation of this relatively underutilized approach. Secondly, this work adds another branch to the research in incomplete contracting. It recognizes the behavior model inherent in the incomplete contracting literature, and focuses on that. In so doing, it posits that the property rights aspect of this theory is only on of a variety of ways to offer assurances. Other methods might include, dependence balancing, reputation, trust, and messaging. Further, this work avoids the argument over whether contracts can be written to simulate property rights, by assuming a temporal structure wherein the gain to trade is present before contract negotiations take place (see Figure 1Figure 2). Accordingly, contracts must begin as incomplete regardless of the describeability of states of the world, or the verifiability of outcomes. Figure 2: Timeline of Relationship Value proposi tion to trade in period four exogenously established Period 1 Firms negotiate a contract to maxi mize surplus in period 4 Period 2 Firms make investments tha t determine surplus Period 3 Firms negotiate over surplus contingent on contract Period 4 The third contribution is a deeper understanding of the reasons for contracting. It is known that firms write contracts to solve problems, but it is not clear, at a fundamental level, what those problems are. Using the behavior model of incomplete contract theory, this work proposes that 6 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments the problem contracts solve is one of investment. Specifically, contracts modify non-cooperative payoffs, which in turn alter threat points in bargaining over joint surplus allowing a firm to collect a larger percentage of the surplus it generates. A larger percentage equates with a larger marginal benefit, which leads to greater investment and hence greater surplus. Thus, a properly written contract leads to a more productive relationship. A forth contribution of this work lies in taking a close look at the actual text of real contracts. By showing the IS community the text of contracts, rather than just a model of what they can do, this work should provide the impetus for new thinking about outsourcing and IORs in general. Analysis of the presented text has been left purposefully open in hopes that future researchers will be stimulated to think through new theory to help explain IS contracting. Finally, with the contract in place and the belief that the partner firm has unique and valuable expertise, it is necessary to validate that the relationship is adding values to both firms. To examine this, the final essay entitled, “Inducing Quality Investments in Electronic Commerce,” will focus on empirical validation of the value of relationships using the incomplete contract results of Hart and Moore (Hart and Moore 1988). This is the multi-relationship view of incomplete contract theory that has been widely cited in the ISs literature (Bakos and Brynjolfsson 1993), but never rigorously tested. In fact, the multi-relation aspect has never been tested in any literature of which I am aware. The basic result is that firms should have fewer suppliers in order to provide those suppliers with more bargaining power to properly motivate them to make investments. A number of hypotheses are developed to inform greater understanding of the impacts of IORs. For example, I propose that a supplier firm should suffer less from having a great number of partner firms because each new firm brings additional value to the table. In contrast, a purchasing firm generally requires a fixed amount of an input and bringing in more partners to supply that input simply weakens each of the other partners. The subtlest hypothesis examines the interaction of quality initiatives, such as ISO 9000 certification, with the number of partners. An important aspect of quality initiatives is to develop and use many measures for processes and product quality. Thus, firms pursuing quality initiatives will be better able to use contracts to mitigate incomplete contracting problems, and this effect should be more pronounced for firms with greater numbers of partners. 7 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments RESEARCH METHODOLOGY While human interaction is the purview of Psychology and Sociology, firm interaction is the province of Marketing and Economics. Each of these disciplines has contributed greatly to the understanding of IORs (Grossman and Hart 1986, Hart and Moore 1988, Hart and Moore 1990, Heide and John 1988, John, Weiss and Dutta 1999, Rindfleisch and Heide 1997, Williamson 1975, Williamson 1985) and offers insights for IS researchers to apply to the understanding of the IT domain. Thus, the reference discipline of this research will be economics, and the perspective will have all of the benefits and drawbacks of economic research. I am particularly proud of the methodologies employed in the dissertation. I propose to use three different methodologies to better generate subject matter for future research. These techniques include analytical modeling, interpretive research, and statistical research. The first essay builds an analytical model of information as a function of firm structure, and then proves several theorems. This allows me to build a very precise theory of the value provided by partnerships. I can then carry this precise model forward into the other essays. The second essay uses interpretive analysis of actual partnering contracts to better understand the issues faced by firms in the contracting phase. The goal is not so much to test hypothesis or to construct a model, as it is to understand the contracting process. The final essay will use newswire announcements of partnerships to build a dataset. Aggregating this data over multiple years will allow me to construct a measure of the number of partnerships. Supplemented with financial data, this will allow me to use econometric techniques to test the model’s hypothesis. RESEARCH PLAN Thus far, my progress has been consistent with the proposed competition date of 2002. The analytical model of the first essay has been developed and solved, and most of the front end of the essay written. What remains to be done is to more thoroughly explain the propositions developed from the model, and to expand the conclusion. Then it will be a matter of making the minor revisions required of specific committee members. This will be completed by early May. The second essay is partially complete. I have already acquired the data (contracts from a major IT vendor), and constructed the theoretical basis for the analysis. What remains is to delve deeper into the contracts to strengthen my case, to develop a compelling conclusion, and to submit to the specific requirements of my committee. Work on this essay will begin in earnest in April and continue through to July. April will be devoted to finishing a first draft, May to gathering feedback on that draft, and June and July will be spent responding to that feedback. 8 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments Several items remain for the final essay. The first step, slotted for May 2001, is to gather the preliminary data about partnership announcements. I have done similar work before and am fortunate to have an intelligent software agent constructed specifically for this type of data gathering. I expect that, with my other commitments, it will take 2 months, June and July, to sift through the data and determine which announcements to study. Gathering the appropriate financial data is my task for August. September and October will see me beginning the data analysis. November will be the month for producing the first draft. December will be spent gathering feedback, and preparing my proposal defense. January and February will be occupied chiefly with job search activities. March and April will find me responding to the feedback with finishing touches and a final defense in May. In June, I will go on vacation. EXPECTED CONTRIBUTION The relational model of firm production will become more pronounced in the future, as firms strive to compete successfully. Firms will have to rely on outside relationships for a whole range of IT needs from outsourcing, to IOSs, to B2B marketplaces. The success of these systems depends on the quality of the relationship among the firms. This dissertation seeks to build a rich theoretic understanding for how firms can manage their IT relationships to generate maximum benefit, not just for themselves, but also for the entire productive partnership. By understanding both the antecedents and consequences of the relationships, as well as the behavioral framework from which firms first enter these relationships, I hope to make a lasting contribution that will help both scholars and practitioners better understand new business forms. CHALLENGES I foresee no significant challenges to completion. The first essay relies on an analytical model which has been solved and developed. The data for the second essay has already been collected and the theoretical model explicated. The final essay relies on publicly available data and thus, does not have the problems inherent in relying on an outside source (i.e. relational problems). The largest potential problem is that there will be no results from the empirical tests. This is still interesting in that is will constitute the firs empirical test of a well established theory, and will refute that theory. Of course, as with any long term project, any number of unforeseen difficulties may arise. 9 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments SELECTED REFERENCES (Full References Available On Request) [1] Bakos, J. Y., and Brynjolfsson, E. “Information technology, incentives, and the optimal number of suppliers,” Journal of Management Information Systems (10:2), 1993, pp. 3753. [2] Clemons, E. K., Reddi, S. P., and Row, M. C. “The impact of information technology on the organization of economic activity: The "move to the middle" hypothesis,” Journal of Management Information Systems (10:2), 1993, pp. 9-29. [3] DeSanctis, G., and Poole, M. S. “Capturing the Complexity in Advanced Technology Use: Adaptive Structuration Theory,” Organization Science (5:2), 1994, pp. 121-147. [4] Farmer, M. A., and Luening, E. “i2-Nike fallout a cautionary tale,” (2001:April 5), 2001 (available online at: http://news.cnet.com/news/0-1007-200-5070729.html?tag=tp_pr). [5] Grossman, S. J., and Hart, O. D. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy (94:4), 1986, pp. 691719. [6] Gurbuxani, V., and Whang, S. “The Impact of Information Systems on Organizations and Markets,” Communications of the ACM (34:1), 1991, pp. 59-73. [7] Hart, O., and Moore, J. “Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation,” (56:4), 1988, pp. 755-785. [8] Hart, O., and Moore, J. “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” The Journal of Political Economy (98:4), 1990, pp. 1119-1158. [9] Heide, J. B., and John, G. “The Role of Dependence-Balancing in Safeguarding Transaction-Specific Assets in Conventional Channels,” Journal of Marketing (52), 1988, pp. 20-35. [10] John, G., Weiss, A. M., and Dutta, S. “Marketing in Technology-Intensive Markets: Toward A Conceptual Framework,” Journal of Marketing (63:Special Issue), 1999, pp. 78-91. [11] Lacity, M. C., and Hirschheim, R. Information Systems Outsourcing: Myths, Metaphors and Realities. New York, New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1993. [12] Lacity, M. C., and Hirschheim, R. Beyond The Information Systems Outsourcing Bandwagon. New York, NY: John Wiley & sons, 1995. [13] Lacity, M. C., and Willcocks, L. P. “An Empirical Investigation of Information Technology Sourcing Practices: Lessons from Experience,” MIS Quarterly (22:3), 1998, pp. 363-408. [14] Malone, T. W., Yates, J., and Benjamin, R. I. “Electronic Markets and Electronic Hierarchies: Effects of Information Technologies on Market Structure and Corporate Strategies,” Communications of the ACM (30:6), 1987, pp. 484-497. [15] Maskin, E., Qian, Y., and Xu, C. “Incentives, Information, and Organizational Form,” Review of Economic Studies (67:231), 2000, pp. 359-378. [16] Mason, R. O., and Mitroff, I. I. “A Program for Research on Management Information Systems,” Management Science (19:5), 1973, pp. 475-487. [17] Mayor, T. “Our Vendors, Ourselves,” in CIO, vol. 14, 2000, pp. 195-200. [18] Murphy, T. “Dog Of The Day: I2 Technologies,” (2001:April 4, 2001), 2001 (available online at: http://www.forbes.com/2001/02/27/0227mu1.html). [19] Orlikowski, W. J. “The Duality of Technology: Rethinking the Concept of Technology in Organizations,” Organization Science (3:3), 1992, pp. 398-427. 10 Managing Interorganizational Relations in Information Technology Intensive Environments [20] [21] [22] [23] [24] [25] PRNewswire. “Nike Revises Third Quarter and Fiscal Year 2001 EPS Guidance,” Nike Inc., Press Release February 26 2001. Rindfleisch, A., and Heide, J. B. “Transaction cost analysis: Past, present, and future applications,” Journal of Marketing (61:4), 1997, pp. 30-54. Siberia, P., Girard, K., and Robinson, E. “Just Blame the Software Guys,” in Business 2.0, 2001, pp. 25. Willcocks, L. P., Lacity, M. C., and Kern, T. “Risk mitigation in IT outsourcing strategy revisited: longitudinal case research at LISA,” Journal of Strategic Information Systems (8:3), 1999, pp. 285-341. Williamson, O. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press, 1975. Williamson, O. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Ney York, New York: Free Press, 1985. 11