Health Insurance and Consumption: Evidence from China’s New Cooperative Medical Scheme Chong-En Bai Binzhen Wu* Tsinghua University Abstract The precautionary saving motive is a popular explanation for the Chinese Saving Puzzle, but few empirical studies quantify the importance of the precautionary savings in China. We exploit the quasi-natural experiment provided by the introduction of a health insurance program in rural China to examine how the insurance coverage affects household consumption. The results show that the health insurance coverage on average stimulates non-healthcare related consumption by more than 5 percent. The effect exists even for households that have no health-care expenditure. In addition, the effect is stronger for poorer households and households with worse self-reported health status, who both have higher risk of relatively large health expenditure. We also find that the insurance effect varies with households’ experience with the program. Particularly, the effect is only significant in villages in which households witness some reimbursement resulting from the insurance coverage. In addition, the program stimulates more consumption for experienced participants than for new participants of the program in these villages. Keywords: New Cooperative Medical Scheme; Consumption; Health Insurance; Precautionary Savings; Chinese Saving Puzzle JEL Classification Nos.: D12, E21, I18 * Corresponding author. Email: wubzh@sem.tsinghua.edu.cn; Tel: 86-10-62772371. For their valuable suggestions, we want to thank participants in the workshops for Saving and Investment in China at Tsinghua University, seminar participants at the Central University of Finance and Economics, and participants at the Stanford-Tsinghua Conference on “Chinese Policy Reform: Topics for Troubled Times.” 1 1 Introduction Chinese high and rising saving rate has attracted a lot international attention. Household saving rate has risen by about ten percentage points between 1995 and 2008, reaching 28 percent of the disposable income in 2008, which is higher than most of other countries including East Asian countries (Prasad, 2009). The literature has proposed many explanations for this Chinese Saving Puzzle. A popular one is that the dissolution of the traditional social safety net has created more precautionary savings (Chamon and Prasad, 2008; Meng, 2003).1 Chinese government has made a lot effort to improve its safety net. The social insurance programs disbursed 1.2 trillion RMB in 2009, with an annual growth rate of 19.4% since 2000. However, there have been very few empirical studies that quantify the size of precautionary savings in China. Given that Chinese saving rate has important global impacts, it is crucial to learn how much the public insurance programs affect consumption and savings in China. The existing empirical literature for the developed countries delivers quite mixed results on the role of the precautionary savings. The results range from being very small (Dynan, 1993; Guiso, Jappelli, and Terlizzese, 1992; Hurst, et al., 2010; Starr-Mccluer, 1996) or modest (Engen and Gruber, 2001; Lusardi, 1998) to quite large (Banks et al., 2001; Carroll and Samwick, 1998; Fuchs-SchÜndeln and SchÜndeln, 2005; Kazarosian, 1997). Studies in the developing countries are still in their early stages (Lee and Sawada, 2010; Meng, 2003; Zhang and Wan, 2004). Most of the studies find a substantial amount of precautionary savings. Recent studies exploit the exogenous variations of the insurance coverage caused by policy changes, including Gruber and Yelowitz (1999), Engen and Gruber (2001), and Kantor and Fishback (1996) for the US, Atella, Rosati, and Rossi (2005) for Italy, Wagstaff and Pradhan (2005) for Vietnan, and Chou, Liu and Hammitt (2003) for Taiwan. Most of these studies confirm the importance of the precautionary savings, but it is not clear whether the estimates can be applied to China, not to mention that Chinese culture remains a popular explanation for the Chinese Saving Puzzle. 1 Other explanations include the life-cycle model with demographic changes (Kraay, 2000; Modigliani and Cao, 2004), high income growth and habit (Horioka and Wan, 2007), changes in the return rate of investment (Wen, 2009), the imbalance in the sex ratio (Wei and Zhang, 2009), financial underdevelopment (Caballero, Gourinchas and Farhi, 2008), income inequality (Jin, Li, and Wu, 2010) and cultural difference. 2 The launch of public health insurance programs in China provides natural experiments to investigate the size of the precautionary savings in China. This paper exploits one of most important policy changes in the rural areas: the introduction of the New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) since July 2003. This public health insurance program is heavily subsidized by the government, and has been introduced sequentially in different counties. Households’ participation is voluntary. We focus on the double-difference comparison between the insured and the non-participants in the villages that have launched the program. The reason is that households in the same village are more comparable to each other than to households in a different village and it can reduce the bias resulted from the contemporary policy changes that were introduced simultaneously with the NCMS. The difference-in-difference framework helps remove all the time-invariant selection bias. Selection bias on the observables is further reduced by allowing the temporal change in consumption to vary with income and health status or by applying matching difference-in-difference. The data we use combine the longitudinal Rural Fixed-Point Survey between 2003 and 2006 and a household survey on the NCMS for a subsample of the 2006 round of the Rural Fixed-Point Survey. The results indicate that household consumption other than health expenditure has increased by about 5.6 percent or 147.7RMB owning to the health insurance coverage. The magnitude is much larger than the average cost of the insurance that was mostly 30 RMB in 2003 and 50RMB in 2006. This is also consistent with the time trend of the saving rate at the aggregate level: the saving rate in the rural area has declined sharply since 2005 (Prasad, 2009). The result is quite robust to different specifications that try to control the difference in the counterfactual trend of consumption between the insured and the non-participants. We also find that the insurance effect remains significant for households who have no health care expenditure in the year, which cannot be explained by the “crowd-in” story that emphasizes that the insurance coverage reduces the out-of-pocket health expenditure, and thereby insured households have more income left for other consumption. Moreover, the insurance effect on consumption is much stronger for poorer households and households with worse self-reported health status, which is consistent with the argument that the higher the risk of having relatively huge health expenditure is, the more households reduce precautionary savings after being covered by the insurance. 3 Finally, the insurance effect varies with households’ experience with the program. In addition, households’ trust in the program can be crucial for the stimulation of consumption. For the experienced participants, the insurance effect on consumption increases to over 11 percent on average. Besides, the insurance effect on consumption is significant only in the villages where households witness reimbursement from the program and thus may establish trust in the program. Moreover, in such villages, the stimulation of consumption is stronger for the experienced members of the program than for the new members. In contrast, in the villages that have seen no reimbursement, both the insurance effect on average and the difference between experienced and new are insignificant. To our best knowledge, this is the first paper exploiting this policy change to rigorously assess the extent of precautionary savings in rural China. The finding about the role of the “trust” warrants more attention in both the literature and the policy making, particularly for public insurance programs in the developing countries where transparency and trust are often missing. The rest of the paper unfolds as follows. The second section introduces the background of the NCMS and the literature. Section 3 introduces the data and gives descriptive statistics. Section 4 discusses our econometric specifications. Section 5 shows the results for the baseline model. Section 6 shows the robustness tests. Section 7 concludes. 2 Background The New Cooperative Medical Scheme Since the dissolution of the rural Cooperative Medical System in the early 1980s, illness has emerged as a leading cause of poverty in rural China, and high cost of health care has deterred households from obtaining necessary health care (You and Kobayashi, 2009). 2 In response, the Chinese government started the pilot programs of the New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) in 2003. The primary goal of the NCMS is to reduce impoverishment due to catastrophic illness and improve the affordability of health care. The pilot program began in 310 rural counties of China’s more than 2800 rural counties in July 2003, expanded to 617 counties in 2005, 1451 counties in 2006, and by June 2007, 2 In 2003, 96% of rural households in China had no health insurance, 38% of the sick did not seek health care. Large negative health shocks reduced annual income by around 12.4% in rural China, and 22% of poor households attributed their poverty to illness or injury in 1998 (You and Kobayashi, 2009). 4 the time that we collect our data for the study, the program had expanded to over 84.9% of all rural counties and 82.8% of all rural residents. Although the central government has issued broad guidelines for how the NCMS should be designed and implemented, provincial and county governments have retained considerable discretion over the details of the program, including the placement of the pilot program and the insurance package. There are several main features of the NCMS: 1) the program targets at rural residents;3 2) participation is voluntary but should be in the unit of household;4 3) participating households need to pay a flat-rate premium, but the insurance is heavily subsidized by the governments; 4) the program mainly reimburses large expense; 5) the program is operated at the county level rather than township or village level. The voluntary nature of the participation raises concerns on the adverse selection that can threat the financial sustainability of the NCMS. However, the participation rates in pilot villages were generally very high, with an average of 86% between 2003 and 2006 in our sample. An important reason for the high participation rate is the generous government subsidies. For the premium, the standard in 2003 was that the participating household paid 10RMB and the government paid more than 20 RMB a year for each member in the household. Since 2006 (inclusive), the government subsidy has increased to 40 RMB for each member while household contribution has remained the same.5 Together with NCMS, the governments also implemented some supporting policies, such as improving the quality and the delivery of the health care service and strengthening the pharmaceutical governance. At the same time, there are statistics showing that the average expenditure per visit has increased after the introduction of the NCMS program (Yao and Kobayashi, 2009; Mao, 2005). These changes also affect households who choose not to participate the NCMS. In addition, the government has set up a parallel program, the medical assistance (MA) scheme, to help poverty-stricken population. Since counties have had substantial authority over the design of the NCMS, there has been considerable heterogeneity in the package of the benefit, coverage, and management 3 Urban districts and county-level cities that contain rural residents can also receive the program. The requirement of participation as a household unit is imposed over 97% of the counties in our sample. Some studies suggest that local governments have made considerable efforts to attain high participation rate, including mandating households to participate (Wu et al. 2006). However, our survey shows less than 1% households report compulsory enrollment in 2007, although it is not clear whether it was so in early years. 5 The poor and certain other groups have their contributions exempted. In 2008, the government subsidies increase to 80 RMB a year per person. Household’s contribution is raised to 20 RMB a year. 4 5 across counties. Table 1 shows the main parameters of the insurance packages for the 54 counties that we have detailed information on the insurance. We first notice that the insurance is typically not generous, maybe due to the scarce financial resources of the government. Particularly, many services, including outpatient care, are not fully covered, deductibles are high, ceilings are low, and coinsurance rates are high. However, the insurance program can still reduce the out-of-pocket health care substantially for the insured. At the township clinics, the deductible was on average about 125 RMB, and the ceiling was 14838 RMB, and the reimbursement rate was 50.9% in 2006. This implies that households could save 7489RMB at most. Moreover, the insurance plans have become more generous over time for all levels of health-care centers, particularly for the township clinics. Second, all counties cover the inpatient care, but the reimbursement rate varies substantially across counties, ranging from 20% to 75%. Third, most counties apply different insurance schemes for different levels of facilities. The insurance is more favorable to the low-level health-care centers as the coinsurance rate and the deductible are lower when households utilize health-care service at the township clinics than at county and (or) above levels of hospitals. And this feature has magnified over time. In contrast, the difference in the reimbursement rate for different amount of expenditure is small and declines over time.6 Literature (I think for JpubE, we can skip this part) After the seminal theoretical papers of Zeldes (1989), Deaton (1991), and Carroll (1992) that illustrate the potential importance of precautionary savings, many studies have examined the strength of the precautionary saving motives using micro data. Simulations or Structural estimations mostly find precautionary savings can explain a sizeable portion, as much as fifty percent, of U.S. savings (Cagetti, 2003; Gourinchas and Parker, 2002; Hubbard, Skinner, and Zeldes, 1994; Palumbo, 1999). In contrast, empirical studies that econometrically assess the role of precautionary savings have reached quiet mixed conclusions: Dynan (1993), Guiso et al. (1992), Hurst, et al. (2010) and Starr-Mccluer 6 Other statistics include: the procedure to get reimbursement has become simpler over time. In 2006, about 37.5% counties disburse the reimbursement immediately when households pay the health expenditure. In addition, around 48% counties provide insurance for migrants, although the reimbursement is usually much less generous for the health-care expenditure at the hospitals outside the county. 6 (1996) find little or no precautionary savings, whereas Banks et al. (2001) (for the UK), Carroll and Samwick (1998) and Kazarosian, (1997) (for the US), and Fuchs-SchÜndeln and SchÜndeln (2005) (for the Germany) find economically important precautionary motive. Early studies mostly examine the issue by relating wealth accumulation to some measures for the amount of risk that households face. The mixed results can be partially attributed to the difficulty in identifying an exogenous measure for the income uncertainty. Various measures have been tried, including the variability of income (Carroll and Samwick, 1998; etc.), the variability of consumption (Dynan, 1993), expectations of future job loss (Guiso et al., 1992; Lusardi, 1998), actual job loss (Carroll, Dynan, and Krane, 2003), a proxy based on job characteristics or education (Skinner, 1988), and households’ insurance coverage (Starr-Mccluer, 1996; Guariglia and Rossi, 2004). In the Chinese context, the literature along this line generally find strong evidence for the importance of precautionary savings (Meng, 2003; Zhang and Wan, 2004; Long and Zhou, 2000). However, these studies all suffer from the problem that individual’s income risks or subjective assessments of the risks are likely to be correlated with underlying tastes for savings. Recent studies exploit the exogenous variations of the insurance coverage caused by policy changes or variations, including Engen and Gruber (2001), Gruber and Yelowitz (1999), and Kantor and Fishback (1996) for the US, Atella and Rosati (2005) for Italy, and Wagstaff and Pradhan (2005) for Vietnam. An implication of the precautionary-saving story is that social insurance programs, by reducing income or expenditure risk, would reduce asset accumulation. Most of these studies all confirm this prediction, although they focus on different programs, including unemployment insurance, worker’s compensation, and health insurance. The research for developing countries is still at the early stage. Lee and Sawada (2010) investigate precautionary saving under liquidity constraints in Pakistan using household panel Data and find substantial evidence of the presence of precautionary saving. Wagstaff and Pradhan (2005) study the case in Vietnam and find the introduction of the health insurance program increases nonmedical household consumption, mostly non-food consumption, and the magnitude is much higher than the reduction in the out-of-pocket health expenditure. Chou, Liu and Hammitt (2003) find that the universalization of health 7 insurance in Taiwan reduced the household savings rate by about 2.5 percentage points. Ma, Zhang, and Gan (2010) examine the effect of the NCMS on rural household’s food consumption, and conclude the participants have higher calorie, carbohydrate, fat, and protein intake than the non-participants. Liu et al. (2010) investigate the effect of the public health insurance program on consumption for urban households in China, and their preliminary results show that the insurance has stimulated household consumption by 10.2 percent. There are also several papers trying to evaluate the effect of the program on the utilization of health care (Lei and Lin, 2009; Wagstaff et al., 2009). However, the impact of the NCMS on consumption in rural areas has not been fully explored. Some studies have shown that rural residents respond differently from the urban households to the income uncertainty (Zhang and Pei, 2007). In addition, the literature indicates the strength of the precautionary saving can be different between different income groups (Carroll, Dynan, and Krane, 2003). Notice that the Chinese government has planned to spend 40 billion RMB to boost consumption in the rural area in 2009, it is important to learn how the NCMS can help stimulate consumption. 3 Data and Descriptive Statistics Our data come from the longitudinal Rural Fixed-Point Survey (RFPS) between 2003 and 2006 and a supplementary household survey that aims at evaluating the NCMS. RFPS has surveyed the same households each year since 1980s. The sample is selected based on a multi-stage stratified random sampling strategy. The 2006 round includes 19,488 households in 313 villages drawn from 26 Chinese provinces. The survey uses the weekly book accounting information maintained by the households as the primary information source. It provides information about household and individual characteristics, and details about income and expenditure.7 The supplementary survey was conducted by Tsinghua University in May 2007. It surveyed a subsample of the 2006 round of RFP and covered 23 provinces, 143 villages, 5728 households. It collected detailed information about the time that a household enrolled in the NCMS, and the retrospective information on each member’s health 7 Unfortunately, there are a lot mistakes in the identification code for tracking individuals and households. We use conservative rules based on individual’s age, sex, and education to match individuals and households over years. If more than half of the household members cannot be matched across two years, we exclude the household from our sample. Altogether, we delete around 8% households in our sample due to the inconsistency of the identification code. 8 care utilization and expenditure in each year between 2003 and 2006. The survey oversampled households with economically meaningful health care expenditure.8 Table 2 shows the participation rate of the villages and households between 2003 and 2006.9 The enrollment of our sample villages spreads over different years with relatively higher rates in 2006, increased from about 15% in 2003 to about 77% in 2006. Similarly, the enrollment of households also spread over years, gradually increased from 10% in 2003 to 71% in 2006. These numbers are also consistent with the national data. In the villages that have launched the NCMS (called as NCMS-villages), the majority of households participated the program, and the participation rate increased from 64% in 2003 to 94% in 2006. Moreover, most households started to participate in the first year that the village launched the program, and the participation rate was 64% in 2003 and 96% in 2006 in the villages that launched the program for the first year. Nevertheless, these numbers also indicate that quite a few households chose not to participate the program or delayed in participation: over the 4 years between 2003 and 2006, about 13.9% households in the NCMS-villages did not participate, and among the participant about 14.4% households did not participate right after the village enlisted the NCMS. To relate consumption with households’ enrollment status of the NCMS, we exclude some outliers, such as households who have ever exited the NCMS or have participated some cooperative insurance program between 1993 and 2002. 10 Also excluded are households who have purchased commercial insurance in 2007 or have not participated in the NCMS but enrolled in some government insurance programs in 2007. 11 Finally, noticing that the program was first piloted in July 2003, we have excluded the observations in the year of 2003 for villages that launched the program in 2003, which can avoid the complication that the effect of the NCMS actually started in the middle of that year. As a result, the year of 2003 can be seen as the year where no counties have introduced the 8 More specifically, the survey first ranks all the households in the 2006 round of the RFPS based on their average health care expenditure between 2003 and 2006. Then it randomly draws 80% of the observations in the top one third of the sample, and 50% of the observations in the remaining two thirds of the sample. 9 The table shows the results for the balanced panel. For the unbalanced panel, we have more observations but the pattern of the results is very similar. 10 Only 107 households exit the program. About 4.6% households have enrolled in some cooperative insurance program between 1993 and 2003, and most of them participated after 1997. 11 For these two types of households, we exclude their observations in all years as we only have the information on the commercial insurance and government insurance program in 2007. About 6% of households report having some commercial insurance in 2007. 9 NCMS.12 Eventually, the sample includes 517 villages and 17,715 households in 4 years. Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics for three groups between 2004 and 2006: the insured households and two kinds of uninsured households: the non-participants who lived in the NCMS-villages but chose not to participate the program, and the non-exposed households who lived in the non-NCMS villages. Since more villages and households join in the program over time, the insured group includes more observations in 2006, while the non-exposed group includes more observations in 2003. To make the values of the variables that may change over time more comparable between these three groups, we focus on their values in 2003. The table illustrates that compared with the non-participants, the households choose to enroll in generally have higher consumption and higher income. In addition, they have more members reporting fair or worse health status, and spend more on in-patient health care than the non-participants. However, the participants have less members with very bad health-status, which help explain why they spend less on health-care.13 In addition, their heads are slightly older, more educated, less likely to single, or being a non-agricultural worker. They are also more likely to have communist members, while less likely to be a minority or household in poverty ("Wubao"). Table A.1 in the appendix gives the regression of households' participation decisions on observable household and village characteristics given that the village has launched the program. It confirms that most of these differences are significant. Moreover, the evidence for adverse selection is mixed: the probability of participation increases with the share of members with good or fair health status, where the reference group is the share of members with excellent health status; however, the participation rate actually declines when the share of the members with bad health status rises. Moreover, column 3 shows that even the positive evidence of the adverse selection disappears when we focus on the within-village comparison by controlling for the village fixed effect.14 12 We include these observations as a robust test, and find a smaller insurance effect of the NCMS on consumption as expected. 13 The pattern is the similar if we use the number of members with different health status. The subscribing households also on average have less members older than 65 or younger than 10, more migrants, and less likely to have a female head. However, the regression in Table A.1 shows that these differences are not significant or the signs are different. 14 What remains under within-village comparison is that non-participants are more likely to have members with bad health status, have younger or single head, be "Wubao" families, or have head working in the 10 The difference in the health-status is much smaller between the NCMS-villages and non-NCMS villages. However, the NCMS-villages on average spend more on in-patient expenditure than non-NCMS villages. Furthermore, the NCMS-villages are much richer, having less clinic but more kids taking vaccinations than the non-NCMS villages. They are also have less migrants, more laborers, higher education and are less likely to be in mountain areas, western or central areas. Column 4 of Table A.1 confirms these differences are significant. The table also indicates that although the non-participant are different from the insured, they seem to be more similar to the insured than the non-exposed in terms of income and consumption. This is not surprising as households living in the same village are more likely to be similar to each other than to people living in a different village. Column 4 confirms the significant difference between the NCMS-villages and the non-NCMS villages. Particularly, the NCMS-villages have higher income, less clinics, more kids vaccinated, less migrants, more laborer, and higher education. They are also less likely to be in the mountain areas, western or central areas.15 4 Baseline Empirical Model The empirical analysis exploits the quasi-natural experiment provided by the NCMS to examine the effect of the insurance coverage on household’s consumption. We start with applying the Difference-in-Difference (DID) framework to the 4-year panel. More specifically, the effects of the NCMS are identified by the differences in the dynamic changes in consumption around the launch of the NCMS between the insured and uninsured households. The advantage of the double-difference method is to remove all the time-invariant selection bias. This is crucial in our context because the participation is voluntary, which implies that households who chose not to participate are different from the participants in both observable and unobservable characteristics and hence in the counterfactuals of consumption. Similarly, the program placement over villages can be non-random. The double-difference method between the insured and the uninsured can still deliver unbiased and consistent estimations, as long as the temporal change in households’ non-agricultural sector. 15 This regression is based on county-level data. When we run on the household-level data, almost all the variables become significant. 11 consumption would have been parallel if there had been no NCMS. In our context, there are actually two groups of uninsured households in each period. One is the non-participants who chose not to enroll in the NCMS-villages that have launched the program. The other is the non-exposed who lived in the non-NCMS villages that have not introduced the program. Their reasons to be uninsured are quite different. To examine the precautionary saving motive, we focus on the double-difference between the insured and the non-participants in the NCMS-villages for two reasons. The first one concerns the fact that other changes happened together with the introduction of the NCMS. Particularly, the governments provided supporting policies to improve the quality and the delivery of health care service. In addition, a lot anecdotal evidence indicates that the price of the health-care service has increased after the introduction of the program (Mao, 2005). For the precautionary-saving story, we need to identify the insurance effect of the NCMS that works only through the insurance coverage, and hence exclude the effects of these contemporary policies or changes. The insurance effect can be estimated by the double-comparison between the insured and the non-participants within the NCMS-counties because both groups were affected by these changes.16 In contrast, the double-difference between the insured and the non-exposed delivers the gross effect of the NCMS on the insured, which includes both the insurance effect of the NCMS and the effects of other associated changes. The second reason is related to the identification assumption for the difference-in-difference model: the dynamics of consumption between the insured and the control group should be the same around the relevant period. We argue that the assumption is more problematic for the comparison between the insured and the non-exposed than the comparison between the insured and the non-participants. First, households in the same village are more likely to be similar to each other than to households living in a different village. This argument is partially justified by table 3 and table A.1, where we see significant difference between the NCMS-villages and the non-NCMS villages.17 Second, 16 The effects of these policies can be different for the insured and the non-participants. Thus, the insurance effect has incorporated the difference. The NCMS may also activate or strengthen the precautionary-saving motive as it has educated people about the risks to stimulate more participation. 17 We have also tried the propensity matching procedure to balance on the observable village and household characteristics. It turns out to matching is much more successful when matching insured with the non-participants in the NCMS-villages than matching between the insured with the non-exposed in a 12 the consumption can grow more similarly among people living in the same geographic areas than among people living in different areas. This is related to the issue of non-random program placement: the rolling-out of the NCMS was strongly correlated with village’s average income and hence consumption. To implement the DID framework for the panel data, the baseline model applies the fixed-effect regression that controls both household and year fixed effects. All the time-invariant effects of household characteristics are controlled by the household fixed effects, and the yearly time trend of consumption that is common for all households is controlled by the year fixed effects.18 Refinements such as matching DID and tests of the identification assumptions are discussed in Section 6, which confirm that the baseline model is reliable. More specifically, the baseline model for the double-difference between the insured and the non-participants is as following: Yijt Family _ insured it t Tt i Di X ijt ijt , (1) where Yijt represents the log value of households’ consumption net of health expenditure for household i who lives in village j in period t. The reason to exclude health expenditure is that we want to focus on precautionary savings, and health expenditure is affected by insurance through other channels. 19 To simplify exposition, consumption means all consumption expenses net of health expenditure throughout the paper, unless otherwise specified. Family_insuredit is the binary variable indicating whether household i having subscribed the insurance program in year t. Tt includes 3 year dummies. Di includes all the household indicators. Xijt includes all the observable household and village variables that vary over time and may affect consumption dn the participation decision, including log(household income), household size, and log(average income per person in the village), different village. 18 One advantage of the regression method is that we can easily control the effect of time-variant variables that may affect household’s treatment status and consumption. Moreover, it is quiet easy to estimate the difference in the impacts across subsamples using the regression method. However this method imposes the linearity functional assumption that can be problematic when the treated and untreated are quite different. 19 We also tried other outcomes, such as consumption per person, total consumption including health expenditure, spending (including consumption and investment), and savings (measured by the savings in the saving account plus money borrowed out). The results for consumption per person are almost the same as those for consumption. The results for total consumption and spending show similar patterns, but the magnitudes are smaller, particularly for the spending. The effect of the NCMS on savings is mostly not significant, although the direction is consistent with our expectation. However, savings are not well measured in this dataset. 13 number of members over age 65, number of members under age 10, whether having communist party members, and whether being officially poor (“Wubao” family). In equation (1), γ measures the effect of the insurance coverage on consumption. The precautionary-saving story indicates that >0. Since we control for log(income), also represents the effect of the NCMS on the average propensity to consume (or consumption rate), as log(consumption rate) is equal to the difference between log(consumption) and log(income). For expositional simplicity, we hereafter use consumption and consumption rate interchangeably. A main concern in the baseline model is the identification assumption may not hold, that is, after conditional on the observable characteristics, the consumption of the insured and that of the non-participants may not be parallel in absence of the NCMS. 20 The most likely story is related to the adverse selection: households who expect substantial health expenditure in the next year are more likely to participate and hence their consumption path around the implementation of the NCMS would have been different from households who have no such expectation. By excluding health expenditure from consumption, we actually avoid the complication that the participants tend to have more expenditure on health-care after being covered by the insurance. In addition, the selection bias tends to underestimate the precautionary-saving motive as families with the expectation of huge health expenditure are more likely to be frugal in consumption. Finally, although the expectation on the health expenditure in the near future is unobservable, it can be proxy by the self-reported health status. As a result, we can address the potential selection bias by allowing households with different health status to have different time trend in consumption. Similarly, we can allow households with different income to have different time trend in consumption to address the concern resulted from the phenomenon that the insured are generally richer than the non-participants and different income groups may have different income growth rate. 20 Wagstaff et al. (2009) focus on the double-comparison between the insured and the non-exposed to evaluate the effect of the NCMS on health-care expenditure. We think their choice is reasonable when the focus is a program evaluation so that the gross effect may be more important. Also when the outcome interested is health-care expenditure, the potential selection bias due to the voluntary participation is a serious concern for the double-difference comparison between the insured and the non-participant, because the reason that the non-participants did not join the program can be that they were confident of not needing substantial health care in the foreseeable future while the participants were just the opposite. 14 5 Results for the Baseline Model 5.1 Average Treatment Effect on the Treated Table 4 reports the results for the baseline model that focuses on the double-comparing between the insured and the non-participants. All the specifications control the household fixed effect, year fixed effect, and time-variant characteristics of household and village, including log(household income), household size, log(average income per person in the village), share of members over age 65, share of members under age 10, whether having communist party members, and whether being a “Wubao” household.21 The first column shows that the insurance coverage has stimulated more consumption net of health-care expenditure for the insured. Although the NCMS is often criticized for being ungenerous, consumption increases by 5.5 percent, which is anything but trivially. Since the average consumption per person for the participants in 2003 is about 2637.5RMB between 2003 and 2006, a 5.5 percent implies an increase of 145.1RMB, which is much higher than the average cost of the insurance that was mostly 30 RMB in 2003 and 50RMB in 2006. The program is definitely more effective in stimulating consumption than the cash transfers from the government since the average propensity to consume for the rural residence is only about 0.437. To address the potential selection bias, column 2 adds the interaction between year and household income and interaction between year and village average income to allow the linear trend of consumption to vary with income.22 Column 3 controls additionally the interaction term between year and household self-reported health status in 2003.23 Both columns show an insurance effect similar to that in the baseline model, including both the magnitude and significance level. The result remains robust when we allow the difference 21 Some of the family characteristics do not vary much over time. But the results are very robust to whether including them or not. 22 We also try income in 2003 instead of income in the current year, and there are little changes in the results. 23 There are 4 categories for the self-reported health status: excellent, good, fair, and bad (including no working capacity). The result here considers two measures: the share of household members reporting fair or bad health status and the share of members reporting bad health status. Results are quite similar if we use other measures of health status, such as controlling instead the mean value of the health status in the household or controlling additionally the share of members with good health status. Notice that the health status can be affected by the insurance coverage, we only consider the health status in 2003 when there was no NCMS. Using the information in 2003 reduces the number of observations. To check the robustness, we use the health status in the current year and get very similar results. 15 in the trend to vary year by year by controlling the interaction terms between the year dummies and household income, village average income, and household health status (column 4). In column 5, we future allow different provinces to have different trend in consumption by adding into the covariates the interaction between provincial dummies and year. The magnitude declines slightly, but still significant and substantial.24 There can be other differences between the insured and the non-participants. Similar to the idea of matching, we can summarize the difference by a one-dimension variable, the household’s “propensity score” of participating the program. The estimation of the propensity score is discussed in details in Section 6. Here, we control the interaction between year and the propensity score to allow the trend in consumption to vary with the propensity score. The estimate is in column 6, which shows a similar result again. 25 Controlling the interaction between the year dummies and the propensity score does not change the result either.26 Since more and more counties and households enroll in the program, we have an unbalanced panel in table 4. Appendix A.2 reports the estimates for the balanced panel. Although there are much fewer observations, the insurance effect is still substantial, actually is stronger, and the effects are robust to allowing different trends between the insured and the nonparticipants. More specifically, the effect is on average 9.6% after we allow the trend to vary linearly with income and health (column 3). The difference in the magnitude between the balance and unbalanced panel can be explain by the fact that the unbalanced panel consists more new members of the NCMS, and the experienced members of the program show more increase in consumption than new members, which will be shown later. In summary, the estimates of the insurance effects are quite robust to the specifications that allow the observable difference between the treated and the untreated to bring on 24 If the insurance coverage stimulates the growth of consumption, which is the case as we show later, this method would underestimate the positive insurance effect. The reason is that for provinces that unveiled the program in 2003 or 2004 and most residents participated, the time trends of consumption have incorporated the insurance effect to some extent. 25 The consistency of the estimate in this specification requires an additional assumption: the conditional expectation of the outcome given the propensity score is linear in the propensity score. Moreover, the standard errors are not consistent as we have not adjusted for the first-stage estimation for the propensity score. 26 Another specification we have tried is to consider the first-difference version of the baseline model. Particularly we study how the change in the insurance coverage affects the change in consumption. The insurance effect is 4.5% and significant. 16 different trends of consumption. The results also survive in many robust tests, such as excluding family variables that are quite stable over time, using more homogenous sample, applying to two periods before participation, matching DID, and regression with matching. These increase our confidence that the baseline model gives a reliable estimate for the insurance effect. 5.2 Precautionary Savings This section examines whether the increase in consumption net of health expenditure really represents the reduction in precautionary savings. The estimates in this section all control household fixed effect, year fixed effect, time-variant household and village characteristics, and the interaction between year and household income, average income in the village, and household health status in 2003, similar to the specification in column 3, table 4. Precautionary Savings and Crowd-in Effects An alternative explanation for the positive effect of the NCMS on consumption net of health expenditure is that the insurance reduces households’ out-of-pocket health expenditure; therefore, the insured households can have more income left for other consumption. This is a simple ex-post “crowd-in” effect. Since the “crowd-in” story only works for the households who have health expenditure in the current year, we can exclude this channel by estimating the effect only on households who have no health expenditure in the current year. Column 1 of Table 5 shows that the insurance effect remains significant for households have no health expenditure in the current year. Actually, the magnitude is even stronger than that when we pool all households together. 27 The “crowd-in” story highlights that the insurance coverage affects health expenditure and consumption net of health expenditure simultaneously and the effects may not be independent. In the second column of Table 5, we consider the effect of the NCMS on total consumption that includes health expenditure. The result shows that the insurance coverage stimulates total consumption by 6 percent, which is not much different from the effect on 27 When we consider only households having health expenditure in the current year, the estimate of the effect of the NCMS is insignificant in many specifications. However, there are only a few non-participants in this estimation, and therefore the estimate may not be reliable. 17 consumption net of health expenditure.28 The Insurance Package If the increase in consumption comes from the reduction in precautionary savings, we expect that the insurance effect increases with the generosity of the insurance program. Column 3 and 4 of Table 5 test this conjecture by exploiting the information of the NCMS collected for 54 villages. The result shows that households do respond to the generosity of the insurance for the health expenditure at county facilities, and the direction is consistent with the expectation: the lower the deductible or the coinsurance rate is, the more consumption the insurance program can stimulate. However, the generosity of the insurance for the health expenditure at the village clinics does not have such significant effects. This is somewhat reasonable as most households go to the county hospitals when they face serious health problems that demand the insurance most. Insurance Effect and Risks Table 6 studies how the insurance effect varies with the uncertainty about future health expenditure. We first look at the difference between income groups. Since poor households are more likely unable to afford large health care expenditure, we expect the effect of the insurance on consumption is stronger for the poor. The first three columns of Table 6 confirm this conjecture. The first column confirms that the positive effect of the NCMS on consumption decreases with income. The second and third columns run the regression separately for the two halves of the income distribution, where the bottom half is labeled as the poor and the top half labeled as the rich. The results show that the positive insurance effect is only significant for the poor. When further dividing the population into 3 income groups, we find the group with the least income shows the largest increase in consumption after acquiring the insurance coverage. The second part of Table 6 concerns the risk in regard to household’s health status. On 28 We have estimated the effect of the NCMS on the out-of-pocket health expenditure. The result shows no significant effect, which contradicts with the “crowd-in” story. This finding is consistent with the results in the studies that evaluate the NCMS (Wagsaff et al. 2009; Lei and Lin, 2009; and Mao 2005). However, no significant reduction in the out-of-pocket health expenditure does not mean that the insurance coverage does help reduce the risk. Households may have visited health-care facilities more often after being covered by the insurance; or the price of the health care may have increased after the launch of the NCMS. If the latter is true, for a given visit, households’ health-care expenditure would have increased if they had no insurance. 18 the basis of the self-reported health status for each member of the household, we construct two measures of the risk. The first measure first assigns a value to each category of the self-reported health-status, 5 for excellent, 4 for good, 3 for fair, 2 for bad, and 1 for no working capacity, and then calculate the average value of the self-reported health status for the household in 2003. As shown in column 4 to 6, the positive insurance effect decreases as the average health status gets better, and the effect is only significant for the bottom half of the health distribution, labeled as “poor health”. If we future divide the population into 3 groups base on the average value of the health status, the group with the worst health shows strongest response to the health insurance coverage. Columns 7 to 8 consider the second measure of the health risk, which is whether having household members self-reporting fair or bad health in 2003, including no working capacity. In our sample, about 89% of individuals report good or excellent health. Therefore, reporting fair or bad health seems to indicate serious health problems that may need substantial health expenditure in the future. The results confirm that after being covered by the insurance, households having members with fair or bad health status consume much more than households having no such members. 29 The results of Table 6 are consistent with the argument that the insurance effect reflects the reduction in precautionary savings and the effect is stronger for households having higher risk of incurring “expensive” health care spendings in the future.30 5.3 Dynamics of the Insurance Effect and Trust This section analyzes how the insurance effect varies with household’s experience with the insurance program. After the dissolution of the old Cooperative Medical System in 1980s, most households in the rural areas have not been covered by any health insurance for a long time. Moreover, the NCMS differs from the old CMS in many aspects. As a result, it takes time for the households to understand and establish trust in the new program. Anecdotal evidences show that many households were not clear about the details of the 29 Use the health status in the current year delivers quite similar estimates. One concern for the regressions in this section is that there are only a small number of non-participants when we divide the sample into smaller groups. Here are the numbers of non-participants in each estimate: 324 among the rich, 435 among the poor; 410 among the group with good health, 349 among the group with bad health, 242 among the households with bad or fair health members, and 517 among households with no such members. 30 19 package, including the exact deductible, the coinsurance rate, and the ceiling, particularly before any households in the village went through the procedure and diffused the information. Therefore, it is possible that households participated the program without realizing the essence of the insurance or having enough trust in the program. Column 1 of Table 7 adds a dummy for the experienced participants to the baseline model to allow the experienced have a different insurance effect from the new participants. Here, the new members are those who have participated the NCMS for less than one year while the experienced have participated for more than one year. It shows that although the insurance effect is significant among the new, about 4.5 percent; it is much lower than the effect on the experienced participants by 6.7 percent. So compared with the non-participants, the experienced members increases consumption by 11.2 percent due to the health insurance coverage. The results are similar when we estimate the coefficients in the subsamples: respectively comparing the new members with the experienced, comparing the new with the non-participants, and comparing the experienced and the non-participants. When we further allow the insurance effect to differ in the second, third, and fourth year of a household’s subscription in the program, we find that the increase in consumption mainly complete in the second year of subscription.31 The dynamics of the insurance effect can result from the fact that the experienced learned more about the benefit of the insurance. An alternative explanation for the dynamics is that the NCMS becomes more generous over time, and people reduce more precautionary savings in response to the increasing generosity. We add an interaction term between household’s enrollment status and year to study how the insurance effect change over time in column 2. It shows no significant upward trend in the insurance effect. The third column further confirms that the difference between the new members and the experienced members remains significant after we control the time trend of the insurance effect. Therefore, the change in the generosity of the insurance cannot fully explain the 31 We have also distinguished two types of the new members: one is the real new participants for whom the program was also new; the other is the delayed new participants who participated the program for the first year but the program has been implemented for more than one year. The delayed new might have learned about the program from their neighbors who have enrolled in the NCMS earlier. The results indicate that in terms of the insurance effect, the delayed new members are not significantly different from the experienced participants; however, they are also not significantly different from the real new members either. Therefore, the knowledge from the neighbors can help learn, but learning from self-participation is better than learning from the neighbors. 20 increase in the insurance effect for the experienced compared with the new members. Another explanation for the dynamics of the insurance effect is related to households’ trust in the program. The effect of knowledge on the program is two-edged. Particularly, if households find out the alleged benefits of the program are just void, more knowledge about the insurance cannot help reduce precautionary savings. Therefore, what matters most may be households’ trust in the insurance program. To identify the “trust” effect, we control the interaction between households’ insurance coverage and the indicator on whether some households in the village have gotten some reimbursement from the NCMS in column 3 (village reimbursement=1 if yes, 0 if no). The result shows that the insurance effect becomes significantly stronger, by 17 percentage points, when the benefit of the insurance is witnessed in the village. For the villages that have not had any reimbursement, the insurance effect is even negative, although the estimate may become insignificant in different specifications. The results are confirmed by the estimates on the subsamples. Column 4 and 5 consider only villages that have not experienced any reimbursement. Now there is no significant insurance effect for the participants (column 4), no matter whether the participant is experienced or not (column 5).32 In contrast, when we only consider villages where there have been some reimbursements (column 6 and 7), households’ consumption increases by 6.3% due to the insurance coverage (column 6), higher than the average insurance effect 4.9% reported in the baseline model. In addition, the experienced participants in these villages consume significantly more than the new members (column 7), which might because they learn more about the insurance or because they have more trust in the program. These results highlight that only when households trust the insurance, they start to reduce precautionary savings and consume more. Noticing that only 39% of the new participants observe any reimbursement in the village, while for experienced, the percentage is 86%. Thus, the stronger insurance effect for the experienced in the first column of Table 7 can be explained by that the experienced are more likely to establish trust in the program.33 32 We need to be cautious on explaining the negative insurance effect here as there are only a few villages, around 18.6% between 2004 and 2006, that have launched the program but experienced no reimbursement. 33 The responses related to the “trust” are also consistent with the pattern on the participation decision. We find that for those who do not participate immediately after the village introduces the program, the participation rate in the village with some reimbursement is 67%, while the rate in the village with no 21 6 Robustness and Refinements of the Baseline Model The main concern of the baseline model is that households who enrolled in the NCMS are not comparable to households who did not. Particularly, we worry that households who have not participated by 2007 may have been covered by other insurance or have very special characteristics. Therefore, we exclude this kind of households to test the robustness of our main results. The first column in Table 8 shows the estimate for the average insurance effect is 5.1%, which is quite similar to that in the baseline model. To test whether the identification assumption holds, we apply the same model to periods that households have not been covered by the insurance. Particularly, we exclude the observations in 2006 and for other years, we only consider households that have not enrolled in the program in that year; and households’ treatment status in a year t is defined as their status in the next year t+1. By construction, the treatment status does not represent the real status of the insurance coverage. Column 2 of Table 8 shows no significant insurance effect as it should be. This increases our confidence that the estimate for the insurance effect in the baseline model does represent the causal effect of the NCMS. Besides the introduction of the NCMS, there is another important policy change during the same period: the reduction of the agricultural taxes and fees in the rural areas. The tax reduction started with pilot programs in two provinces in 2004 and ended with the abolition of the agricultural taxes nationally in 2006. It increases households’ disposable income and consumption. If the amount of tax reduction is correlated with the launch of the insurance program, then our estimate of the insurance effect is biased. To test how serious the problem is, we include the log value of the tax and fee payment as a covariate in Column 3 of Table 8. The estimate for the insurance effect does not change much. We have also tried to directly control the disposable income that has subtracted the expenditure in taxes and fees. The result is also quite similar. We argue that the positive effect of the NCMS on consumption net of health expenditure results from the reduction in precautionary savings, but this story should not affect the basic or subsistence consumption for human needs. We use food consumption to represent the subsistence consumption in column 4. As we expected, both the magnitude and the significance level of the insurance effect become much smaller. Nevertheless the reimbursement is only 36%. 22 effect is still significant. The main reason is that this measure still includes non-basic food consumption. Besides food consumption, we examine educational expenditure in column 5 and find a strong positive insurance effect for families who have members under 25. This is consistent with the finding in Meng (2003), which indicates that urban households cannot smooth their education expenditure, and they reduce their education expenditure substantially when income uncertainty increases. However, the result for education expenditure is somewhat sensitive to the model specification. 7 Gross Effects and Matching DID Gross Effects Our previous analyses all focus on the insurance effect that is estimated based on the double difference between the insured and the non-participants in the NCMS-counties. In this section, we are going to examine the gross effect of the NCMS that may incorporate the effects of other changes that accompanied with the NCMS. This effect in principle can be estimated by the double-difference between the insured and the non-exposed and applying the following regression: Yijt g Family _ insured it t Tt i Di X ijt ijt (2) The equation is the same as the baseline model with the exception that here we consider only the insured and the non-exposed while in the baseline model we consider only the insured and the non-participants in the NCMS-counties. The potential selection bias comes from the non-random placement of the NCMS across villages. Again, to address the issue, we allow the counterfactual time trend in consumption to vary with income and health status. And we do so by controlling for the interaction between year and household income, average income in the village, and household health status in 2003. The first column of Table 9 reports the estimation. It shows an insignificant gross effect, which implies that other changes that were contemporary with the introduction of the NCMS have depressed consumption for the insured. This could result from the increase in the price of health care after the launch of the NCMS. This explanation is consistent with the findings from the program-evaluation studies that conclude the overall out-of-pocket 23 payments have not been reduced by the NCMS. However, we do not have enough information on the price of the health care to confirm this conjecture and this is definitely a question warrants more research. Although the average gross effect is insignificant, the next four columns of Table 9 show that the gross effect varies significantly across different groups. First, the gross effect is significant positive for the poor households, but declines quickly with income (column 2).34 Second, the effect is significant positive for bottom half of the health distribution, but declines with health status (column 3). Third, the gross effect is significantly positive for the experienced families and the difference between the experienced and the new members are significant (column 4). Finally, the gross effect tends to be more positive among villages that have seen some reimbursement, although it is not significant (column 5). However, the experienced members in the counties that have seen reimbursement show much stronger and significant positive gross effect than the counterparts in the counties that have seen no reimbursement (column 6 and 7). These variations across different groups are quite similar to those for the insurance effect. This is consistent with the explanation that the effect of other contemporary policies on consumption is similar among all groups, so the difference in the gross effect is similar to the difference in the insurance effect. Previous analyses all rely on the subsample of the population. The next column in table 9 use the whole sample but distinguish the insurance effect and the gross effect as illustrated as following: Yijt Family _ insured it o County _ enroll jt t Tt i Di X ijt ijt (3) Here, Family_insuredit is the binary variable indicating whether household i having subscribed the insurance program in year t, while County_enrollit is the binary variable for whether the village j having launched the NCMS in year t. As a result, represents the program’s insurance effect that works only on the insured, while o represents the other effect of the contemporary changes on all the households in the NCMS-counties. And + o represent the gross effect of the NCMS. The identification assumption of equation (3) is that conditional on the observable characteristics (Tt, Di, Xijt), the whole population, including the insured, the non-participants, and the non-exposed, would have parallel It is significant for the bottom one-third of the income distribution, which we do not report due to space limit. 34 24 dynamics of consumption if there had been no NCMS. If the assumption holds, then the equations (1) to (3) should give the same estimate for , g and o. Nevertheless, the estimations based on the sub-samples (equation 1 and 2) require weaker identification assumptions as they only require parallel trends in consumption within the sub-sample rather than the whole sample. Column 9 of Table 9 reports the estimate for the equation (3). Again, we see a significant positive insurance effect on consumption net of health expenditure. The magnitude is about 4.8%, similar to that in the baseline model. Also consistent with previous results on the insurance effect and gross effect, we see a significant negative effect of other contemporary changes.35 The negative other effect is further confirmed when we double compare the uninsured with the non-exposed. The last column of Table 9 compares the insured with all the uninsured. The coefficient for the Family_insured should be a linear combination of the insurance effect and the gross effect, and the weight depends on the composition of the uninsured group. The result indicates no significant effect. These results highlight the importance to consider the sample composition for the estimation and the corresponding economic meaning. Matching Difference-in-Difference Now, we couple the difference-in-difference approach with matching to reduce the selection bias on the observables. The identification assumption for the linear regression and that for the matching approach are the same. However, the matching method does not require strong functional form assumptions, so it can address two kinds of potential bias of the simple linear regression method: the bias due to the difference in the supports of the observable covariates between the treated and untreated groups and the bias due to the difference between the two groups in the distribution of the observables over its common support (Smith and Todd, 2005).36 Since we have more than two periods, the traditional DID matching method needs to be modified. We first estimate respectively the insurance effect in each year between 2004 and 35 Although not reported, we have re-estimated the results from table 4 to table 8 based on the specification in equation (3) and confirm that all the conclusions remain. 36 The matching method also exploits a weighting system that is different from the regression method. In the cases where the effect of the treatment varies across households, the matching estimate gives us the treatment effect on those who are most likely to be treated. This is the parameter of interest here. 25 2006. Then we calculate a weighted average of the insurance effect over these three years by weighting the effect in each year using the ratio of the number of the treated household in that year over the total number of the treated. Another complication here is how to deal with the experienced participants. For the experienced participants in year t, although they enroll in the program, there is no change in the treatment status between year t and year t-1. Their temporal change in consumption represents the additional increase in consumption due to the NCMS after the first-year participation. To simplify the analyses, we exclude all the experienced participants and focus on the effect of the NCMS on consumption for the new participants. The matching method applied here is the propensity score matching, where the propensity score measures the “closeness” between the treated and untreated households. We estimate the propensity score based on two steps. First, in each year, we estimate the probability that a household enrolled in the NCMS given the village has launched the program. This is estimated based on households in the NCMS-villages in that year. For households in the non-NCMS villages, we predict their probability to enroll based on the estimate. Second, we estimate the probability that a village enrolled in the NCMS in each year.37 For both steps, a probit model is estimated.38 For the comparison between the insured and the non-participants, the predicted probability from the first step is the propensity score. For the comparison between the insured and the non-exposed or between the insured and all the uninsured, we need to consider both the similarity between households and that between villages, hence the (composite) propensity score in each year is the product of the two probabilities predicted from both steps in that year. Figure 1 gives the histogram for the (composite) propensity scores for the three groups: the insured, the non-participants, and the non-exposed. As expected, the distribution of the propensity score is more skewed to the right for the insured than for the non-participants. Nonetheless, the region of common support is ample. The propensity score distribution for 37 To weight the data by the number of households surveyed in each county, the model is estimated on the household-level data. 38 Noticing that the propensity score is only to reduce the dimensions of the conditioning; as such, it has no behavioral assumptions attached to it. For the choice of covariates to include in the estimation of propensity score, we start with all of the plausible variables that affect the participation decision, including all the covariates considered in table A.1. Then which variable to be included or excluded is determined solely by the balancing requirement (tested by the “pscore” logarithm in Stata). As a result, the ultimate covariates vary across years. The estimates are available upon requests. 26 the non-exposed is even more left skewed than the non-participants. This justifies the focus on the comparison between the insured and the non-participants in the NCMS-villages. We use the five-nearest neighbors matching with replacement and caliper 0.01, and impose common support condition. 39 The distance between the propensity score is measured by the Mahalanobis metric. Since there are only a handful of untreated units comparable to the treated units in our sample, allowing replacement is expected to perform better than without replacement. Among the three choices: imposing common support condition, using multiple nearest neighbors, and matching with replacement, the first and the second ones increase bias but reduce variance, while the third one is on the opposite. Table 10 reports the results, where the standard errors are bootstrapped with 100 replications. The results in the baseline model are all confirmed: the insurance effect estimated by comparing the insured with the non-participants is about 5.2%; the gross effect estimated by comparing the insured with the non-exposed is not significant; and there is no significant effect of the NCMS on consumption if we simply compare the insured with all kinds of uninsured. We also show the reduction in the bias on the observables achieved through matching. The first column indicates that when the non-participants in the NCMS-villages are used as the controls, the mean absolute standardized ‘bias’ after matching is reduced substantially, by 41%.40 However, the reduction in the pseudo R2 statistics from a probit model is modest, by 19%. When the non-exposed are used as the comparison group (column 2), matching only reduces the mean “bias” by 9%, and even raises the pseudo R2. These results imply that matching is more successful when using the non-participants as the controls than using the non-exposed as the controls.41 39 We confirm the results are not sensitive to other choices of calipers, including 0.005 and 0.0025. Our sample is not a random sample but over-samples households with substantial health-care expenditure that itself is affected by the participation choices. Therefore, this is a choice-based sample, but the sampling weights are unknown. As a result, we need to match on the odds ratio, P/(1-P), where P is the propensity score (Smith and Todd, 2005). However, for nearest neighbor matching, it does not matter whether he matching is performed on the odds ratio or on the propensity scores, because the ranking of the propensity score is the same and the same neighbors will be selected. However, for methods that consider the absolute distance between observations, such as kernel matching, it does matter. 40 The reduction in biases shown here is based on the “psmatch2” logarithm in Stata. 41 The matching DID estimates are not sensitive to the number of neighbors and caliper, but is somewhat sensitive to the estimation of the propensity score and the matching method such as the Kernel estimation. However, the most sensitive estimates are those for the other effect, followed by the gross effect. The insurance effect is least sensitive. 27 Regression with Matching The simple matching DID estimator is still problematic in finite samples when the matching is not exact, that is the covariates for the treated and those for the matches are not equal, although they are close after the matching process (Imbens and Wooldridge, 2009). Moreover, in our context, matching is sensitive to the estimation of propensity score and easily breaks down as we do not have a large sample for the non-participants. The literature has proposed a combination of weighting or matching and regression to attain "double robustness": as long as the parametric model for either the propensity score or the regression function is specified correctly, the resulting estimator for the average treatment effect on the treated is consistent. This is particularly valuable when one method alone is not sufficient to obtain consistent or efficient estimates. We consider three ways to combine regression and weighting. First, apply the regression method over the common support of the treatment and control groups, where the common support is the one used in the matching DID; Second, apply the regression method over the matched pairs in the matching DID; third, apply the weighted least regression, where the weight is one for the treated unit, and P/(1-P) for the untreated unit, and P is the estimated propensity score.42 The first two methods can be easily incorporated into to the fixed-effect model for the panel data. Column 4 and 5 of Table 10 display the estimates for the insurance effect and we see a even stronger insurance effect than that in the baseline model. The third method, by contrast, cannot directly be applied to the baseline model because weighting is not allowed in the fixed-effect model. As a compromise, we consider the regression model for the repeated cross-sectional data that can easily incorporate weights. More specifically, the model for the insurance effect is as following: Yijt Family _ insured it t Tt i Gi X ijt ijt (1' ) There are only two differences between this equation and the baseline model. First, instead of controlling all the household indicators (the household fixed-effect), we only the time-invariant dummies indicating whether the household participated in 2004, 2005, or 2006, and whether the household has participated immediately after the village launched 42 The second and third methods may be less efficient, as they discard more control observations and weights some more than others. It has the advantage, however, of only using the most relevant matches. 28 the program. Second, Xijt includes not only time-variant characteristics, but also time-invariant characteristics of the households and villages, such as health status indicators in 2003, whether being minority, the head’s gender, marital status, education, and job, and all village indicators. The sixth column in table 10 gives the estimate. We see a larger insurance effect that is still significant, although the estimate becomes less precise. The next two columns estimate the gross effect and composite effect of the NCMS. Both show no significant effect. In summary, the robustness checks deliver a clear message that the insurance effect in the baseline model is quite robust and reliable. The gross effect also keeps insignificant in different specifications. 8 Conclusion This study exploits the introduction of the NCMS in the rural area to examine the effects of the health insurance coverage on consumption in rural areas. We find that the insurance stimulated the consumption net of health expenditure by around 5.6 percent for the insured. This effect does not seem to result from the “crowding-in” effect that argues that health insurance reduces the out-of-pocket expenditure of the insured and hence increases the disposable income for other consumption. However, we find that even for households that do not incur any healthcare expenditure, the insurance program has stimulated more consumption. In addition, the effect is stronger for those expecting higher risk of having relative expensive health-care expenditure, including households with lower income or with worse health status. Besides, the insurance effect increases with the generosity of the package for the expenditure at the county facilities. These are all consistent with the precautionary-saving story. We also find that the insurance effect varies with households’ experience with the program. Particularly, the increase in consumption is stronger for the experienced participants than for the new participants. However, the dynamic change of the insurance effect is not significant in the villages that have not witnessed any reimbursement from the program. Moreover, there is no significant insurance effect at all in such villages. In contrast, both the insurance effect for the new participants and the increase in the insurance effect for the experienced are significant in the villages in which households have 29 witnessed some reimbursement and hence established trust on the program. These results indicate that people’s trust in the public insurance program can be crucial for the stimulation of consumption for public insurance programs. The findings are quite robust to different specifications including allowing the time trend of consumption to vary with income, health status, or propensity, using more similar control groups, using two periods before joining in the program, matching difference-in-difference, and regression with matching. Our results also suggest some negative spill-over or general equilibrium effect, although we need to be cautious on this as the comparison between households in the NCMS-counties and those in the non-NCMS counties may face serious selection biases. This is a question warrants future research. The findings have strong implications. Although the NCMS was often complained for being ungenerous, still it has stimulated more consumption than the cost in the rural areas. When the insurance program is expanded to more areas and becomes more generous, we expect more increase in consumption, which is quite beneficial in rebalancing Chinese growth. However, to exert the stimulation of consumption to the most, it is important to make people trust the public safety net and educate them about the insurance. The results about the gross effect on consumption of the NCMS are less positive than the insurance effect. Such a result does not mean the insurance program is not useful in increasing consumption. Rather, it suggests that measures should be taken in company of the insurance program to reduce the cost of healthcare delivery. Possible such measures include improving the compensation scheme for healthcare delivery, introducing more competition in the healthcare delivery market, and improving the governance and regulation of healthcare delivery organizations. More research is needed to see how one can bring about significant gross effect of insurance on consumption. 30 Reference Atella, Vincenzo, Furio C. Rosati, and Mariacristina Rossi, 2005. Precautionary Saving and Health Risk: Evidence from Italian Households using a Time Series of Cross Sections, Working Paper Banks, J., Blundell, R., Brugiavini, A., 2001. Risk pooling, precautionary saving and consumption growth. Review of Economic Studies 68, 757–779. Caballero, Ricardo J., Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 2008. An Equilibrium Model of "Global Imbalances" and Low Interest Rates, American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 98(1), pages 358-93, March. Cagetti, Marco, 2003. Wealth Accumulation Over the Life Cycle and Precautionary Savings, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 21(3), 339{353. Carroll, Christopher D., 1992. The Buffer-Stock Theory of saving: Some Macroeconomic Evidence, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 61-156. Carroll, Christopher D., Karen Dynan, and Spencer Krane, 2003. Unemployment Risk and Precautionary Wealth: Evidence from Households’ Balance Sheets, Review of Economics and Statistics, 85, 586-604. Carroll, Christopher D., and Andrew Samwick, 1998. How Important is Precautionary Saving? Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (August 1998), 410–419. Chamon, Marcos D., and Eswar S. Prasad, 2010. Why Are Saving Rates of Urban Households in China Rising? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, American Economic Association, vol. 2(1), pages 93-130, January. Chou, Shin-Yi, Jin-Tan Liu, and James K. Hammitt, 2003. National Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving: Evidence from Taiwan, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 87, No. 9-10, pp. 1873-94. Deaton, Angus,1991. Saving and Liquidity Constraints, Econometrica, 59, 1221-1248. Dynan, Karen E. 1993. How Prudent Are Consumers? Journal of Political Economy,101 (December 1993), 1104–1113. Engen, Eric M., and Jonathan Gruber, 2001. Unemployment Insurance and Precautionary Saving, Journal of Monetary Economics 47 (June 2001), 545–579. Fuchs-SchÜndeln, Nicola, and Matthias SchÜndeln, 2005. Precautionary Savings and Self-Selection: Evidence from the German Reunification Experiment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 1085-1120. Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Jonathan Parker, 2002. Consumption Over the Life Cycle, Econometrica, 70(1), 47-89. Gruber, Jonathan, and Aaron Yelowitz, 1999. Public Health Insurance and Private Savings, Journal of Political Economy, 107(December 1999), 1249-1274. Guariglia, Alessandra and Mariacristina Rossi, 2004, “Private medical insurance and saving: evidence from the British Household Panel Survey”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. (23)4, pp.761-783 Guiso, Luigi, Tullio Jappelli, and Daniele Terlizzese, 1992. Earnings Uncertainty and Precautionary Saving, Journal of Monetary Economics 30 (November 1992), 307–337. Horioka, Charles Y., and Junmin Wan, 2007. The Determinants of Household Saving in China: A Dynamic Panel Analysis of Provincial Data, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. 31 Hubbard, R. Glenn, Jonathan Skinner, and Stephen P. Zeldes, 1994. “The Importance of Precautionary Motives in Explaining Individual and Aggregate Saving,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 40 (June 1994), 59–126. Hurst, Erik, Arthur Kennickell, Annamaria Lusardi, and Francisco Torralba, 2010. The Importance of Business Owners in Assessing the Size of Precautionary Savings,Review of Economics and Statistics,February 2010, 92(1): 61–69 Imbens, Guido W., and Jeffrey M. Wooldridge, 2009. Recent Developments in the Econometrics of Program Evaluation, Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 47(1), pages 5-86, March. Lei, Xiaoyan, and Wanchuan Lin, 2009, The New Cooperative Medical Scheme in Rural China: Does More Coverage Mean More Service and Better Health? Health Econ. 18: S25–S46 (2009) Lee, Jeong-Joon, and Yasuyuki Sawada, “Precautionary saving under liquidity constraints: Evidence from rural Pakistan,” Journal of Development Economics 91 (2010) 77-86 Jin, Ye, Hongbin Li, and Binzhen Wu, 2010. Income Inequality, Consumption, and Social-Status Seeking, Journal of Comparative Economics, Forthcoming Kantor, Shawn Everett, and Fishback, Price V. 1996. Precautionary Saving, Insurance, and the Origins of Workers’ Compensation, Journal of Political Economy, 104 (April 1996): 419–42. Kazarosian, Mark, 1997. Precautionary Savings-A Panel Study, The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 79(2), pages 241-247, May. Kraay, Aart, 2000. Household Saving in China, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 14, No. 3 (September), pp. 545-70. Kuijs, Louis, 2006. How will China’s Saving-investment Balance Evolve? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper #3958. Long, Zhihe and Haoming Zhou, 2004. An Empirical Study of Precautionary Savings of Urban and Township Inhabitants in China, Economic Research Journal (Jin Ji Yan Jiu) (in Chinese), 2000 (11), pp:33-38 Lusardi, Annamaria, 1998. On the Importance of Precautionary Saving, American Economic Review 88 (May 1998), 448–453. Liu, Guoen, Wenbin Zang, Fei Xu, and Xinjun Xiong, 2010. The Effect of Urban Resident Basic Medical Insurance on Household Consumption, working paper (in Chinese) Ma, Shuang, Wenbin Zang, and Li Gan, 2010. The Effect of New Rural Cooperative Medical System on Rural Household Food Consumption, Quarterly Journal of Economics (in Chinese), forthcoming. Mao Zhengzhong, 2005. Pilot Program of New Cooperative Medical Schemes (NCMS) in China: System design and progress, Unpublished manuscript Meng, Xin, 2003. Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing, and Precautionary Saving in Urban China. Journal of Comparative Economics 31(3): 465-485. Modigliani, Franco, Cao, Shi L., 2004. The Chinese Saving Puzzle and the Life-cycle Hypothesis. Journal of Economic Literature 42: 145-170. Palumbo, Michael, 1999. “Health Uncertainty and Precautionary Saving Near the End of the Life Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies, April 1999, 66(2), pp. 395–422. Skinner, Jonathan, 1988. Risky Income, Life Cycle Consumption and Precautionary Saving, Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 237-255. 32 Smith, Jeffrey, and Petra Todd 2005. Does Matching Address LaLonde’s Critique of Nonexperi-mental Estimators, Journal of Econometrics, 125(1-2), 305-353. Starr-McCluer, Martha, 1996. Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving, American Economic Review 86 (March 1996), 285–295. Wagstaff, Adam, Lindelow, Magnus, Jun, Gao, Ling, Xu and Juncheng, Qian, 2009. "Extending Health Insurance to the Rural Population: An Impact Evaluation of China's New Cooperative Medical Scheme," Journal of Health Economics, Elsevier, vol. 28(1), pages 1-19, Wagstaff, Adam, and Menno Pradhan, 2005, “Health Insurance Impacts on Health and Nonmedical Consumption in a Developing Country” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3563, April 2005 Wei, Shangjin, Zhang, Xiaobo, 2009. The Competitive Saving Motive: Evidence from Rising Sex Ratios and Savings Rates in China. NBER working paper No. w15093. Wen, Yi, 2009. Saving and growth under borrowing constraints: explaining the high saving rate Puzzle, Working Papers 2009-045, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. You, Xuedan, and Yasuki Kobayashi, 2009. The new cooperative medical scheme in China, Health Policy 91, 1–9 Zhang, Yin, and Wan, Guanghua, 2004, “Liquidity constraint, uncertainty and household consumption in China”, Applied Economics, Vol.(36), pp.2221-2229. Zhang, Xuheng, Chunxia Pei 2007, The Consumption Study of Chinese Urban and Rural Households Consumption Behavior in Transitional Period, The Journal of Quantitative & Technical Economics, (in Chinese), 2007 (10). Zeldes, Stephen P., 1989. Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence, Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (May 1989), 275–298. 33 Figure 1 The Distribution of Propensity Scores for Three Groups 34 Table 1 Insurance Schemes for the NCMS Programs Average reimbursement rate for in-patient service Deductibles Year Township clinics County hospitals Upper-level hospitals Township clinics County hospitals Upper-level hospitals 2003 371 457 743 39.7% 38.4% 32.3% 2004 183 294 570 46.0% 37.5% 29.7% 2005 133 261 550 48.6% 41.4% 32.6% 2006 125 302 641 50.9% 40.4% 31.4% 2007 87 252 574 52.5% 44.2% 33.7% Mean 138 289 603 49.7% 41.3% 32.2% Reimbursement rate for in-patient service under 3000 RMB Reimbursement rate for in-patient service between 3000 and 10000 RMB Township clinics County hospitals Upper-level hospital Township clinics County hospitals Upper-level hospital 2003 29.1% 24.0% 16.9% 28.9% 33.4% 26.3% 2004 33.0% 25.8% 17.4% 38.3% 33.4% 25.0% 2005 44.6% 33.6% 23.0% 45.9% 40.2% 29.4% 2006 45.8% 34.6% 23.7% 48.8% 39.9% 29.6% 2007 50.0% 38.2% 24.6% 50.5% 43.3% 30.9% Mean 44.4% 33.9% 22.7% 46.3% 39.9% 29.2% Ceilings Having different schemes for different facilities Having different schemes for different levels of expenditure 2003 13571 85.7% 85.7% 2004 15200 91.7% 84.6% 2005 13250 95.2% 76.2% 2006 14838 97.2% 69.4% 2007 19321 100.0% 62.1% Mean 15732 96.2% 71.7% 35 Table 2 The Participation Rate in Different Years 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 or later Number of counties newly enrolled 20 21 18 44 31 Cumulative rate 14.9% 30.6% 44.0% 76.9% 100% Number of households newly enrolled 424 563 634 1,292 1,201 Cumulative rate 10.3% 24.0% 39.4% 70.8% 100% Number of participants in the NCMS-county 424 987 1,621 2,913 Number of non-participants in the NCMS-county 241 247 273 196 Number of non-exposed households 3,453 2,885 2,225 1,009 Participation rate in the NCMS-county 63.8% 80.0% 85.6% 93.7% Exposure rate 16.1% 30.0% 46.0% 75.5% Cumulative participation rate in counties launched the NCMS in 2003 63.8% 82.4% 94.4% 97.1% 100% 77.2% 94.4% 95.6% 100% 69.1% 85.0% 100% 95.6% 100% Year Counties’ participation: Households’ participation: Cumulative participation rate in counties launched the NCMS in 2004 Cumulative carticipation rate in counties launched the NCMS in 2005 Cumulative participation rate in counties launched the NCMS in 2006 36 Table 3 Descriptive Statistics for Three Groups All Mean 10424 10847 25880 625.5 168.6 Non-NCMS villages Non-exposed Mean 8719 9166 20995 661.5 222.3 NCMS-villages Variable Consumption net of health expenditure in 2003 Total consumption in 2003 Household income in 2003 Health expenditure in 2003 In-patient health expenditure in 2003 Share of members with fair or worse health in 2003a Share of members with bad health in 2003 Share of members older than 65 Share of members younger than 10 Share of migrants in 2003 Household size Head's age Head's years of education Female head Single head Head is a non-agriculture worker Having communist members Minority household "Wubao" household Village average income per capita in 2003 Capital of the town Number of clinic in 2003 Share of kids vaccinated in 2003 Share of migrants in 2003 Share of laborer in the village Share of laborer with high school degree or above in the village Mountain area Highland area Western area Central area Observation (based on consumption) Insured Mean 10462 10873 26442 610.3 183.3 Non-participants Mean 10131 10637 21460 738.3 63.0 13.9% 13.6% 13.9% 12.8% 4.2% 8.8% 7.1% 15.6% 4.01 51.82 6.72 5.2% 7.8% 39% 17% 9.7% 0.26% 3396 15% 1.28 97.40 23% 57% 7.2% 9.7% 7.5% 13.1% 4.13 50.50 6.44 6.7% 12.2% 41% 10% 17.1% 0.79% 3241 12% 1.26 98.54 23% 55% 4.5% 8.9% 7.1% 15.3% 4.02 51.68 6.69 5.4% 8.3% 39% 16% 10.5% 0.32% 3379 15% 1.28 97.53 23% 56% 5.1% 8.1% 7.5% 16.7% 4.15 50.96 6.50 7.6% 9.0% 33% 16% 14.8% 0.22% 2727 14% 1.32 94.29 25% 54% 34% 32% 34% 30% 47% 25% 20% 42% 6392 53% 21% 20% 41% 761 48% 24% 20% 42% 7153 56% 23% 27% 48% 10274 Note: The health status is self-reported and there are five categories: excellent, good, fair, bad, and no working capacity. We label both bad and no working capacity as bad health. 37 Table 4 Results for the Baseline Model Dependent variable: Log (consumption net of health expenditure) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Insured family Log(income) Household size Log (village income) 0.055*** (0.021) 0.437*** (0.020) 0.099*** (0.012) -0.065 (0.041) Year*log(income) Year*log(village income per capita) Year * share of members with fair and bad health 03 Year * share of members with bad health 03 Year * propensity of participation Propensity score of participation Yearly trend vary with income, village income, and health status Observations R-squared Households 0.055*** (0.021) 0.424*** (0.021) 0.098*** (0.012) -0.077* (0.041) -0.005 (0.005) -0.017** (0.007) 0.056*** (0.021) 0.428*** (0.021) 0.096*** (0.012) -0.085** (0.043) -0.007 (0.006) -0.015** (0.007) 0.010 0.058*** (0.021) 0.431*** (0.021) 0.096*** (0.012) -0.094** (0.043) 0.042* (0.022) 0.426*** (0.021) 0.097*** (0.012) -0.120** (0.050) -0.002 (0.006) -0.023*** (0.009) 0.014 (0.016) (0.017) -0.045 -0.043 (0.030) (0.031) 0.066*** (0.021) 0.437*** (0.022) 0.093*** (0.012) -0.090** (0.043) -0.266* (0.157) -0.049 (0.064) Y 9,730 0.284 3,963 9,730 0.286 3,963 9,068 0.293 3,658 9,068 0.297 3,658 9,068 0.303 3,658 9068 0.292 3658 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The sample includes all the NCMS-counties and their corresponding observations in 2003, but excludes the observations in 2003 for counties who enroll in 2003. All the columns control household fixed effect, year fixed effect, log(income), household size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and log(village income per capita). Column 4 controls the interaction between year dummies and log(income), log(village income per capita), the share of members with fair or bad health in 2003, and the share of members with bad health status in 2003. 38 Table 5 A Story on the Precautionary Savings Precautionary savings vs. “crowd-in” Dependent Log(consumption net of Log(total variables: health expenditure) consumption) Households having no health expenditure All the sample (1) (2) 0.072* (0.039) 0.060*** (0.021) Insurance package Log(consumption net of health expenditure) Scheme for Scheme for expenditure at expenditure at village facilities county facilities (3) (4) Covariates Insured family Deductibles 0.007 (0.037) -0.046** (0.019) Reimbursement rate 0.101 (0.128) 0.625*** (0.177) 2,299 0.282 1,282 2,282 0.295 1,265 Observations R-squared Households 3,917 0.317 2,241 9,068 0.302 3,658 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The sample includes all the NCMS-counties and their corresponding observations in 2003. All the specifications control household fixed effect, year fixed effect, log(Income), household size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and Log(village income per capita). 39 Table 6. The Insurance Effect and Risks Sample: Covariates Insured family Insured family * log(income) Dependent Variable: log (consumption other than health expenditure) Insurance effects and income Insurance effects and health Insurance effects and health 2 Households Households having fair having no All the All the Bad Good All the The poor The rich or bad fair or bad sample sample health health sample health health members members (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) 0.652*** (0.244) 0.055** (0.025) 0.021 (0.043) 0.293*** (0.093) 0.072** (0.031) 0.039 (0.028) 0.087** (0.036) 0.041 (0.025) 2,925 0.325 1,163 6,143 0.283 2,495 -0.061** (0.025) -0.055*** (0.021) Insured family * Health Insured family * Number of Fair or Bad Health Members Observations R-squared Households 0.040* (0.023) 0.034* (0.018) 9,068 0.295 3,658 4,598 0.339 2,424 4,470 0.195 2,234 9,065 0.294 3,658 4,623 0.332 1,874 4,441 0.255 1,783 9068 0.294 3658 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Column 2 (3) only considers the bottom (top) half of the income distribution of this sample. Column 5 (6) only considers the bottom (top) half of the health distribution in 2003. Column 8 considers only households having members with fair or bad health in 2003, while column 9 considers households having no such members. All the columns control household and year fixed effect, log(income), household size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and log(village income per capita). 40 Table 7. Learning and Trust in the NCMS Program Dependent variables: Log (consumption other than health expenditure) Dynamic effects Trust All the NCMS-villages without NCMS-villages with All the sample sample reimbursement reimbursements (1) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (2) Covariates Insured family 0.045** 0.058** -0.104* -0.078 -0.085 0.063** 0.061** 0.026 (0.021) (0.053) (0.089) (0.092) (0.030) (0.030) (0.028) (0.029) Experienced members 0.067*** (0.016) Insured family * year 0.068 (0.094) 0.070*** (0.017) 0.002 (0.019) -0.016 (0.019) Village reimbursement -0.155*** (0.056) Family_insured * Village reimbursement 0.170*** Observations R-squared Households 0.069*** (0.019) (0.059) 8,996 0.294 3,651 9068 0.293 3658 8996 0.294 3651 8,702 0.288 3,648 3,690 0.248 2,788 3,689 0.249 2,788 7,616 0.307 3,567 7,595 0.309 3,563 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Village reimbursement is a dummy that is 1 if some households in the village have gotten some reimbursement from the NCMS. Column 5 and 6 only include observations in the villages that have shown no reimbursement, while column 7 and 8 include observations in the villages that have seen some reimbursement. All the columns control household and year fixed effect, log(income), family size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and log(village income per capita). 41 Table 8. Robustness Tests Dependent Log(consumption excluding health expenditure) Variable Participants by Periods before Consider tax policy 2007 treatments (1) (2) (3) Covariates 0.051** 0.024 0.053** Insured family (0.024) (0.029) (0.021) Log(education expenditure) (4) (5) 0.031* (0.017) 0.041 (0.061) 9065 0.305 3658 4145 0.084 1979 -0.007** (0.003) log(tax and fee) Observations R-squared Households Log(food expenditure) 8,648 0.294 3,492 5,064 0.236 2,848 9,068 0.294 3,658 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Column 1 includes households that have participated the program by 2007. Column 2 considers only the uninsured and “Insured family” represents the indicator of whether the family is insured in the next year. All the columns control household fixed effect and year fixed effect, log(income), household size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and log(village income per capita). 42 Table 9. Gross Effects of the NCMS program (1) Dependent variable: Log (consumption net of health expenditure) Gross effect Composite NCMS-village NCMS-villag Insured vs. All s without es with uninsured All the The insured vs. non-exposed: reimbursemen reimburseme sample t vs. nt vs. non-exposed non-exposed (4) (5) (7) (8) (10) (2) (3) (9) Covariates Insured family 0.006 (0.011) 0.311** (0.152) 0.280*** (0.067) -0.002 (0.011) -0.007 (0.017) -0.011 (0.021) -0.004 (0.013) 0.029 (0.044) 0.060*** (0.015) 11237 0.230 4083 14834 0.261 4692 Enrolled Village Insured family * log(income) 0.013 (0.011) 16720 0.256 4811 16720 0.255 4811 -0.031** (0.016) Insured family * Health in 03 -0.063*** (0.015) Experienced members 0.059*** (0.014) Village reimbursement Observations R-squared Households 0.048*** (0.017) -0.042** (0.017) 0.012 (0.018) 15961 0.257 4775 15961 0.257 4775 15958 0.258 4775 15889 0.257 4767 15837 0.252 4765 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. All the columns control household fixed effect, year fixed effect, log(income), household size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and log(village income per capita). Columns 5 estimates based on the insured and the non-participants in the NCMS-counties. Columns 6 estimates on the insured and the non-exposed. Other columns use all the observations. 43 Table 10. Matching Difference-in-Difference and Regression with Matching Dependent variable: Log (consumption net of health expenditure) Matching DID Regression with Matching Insurance Gross Insurance Gross Insurance Insurance effect: effect: effect: effect: Insured vs. effect: effect: insured vs. insured vs. common common uninsured common weighted non-partici non-expos support + support + support regression pant ed matches matches (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Insured family 0.052*** (0.024) -0.015 (0.017) -0.003 (0.016) Number of Untreated Number of Treated Post-matching bias % change in bias through matching Post-matching pseudo R2 % change in pseudo R2 through matching Post-matching Prob value of Chi-squared Observations R-squared Households 712 2,442 9.13 6,274 2,442 9.88 6,986 2,442 9.67 -40.8% -9.1% -7.9% 0.096 0.098 0.090 -18.8% 19.8% 21.8% 0.000 0.000 0.000 Insured vs. uninsured: common support + matches (8) 0.064*** (0.020) 0.061* (0.032) 0.095* (0.050) 0.004 (0.023) 0.008 (0.022) 8753 0.297 3648 6299 0.170 3397 8806 0.725 7143 0.170 4062 7485 0.175 4235 Note: Bootstrap standard errors with 100 replications in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Each estimate is a weighted average of the corresponding effect in 2006, 05, and 04. The weight is the ratio of the number of the treated households in each year over the total number of treated households over three years. In this table, we exclude experienced participants to simplify the analyses. 44 Appendix A Table A.1 Household’s Participation Decision and County’s Enrollment Household’s participation decisiona County’s enrollment (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.149*** 0.139*** 0.049 0.443** Log(Income) Log(village income ) (0.040) (0.044) (0.054) (0.186) -0.002 0.017 0.027 Village classified as -0.352** Household size (0.017) (0.020) (0.026) “Xiaokan” (0.176) Share of members with 0.207*** 0.190** -0.105 Village classified as -0.154 good health in 2003 b (0.070) (0.080) (0.094) “Pingkun” (0.289) Share of members with 0.459*** 0.531*** 0.076 0.129 Surburb area fair or bad health in 2003 (0.142) (0.159) (0.186) (0.281) Share of members with -0.868*** -0.813*** -0.643*** -0.254 Capital of the town bad health in 2003 (0.169) (0.179) (0.215) (0.326) Share of members older -0.015 0.006 -0.109 -0.308 Agricultural village than 65 (0.139) (0.148) (0.171) (0.254) Share of members 0.453** 0.548*** 0.321 0.153 Log(population) younger than 10 (0.200) (0.207) (0.274) (0.145) Share of migrants in 0.114 0.101 -0.095 2.663*** Share of laborer 2003 (0.132) (0.141) (0.154) (0.766) -0.673*** -0.812*** -0.019 Share of high school 0.064 Minority (0.081) (0.106) (0.216) or above (0.728) -0.690** -0.826** -1.311*** Share of migrants in -0.228 “Wubao” household (0.304) (0.355) (0.440) 2003 (0.482) Having communist 0.216*** 0.119 0.150 Number of clinic in -0.072 members (0.074) (0.078) (0.095) 2003 (0.080) 0.089 0.257** 0.156 Share of kids 0.013** Female head (0.112) (0.116) (0.145) vaccinated in 2003 (0.006) 0.013*** 0.011*** 0.009*** -0.470*** Age of the head Mountain areas (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.180) -0.233*** -0.233*** -0.221** 0.535** Head is single Highland area (0.084) (0.087) (0.103) (0.219) Head’s education years -0.024 0.070 0.223* -0.602** Western China 3-6c (0.101) (0.104) (0.127) (0.256) Head’s education years 0.047 0.166 0.239* -0.334* Central China 7-9 (0.108) (0.114) (0.136) (0.203) Head’s education years 0.122 0.230 0.043 10 and above (0.143) (0.152) (0.175) Head is non-farm -0.237*** -0.286*** -0.074 self-employedd (0.074) (0.086) (0.106) 0.131* 0.017 0.026 Head is an employee (0.074) (0.079) (0.093) Head works in other 0.020 -0.023 0.184* non-farm jobs (0.071) (0.077) (0.106) Village Dummies no no yes no Province Dummies no yes no no Year Dummies yes yes yes yes Observations 6575 6492 3960 Observations 394 likelihood -1904 -1711 -1154 likelihood -212.5 pseudo-R2 0.194 0.273 0.406 pseudo-R2 0.222 Note: Standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. a). In column 1 and 2, we also control all the village characteristics considered in column 4. b). The health status is self-reported and there are five categories: excellent, good, fair, bad, and no working capacity. Most people report “excellent.” We label both bad and no working capacity as bad health. c). The omitted category is illiterate or the years of education less than 3. d). The omitted category is farmer. 45 Table A.2 Results for the Baseline Models: Balanced Panel Dependent variable: Log (consumption net of health expenditure) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Covariates 0.075** 0.101*** 0.096*** 0.111*** 0.090** 0.094** Insured family (0.037) (0.037) (0.037) (0.039) (0.037) (0.037) 0.493*** 0.405*** 0.392*** 0.417*** 0.393*** 0.420*** log(income) (0.039) (0.041) (0.041) (0.042) (0.041) (0.043) 0.067*** 0.065*** 0.066*** 0.067*** 0.062*** 0.051** Household size (0.022) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.022) (0.021) 0.036 0.008 0.025 0.013 0.032 -0.037 Ln(Village Income) (0.080) (0.078) (0.079) (0.082) (0.092) (0.081) -0.029*** -0.034*** -0.028** -0.031*** Year*log(income) (0.011) (0.011) (0.012) (0.011) -0.061*** -0.057*** -0.025 -0.072*** Year*log(village income per capita) (0.021) (0.021) (0.033) (0.022) Year * share of -0.051 -0.064** -0.055 members with fair (0.031) (0.032) (0.034) and bad health 03 Year * share of -0.058 -0.042 -0.023 members with bad (0.065) (0.067) (0.076) health 03 0.010 Year * Propensity of participation (0.137) -0.508* Propensity of participation (0.299) Yearly Trend Vary with Income, Y Village Income, Health Status Observations R-squared Households 1992 0.283 498 1992 0.303 498 1992 0.305 498 1992 0.314 498 1992 0.311 498 1992 0.311 498 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. All the columns control household fixed effect, year fixed effect, log(income), household size, the share of members over age 65, the share of members under age 10, whether having communist members, whether being “Wubao” household, and log(village income per capita). 46