Working Papers on University Reform Working Paper 8: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? - Theorising university financial management By DR. PENNY CIANCANELLI Danish University of Education, University of År Udgivelsesmåned Århus May 2008 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Working Papers on University Reform Series Editor: Susan Wright This working papers series is published by the research unit ”Transformations of universities and organizations” at the Danish School of Education, Århus University. The series brings together work in progress in Denmark and among an international network of scholars involved in research on universities and higher education. ”Transformations of universities and organizations” aims to establish the study of universities as a field of research in Denmark. The field has three components: International and national policies to revise the role of universities in the knowledge economy; the transformation of universities as organizations; and changes in teaching and learning in higher education. The research unit aims to understand each of these components in the context of the others and explore the links between them. The central questions are: How are different national and international visions of learning societies, knowledge economies, and new world orders spurring reforms to the role and purpose of universities and to the policies and practices of higher education? How do university reforms introduce new rationalities of governance, systems of management and priorities for research and teaching? How do managers, researchers, and students negotiate with new discourses, subject positions and forms of power arising from university reforms? What kinds of changes are students, academics and university managers themselves initiating, and how do these interact with reforms coming from governments and international organizations? This interaction is central to the work of the research unit. The unit draws together ideas and approaches from a range of academic fields and collaborates internationally with other higher education research environments. Currently the unit’s main activity is a research project, ‘New management, new identities? Danish university reform in an international perspective’ funded by the Danish Research Council (2004-2008). The unit holds seminars and there is a mailing list of academics and students working in this field in Denmark and internationally. Members of the unit include professor Susan Wright, Danish School of Education, associate professor John Krejsler, Danish School of Education, assistant professor Jakob Krause-Jensen, Danish School of Education, Ph.D. student Gritt Bykærholm Nielsen, Danish School of Education, and research assistant Jakob Williams Ørberg, Danish School of Education. Further information on the research unit and other working papers in the series are at http://www.dpu.dk/site.asp?p=5899. To join the mailing list, hold a seminar or have material included in the working paper series please contact professor Susan Wright at suwr@dpu.dk or at the Danish School of Education, Tuborgvej 164, 2400 Copenhagen NV, Denmark. Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? - Theorising university financial management DR. PENNY CIANCANELLI Department of Accounting and Finance Strathclyde University 100 Cathedral Street Glasgow, UK Email: p.ciancanelli@strath.ac.uk Tel +44 141 548 3689 Fax: +44 141 552 3547 Copyright: Penny Ciancanelli Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Contents Abstract.......................................................................................................................... 1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 1 Controlling the Controllers .......................................................................................... 3 Performance measurement and control............................................................................. 3 Funding versus Finance............................................................................................... 6 What does a University Cost? ............................................................................................. 9 Do universities cost their operations? .............................................................................. 10 Impatient wealth ................................................................................................................ 11 Conclusion .................................................................................................................. 13 References ................................................................................................................... 14 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Abstract The aim of this paper is to challenge taken-for-granted assumptions about the ease with which universities can turn a profit in global education markets. Drawing on Weber’s neglected insights into the financial management of non-business units, the paper theorizes structural differences in financial management of non-profit and business organizations, drawing attention to differences in the fungibility of the financial resources at management’s disposal. It argues that cost identification is the financial Achilles heel of such organizations because unlike business units, their aims do not offer a normative basis (profit maximization) for distinguishing between necessary and discretionary expenditures. Difficulty in identifying and calculating costs amplifies the financial risks of commercial ventures, making it highly unlikely that they offer public universities a sustainable alternative to government funding. Key words: Higher Education Financial Management, Cost identification, Non-profit organizations Introduction For most of the post World War II period, the core structures and processes of university life in Europe were not much different to those that characterized 19th century universities. Badly paid professors lectured badly behaved students and the technology of Guttenberg ruled. Self-regarding governance in the context of public support for enlightenment ideals appeared to conserve a way of life that had largely accommodated rather than capitulated to capitalism (Reading 1996). Today, however, the signs of institutional transformation are abundant. Globalization and neo-liberalism — as ideologies and programmes of deregulation and privatization—have succeeded in cracking open the defences that allowed some aspects of life in universities to evade full on commoditization (Epstein et al. 2008; Wright and Ørberg 2008; Marginson 2004; Scott 2002). One example is the attribution of declining government support for public universities to the fiscal consequences of globalization (Vincent-Lancrin 2004; Johnstone et al. 2000; Varghese 2001, CIHE 2005). This has encouraged many public universities to supplement their revenues through commercial ventures.i The financial realism of this turn toward market sources of revenue is rarely challenged. Indeed, most criticisms of such engagements by universities are moralpolitical, concerned with the threats they pose to valued modes of teaching, research and self-governance (Nobel 2003; Aronowitz 2001; Reading 1996). The presumption in much of the research seems to be that the difference between a business and a nonprofit university is largely ideological; if non-profit organisations change their mindset, they can change their financial fate. This may explain why some governments have mandated business-style accounting for universities on the argument that this 1 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? will promote more business-like resource management (Ciancanelli 2008a; HEFCE 2004; IFAC 2002). Even financial management research tends to minimize the difference between financial management in business and non-profit organization. Overall emphasis is placed on the politics (and ideology) of budgeting and its similar effects on individuals in organizations (Helmig et al. 2004; Olson et al. 1998; Covaleski and Dirsmith 1988). Studies contrasting the effects of budgeting in business units and non-profit organizations are almost unknown. It is certainly true there are significant formal similarities in the financial management of the two types. Both types allocate resources according to some kind of plan (budget) and regularly assess the efficiency and effectiveness of the plan (control). In addition, both types rely on monetary accounting as the core valuation technology used in both constructing the plan (budget) and defining the assessment measure (control). However, the legal and other purposes of planning and control in non-profit organizations are fundamentally different to those in business units. Arguably, these differences in purpose have consequences that warrant investigation. One possible reason for the influence of these purely formal approaches is the paucity of theoretical research on financial management in non-profit organizations (Ciancanelli 2008a, b; Helmig et al. 2004). In conventional research on planning and control, theoretical interest lies in organization processes common to both types of organizations, (e.g. labour control processes) and the reliance on politicalsociological theories of organization behaviour. The technical features of cost measurement have attracted little interest in this body of research (Jones 1995). There is very little theoretical research on financial management of non-profit organizations (Helmig et al. 2004) and virtually no research into possible structural differences in the financial management of profit and non-profit organizations.ii The large body of research on public sector reforms conforms to this pattern. Thus, rather than theorizing how the different aims of business and non-profit organisations affect the implementation of formally similar planning and control technologies (Olson et al. 1998), researchers have tended to rely on non-financial theories of organizational life when analyzing empirical materials on non-profit universities (Deem 2004; Ehrenberg 2002a; Covalesky and Dirsmith, 1988). The aim of this paper is to challenge the assumption that organizational aims exert little or no influence on financial management practices.iii Highlighting legal differences in the uses of funds and structural features of performance measurement, this paper proposes a theoretical explanation for observed differences in cost management in the two types of economic units. Whereas the aim of profit maximization forces business units to attend to cost identification and minimization, there is no equivalent link between the organizational aim and costs in non-profit organizations. This makes it difficult (if not impossible) for the latter to identify necessary costs and distinguish them from discretionary expenditures. The discussion of these issues is presented in three main sections. The first offers a theoretical exploration of the differences between planning and control in non-profit organizations and capitalist firms. It extends the ideas developed in 2 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Weber’s discussion of substantive and formal rationality in monetary accounting, identifying theoretical reasons why capitalist firms must focus on costs and why nonprofit organizations find it difficult to do so. The second section is devoted to an analysis of the type of funding relied upon by non-profit organizations, noting how restrictions on fungibility amplify the problems of cost identification, on one hand, and financial accountability, on the other. The discussion in the concluding section offers illustrations that point to the empirical pertinence of the theoretical ideas developed in the first two sections. Controlling the Controllers …the accounting calculations of a profit-making enterprise and a consumption unit differ as fundamentally as do the ends of want satisfaction and of profit-making which they serve” (Weber 1978: 92). The starting point for theoretical clarification of at least some of the structural differences in planning and control in these types of units can be found, curiously enough, in Weber’s (1978: 86-89) discussion of the rationality of monetary accounting, especially his ‘formulation of a precise concept of the rational budgetary unit as distinguished from that of a rational profit-making enterprise…’ (Weber 1978: 89, Note 3). This discussion and the subsequent elaboration of the distinction between formal and substantive rationality of accounting control in capitalist firms (Weber 1978: 92-118) offers a useful way to begin theorising structural differences in planning and control. Because these particular insights are not integrated into contemporary conceptualizations of planning and control, they are worth reviewing them in some detail (Colignan and Covalesky 1991). Performance measurement and control Weber’s discussion of monetary accounting is situated between his definition of formal versus substantive rationality in economic action and his discussion of the concept and types of profit making units (Weber 1978: 85-90). As discussed more fully elsewhere (Ciancanelli 2008a), Weber’s treatment of monetary accounting is, in effect, a comparison of the value rationalities that underpin planning and control in the two types of economic units — one oriented towards consumption (Haushalt) and the other oriented towards profit (Erwerb).iv In the course of the development of profit-oriented firms in Europe, a specific type of monetary accounting was devised and subsequently used by capitalist enterprises (Yamey 1978). Weber summarized the features of this specialist accounting in the following way: Capital accounting is the valuation and verification of opportunities for profit and of the success of the profit-making activity by means of a valuation of the total assets (goods and money) of the enterprise 3 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? at the beginning…and at the end of the accounting period (Weber 1978: 91). As details of his discussion make clear, Weber (1978) used the term capital accounting for those practices that are now referred to as financial accounting and ‘household’ accounting for practices that are now referred to as budgets or financial plans. In Weber’s representation, the commercial virtues of capital accounting lie in the way it offered the capitalist ‘control’ over operations through the provision of information about the incremental effect of market exchanges (transactions) between his firm and others. Weber writes: Through a system of individual accounts, the fiction is here created that different departments within an enterprise, or individual accounts, conduct exchange operations with each other, thus permitting a check, in the technically most perfect manner, on the profitability of each individual step or measure (Weber 1978: 93). This leads him to conclude that the use of this specialist monetary accounting instantiates substantive rationality in the capital budgeting process (planning) because the success (or failure) of the plan can be precisely calculated (its monetary value) in exactly the same terms as the aim of the plan (acquisition of wealth). Thus, capitalist accounting is said to impose substantively rational controls (performance measures) on the controllers of these types of economic units (see Carruthers and Espeland 1991 for a critique). Weber’s observations anticipated subsequent theories of accounting concerning the distinctive benefits claimed for capital accounting. His conceptual distinction between the type of income and wealth held by business and non-profit organizations anticipates the modern profession’s construction of specific technical meanings for the terms income and capital (Parker et al. 1986). For example, in Anglo-American accounting, the term income refers to profit, not revenue and its measurement is regulated by concepts and rules known as generally agreed accounting principles or GAAP. For non-profit units, accountants prepare a very different summary financial statement; it is a ‘revenue’ statement as distinct from a profit and loss account (UK) or income statement (US). In this sense, professional practice reflects a judgement that the economic substance of business income is quite different to that of non-profit revenue. Moreover, the revenue statement is often compiled on a funds basis rather than a consolidated basis.v The difference between income and revenue turns on the difference between the ‘wealth’ of a unit oriented towards consumption and the capital of a unit oriented towards acquisition or profit—a difference reflected in the terminology. Weber used to distinguish wealth (vermogen) from Kapital (See Note 14 in Weber 1978: 206). In contemporary financial management terminology, the reserves and endowment funds controlled by non-profit organizations usually have the legal status of ‘wealth’ (his concept of vermogen) rather than capital (his concept of Kapital). With respect to the 4 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? measurement of the value of both types of wealth, Weber thought each ought to include social advantages, now referred to as intangible assets. Thus, Weber wrote: The category of ‘wealth’ includes…all economic advantages over which the unit has assured control, whether that control is due to custom, to the play of interests, to convention or to law (Weber 1978: 89: Note1) The profit (or income) of a business unit is ‘capital maintained income’ which means it is the surplus (measured in money) over and above the monetary value of the firm’s capital at the beginning of the production period (Lee 1996). This means that for a business, the expenses of the period will include not only those outflows of money required to earn the inflows of revenue. They will also include imputed charges (accruals) whose value is based on estimates of the monetary value of the capital assets used up or consumed in the period (e.g. depreciation) (Parker et al. 1986). In contrast, the revenue of non-profit organizations consists of the monetary value of inflows received by the unit during the reporting period; it declares as net revenue the ‘surplus’ left after expenses have been paid. This means expenses are equivalent to payments and costs are not matched to the revenues they are thought to generate. There was longstanding agreement that the wealth of non-profit units does not constitute capital, per se, which gave rise to objections to the practice of imputing charges for the so-called ‘cost’ of capital (Wynne 2003; Lapsley 1999; Sidebotham 1965). Indeed, there are often legal restrictions that limit the uses to which a resource may be put. For example, non-profit organizations may have access only to the income from a bequest; the capital itself is held in trust in perpetuity. In such cases, it is accepted that this wealth does not conform to the statutory definition of capital used by financial managers when measuring the value of income in a business unit (Mautz 1988; Barton 2000). Following on his discussion of differences between business and non-profit units, Weber proposes that the particular monetary accounting practices used by business units impose substantively rational ‘controls’ on the controllers of those units (Weber 1978: 92-95). These practices do so, according to Weber, because the mechanism of control (quantitative measure of increase or decrease in monetary income and wealth) is symmetric with the aims of the organization (quantitative increase in monetary income/wealth). According to Weber’s framework, monetary accounting does not provide substantively rational control of the plans agreed by the controllers of non-profit organizations. It cannot do so because there is no equivalence between monetary measures of performance and the diverse qualitative purposes non-profit and government organizations aim to serve (Ciancanelli 2008a). The crux of Weber’s argument is that the substantive rationality of monetary accounting in capitalist firms lies in the use of the same value base to measure means and ends. Since the measurement of ‘ends’ (increase or decrease in capital maintained income or profit) requires value equivalent measurement of means (operating costs), the capitalist’s focus on profit is simultaneously (and necessarily) a focus on costs. Of particular 5 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? importance to commercial competence is the premium this places on identifying the minimum necessary costs, as doing so allows maximization of profit. In units oriented towards consumption, monetary accounting does not have equivalent rationality and provides no basis for identifying minimum operating costs. The rationality of monetary accounting is limited to providing a unit measure of value that allows for a purely formal comparison of revenue and expense. In non-profit organizations, the value of the items in the consumption bundle to members of the organization cannot be measured in money. As a result, controllers of such units, who attempt to characterize a subset of expenditures as necessary or a certain consumption bundle as essential to the organization, are advancing a political claim about which organizational actors’ needs should have priority. By implication, the path of least organizational resistance in non-profit organisations would be to treat all expenditures as operating costs and focus instead on revenues, allocating resources to efforts to secure more revenue in order to ‘cover’ ever increasing costs. Such an orientation is obviously dysfunctional when undertaking a commercial venture since a project may appear to generate enough revenue to cover only the most obvious of its direct costs (wages and consumables) while not generating enough to cover its full economic cost (e.g. including all indirect costs and net of joint costs). Absent are both the capitalist’s motive to reduce costs (as this increases profit—all things remaining the same) and accounting information that supplies the required details. Therefore it is unlikely that revenue-focused controllers would be able to rationally assess a venture’s performance or to determine its ‘true’ financial contribution to the overall costs of running the university. Funding versus Finance A key difference in the monetary resources managed by business and non-profit units is their fungibility. In Weber’s discussion of the rationality of the planning control nexus, markets supply price information that enhances the rationality of two types of economic calculation—one is the marginal rate of substitution between utilities and the other is the opportunity cost of investment capital. The more that the monetary accounts integrate market prices, the greater the rationality of both planning and control (Weber 1978: 109-113). vi By implication, any normative or legal prohibitions that constrain the flexibility of resource allocation, also constrain the rationality of monetary accounts. Limited flexibility is a qualitative property of the resource that cannot be communicated by a quantitative measure of value expressed in monetary accounts. Contemporary financial management employs the concept of fungibility vii to describe this feature of budgeted resources. In both non-profit and capitalist organizations, financial management hierarchies dictate the parameters of the budget holders’ authorization to spend the organization’s money. If the budget holder is free to revise his authorized plan of expenditures (e.g. reallocate resources within the total spend she controls) the overall resource is fungible. If she does not have that freedom, the use of the resource is 6 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? stipulated; it is a non-fungible resource. A central difference between capitalist firms and non-profit organizations is that in the former internal actors (e.g. the owners/controllers of capitalist firms) design the constraints on fungibility in light of the agreed organization structure (management hierarchy) up to and including constraints on the powers of the chief operating officer. For government and non-profit units, however, decisions on fungibility are made by external actors including legal terms of reference or specific terms of a grant or bequest or the vote of legislative funding bodies. With respect to the latter, in parliamentary democracies, for example, departments of government are authorized (on vote) to spend specific amounts for specific purposes (Jones and Pendlebury 1996). In order to take money voted for purpose A and use it for purpose B, civil servants require approval from someone higher up in the department (or from parliament itself). In such a context, it would hardly make sense to ‘control’ the controllers with a performance measure that assumes complete freedom in resource allocation. This is why prior to neo-liberal reforms, control in government organizations consisted of budget outturn reports, as these highlight any variance between how a department allocated its resources and how it was supposed to (as set out by government, parliament or other relevant authority) (Wynne 2003). Differences in fungibility have two main financial management implications. Firstly, the more reliant the unit is on non-fungible resources and the more diverse the sources of revenue, the more difficult it will be to define an organization’s own operating costs, and by extension, the more difficult to ascertain the revenue benefits of a venture to the organization, per se. Secondly, the more reliant the organization is on non-fungible resources, the more limited will be its ability to fund (or finance) commercial ventures without diverting resources from its previous portfolio of activities. Given the internal dissent such diversion might provoke, commercial ventures may be afflicted with unrealistically short limits on the amount of time they are given to demonstrate their merit. Thus, we expect commercial undertakings by public universities to pose more of a hazard to their public benefit obligations (via diversion of resource) and to be subject to commercially inappropriate time horizons. As elaborated in Ciancanelli (2008a), the global higher education sector is composed of three main types of universities. The most common type is a public university, one that is funded by government from its overall tax take. From a governance perspective, a public university is a department of government and its controllers are civil servants who are expected to implement plans that reflect the diverse, qualitative aims set by government. The next most common type is a nonprofit private university. This type is organizationally and financially independent of government. It funds its operations from grants received from various stakeholders— such as wealthy benefactors, students viii and government departments that pay for research undertaken by universities. The third type, a corporate university, is one that has increased in importance over the past decade. Like any business, its purpose is to profit from the sale of services and it finances operations from the capital markets or the personal wealth of its owners. The budgets or plans of each of these types allocate resources in light of their founding requirements and related statutory terms of reference. Thus, civil servants 7 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? are expected to allocate resources in public universities in line with public benefit priorities imposed by party political institutions. Those in charge of a private university are expected to govern in line with the largely public benefit rationales imputed by its benefactors and imposed by their statutory terms of reference. Businessmen are expected to govern for-profit universities in the interests of owners’ income and wealth accumulation. Differences in the structure of financial management emanate from, inter alia, differences in flexibility to allocate resources along a continuum from full flexibility to quite limited freedom to revise the plan. Controllers of corporate universities have the most financial freedom, while the capital assets of the unit may be temporarily fixed in the form of machines, real estate, etc., they are in principle a fully fungible resource. This means the owners are free to sell all or any part of the business and pocket the proceeds. Slaughter and Leslie (1997) draw attention to the importance of ‘nonstipulated’ resources for academic entrepreneurs. Their work does not make clear whether non-stipulated resource refers to ‘free cash flows’ (e.g. internal surpluses) or to revenues that are fully fungible. Their discussion does not consider the fungibility of the stock of wealth at the disposal of the university’s controllers, a subject of increasing importance in recent charges that wealthy US universities prefer to raise student tuition rather than spend a reasonable portion of their endowment income (e.g. over 5%) (Lederman 2008). In contrast, in typical private universities, a substantial share of the income and (normally) all its assets have limited fungibility. The controllers of non-profit organizations often have little or no authority to liquidate the unit’s assets; if such authority is supplied, the problem arises as to whom to distribute the proceeds to, since these organizations do not have owners in a conventional sense (Sidebotham 1965). The constraints on fungibility derive from reliance on grants and bequests that stipulate how the funds are to be used and, in some jurisdictions, from strict fiduciary obligations that limit the uses to which any internal surpluses may be put (Jackson and Cowley 2002; Dukes 2002).ix In the case of public universities, the lack of fungibility is even greater and reflects the organization’s subordination to legislative or parliamentary appropriations processes. By limiting fungibility, legislatures aim to prevent unelected civil servants from diverting public finances to private uses. It is argued that unlimited fungibility of resources allocated to public bodies is undesirable in as much as it creates both fiscal and moral hazards. The fiscal hazard is that public bodies will spend more than allowed; the moral hazard is that spend will be for personal rather than democratically determined purposes (Sidebotham 1965; Wynne 2003; Jones and Pendlebury 1996). The fungibility constraints on the controllers of non-profit universities (both public and private) have two main consequences for the management of commercial ventures. First, reliance on grants creates complexity in the identification of operating costs (or even the definition of cost categories) which limits control to purely formal control of the organization’s resources (e.g. keeping records of inflows and outflows of cash). Complexity is created because receipt of grants requires honouring the cost 8 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? categories defined by the funding body; the more diverse the funding bodies relied on, the more cost categories (and details of cost measurement) can be expected to vary. Even if there is a sophisticated accounting information system in place, this heterogeneity in sources of funding implies heterogeneity in uses. This will make it difficult to identify all the costs incurred by the organization and to ascertain whether these costs were actually covered by the level of expenditure the grant authorizes. In other words, cost recovery is more technically demanding, the more diverse the funding base. This suggests that efforts to diversify sources of revenue through commercial ventures generate at least two types of hazards. The first is an untracked but continual increase in uncovered administration costs whose payment will perforce come out of the organization’s general revenue. This is because without detailed and reliable data, it will be impossible to assign all the costs generated by the commercial venture to its project accounts. Leslie and Rhoades (1995) were among the first to associate rising administration costs with efforts to diversify the funding base of US universities. The second hazard concerns how ventures are financed. Commercial ventures require the advance of money ‘today’ in expectation of more money (capital maintained income) tomorrow. This means investment in commercial ventures requires deciding which elements of the negotiated consumption bundle must be sacrificed today to fund the investment that it is hoped will bring a cash benefit tomorrow. If the uses of revenues received by public universities are largely stipulated, funding commercial ventures requires controllers to reduce costs or to increase sources of revenue to which no strings are attached. Even private universities will be hemmed in by constraints on such possibilities if only because of their obligations to maintain expensive campuses or other heritage assets. It seems unlikely that commercialization can increase revenue quickly enough to withstand the internal tensions that are created by (at least initially) taking resources away from existing operations. Even if such ventures were debt financed, the project itself would require management, a requirement that would mean diverting existing staff to that purpose or the hiring of additional staff. Either choice implies some degree of reallocation of resources away from current uses; how much depends on the extent to which the controllers have access to resources whose use is unstipulated (such as increasing student fees). What does a University Cost? There is a deep tradition and understanding in higher education that resources equates to quality—that more money results in better institution and that you cannot cut money without reducing quality (Wellman 2007 in Lederman 2007:2). The habit of equating more money with higher quality (cited above) suggests that universities are managed in line with an orientation towards consumption rather 9 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? than acquisition. If so, the main theoretical implication of such an orientation is the management of finance with an eye to ‘covering the cost’ of the non-profit organization’s traditional consumption bundle. This supplies a structural explanation for universities’ focusing on expanding revenue to meet costs. The remainder of the discussion in this section offers two sets of events that illustrate the revenue bias of financial management in non-profit universities. The first concerns cost identification and measurement in EU and US universities. The second concerns the relationship between fungibility and commercial ventures. Do universities cost their operations? In a remarkable coincidence, higher education policy research in both the US and Europe has turned its attention to the cost of universities and discovered that systematic identification and measurement of costs does not feature much in their planning and control routines. In the US, the Delta Project on post secondary costs, productivity and accountability, headed by Wellmanx is the higher education establishment’s response to widespread discontent with the inexorable rise in the costs of attending university (Ehrenberg 2002a) and with the lack of transparency in university financial management (Ehrenberg 2002b; Ehrenberg and Rizzo 2004). Initiated in late 2006, the results of its research will not be fully known until late in 2008 (Lederman 2007). However, the results made public thus far point to a revenue bias in university financial management. A survey of the chief financial officers of over 2000 universities revealed that the majority report expenses only in the aggregate and decoupled from performance; fewer than twenty-five percent report the use of what are referred to as standard methodologies for reporting costs. Implied is Wellman’s belief that ‘standard methodologies’ are business methodologies even though there is considerable research that suggests such methodologies are problematic when used by non-profit organizations in the public sector (Wynne 2003; Lapsley 1999; Olson et al. 1998). Interestingly enough, her results indicated that the trustees and other controllers are not concerned with the issue of costs per se. Instead, they are preoccupied with comparing the salaries paid to faculty (and the tuition charged to students) in those universities (and only those universities) they regard as having a similar status (Lederman 2007). This seeming lack of interest in costs is emphasised in Wellman’s testimony before the US Congress. In it Wellman argued ‘Despite repeated calls…(to document costs)…governing boards focus on growing revenues and meeting the market (sic) for tuition. The focus remains on tuition and financial aid, not on how the money is spent’ (Wellman 2007:6). The second illustration is the European University Association’s (EUA) project on funding and accounting at EU universities. Recently, spokesmen for the project made public (via interviews and press releases) the association’s concerns about the low awareness of costs evidenced in the financial management of most European universities. According to the director of finance at Liverpool University, 10 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? initial findings from research on accounting controls ‘revealed that, as yet, there is no common understanding of the financial terminology used, let alone a coherent way to define the full costs of university activities’ (Haworth 2008a). Indeed, at a EUA conference on the subject, the corporate controller of Amsterdam University reported that the basic conditions for identifying costs do not yet exist. He also expressed scepticism that what was required could be achieved, even though ‘…only institutions that knew the full costs of their activities could judge if they were operating on a financially sustainable basis’ (Haworth 2008b).xi Nothing in either initiative points to a theoretical understanding of the question raised by the reported results. Indeed there is a remarkable absence of curiosity about finding the same defect in the financial management of organizations across Europe, a set of institutions whose only common feature is their claim to being universities. Otherwise, what characterizes the population surveyed is enormous diversity in historical origin, institutional characteristics and funding base. That such a diverse group should manifest the same financial management shortcoming deserves more theoretical attention than has been given thus far. In addition to the empiricism that seems to drive the policy research agenda in both the US and the EU, there is little acknowledgement of the known difficulties of cost measurement in non-profit organizations (Salerno 2003). Accounting research on the latter has long suggested that the technical basis for constructing measures of costs of such organizations is very weak. Thus, one scholar commented that initiatives that focus on cost ‘…fail to acknowledge the frailties of performance measures in the public sector, the absence of robust measures and the potential for displacement of important elements of service which are not measurable’ (Lapsley 1999: 203). Impatient wealth It was argued above that the more reliant on non-fungible monetary resources, the more resources would have to be diverted from existing operations to finance (or fund) commercial ventures. This implies, among other things, that public universities would have more difficulty sticking with a venture than might be the case if it were capitalist firm. Any such short-termism would amplify problems in ascertaining what the venture was costing the university if for no other reason than the expectation that it would be possible to recover costs in what any businessman might regard as an unrealistically short time frame. This type of financial hazard is evidenced in two recent, high profile commercial failures. One involves a consortium of private universities in the US, the other involving a public university in Australia. The first example is Fathom—an online, distance-learning venture launched by a consortium of wealthy private universities in the US in 2000. The venture itself appears to have been the equivalent of an on-line culture-mall that would allow individuals (and businesses) to shop for high-end, cultural goods (museum products) and services (training classes, cruises, etc) produced by members of the consortium. Columbia University was the lead institution and a majority shareholder, having initially invested $14.9 million. When the venture was shut down in 2003, its 11 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? commercial viability was cast in doubt by the meagre level of sales (circa $700,000). This was much less than its attributed three-year operating costs. Columbia University declared it had lost $25 million—its initial investment in the consortium and the cash injected into the business between 2000 and 2003 (Hane 2003). The discussion in the faculty senate of Columbia University makes clear that many were disposed to close the project because of its repeated calls for additional finance. Such calls, however, were not necessarily proof that the venture was a bad idea. They could be taken to reflect the university senate’s perception that it should not require more money. The basis of this perception is undocumented and it remains an open question whether it reflects a rational assessment or one emerging from internal political disputes. One could argue that $25 million (or even twice that) is not a lot of money for a very rich university (Columbia’s wealth in 2003 was reported as circa $6 billion and its annual revenues as $2bn) (Columbia University 2003). On the other hand, one could just as easily point to the opportunity cost of the venture from the perspective of the university’s highly indebted undergraduates. An expenditure of $25 million would have been sufficient to waive the tuition fees (estimated at $15,000 per annum) for all undergraduate students (circa 7,000) for 2.5 years or so (Columbia University 2003). Another illustration of dubious investment time horizons concerns the efforts of the University of New South Wales of Australia to set up a university in Singapore (Cohen 2007). The bespoke campus (whose costs of production are not clear but which one source estimates at $145 million) was built to accommodate 15,000 students, drawn from all parts of the globe (Forss 2007). The project reflected the Singapore government’s desire to establish the island as a regional hub of higher education (Epstein et al. 2008). The University claimed that a minimum of 800 students would enrol in the first year and the number would increase to about 3,000 per year within ten years. In the event, fewer than 150 signed up in 2007, two thirds of them from Singapore. This provoked a rapid (some might say overly hasty) response from the University. It announced closure of the operations only two months into the academic year and ceased operations altogether only 5 months after opening its doors (Forss 2007). When setting up the new university, the University of New South Wales received $15 million in loans and grants from the Singapore government. Its decision to close the new university after only two months meant it had to repay the entire $15 million (Cohen, 2007). Undoubtedly the University lost some of its own money; how much is unclear. There is a considerable lack of transparency in the financial details of the affair, including the extent of financial losses incurred by the Singapore government (Forss 2007). The auditor’s report and other sources suggest the closure was prompted not only by the disappointing enrolment but also by the auditor’s lack of confidence in the commercial ability of those in charge of the university. According to the report, ‘The degree of control exercised by the University over all its controlled entities has not always been consistent with that required’, an observation which suggests the University collected financial information in ways that did not allow it to distinguish differences in costs across the group (Auditor General 2007). This criticism points to 12 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? the disturbing possibility that the university’s controllers thought it was possible to manage the dozen or so units under its control without such basic information. In light of these events, it is possible the university controllers believed the $15 million paid by the Singaporean government and the tuition fees charged the 800 or so students would not only cover costs but also generate a surplus (else why do it). Given their hasty withdrawal, it seems likely that the true scale of the costs they would have had to bear were much greater than they calculated. It is rather astonishing that the financial projections of the University were either so crude or so mistaken they did not allow for the possibility that enrolments might be quite low, at least in the first few years. Further evidence of revenue bias is found in research by Ehrenberg. Citing evidence from his 1999 survey of financial management of both private and public universities in the US, he emphasises that centralized control of budgets and the shared system of governance combine to minimize internal pressures to reduce costs (Ehrenberg 2002a). Moreover, Ehrenberg (2002a) argues that administration costs have risen more rapidly at selective private universities because in addition to the ineffectual control of costs there is a dysfunctional competition for prestige— including costly efforts to manage how they are ranked by external sources such as Business Week. While US studies, such as Ehrenberg’s, rely on what Wellman (2007) regards as unsystematic and incomparable cost data, she expects that when good data become available, they ‘…will show that most of the growth in spending…(has been for) administration, fund-raising and costs of regulation’ (Wellman 2007 cited in Lederman 2007:3), a possibility first noted by Leslie and Rhoades (1995). Thus, it seems fair to conclude that many university controllers are remarkably unwilling to ‘look under the hood of higher education expenditures’ (Callan 2007; Lederman 2008: 3). Conclusion Arguably, these various illustrations point to the empirical pertinence of the proposal that financial management in non-profit organizations is structurally different to that in capitalist firms. In favour is the (admittedly limited) body of research which points to weaknesses in cost identification and a bias towards revenue growth to resolve financial problems. Unfortunately, in most current research on the subject, revenue bias is treated as an empirical rather than structural feature of non-profit financial management. This treatment underpins the unwarranted assumption in the work of Wellman (2007) and others that cost identification by universities is technically possible and just overlooked, rather than structurally difficult and so avoided. Thus, the EU proposes the importation of business accountants to install ‘proper’ cost accounting systems. The danger with such proposals is they may provoke efforts to change university management to fit the accounting that is imported rather than innovate a kind of accounting that is compatible with non-pecuniary value rationalities that ought to govern resource allocation in non-profit universities (Rhoades et al. 2004; Peters 2004). 13 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? We have argued that the ‘revenue bias’ of non-profit organizations derives from the inability of capital accounting to impose substantively rational controls on resource allocation. The central implication is that such controls cannot be sought in accounting per se. Instead, universities and non-profit organizations must look to their governance arrangements and reform them along lines that encourage greater transparency in resource allocation. (Lauter 2002; Scott 2002). Transparency and dialogue are essential because cost identification (as opposed to merely recording expenditures) requires agreement on the (minimum) necessary consumption bundle required to constitute a university (or other public benefit non-profit organization). The only politically sustainable basis for reaching such agreement will be a commitment to social relations within the organization that make it possible to forge substantively value-rational links between the organization’s resource allocation processes and the aims agreed by stakeholders. While we have theorized reasons to be sceptical of the financial realism of commercialization by universities, much more work is required to understand the drivers of resource allocation in non-profit organizations. Some of that work is theoretical with further clarification required of the different roles played by class and status in setting the expenditure agendas of universities. Other necessary work is empirical, including for example, detailed case studies that make use of the financial information disclosed in the annual accounts of universities to shed light on the murky relationship between rising administration costs, rising student fees and efforts to diversify income through commercial ventures. At stake is the much broader issue of financial management in nongovernmental organizations, the proliferation of a new type of non-profit organization as the faux frais of the neo-liberal reforms of the public sector. Largely funded by the public purse (either directly or indirectly through favourable tax treatments), such organizations now provide a range of essential public services at arms length to government and its accountability mechanisms. More research is needed to understand how this new organizational form is managing public money and whether it is to be trusted to deliver services in the public’s interest. References Aronowitz, S. (2001) The Knowledge Factory: Dismantling the Corporate University and Creating True Higher Learning. Beacon Press: New York. Auditor General (2007) Report to Parliament on University of New South Wales accessed http://www.audit.nsw.gov.au/publications/reports/financial/2007/vol2/pdf/17_0454_u niversity_of_new_south_wales.pdf on March 2, 2008. Barton A. (2000) Accounting for public heritage facilities: assets or liabilities of government? Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal 13(2): 219-235. 14 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Callan P. (2007) Looking under the hood of higher education. Inside Higher Education Nov 2 accessed at http://www.insidehighered.com/views/2007/11/2/callan on 22 January 2008. Carruthers B. and Espeland W. (1991) Accounting for rationality: double-entry bookkeeping and the rhetoric of economic rationality. American Journal of Sociology 97(1): 31-39. Ciancanelli, P. (2008a) The business of teaching and learning. Learning and Teaching: The International Journal of Higher Education in the Social Sciences 1(1): 155-183. Ciancanelli, P. (2008b) (Re)producing Universities: Knowledge Dissemination, Market Power and the Global Knowledge Commons in Epstein D., Boden R., Deem R., Rizvi F. and Wright S. (eds) (2008) Geographies of Knowledge, Geometries of Power: Higher Education in the 21st Century, World Year Book of Education. Falmer/London: Routledge. CIHE (Council for Industry and Higher Education) (2005) International Competitiveness: Setting the Scene. July accessed at www.ciheuk.com/docs/PUBS/0507INTNL_COMP_setting the scene.pdf on Sept 15, 2005. Cohen D. (2007) Settlement in Singapore over failed university. Inside Higher Education Dec 13 accessed at http://www.insidehighered.com/news/12/13/Singapore on 25 January 2008. Colignan R. and Covaleski M. (1991) A Weberian framework in the study of accounting. Accounting, Organisations and Society 16 (2): 141-157. Columbia University (2003) Financial Statements. Accessed at http://www.finance.columbia.edu/controller/resources/financials.2003.pdf accessed 21 June 2007. Covalesky M. and Dirsmith M. (1988) An institutional perspective on the rise, social transformation and fall of a university budget category. Administrative Science Quarterly 33 (4): 562-587. Deem R. (2004) The knowledge worker, the manager-academic and the UK university: New and old forms of public management. Financial Accounting and Management 20 (2): 107-128. Dukes C. (2002) A Word about Fiduciary Obligations. Volaw Trust and Corporate Services, Ltd: Jersey, UK. 15 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Ehrenberg R. (2002a) Tuition Rising: Why College Costs So Much. Boston, Mass: Harvard University Press. Ehrenberg R. (2002b) Tuition is rising and why college costs so much. Educause, November 6. accessed at http://www.Educause.edu/ir/library/pdf/ffp0005s.pdf on May 4, 2007. Ehrenberg R. and Rizzo M. (2004) Financial forces and the future of American higher education Academe, accessed at www.aaup.org/publications/Academe/2004/04ja/04jaehre.htm on May 4, 2007. Epstein D., Boden R., Deem R., Rizvi F. and Wright S. (eds) (2008) Geographies of Knowledge, Geometries of Power: Higher Education in the 21st Century, World Year Book of Education. Falmer/London: Routledge. Forss P. (2007) University of New South Wales Singapore campus to shut in June. New Asia, May 23. Accessed at www.channelnewsasia.com/stories/singaporelocalnews/view/277985/1/.html on Mar 3, 2008. Hane P. (2003) Columbia University to close Fathom.com. Accessed at http://newsbreaks.infotoday.com/nbReader.asp?articleid=16813 on June 20, 2007. Haworth D. (2008a) Universities move to full cost accounting. University World News, Feb 17. Accessed at http://www.universityworldnews.com/article.php?story=20080214160432976 on 17 February 2008. Haworth, D. (2008b) EU low awareness of comparative accounting. University World News, February 17, Accessed at http://www.universityworldnews.com/article.php?story=20080214160314880 on 17 February 2008. HEFCE (Higher Education Funding Council of England) (2004) with RSM Robson Rhodes. Financial Management and Governance in Higher Education Institutions: England. OECD IMHE-HEFCE, International Comparative Higher Education Financial Management and Governance Project. January. Helmig, B., Jegers, M. and Lapsley, I. (2004) Challenges in Management of Nonprofit Organizations: A Research Overview. Working Paper Series Nonprofit Management. WP NPO No1/2004. University of Fribourg Switzerland accessed at http://ssrn.com/abstract=929484 on Nov 24 2006. 16 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? IFAC (International Federation of Accountants) (2002) Transition to the Accrual Basis of Accounting: Guidance for Governments and Government Entities, Public Sector Committee, Study 14. Jackson J. and Cowley J. (2002) Blinking dons or donning blinkers: fiduciary and common law obligations of members of governing boards of Australian universities. University Governance Journal 6: 8-17. Johnstone, B. with Akora, A and Experton, W. (2000) The Financing And Management of Higher Education: A Status Report on Worldwide Reforms. (http://buffalo.suny.edu/johnstone). Jones C. (1995) Accounting and the Enterprise: A Social Analysis. London and New York: Thomson Learning. Jones R. and Pendlebury M. (1996) Public Sector Accounting. London: Pittman Publishers. Lapsley I. (1999) Accounting and the new public management. Financial Accountability and Management 15:3:201-207. Lauter P. (2002) From Adelphi to Enron. Academe Online accessed at http://www.aaup.org/AAUP/pubres/academe/2002/ND/Feat/Laut.html on 28 Jan 2008. Lederman D. (2007) Costs and the college trustee. Inside Higher Education, March 6. Accessed at http://insidehighered.com/news/2007/03/06/agb on December, 2007. Lederman D. (2008) Snapshots of endowment spending Inside Higher Education, March 7. Accessed at http://insidehighered.com/news/2008/03/07/endow on March 10, 2008. Lee T. A. (1996) Income and Value Measurement: Theory and Practice. Revised Third Edition. London: Thomson Business Press. Leslie L. and Rhoades G. (1995) Rising administration costs: seeking explanations. Journal of Higher Education 66(2): 187-212. Marginson S. (2004) A revised Marxist political economy of national education markets. Policy Futures in Education 2(3/4): 439-453. Mautz R. K. (1988) Monuments, mistakes and opportunities. Accounting Horizons 2(2): 123-8. 17 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Nobel, D. (2003) Digital Diploma Mills: The Automation of Higher Education. New York: Monthly Review Press. Olson O., Guthrie J. and Humphreys C. (eds) (1998) Global Warning: Debating International Developments in New Public Financial Management. Oslo: Cappelen Akademisk Forlag. Parker R. H., Harcourt G. and Whittington G. (eds) (1986) Readings in the Concept and Measurement of Income. Second Edition. Oxford, England: Philip Allan. Perkinson R. (2006) Trends in Global Higher Education…the Changing Landscape. Presentation to IFC International Investment Forum for Private Education, February 2 and 3 accessed at http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/che.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/Ed_06_Perkinson/$FILE/Perkin son_Global+Trends+in+Private+Higher+Education.pdf on 13 March 2008. Peters M. (2004) Marxist futures: knowledge, socialism and the academy. Policy Futures in Education 2(3-4): 435-438. Reading, B. (1996) The University in Ruins. Boston, Mass: Harvard University Press. Rhoades G., Maldonado-Maldonado A., Ordouka I. and Velazquez M. (2004) Imagining alternativas to global corporate, new economy, academic capitalism. Policy Futures in Education 2(2): 316-329. Salerno C. (2003) What We Know about the Efficiency of Higher Education Institutions: The Best Evidence. Working Paper University of Twente. Accessed at http://www.minocw.nl/documenten/bhw-99-bgo99.pdf on September 15, 2005. Scott J. W. (2002) The critical state of shared governance. Academe Online 88(4). Accessed at http://www.aaup.org/AAUP/pubsres/academe/2002/JA on September 15 2005. Sidebotham R. (1965) An accounting framework for local authorities. Abacus 1(1): 24-40 Slaughter, S. and Leslie, L. (1997) Academic Capitalism: Politics, Polices and the Entrepreneurial University. Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press. Varghese N. V. (2001) The limits to diversification of sources of funding in higher education. International Institute for Educational Planning (IIEP) Contributions No. 34. Paper presented at the IMHE General Conference, 11-13 September, OECD, Paris. Accessed at http://www.unesco.org/iiep on September 15, 2005. 18 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Vincent-Lancrin S. (2004) Building future scenarios for universities. Policy Futures in Education 2(2): 245-263. Wellman J. (2007) Barriers to Equal Educational Opportunity: Addressing the Rising Costs of a College Education. Testimony before the House Committee on Education and Labor, Nov 1 Accessed at http://republicans.edlabor.house.gov/media/files/Hearings/FullCommittee/11107/Well man%20-%20housetestimonyfinal.doc on January 5, 2008. Weber, M. (1978) Economy and Society. Edited and translated by G Roth and C Wittich Berkeley, California: University of California Press. Wynne A. (2003) Do private sector financial statements provide a suitable model for public sector accounts? Paper presented at the European Group of Public Administration, Portugal, 3-6 September, pp.1-22. Wright S. and Ørberg, J. W. (2008) Autonomy and Control: Danish university reform in the context of modern governance. Learning and Teaching: The International Journal of Higher Education in the Social Sciences 1(1): 27-57. Yamey, B. (1978) Essays on the History of Accounting. New York: Arno Press. 19 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? Endnotes i Aggregate data on university funded commercial ventures are not compiled. Public bodies, such as the International Finance Corporation (Perkinson 2006) and others cited in text, offer data on the sector as a potential site of private investment but not on the sector as a source of private investment into other sectors. Some information on commercialization can be gleaned from tertiary sources including Inside Higher Education (http://www.insidehighered.com) for mainly US news and University World News for mainly European and Developing Countries (http://www.universityworldnews.com). ii Examples of research of this type can be found in Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal and Accounting, Organizations and Society. For a discussion of its debts to Sociology, see Jones (1995). iii This paper elaborates themes initially developed by Ciancanelli (2008a) on the rationality of using monetary accounting to assess the performance of the controllers of non-profit organizations. iv The dictionary translation of Erwerb (a noun) is given as acquisitive (an adjective); in the text, Erwerb is translated as ‘business’ (a noun) an English language word for a unit focusing on acquisition wealth (profit accumulation). v The difference turns on how the financial position in summarized. A fund’s basis would reveal the net revenue/net worth of each specific (or specific type of) endowment whereas consolidation would aggregate the ‘net revenues’ of each into the net revenue of the unit. If the uses of a bequest are highly stipulated, there is good reason not to include the income on the amount into consolidated revenue since its proceeds cannot be used for general purposes. A fuller discussion of the lack of fungibility of bequests is given in the next section. vi In Ciancanelli (2008a) attention was drawn to the relation between resource fungibility and the difference between the substantive (as opposed to purely formal) rationality of monetary accounting. The discussion here draws attention to the implications of resource fungiblity for cost management. vii A contrast can be drawn between liquidity and fungibility; liquidity concerns how readily the asset may be exchanged for other types of goods and services. Monetary resources are highly liquid. Fungibility refers to its use. In commerce, monetary resources are not only assumed to be liquid but to be available for any purpose. viii It may seem odd to refer to tuition fees as a ‘grant’ rather than a ‘user charge.’ The difficulty with ‘user charge’ is that it implies any individual, for a fee, can use the service, something that may be true of public transport but is obviously not true of university education. The individual must first be granted admission to study at the university before he/she is given the opportunity to pay a fee for the privilege. ix Lederman (2008) reports that a US government survey revealed a wide range of differences in the fungibility of endowments. Texas A&M University reported that 20 Working Papers on University Reform Penny Ciancanelli: Will market-based ventures substitute for government funding? restrictions were placed on 90% of its endowment in contrast to Rice University, which claimed that restrictions were placed on 53% of its endowment. x Wellman is the executive director of the Delta Project on Postsecondary Costs, Productivity and Accountability http://deltacostproject.org/page4.html. Funding for the project comes from Lumina Foundation. xi An illustration of the structural insensitivity to costs is given by the so-called serials crisis faced by most university libraries in the last few decades. Monopoly pricing of academic journal subscription, particularly science, technology and medical journals, was ignored by the financial officers of most universities. Indeed, there is little evidence to suggest any of them took the trouble to understand the drivers of the event, its implications for the autonomy of their organization or the alternatives (including new modes of publishing that were innovated by members of their own organizations). It took the efforts of scientists and librarians at two public universities in the US (University of California and University of Wisconsin) to initiate efforts to understand, to identify the cause and to come up with a solution—all aspects of which were resolutely ignored or opposed by the financial managers of universities. The alternative pioneered by these scholars (Open Access) is now embraced by agencies that fund much of the research conducted at public universities, such as the National Institute of Health in the US and the research councils in the UK. For an overview of these developments, including a theoretical perspective on their origins, see Ciancanelli 2008b. Previous Working Papers in this series: 1. Setting Universities Free? The background to the self-ownership of Danish Universities, Jakob Williams Ørberg, July 2006. 2. Trust in Universities - Parliamentary debates on the 2003 university law, Jakob Williams Ørberg, October 2006. 3. Histories of RUC - Roskilde University Centre, Else Hansen, November 2006. 4. An Insight into the Ideas Surrounding the 2003 University Law – development contracts and management reforms, Peter Brink 21