12338,"what individual freedoms are denied in a totalitarian state",12,,,260,http://www.123helpme.com/search.asp?text=totalitarian+state,3.7,38800,"2016-02-25 04:46:34"

advertisement
Freedom and Prosperity
Jake Dubuque
Dubuque 2
Abstract:
The purpose of this project is to examine the relationship between freedom and
economic prosperity on the theoretical and empirical level. An extensive review of
literature defines the concept of freedom, which is broken into political and economic
varieties and how these are related to wealth. Several similar empirical studies have been
included for the purpose of analyzing their methodology and results, in order to provide a
reasonable expectation for the results of this study. Then, data from 152 counties for
1995-2005 are statistically tested to determine whether a relationship between freedom
and prosperity exists. Freedom House’s Freedom in the World index is used to measure
political freedom, while The Index of Economic Freedom, produced by the Heritage
Foundation and the Wall Street Journal measure the second variety of freedom. These
indices are compared to the GDP per capita of each country. The results indicate that
there is a significant correlation between each variety of freedom and wealth.
Dubuque 3
1. Introduction
Freedom is perhaps one of the most explored concepts in all of human history.
Wars have been fought over it; philosophers have debated its nature and lawyers have
argued its legal definition. The amount of material on the subject is beyond superlatives
and yet the discussion of freedom remains one of humanity’s most enduring, engaging
issues. While most frequently admired for its intrinsic value, it has also been suggested
that freedom provides an economic value. The goal of this project is to examine recent
history in an effort to ascertain if and to what extent a relationship exists between
freedom and economic prosperity. Preparing to look into this possible correlation, one
must first engage a variety of the material written on the subject. Then, once the concept
of freedom has been sufficiently defined and other similar projects explored, pursuit of
the main question can begin. Through analyzing recent economic data and multiple
freedom indices, we can hopefully determine whether a relationship exists between the
variables and to what extent they are correlated.
The discussion inevitably begins with freedom and how to define it. In order to
break down the larger concept into more manageable components, this study will
distinguish between political freedom and economic freedom. While this distinction is
necessary, it should not be implied that the two varieties are mutually independent of
each other. By identifying and exploring each type, it will clarify how the two are
interrelated and establish a strong foundation for analyzing the relationship between
‘freedom’ and economic prosperity.
Dubuque 4
2. Defining Political Freedom
On the subject of political freedom, a great deal has been written and one
universally accepted definition has proved elusive. The one common political term used
to identify freedom is ‘liberalism,’ although the meaning of this term has become as
amorphous as the definition of freedom. The classic liberal from the nineteenth century
had a definition of liberalism that differs from more recent American liberals. Some
argue that this was merely an intellectual evolution, while others believe that anti-liberal
forces usurped the term and fundamentally changed its meaning. Social scientist F.A.
Hayek writes that “to the great apostles of political freedom the word had meant freedom
from coercion, freedom from the arbitrary power of other men, release from the ties
which left the individual no choice but obedience to the orders of a superior to whom he
was attached.”1 This classic understanding of liberalism defines political freedom as
freedom from oppression; a system of governance that maximizes individual rights.
Milton Friedman expands on this point, saying that “the fundamental threat to freedom is
power to coerce, be it in the hands of a monarch, a dictator, an oligarchy, or a momentary
majority. The preservation of freedom requires the elimination of such concentration of
power to the fullest possible extent and the dispersal and distribution of whatever power
cannot be eliminated.”2 According to Friedman, concentration of power inevitably
infringes on the freedom of others. Therefore, the only way to insure the protection of
freedom is to limit the size and scope of government.
Political scientist Francis Fukuyama adds to the discussion by identifying what
type of philosophy liberalism encourages. He states that “political liberalism can be
1
2
Hayek, F.A. The Road to Serfdom. p. 25
Friedman, Milton. Capitalism and Freedom. p. 15
Dubuque 5
defined simply as a rule of law that recognizes certain individual rights or freedoms from
government control.”1 According to liberalism then, freedom is not anarchy, but a
system of laws that governs all citizens and protects their individual rights. In order to
facilitate the dispersal of what power is granted to the government, a system of checks
and balances ought to be put in place. In this ideal liberal state, Friedman believes that it
is the duty of the government to provide “a means whereby we can modify the rules,
[mediate] differences among us on the meaning of the rules, and to enforce compliance
with the rules on the part of those few who would otherwise not play the game.”2 In this
manner the government is an external force that upholds the principle of political
freedom by establishing laws that protect individual rights, agrees to arbitrate disputes
between individuals, and enforces the established rules. According to this philosophy,
government is only considered to be liberal if it recognizes individual rights and
freedoms while minimizing coercive authority.
If the measurement of political liberalism is the extent to which the government
protects individual freedom, then it is important to understand what those political rights
and liberties are. Perhaps the most widely agreed upon definition of these rights can be
found in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, which was adopted 1948 by the
General Assembly of the newly formed United Nations. Although there are some thirty
articles that compose the declaration, most can be grouped together into three broad
categories that embody classic liberalism. The first article states that “all human beings
are born free and equal in dignity and rights.” This idea of equality includes the fact that
everyone is entitled to the rights set forth in the declaration and that discrimination before
1
2
Fukuyama, Francis. The End of History and the Last Man. p. 42
Friedman. p. 25
Dubuque 6
the law is unacceptable. The second theme found in the declaration embodies the idea
that everyone has personal rights, including the rights “to life, liberty and security of
person,” in addition to the rights to privacy, education, religious freedom, freedom of
expression, and the right to own property. Finally, everyone is entitled to participate in
government, either directly or through elections. These three basic rights can be summed
up as the right to be treated equally, the right to individual autonomy, and the right to
participate in government. The philosophical idea of political freedom is grounded in
these specific rights that according to the preamble of the declaration recognize the
“inherent dignity and of the equal and inalienable rights of all members of the human
family is the foundation of freedom, justice and peace in the world.” 1
According to Hayek and Friedman, this definition of liberalism was gradually
eroded by socialists around the turn of the twentieth century. Seeking to equate
egalitarianism with liberalism, the socialists identified new economic rights that they
believed superseded the classic liberal rights. The UN declaration even included some of
these in its articles, like the right to an adequate standard of living: “including food,
clothing, housing and medical care and necessary social services, and the right to security
in the event of unemployment, sickness, disability, widowhood, old age or other lack of
livelihood in circumstances beyond his control.”2 Fukuyama calls them second and third
generation economic rights, but argues that “the problem with such an expanded list is
that the achievement of these rights is not clearly compatible with other rights like those
of property or free economic exchange.”3 Because liberals believed that the expanded list
1
Universal Declaration of Human Rights. http://www.unhchr.ch/udhr/lang/eng.htm
Universal Declaration of Human Rights. Article 25.
3
Fukuyama. p.42
2
Dubuque 7
of rights the socialists proposed were not always reconcilable with their ‘first generation,’
individual rights, the debate became one of egalitarianism versus liberalism.
For the classic liberal, equality was achieved through the idea of universal rights
that treated all individuals equally. They “distinguish[ed] sharply between equality of
rights and equality of opportunity, on the one hand, and material equality or equality of
outcome on the other.”1 For the socialists, equality was measured through the latter
definition; they believed that a minimum quality of life must be achieved before
individual rights had any meaning. This minimum was identified as “freedom from
necessity, release from the compulsion of the circumstances which inevitably limit the
range of choice of all of us . . . [b]efore man could be truly free, the ‘despotism of
physical want’ had to be broken, the ‘restraints of the economic system relaxed.’”2 This
competing definition of freedom was based on the idea that physical deprivation was a
powerful form of constraint on the individual’s ability to act. Unlike the classic liberals,
the socialists saw government action as a necessary means to promote their new
definition of freedom. For them, government was a tool for ensuring that a
predetermined quality of life was achieved for all. Yet if the state is responsible for
providing some degree of equality of means while continuing to protect individual rights,
tension inevitably develops between these two obligations.
Of course the argument cannot be simplified to a disagreement between those that
prefer the good of the individual and those that favor the good of society. Indeed both
ideological camps believe that the freedom their rights engender makes both the
individual and society better off. It is not enough to take socialism to simply mean the
1
2
Friedman. p.195
Hayek. p.26
Dubuque 8
ideal of greater equality; it is also a philosophy of how to achieve those ideals. Hayek
finds that “[n]early all the points which are disputed between socialists and liberals
concern the methods common to all forms of collectivism and not the particular ends for
which socialists want to use them.”1 In order to achieve social justice, equality, and
freedom from ‘necessity,’ socialists almost always believe that a “rational utilization of
our resources requires central direction and organization of all our activities according to
some consciously constructed ‘blueprint.’”2 This method certainly conflicts with the
liberal definition of political freedom in that it concentrates coercive power in the state,
or whatever body is set up to determine the organization and regulation of economic
activity. If the socialist ideal of economic security for all is realized through a centrally
administered economy, then freedom from necessity does not create freedom in any real
sense of the term. While socialists can argue that physical depravation severely
constrains individual freedom, the material security that their philosophy provides does
not liberate the individual. Instead they are made dependent on the state. Even though
the state’s motives might be altruistic, it still must have the power to enforce the
regulations or central plan of the economy. With such a concentration of power in
government and the state of dependency it creates, the individual cannot be described as
politically or economically free. It doesn’t matter whether the government is a
dictatorship or democratically elected by the majority; the state is totalitarian. The
achievement of social justice and equality under the socialist system comes at a price: and
that price is freedom.
1
2
Hayek. p.34
Hayek. p.35
Dubuque 9
3. Defining Economic Freedom
If socialism is the ‘road to serfdom’ as Hayek argues, then a closer look must be
given to the concept of economic freedom and its relationship with political freedom. As
Milton Friedman writes, “fundamentally, there are only two ways of co-ordinating the
economic activities of millions. One is central direction involving the use of coercion –
the technique of the army and of the modern totalitarian state. The other is voluntary cooperation of individuals – the technique of the marketplace.”1 This simple
characterization pointedly distinguishes between the two philosophies of economic
organization available to governments. That’s not to say either of these systems exist in
their purest form anywhere in the world; even the most liberal of economies have a large
state sector and the most totalitarian socialist state has a black market. What is important
is to identify how liberalism or ‘capitalism’ differs from state control. Fukuyama writes
that “[i]n its economic manifestation, liberalism is the recognition of the right of free
economic activity and economic exchange based on private property and markets.”2 Like
political freedom, capitalism is the idea of individual rights and liberties within the
economic sphere. Equality is found in the rights and opportunities of individuals, not in
the outcome of material wealth.
The idea of individualism is not a philosophy of selfishness or disregard for the
greater good of society. Rather, its proponents suggest that deferring to the individual is
the only way or at least the best way for achieving the greatest good. The argument is
made that scales of value are relative to the individual. Whereas one individual might
prefer one good over another, a different person has different preferences. Because of
1
2
Friedman. pp. 13-14
Fukuyama. p. 44
Dubuque 10
this, “the individualist concludes that the individuals should be allowed, within defined
limits, to follow their own values and preferences rather than somebody else’s; that
within these spheres the individual’s system of ends should be supreme and not subject to
any dictation by others.”1 This argument holds weight for defending both political and
economic freedom. Whereas for political liberalism the individual ought to be free from
state coercion and empowered within government, in capitalism the individual should not
be denied economic choices, but empowered to make them. The greatest good is not
giving to everyone what a few people value most, but allowing everyone the opportunity
to decide and act on their own preferences. Individualism does not require or assume that
individuals are selfish, but rather recognizes that they are the ones most able to judge
their own needs and work to fulfill them. Capitalism is the philosophy of empowering
the individual in the marketplace.
Unfortunately, capitalism is commonly misrepresented by the term ‘laissez-faire,’
the philosophy of a hands-off approach by government in regards to economic matters.
Milton Friedman disagrees with this characterization writing: “the existence of a free
market does not of course eliminate the need for government. On the contrary,
government is essential both as a forum for determining the ‘rules of the game’ and as an
umpire to interpret and enforce the rules decided on.”2 This metaphor aptly compares
free market economics to a game, not to trivialize it, but to illustrate its characteristics. A
game is not a game if the outcome is already predetermined, or ‘centrally directed.’
What makes a game unique is that players interact with each other knowing in advance
the rules and that any disputes that will be settled by a third party. Free market capitalism
1
2
Hayek. p. 59
Friedman. p.15
Dubuque 11
is not about a ‘laissez-faire’ or hands off approach by the government, but a system
where government sets the rules, enforces them and arbitrates disputes, but does not
actively influence or coerce players. Hayek continues, “of course every state must act
and every action of the state interferes with something or other. But that is not the point.
The important question is whether the individual can foresee the action of the state and
make use of the knowledge as a datum in forming his own plans . . . The state controlling
weights and measures (or preventing fraud and deception in any other way) is certainly
[observing liberal principles].”1 In this regard, the state’s coercive power is limited by
pre-established rules and therefore shapes the dynamics of the game but goes no further.
The capitalist wants the state to empower its citizens to make their own economic
decisions, not make those choices for them.
One of the key arguments made by socialists is that individuals are not free to
make their own political or economic decisions until they have been empowered with
economic security. In a capitalist system some measure of security can be provided to
the very poorest of society without a massive scheme of redistribution of wealth. As
Hayek sees it, there are: “two kinds of security: the limited one, which can be achieved
for all, and which is therefore no privilege but a legitimate object of desire; and absolute
security, which in a free society cannot be achieved for all.”2 He defines the limited type
of security as security from “severe physical privation” and absolute security as the
security of a “given standard of life.” Thus the liberal believes it is the duty of the state
to provide the economic means to sustain life if the individual is incapable or unable to
do so on their own. However, if the state takes it upon itself to guarantee a certain quality
1
2
Hayek. pp. 80-81
Hayek. p. 119
Dubuque 12
of life for all its citizens or attempts to value what quality of life different groups deserve,
then it has eliminated much of the competitive nature of the free market. In order to
guarantee a certain quality of life for some, the state will have to find resources
elsewhere. Most people would agree that some taxation is not only inevitable and
desirable for services rendered, but taxation is also an example of the coercive power of
the state. If the state was to step in and bail out the auto-industry in order to protect those
high paying manufacturing jobs with excellent benefits, other professions would demand
the same state-sponsored security. The resources to provide that security would
inevitably come from those sectors that weren’t protected, thereby encouraging them to
demand protection instead of paying out. It is therefore impossible to provide the more
extensive form of security without controlling the market or abolishing it all together and
in the process reducing individual freedom.
Despite the theoretical discussion of the proper role of government in managing a
liberal economy, the fundamental definition of economic freedom has proved elusive.
Perhaps the most colorful term used to describe the idea of economic freedom comes
from journalist Thomas Friedman of The New York Times, who calls the set of policies
the government must adopt the ‘golden straightjacket.’ Some of his golden rules follow:
. . . making the private sector the primary engine of its economic growth,
maintaining a low rate of inflation and price stability, shrinking the size of
its state bureaucracy . . . eliminating and lowering tariffs on imported
goods, removing restrictions on foreign investment, getting rid of quotas
and domestic monopolies, increasing exports, privatizing state-owned
industries and utilities, deregulating capital markets, making its currency
Dubuque 13
convertible . . . deregulating its economy to promote as much domestic
competition as possible, eliminating government corruption, subsidies and
kickbacks as much as possible . . .1
His list is certainly extensive and illustrates in better detail the broader theme of
government setting the rules and then stepping back to arbitrate. The first step is to have
the state adopt the philosophy of a private market as the principle driving force of its
economy. Once that philosophical decision is made, the other policies of economic
freedom are the tools that build a strong private economy. Friedman’s straightjacket
recognizes the importance of creating a stable business environment by controlling
inflation and maintaining price stability. By doing this, the government provides a
degree of security that encourages individuals to interact within the marketplace and
produce wealth. Policies that bust monopolies, reduce government subsidies and open
the market to foreign producers promote competition and limit unfair advantages.
Monopolies, subsidies, kickbacks, and some forms of government regulation provide
security to a limited number of companies but discriminate against the rest. Economic
freedom means promoting equal opportunities within the market rather than ensuring
special security for some.
4. The Relationship between Political and Economic Freedom
So far economic freedom has been implicitly linked to political freedom; now it’s
time to take a more thorough look at the suggested theoretical relationship. Milton
Friedman addresses the issue appropriately with the statement that, “the relationship
1
Friedman, Thomas. The Lexus and the Olive Tree. p. 103
Dubuque 14
between political and economic freedom is complex and by no means unilateral.”1
Literature on the subject is divided as to what phenomenon causes the other: which
comes first, political or economic freedom? The two classic examples used to buttress
each side of the debate are the countries of India and China. Whereas India gained
political independence and democracy first, it took nearly forty years for the country to
begin to adopt more liberal economic policies. On the other hand China’s Communist
Party has maintained a tight one-party dictatorship for decades while transforming its
socialist economy into a competitive market based on the principles of economic
freedom. Considering the size and importance of these countries, it is impossible to
ignore the implications of their respective histories. While keeping in mind these two
examples and the counterpoints they provide, it’s important to take a closer look into the
theoretical relationship between political and economic freedom.
For some academics, capitalism’s liberalizing influence in the marketplace
directly influences citizens’ drive for democracy and political freedom. Hayek quotes the
‘prominent old communist,’ Max Eastman as saying that “[Marx] is the one who
informed us, looking backwards, that the evolution of private capitalism with its free
market had been a precondition for the evolution of all our democratic freedoms. It never
occurred to him, looking forward, that if this was so, these other freedoms might
disappear with the abolition of the free market.”2 What Eastman had come to realize was
that economic freedom not only encourages the growth of political liberalism, but was a
vital condition for the long term success of democracy. This hinges on the idea that
freedom gained in the marketplace influences the desire for freedom in politics. In a
1
2
Friedman, Milton. p.10
Eastman, Max. Reader’s Digest. July, 1941. p. 39. quoted in Hayek pp.104-5
Dubuque 15
capitalist economy consumers are presented with a wide variety of choices and the ability
to act on their desires. According to this theory, the autonomy granted to them in the
market provides the knowledge and framework for demanding autonomy in politics. The
liberalization of China’s economy has prompted many to predict the inevitable
liberalization of politics as well. An editorial last year in USA Today argued that
“business develops precisely the traits that make democracy work. It requires
independence, much effort, and self-discipline—but also the ability to collaborate.”
Recognizing that China has adopted market capitalism, the author argues that “this has
created opportunity, prosperity and de facto personal liberty. The question now is
whether it will lead to democracy…”1 China in a sense has become the ultimate test for
the theory, the principles of economic liberalism have been in place for some time now,
yet the state continues to maintain a firm grip on political power. For skeptics, China has
already proven the theory defunct; for idealists China remains the Holy Grail.
There are other countries that have liberalized politically after doing so
economically. Gary Becker, an economist at the University of Chicago writes that “the
history of different countries during the past century strongly indicates that economic
freedoms over time typically push societies toward political freedoms.” He cites as
recent examples South Korea, Taiwan and Chile; three countries whose governing
dictatorships gave up centrally directed economies in favor of free market economics.
Becker adds that within two decades of adopting liberal economic policies, “all three
nations had achieved, or were moving rapidly toward, political democracies, with vibrant
competition for elections among competing parties, and a mainly free press.” 2 While
1
2
Scramm, Carl and Robert Litan. “Why Democracy is America’s Second most Valuable Export.”
Becker, Gary S. “Economic and Political Freedom: Does One Lead to the Other?”
Dubuque 16
China remains a pipe dream for the theory, these three countries offer credible evidence
in support of the thesis.
On the other hand, another theory argues the relationship operates in the opposite
direction; that political liberalism and democracy are the forces that have created
capitalism. Hayek was one who believed that economic freedom was the unforeseen
consequence of political freedom. He found that as the individual gained autonomy from
the state, there was a “conscious realization that the spontaneous and uncontrolled efforts
of individuals were capable of producing a complex order of economic activities could
come only after this development had made some progress. The subsequent elaboration
of a consistent argument in favor of economic freedom was the outcome of a free growth
of economic activity which had been the undersigned and unforeseen by-product of
political freedom.”1 According to this line of reasoning, the primary focus of early
liberalization was political. When this new freedom inevitably spilled over into the
economic sphere, individuals began exchanging goods and creating businesses in a free
market environment. This sequence of liberalization was observed in India: political
followed by economic liberalization. However, Becker finds that, “the path from
political to economic freedom . . . is slower and more uncertain. It took India over four
decades to begin to loosen its extensive controls over private companies, labor markets,
start-ups, imports from abroad, and numerous other activities.”2 Even though the country
gained political independence from Great Britain in 1947, a significant amount of time
passed before the government adopted liberal economic policies. Although it might be in
1
2
Hayek. p.15
Becker
Dubuque 17
the best interests of the country to promote the free market, politically liberated
democracies often have powerful special interest groups that promote their own interests
and lobby hard to retain their economic security. Also, since liberalizing economic
reforms that tend to have significant long-term benefit often have short-term costs, these
policy changes are difficult to implement in democracies because of the unpopularity of
the short-term costs. For example, when economic liberalization exposes inefficient
sectors to increased competition, hard restructuring and lay-offs will most likely follow.
Needless to say, these short-term costs would be very unpopular with those affected.
Given the real costs of economic liberalization, it’s important to understand why such
reforms are worth pursuing.
5. The Relationship between Freedom and Economic Prosperity
For the liberal, political and economic freedom are desirable in their own right,
but many intellectuals have come to believe that one or both of these influence, or are
influenced by, economic prosperity. The addition of this third variable is critical for
empirical analysis. Again, much has been written on the subject, hopefully a few
selected studies will help clarify the discussion. One of the seminal studies was
conducted by Seymour Martin Lipset and published in 1959. He noted that “from
Aristotle down to the present, men have argued that only in a wealthy society in which
relatively few citizens lived in real poverty could a situation exist in which the mass of
the population could intelligently participate in politics.”1 His study is an effort to
empirically test this hypothesis in the geographical regions of Europe and Latin America.
To measure economic prosperity, he uses per capita income as well as the number of
1
Lipset, Seymour Martin. “Some Social Requisites of Democracy.” p. 75
Dubuque 18
people per car and per doctor in society, the number of radios, telephones and newspapers
for every thousand people. According to his findings, there is a significant difference
between the relative wealth of ‘more democratic’ countries and ‘less democratic’ ones.
In Europe there were 126 more people per car in the less democratic countries and 175
more people per car in Latin America’s less democratic countries than its more
democratic ones. Similarly the less democratic countries in both regions had an average
per capita income significantly lower than the average per capita income in the more
democratic countries.1
Not only did Lipset find that democratic countries had a higher degree of material
wealth, but he also noticed that these countries were more developed as well. In
measuring levels of industrialization, he found that fewer people worked in agricultural
sectors in the more democratic countries compared to the less democratic ones. Also, all
of the indices that measure urbanization concluded that the more democratic countries
had a greater percentage of their populations residing in urban areas. As for education,
literacy rates also appeared to be correlated with levels of democratization. The more
democratic countries of Europe were almost completely literate while the less democratic
ones averaged 85 percent. In Latin America the difference was even more significant: 74
percent compared to only 46 percent.2 Given all of this information, Lipset makes the
statement:
Increased wealth is not only related causally to the development of
democracy by changing the social conditions of the workers, but it also
affects the political role of the middle class through changing the shape of
1
2
Lipset. p. 75-77.
Lipset p. 78-89
Dubuque 19
the stratification structure so that it shifts from an elongated pyramid, with
a large lower-class base, to a diamond with a growing middle-class. A
large middle class plays a mitigating role in moderating conflict since it is
able to reward moderate and democratic parties and penalize extremist
groups.1
His conclusions find that economic development influences democratization indirectly
through ‘social’ development. By increasing industrialization, urbanization and
education, greater accumulation of wealth increases the size of the middle class and this
class is able to diffuse the natural tension between the rich and the poor. In turn, a more
secure, stable, and educated society not only demands democracy, but also has the
capability to maintain a stable democratic government.
Economist Jagdish Bhagwati agrees with Lipset that “economic prosperity
produces a middle class. This emerging middle class creates, however haltingly, an
effective demand for democratization of politics: the new bourgeoisie, with wallets a
little fatter, seeks a political voice, not just one in the marketplace.”2 At the same time he
cautions that democracies are not the only form of government capable of producing
economic prosperity and cites Chile, Brazil, Spain and China as examples of dictatorships
that have significantly increased the level of wealth within the country. Nevertheless, as
the level of wealth increases in society, Bhagwati agrees that there is a corresponding rise
in pressure for democratization. Political scientist Larry Diamond examined Lipset’s
theory with updated data and concluded that: “This review of the evidence more than
three decades later has demonstrated that Lipset (1960) was broadly correct both in his
1
2
Lipset p. 83
Bhagwati, Jagdish. In Defense of Globalization. p. 94
Dubuque 20
assertion of a strong causal relationship between economic development and democracy
and in his explanations of why development promotes democracy.”1 He also adds that in
countries where democracy already exists, economic development increases the security
and stability of liberal governments and development in totalitarian states leads to an
increasing probability of a successful transition to democracy.
Another comprehensive study examines the relationship of economic prosperity
and political freedom using a different method. In search of an answer, UCLA professors
Roll and Talbott employ an events-study technique, commonly used by financial
economists to study the effects of a particular event. They identified democratic and
antidemocratic events in a wide range of countries and studied the impact these events
had on each country’s gross national income (GNI). Some examples of their democratic
events include Chile freely electing a president in 1990, democracy returning to Peru in
1980, and the establishment of democracy in South Korea in 1987. On the other hand,
some antidemocratic events include a military junta in Myanmar in 1962, Marcos
declaring martial law in the Philippines in 1972 and the Pinochet dictatorship established
in 1973 in Chile.2 After assembling the data on GNI, Roll and Talbott used statistical
tests to analyze individual countries and the average trends in all countries around
democratic and antidemocratic events.
According to their data, the average sample country experienced a 0.67 percent
rate of gross national income (GNI) per capita growth per year, for the ten year period
prior to experiencing a democratic event. Following this event the rate that per capita
income was increasing jumped to 2.2 percent for the next five years, then 1.7 percent for
1
2
Diamond, Larry. “Economic Development and Democracy Reconsidered.” p. 125
Roll, Richard and John Talbott. “Political Freedom, Economic Liberty and Prosperity.”
Dubuque 21
the five years after that, and finally 2.7 percent for the next ten years. Looking at their
data, it seems evident that democratic events had a positive influence on the rate of per
capita income growth. Simply put, the countries in their survey on average had more
economic growth following a democratic event than preceding it. Therefore, the authors
draw the conclusion that there is a causal relationship between political freedom and
economic growth. The data suggests that democratic rights bring about increased
economic prosperity.1
When examining the ‘antidemocratic events,’ the data revealed some interesting
results. The growth rates following those events were mostly flat for the first five years,
followed by a decline in the rate of growth (although not an absolute decline in wealth) in
the next five years, followed by a rate of growth of just 0.85 percent per year for the next
decade.2 While the antidemocratic event on average did not reduce the economic wealth
of the country, it appeared to severely restrict the country’s rate of income growth.
Further, according to the authors’ analysis, every year after a democratic event
experienced a higher growth rate than every year after an antidemocratic event. Given all
of this, the data certainly appears to support the idea that political freedom positively
affects economic growth.
However, their analysis also found that on average, a country experiencing a
democratic event had about an 80 percent higher income leading up to the event than the
average country experiencing an antidemocratic event, although they do add the caveat
that both had average incomes that were very low by our standards.3 This could be
interpreted as an indication that economic prosperity is also a precursor of political
1
ibid
Roll and Talbot
3
ibid
2
Dubuque 22
freedom. The relationship therefore appears to run in both directions: democratic events
(political freedom) triggers economic growth and economic prosperity triggers
democratic events. Although this might frustrate attempts to determine an independent
and dependent variable, it indicates that there is a strong interdependent correlation
between economic prosperity and political rights and freedom. In order to better
illustrate the trends of economic growth and level of prosperity surrounding these events,
one of their graphs has been included below.
1
Although the survey is thorough, it is by no means exhaustive (as is readily
admitted by the authors). Concerned with personal biases, Roll and Talbot had a third
individual from the Hoover Institute assess their list for omissions and
mischaracterizations. As with any survey, there is certainly a degree of error associated
with the sample size, and concern as to whether the sample is an accurate representation
of the population. Despite this, it seems that Roll and Talbot offer legitimate statistics
indicating that there is a correlation between economic prosperity and political freedom.
Their data further suggests a degree of interdependence where economic prosperity is a
1
Roll and Talbot
Dubuque 23
precursor for democratic events, and the events themselves cause an increase in economic
growth in the country.
Thus far, quite a bit has been investigated on the nature of democracy, political
liberalism and economic prosperity; it’s time now to shift the focus to studies examining
the relationship between economic freedom and prosperity. The specific policies
promoting free market capitalism have already been discussed, but one phenomenon has
thus far been left out: globalization. Classic liberal economics encourages free trade as a
method for increasing competition, which in turn increases efficiency, productivity, and
quality; but the original idea of free trade has more of a passive connotation: knock down
the walls around your economy. Today globalization has taken free trade to the next
level: how can you integrate your economy into the global market? This global market is
built on the principles of economic liberalism and in order to successfully integrate the
state economy into the global one, governments must adopt policies promoting economic
freedom. Recall Thomas Friedman’s ‘Golden Straitjacket’ of economic reforms; he says
“[a]s your country puts on the Golden Straitjacket, two things tend to happen: your
economy grows and your politics shrinks. That is, on the economic front the Golden
Straitjacket usually fosters more growth and higher average incomes – through more
trade, foreign investment, privatization and more efficient use of resources under the
pressure of global competition.”1 There are several studies that agree with this claim.
One of the more thorough ones was conducted by two economics professors from the
University of Illinois that sought to not only validate the effectiveness of economic
freedoms in the aggregate, but also identify which particular freedoms had the most
impact on economic growth.
1
Friedman, Thomas. p. 103
Dubuque 24
Professors Ayal and Karras examined a sample size of 58 countries with data
from the years 1975 to 1990. Using the Fraser Institute’s index of economic freedom and
each country’s GDP adjusted for population (per capita), they found a positive correlation
between the level of economic freedom and extent of economic growth. “The results
reported above are very supportive of the proposition that aggregate ‘economic freedom’
enhances growth both via increasing total factor productivity and via enhancing capital
accumulation.”1 They also identified thirteen ‘components’ of economic freedom to
individually test for impact on economic growth. Of the thirteen, Ayal and Karras found
eight that are statistically significant in increasing wealth. The eight components were
grouped into three broad categories: providing a “stable monetary environment, small
government participation, and freedom for citizens to transact with foreigners.”2 While
finding that ‘economic freedom’ broadly defined tended to increase economic growth,
policies that fit into these three categories were the most effective. Indeed most surveys
on the subject find economic freedom in a broad sense to positively influence economic
growth, while at the same time individual components of ‘economic freedom’ have
varying levels of effectiveness.
6. Methodology
After examining other research on the subject of the relationship between political
freedom, economic freedom and economic prosperity, it’s time to set up this particular
study and identify the data that will be used. In order to analyze the subject, reliable
indices of political and economic freedom are needed as well as a method for determining
1
2
Ayal and Karras. “Components of Economic Freedom and Growth.” p. 336
Ayal and Karras. p. 336-7
Dubuque 25
prosperity in a cross-country analysis. When it comes to political freedom, there is one
index that is frequently referenced in the media, utilized in academic studies and helps
the U.S. State Department analyze other nations. “While definitions of freedom can be as
slippery as mercury, the Freedom in the World study gained greater credibility in part
because it uses criteria that most Westerners agree are appropriate indicators.”1 This
praise is awarded to Freedom House’s political freedom index, arguably the most
comprehensive and well respected index available.
The index compiled by Freedom House breaks political freedom into two
components: political rights and civil liberties. Their measurement of political rights
examines “to what extent the system offers voters the opportunity to choose freely from
among candidates and to what extent the candidates are chosen independently of the
state.”2 While the formal system of election laws is important to the survey, also
important are real world influences which might negate legislated political rights. If the
military has a political role in elections, or the royal family maintains considerable
influence, then the survey takes those factors into account. Then, once elected the
government is rated on its level of “accountability, openness and transparency between
elections.”3
In its attempt to quantify the amorphous concept of freedom, the results of the
survey are based on a checklist of questions that is applied uniformly to all countries and
answered by regional observers/experts. These questions fall under the categories of
“Electoral Process,” “Political Pluralism and Participation,” and “Functioning of
Government.” A few examples of questions include ones asking if “there fair electoral
Lehrer, Eli. “Scorecards That Rank Freedom”
www.freedomhouse.org
3
www.freedomhouse.org
1
2
Dubuque 26
laws, equal campaigning opportunities, fair polling, and honest tabulation of ballots?”
Another one asks if “there a significant opposition vote, de facto opposition power, and a
realistic possibility for the opposition to increase its support or gain power through
elections?” Questions also ask to what extent minorities are allowed to participate in
government and the extent to which corruption exists. The complete checklist is
available on the organization’s website.
The second component of the survey examines to what extent civil liberties are
present in each country. This measurement takes into account what the country has for
laws on the books, but gives more weight to actual conditions on the ground as a more
accurate indication of civil liberties. Like political rights, Freedom House carefully
defines civil liberties through their checklist of questions to consider. These fall under
the categories of “Freedom of Expression and Belief,” “Associational and Organizational
Rights,” “Rule of Law,” and “Personal Autonomy and Individual Rights.” Under the first
heading the questions ask if there is a free and independent media; to what extent
religious institutions and expressions are free from the state; and if the education system
practices academic freedom or state indoctrination. Under the second heading, the survey
asks if there is the freedom to assemble and demonstrate; if trade unions exist; and if
other private and public organizations are allowed. Under the third heading fall the
questions relating to the independence of the judiciary, if the police are under civilian
control, and if citizens are treated equally under the law. The last category determines to
what extent individuals are free to choose their own residences, jobs, and travel plans.
Additionally the survey evaluates to what extent individuals and genders are treated
equally.
Dubuque 27
In order to quantify their findings, the organization awards points in both
categories based on positive responses to the questions and the highest total raw scores
are given the lowest ratings. A rating of 1 to 2.5 gives the country a designation of
politically free; 3 to 5 are partially free and 5.5 to 7 are designated not free. This study
will use the combined numerical ratings in its analysis.
While Freedom House’s survey of political freedom is widely accepted for its
broad criteria, most indices of economic freedom are criticized for their ideological slant.
This is does not imply that economic freedom indices are any lest rigorous in their
methodology, rather the definition of this type of freedom is hotly debated. One critic,
Wheaton economics professor John Miller, assails the index used in this study saying that
“in the hands of the Wall Street Journal and the Heritage Foundation, Washington’s
foremost right-wing think tank, . . . an economic freedom index merely measures
corporate and entrepreneurial freedom from accountability. . . The index does not even
pretend that its definition of economic freedom has anything to do with political
freedom.”1 He refers to obvious discrepancies between the Freedom in the World Survey
and the economic freedom index published by the Heritage Foundation. He accurately
observes that countries the Heritage Foundation designates as ‘economically free’ are far
from ‘politically free.’ The coordinator, Bryan Johnson, of the Heritage index agrees
with the critics that this survey is ideologically based. When interviewed, he explained,
“We’re trying to measure the extent to which countries show respect for classical liberal
economic principles. . . It’s not a noncontroversial way of measuring, but we think these
measures are the right ones.”2 It seems that most of the controversy around this index is
1
2
Miller, John. “Free, Free at Last.”
Lehrer, Eli. “Scorecards That Rank Freedom.”
Dubuque 28
whether or not it measures the right criteria for a successful economy; by comparing the
index to the economic performance of each country this study will hopefully evaluate
whether classic liberal economic freedom does indeed positively influence prosperity.
As far as methodology goes, this economic freedom index “[works] with the same
basic methodology as Freedom House, the Heritage Foundation also assigns its
researchers to pore through economic accounts on the world’s nations.”1 In their effort to
identify to what extent countries adhere to the classic liberal economic philosophy the
index identifies fifty independent economic variables that can be grouped into ten
principles categories, weighted equally. These ten categories are: trade policy, fiscal
burden of government, government intervention in the economy, monetary policy, capital
flows and foreign investment, banking and finance, wages and prices, property rights,
regulation, and informal market activity.2 Similar to Freedom House, every county is
rated in each category on a scale from one to five; the lower a score, the closer that
country’s economic environment and set of policies adhere to the index’s definition of
economic freedom. After the country has been rated in all ten areas, its score in each are
combined and averaged to produce a final rating. Scores under 1.99 are free, while those
above a 4.00 are designated repressed; those in between are either mostly free or mostly
unfree. A succinct overview of the criteria used to rate countries in each category
follows. A complete description of the index’s methodology can be found in chapter five
of the Heritage Foundation’s 2006 Index of Economic Freedom report.
In determining a score for ‘trade policy,” the index uses the country’s weighted
average tariff. The higher the tariff the worse the country scores in economic freedom.
1
2
Lehrer.
Beach, William W. and Mark A. Miles. “Explaining the Factors of the Index of Economic Freedom.” p. 2
Dubuque 29
Additionally, the index considers import quotas, licensing requirements and other nontariff barriers as well as corruption within customs services in assessing and determining
the trade policy score of the country. When examining the fiscal burden of the
government the index looks at the marginal tax rate for on income and corporations, and
the yearly change of government expenditure relative to GDP. The lower these rates are,
the better the score in this area. The third category examines government intervention in
the economy. The variables examined are: government consumption as a percentage of
the economy, government ownership of businesses, share of government revenue from
state owned enterprises, and finally economic output produced by the government. A
better score is awarded to those countries with less government intervention.
The fourth factor of monetary policy is rated based on average inflation: lower
inflation and a stable monetary environment yield better scores. Looking at capital flows
and investment in the next category analysts examine a wide variety of factors in an
attempt to determine the ease with which foreigners can do business in the country.
Variables here include restrictions on foreign ownership and investing and to what extent
foreign and domestic companies are treated equally. In the next category a private
banking system is considered essential for economic freedom. Under this heading the
index looks at to what extent the government regulates and restricts private banking and
to what extent government influences who receives credit. The next grouping considers
wages and prices. In this section the index measures to what extent governments control
prices either directly or through subsidies and to what extent the state regulates wages
using minimum wage laws.
Dubuque 30
One of the most important categories is the eighth one: property rights. Not only
are laws protecting private property and defining legally valid contracts important, but so
too is an independent judiciary capable of arbitrating disputes. Any government
expropriation of private property or corruption of the judiciary reduces the country’s
score in this area as well. The second to last category is relatively broad and
controversial in its examination of government regulation. Any licensing requirements to
operate a business, labor regulations, environmental, consumer safety and worker health
regulations detract from a country’s economic freedom score. Corruption in the state’s
regulatory bureaucracy counts against it as well, while ease of obtaining a business
license improves the score. Basically, the index considers any regulation to negatively
impact economic freedom. The final category looks at the impact of ‘informal markets’
on the country’s economy. These black markets could potentially positively impact
economic freedom by offering an avenue for entrepreneurship that otherwise would not
exist in a very repressed economy. However it also has the potential to devastate the
economy due to corruption and piracy of intellectual property rights. To measure and
rate the existence of informal markets the index relies on Transparency International’s
Corruption Perceptions Index. In general higher levels of black market activity lower the
overall economic freedom in the country and the survey adjusts its score accordingly.
Even in this brief overview of the index’s criteria, it’s easy to see how its position
on various economic policies can be considered controversial. The previous theoretical
discussion of economic freedom ought to help explain the rationale for selecting these
variables for an economic freedom index. To what extent a positive correlation exists
Dubuque 31
between a country’s economic freedom score and its economic prosperity remains to be
seen in the analysis of the collected data.
Of course before that analysis can occur, the data used for the dependent variable
must be identified. The decision to examine the relationship between political freedom,
economic freedom and economic prosperity to some extent sidesteps a larger issue.
Increasing wealth is widely considered to be an important part of development; in the
poorest nations increased economic prosperity means being able to afford to eat and drink
clean water and provide some degree of shelter. For middle-tier countries, increased
economic prosperity means being able to afford luxuries beyond basic survival
necessities. However in the richest countries, increasing wealth may be considered of
secondary importance when compared with other quality of life factors like leisure time
or protection of the environment. While ‘economic prosperity’ implies an improved
quality of life, wealth is not desirable for intrinsic reasons, but in its ability to provide a
desirable life. In his study of Development and Democracy in the Third World, Abbas
Pourgerami notes that the United Nations “combines nine social and seven economic
indicators to compute an index of development” and that “[s]everal studies seek to
construct composite indicators of development that can measure not only outcomes of the
development process, but also improvements in the quality of human life over time.”1
Various indicators like the United Nations index on social development and the Physical
Quality of Life Index measure a more comprehensive idea of development. According to
Pourgerami, “Test results indicate that correlations between the conventional and
alternative development and growth indicators are not sufficiently high in order for them
1
Pourgerami, Abbas. Development and Democracy in the Third World. pp. 12-13
Dubuque 32
to be interchangeable.”1 This means that wealth is not interchangeable with quality of
life indices. However, these alternative indices measure a subjective quality of life as
opposed to an objective level of wealth. This problem was considered earlier in the
discussion of freedom and individualism: everyone has a different scale of value,
therefore it is impossible to determine a universal set of preferences.
While the possession of wealth does not guarantee a certain quality of life,
increased wealth does offer an increased means for attaining what is desirable. Because
of that, this study will imply that increased wealth is desirable. Of course it is important
to remember that the purpose of this study is to evaluate the relationship between political
freedom, economic freedom and wealth; any implications that arise from this research are
secondary to that purpose.
In selecting a measure of wealth with which to compare countries, it’s important
to identify a measure that is widely available and easily standardized for cross-country
analysis. The obvious choice and the one most commonly used in this type of study is
the measurement of gross domestic product. Its textbook definition reads: “The total
income earned domestically, including the income earned by foreign-owned factors of
production; the total expenditure on domestically produced goods and services.”2 In
effect, GDP is the measurement of all economic activity over a given time period. While
this figure is widely available for most countries, GDP alone does not allow for a good
cross-country analysis. Because larger countries can produce a greater amount of wealth
than smaller countries, it is important to factor in population size in order to standardize
the comparison. GDP per capita does that by dividing a country’s total gross domestic
1
2
Pourgerami. p. 20
Mankiw, N. Gregory. Macroeconomics 6th ed. p.558
Dubuque 33
product by its population size, yielding an average amount of wealth per person. In order
to compare the relative wealth of say one American to one Indonesian, the monetary
figure must be expressed in the same currency. Purchasing-power parity (PPP) is the
preferred method for standardizing currencies, which is based on normalizing a basket of
goods so that they cost the same amount in each country. For an analysis over time all
data must be expressed in time-specific currency as well. This survey draws its data from
the World Bank’s World Development Index (2006 edition), in the form of GDP per
capita (PPP) in current international dollars.
Using Freedom House’s political freedom index, the Wall Street Journal and
Heritage Foundation’s economic freedom index, and the World Bank’s GDP per capita
data, this empirical study will use correlation analysis in an effort to determine if and to
what extent a relationship exists between the variables. The statistical method of
bivariate correlation is a tool used to measure the linear relationship between two
variables, with the strength of the relationship determined by the Pearson correlation
coefficient (r). A value close to zero implies that there is no linear relationship between
the variables, while a value closer to positive or negative one indicates a stronger
relationship. Positive values indicate a positive relationship while negative values
indicate a negative relationship. Because both the economic and political freedom
indices define 1 as the most free and increasing scores as less free, the expected
coefficient is negative. That is, as freedom scores decrease, economic prosperity is
hypothesized to increase. Additionally, while data is not available for all countries, 152
are represented in this study over the time period of 1995 to 2005. All of the original
data tables from this analysis are available in the appendix.
Dubuque 34
7. Empirical Evidence / Results
The data set used in this analysis is comprised of 152 countries, all of which have
been measured by each index and have reliable data available for GDP per capita (PPP).
Several countries were not included in this survey because of unavailable data for GDP or
they were not ranked by one or both of the indices. Perhaps the most notable exclusions
are Afghanistan, Cuba, North Korea, and Iraq; the rest are small countries like Andorra,
Barbados, Comoros and Vanuatu. Despite these omissions, the vast majority of the
global population has been included in the survey. Some general characteristics of the
data set follow. The mean GDP per capita is $8,884.95 (roughly equivalent to Malaysia),
Sierra Leone has the lowest measured prosperity of $549.10, and Luxembourg has the
high of $53,730.98. The mean political freedom score is 3.45 (the score of Lesotho), 17
countries have the best score possible: 1, and three (Turkmenistan, Sudan, and Syria)
share the most repressed score of 7. For economic freedom, the mean score is
Colombia’s 3.12, with a best score of 1.42 (Hong Kong) and a worst score of 4.62 (Laos).
To begin with a macro analysis of the data, the following results illustrate the
comparison of average GDP per capita for each of the 152 countries with those countries’
averaged economic and political freedom scores. A significant degree of correlation was
found between each index and the measurement of wealth. When the average GDP per
capita over the eleven year period was compared with the average economic freedom
score, a Pearson correlation coefficient of -.788 was observed. This correlation is
significant at the 0.01 level, demonstrating an obvious relationship between the variables.
The positive relationship between economic freedom and average GDP per capita is
Dubuque 35
graphically illustrated in the following diagram. (Recall the best score in each freedom
index is 1).
60000.00
Average GDP per capita
50000.00
40000.00
30000.00
20000.00
10000.00
0.00
1.00
2.00
3.00
4.00
5.00
Average Economic Freedom
Similar results were observed in the analysis of average GDP per capita and
average political freedom. Although the Pearson coefficient was less robust at a -.607,
this still indicates a correlation significant at the 0.01 level and offers evidence of the
existence of a relationship between the variables. The following graph illustrates the
relatively weaker relationship between these two variables.
60000.00
Average GDP per capita
50000.00
40000.00
30000.00
20000.00
10000.00
0.00
1.00
2.00
3.00
4.00
5.00
6.00
7.00
Average Political Freedom
Unlike the previous graph, this one illustrates several outlier countries that have
extremely poor political freedom scores, yet have much greater wealth than countries
Dubuque 36
with similar scores. Looking at the residuals, these countries are: the United Arab
Emirates, Singapore, Bahrain, Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, and Oman. Interestingly, one
characteristic shared by all of these countries (except for Singapore) is that they all export
a significant amount of fuel. The World Bank development indicator’s database has a
data series of “fuel exports as a percentage of merchandise exports.” Using partial
correlation and controlling for fuel exports; the correlation between GDP per capita and
political freedom increases from -.607 to -.628, indicating a marginally stronger
correlation. The same happens when economic freedom is controlled for fuel exports: the
correlation increases from -.788 to -.795. Unfortunately, while marginally improving the
quality of the relationship, fuel exports do not substantially readjust either relationship.
Yet given the level of significance of the original analysis and the controlled test, it is
possible to state that both economic freedom and political freedom are directly related to
economic prosperity.
One characteristic that distinguishes the graph of political freedom from economic
freedom is that for countries earning above average political freedom scores, their scores
appear to be more closely correlated than countries in the bottom half. This observation
is validated by statistical analysis. Whereas the correlation between political freedom
and economic prosperity for all countries was determined to have a Pearson coefficient of
-.607, countries with an above average freedom score have a coefficient of -.754, (still
significant at the 0.01 level); countries with a below average freedom score demonstrated
no correlation with a insignificant coefficient of 0.055. Given that the mean political
freedom score of 3.45 is very close to the scale’s median of 3.50, the data indicates that in
general for countries that tend to be more repressive than free, the actual degree of
Dubuque 37
political freedom does not impact the wealth of the country. On the other hand, for those
countries that are described as more free than not, there is significant correlation between
their actual level of political freedom and economic prosperity. This suggests that when
a repressive regime controls a country, the level of economic prosperity is determined by
the unique characteristics of its policies and cannot be determined based on what small
amounts of political freedom exist. On the other hand, once the population is more or
less free, increasing political freedom positively impacts prosperity.
Breaking the data down in a different way, the strength of the correlation seen in
the complete sample is not found when levels of wealth are grouped into thirds. Those
countries in the bottom third of economic prosperity showed only a -.140 coefficient
when average GDP per capita was compared with average economic freedom and a .073
coefficient when wealth was compared to political freedom. Both figures are not only
close to zero but also are statistically insignificant; indicating that there is no measurable
existence of a relationship among the variables. On the other hand, the middle tier
countries had some evidence of correlation, -.292 for economic freedom and -.331 for
political freedom. These two coefficients indicate that correlation is significant at the
0.05 level. However, it was the wealthiest third that saw the most correlation: -.651 for
economic freedom and -.340 for political freedom. The relationship between economic
freedom and wealth was significant at the 0.01 level while political freedom
demonstrated significance at the 0.05 level. Although this does not dismiss the findings
of the entire sample, it does indicate that the relationship between economic and political
freedom and wealth is most evident in the top tier of wealth while the bottom third
exhibited no significant correlation.
Dubuque 38
If relative freedom in impoverished countries is not correlated to relative wealth,
then it appears that there is some wealth threshold that must be crossed before freedom
will positively impact prosperity. Also, given that progressively more correlation was
observed as wealth increased, this could imply that a linear relationship may not be the
best fit for all countries. To test whether a power relationship is more appropriate, the
square root of the average GDP per capita was taken and analyzed in comparison with
economic and political freedom. The results indicate that there is a greater degree of
correlation in this relationship than the previously observed linear correlation. The
Pearson coefficient for measuring the relationship between economic freedom and
prosperity increased from -.788 to a -.821, while remaining significant at the 0.01 level.
Similarly for political freedom and wealth, the coefficient increased from -.607 to -.635
(significant at the 0.01 level). This indicates that a power relationship provides a better
explanation for the relationship between freedom and prosperity.
When conducting this type of statistical work, it is important to keep in mind that
political and economic freedom are not the only factors that potentially influence
economic prosperity. Of course selecting control variables to further isolate the
relationship between freedom and prosperity is certainly a subjective endeavor. After
carefully explaining the reasoning behind exploring the relationship between political and
economic freedom and prosperity, selecting other variables that would influence
prosperity without adequate explanation appears arbitrary, yet is nonetheless important to
determining the significance of the relationship between the original variables. The
following selected control variables would intuitively be correlated to economic
prosperity, without being correlated to freedom. According to the Solow Growth Model
Dubuque 39
in economic theory, increased national saving should enhance prosperity. Thus the first
control variable is gross domestic savings (as a % of GDP), taken again from the World
Bank database. Education is another often cited factor important in producing wealth, so
the measurement of literacy rates has been included as a rough proxy variable. To
measure the health of the population (and by extension the health of a country’s workers),
life expectancy has been included as another control variable. The second and third
variables have been taken from United Nations statistics. For reasons of availability of
data, the controlling year is 2004.
Using partial correlation testing, when the power relationship between economic
freedom and per capita GDP is controlled for gross domestic savings, literacy and life
expectancy, significant correlation is still observed (significant at the 0.01 level). The
correlation coefficient is a -.624. When the same relationship between political freedom
and per capita GDP is controlled with the same variables, a lesser degree of correlation is
observed, only -.384, while still significant at the 0.01 level. Given that both correlation
coefficients are smaller than before, it is reasonable to assume that the previous analyses
included external factors that affected economic prosperity besides freedom.
As a final comment on the data, average political freedom and economic freedom
for the decade are highly correlated; they have a correlation coefficient of .716, which is
significant at the 0.01 level. Because of the strength of this relationship, controlling for
one type of freedom would prove impractical. Instead, it should be noted that the data
offers clear evidence that freedom in general is positively correlated with economic
prosperity, but among the two types of freedom analyzed, economic freedom more
strongly influences wealth than political freedom.
Dubuque 40
8. Conclusions
After significant theoretical discussion and empirical analysis, it’s time to take
stock of where we stand in answering the question of whether a relationship exists
between freedom and prosperity and to what extent that relationship is observed. From
defining a theoretical construct of freedom in both its political and economic varieties to
observing previous empirical studies of freedom’s relationship to wealth, it appears
evident that such a correlation exists. Additionally, analysis of the data from 152
countries during the period of 1995 to 2005 offers statistically significant evidence that
such a relationship exists. It is probably best to define the correlation as a power
relationship where both economic and political freedoms positively affect the wealth of a
country. This means that as freedom increases, economic prosperity increases at an
increasing rate. Interestingly, while both varieties of freedom are closely correlated, the
degree of economic freedom has a greater affect on wealth than the degree of political
freedom.
Based on previous theoretical discussions, this makes sense. Politically repressive
regimes are capable of implementing sound economic policies, just like liberal
democracies. In fact, such regimes might be able to follow such a path easier than
representative governments because they are capable of unilaterally removing privileges
for special interest groups that also ‘protect’ the economy from increasing its potential
wealth. Almost inevitably though, the data indicates that politically and economically
repressive regimes dwell in the third tier of global wealth. In this group the average GDP
per capita is only $1,376, with an average economic freedom score of 3.69 out of 5 and
political freedom score of 4.66 out of 7. At the other end, the top tier countries enjoy an
Dubuque 41
average GDP per capita of $20,103, with a better average economic freedom score of
2.39 out of 5, and a much better average political freedom score of 1.96 out of 7. It
seems then that a politically repressive regime with a high level of economic wealth is
more of an exception than a rule.
As Americans debate global inequality, the data indicates that we should stop
blaming ‘capitalist’ tendencies as the main factor in keeping poor nations poor, and
instead start talking about how these countries’ repressive political and economic systems
prevent the poorest nations from expanding their wealth potential. If anything, perhaps
our pursuit of freer trade, greater protection of private property, and advocacy of
representative democracy and political rights has helped economically disadvantaged
countries overcome some of their structural constraints that have inhibited from
maximizing their production potential. Based on the data, America’s revolutionary
approach to encouraging greater political and economic freedom ought to help increase
global prosperity, not detract from it.
Dubuque 42
Appendix
Table 1 - Descriptive Statistics
N
Minimum
Maximum
Mean
Std. Deviation
Average Economic
Freedom
152
1.42
4.62
3.1198
.69919
Average Political
Freedom
151
1.00
7.00
3.4497
1.82962
Average GDP per capita
152
549.10
53730.98
8884.9532
9673.50328
Valid N (listwise)
151
Table 2 - Correlations between avg. economic freedom and per capita wealth
Average Economic
Freedom
Average GDP per capita
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Economic
Freedom
1
Average GDP
per capita
-.788**
.000
152
152
-.788**
1
.000
152
152
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 3 - Correlations between avg. political freedom and per capita wealth
Average Political
Freedom
Average GDP per capita
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Political
Freedom
1
Average GDP
per capita
-.607**
.000
151
151
-.607**
1
.000
151
152
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Dubuque 43
Table 4 - Partial Correlations beteen avg. PF and GDP controlled for fuel exports
Control Variables
Fuel exports (% of
merchandis e exports )
Average GDP per capita
Average Political
Freedom
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Average GDP
per capita
1.000
.
0
-.628
.000
144
Average
Political
Freedom
-.628
.000
144
1.000
.
0
Table 5 - Partial Correlations beteen avg. EF and GDP controlled for fuel exports
Control Variables
Fuel exports (% of
merchandise exports )
Average GDP per capita
Average Economic
Freedom
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Table 6 - Correlations for above avg. political freedom
Average Political
Freedom
avgGDP
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Political
Freedom
1
avgGDP
-.754**
.000
79
79
-.754**
1
.000
79
80
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Average GDP
per capita
1.000
.
0
-.795
.000
145
Average
Economic
Freedom
-.795
.000
145
1.000
.
0
Dubuque 44
Table 7 - Correlations for below avg. political freedom
Average Political
Freedom
avgGDP
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Political
Freedom
1
72
.055
.645
72
avgGDP
.055
.645
72
1
72
Table 8 - Correlations in bottom third GDP, between EF and wealth
Average GDP per capita
Average Economic
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average GDP
per capita
1
50
-.140
.332
50
Average
Economic
Freedom
-.140
.332
50
1
50
Table 9 - Correlations in bottom third GDP, between PF and wealth
Average GDP per capita
Average Political
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average GDP
per capita
1
50
.073
.614
50
Average
Political
Freedom
.073
.614
50
1
50
Dubuque 45
Table 10 - Correlations in middle third of GDP, between EF and wealth
Average GDP per capita
Average Economic
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average GDP
per capita
1
51
-.292*
.038
51
Average
Economic
Freedom
-.292*
.038
51
1
51
*. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).
Table 11 - Correlations in middle third of GDP, between PF and wealth
Average GDP per capita
Average Political
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average GDP
per capita
1
51
-.331*
.018
51
Average
Political
Freedom
-.331*
.018
51
1
51
*. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).
Table 12 - Correlations in top third of GDP, between EF and wealth
Average GDP per capita
Average Economic
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Economic
Freedom
-.651**
.000
51
51
-.651**
1
.000
51
51
Average GDP
per capita
1
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Dubuque 46
Table 13 - Correlations in top third of GDP, between PF and wealth
Average GDP per capita
Average Political
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average GDP
per capita
1
51
-.340*
.016
50
Average
Political
Freedom
-.340*
.016
50
1
*. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).
Table 14 - Correlations between square root of GDP and EF
s qrgdp
Average Economic
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Economic
s qrgdp
Freedom
1
-.821**
.000
152
152
-.821**
1
.000
152
152
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 15 - Correlations betewen square root of GDP and PF
s qrgdp
Average Political
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Political
s qrgdp
Freedom
1
-.635**
.000
152
151
-.635**
1
.000
151
151
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
50
Dubuque 47
Table 16 - Measuring controlled correlation of power relationship between EF and GDP
Control Variables
Gross domestic
s avings (% of GDP)
& % literacy above
15 & life expectancy
Average Economic
Freedom
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
s qrgdp
Average
Economic
Freedom
1.000
.
0
-.624
.000
81
s qrgdp
-.624
.000
81
1.000
.
0
Table 17 - Measuring controlled correlation of power relationship between EF and GDP
Control Variables
Gross domestic
Average Political
s avings (% of GDP) Freedom
& % literacy above
15 & life expectancy
s qrgdp
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Correlation
Significance (2-tailed)
df
Average
Political
Freedom
1.000
.
0
-.404
.000
81
Table 18 - Correlations between PF and EF
Average Political
Freedom
Average Economic
Freedom
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Pears on Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed)
N
Average
Political
Freedom
1
Average
Economic
Freedom
.716**
.000
151
151
.716**
1
.000
151
152
**. Correlation is s ignificant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
s qrgdp
-.404
.000
81
1.000
.
0
Dubuque 48
Works Cited:
"2006 Index of Economic Freedom." Heritage Foundation. Jul 2006
<http://www.heritage.org/index/>.
Ayal, Eliezer, Georgios Karras.. "Components of Economic Freedom and Growth: an
Empirical Study." Journal of Developing Areas 32(1998): 327-339.
Beach, William W., Mark A. Miles. "Explaining the Factors of the Index of Economic
Freedom.." 2006 Index of Economic Freedom (2006). p. 2
Becker, Gary S. “Economic and Political Freedom: Does One Lead to the Other?” Blog
entry. 6 Mar 2005. 11 Nov 2005. < http://www.becker-posnerblog.com/archives/2005/03/economic_and_po.html>.
Bhagwati, Jagdish. In Defense of Globalization. New York: Oxford University Press,
2004.. p. 94
Diamond, Larry. "Economic Development and Democracy Reconsidered." American
Behavioral Scientist Vol. 35. (Mar-Jun 1992). p. 175
"Freedom in the World Survey." 2006. Freedom House. Jul 2006
<http://www.freedomhouse.org/template.cfm?page=15&year=2006>.
Friedman, Milton. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962.
Friedman, Thomas. The Lexus and the Olive Tree. 1st. New York: Farrar, Straus, Giroux,
1999.
Fukuyama, Francis. The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Free Press, 1992.
Hayek, F.A.. The Road to Serfdom. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1944.
Lipset, Seymour. Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and
Political Legitimacy. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1959.
Dubuque 49
Lehrer, Eli. "Scorecards that Rank Freedom." Insight on the News 22 Feb 1999.
Mankiw, Gregory N. . Macroeconomics. 6th. U.S.: Worth Publishers Inc., 2006. p.558.
Miller, John. "Free, Free at Last." Dollars & Sense Issue 258March/April 2005 Jun 2006
<http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2005/0305miller.html>.
Pourgerami, Abbas. Development and Democracy in the Third World. Boulder, CO:
Westview Press, Inc., 1991. pp. 12-13.
Roll, Richard and John Talbott. “Political Freedom, Economic Liberty and Prosperity.”
Journal of Democracy. 2003. National Endowment for Democracy. Nov 27,
2005. <http://muse.jhu.edu/journals/journal_of_democracy/v014/14.3roll.html>.
Scramm, Carl and Robert Litan. "Why Democracy is America's Second most Valuable
Export." Inc. 27. 9Sep 2005 23. July 2006
<http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=aph&AN=18090775&si
te=ehost-live>.
"Universal Declaration of Human Rights." Office of the High Commissioner for Human
Rights. United Nations Department of Public Information. July 2006
<http://www.unhchr.ch/udhr/lang/eng.htm>.
"United Nations Population Information Network." United Nations. Jul 2006
<http://www.un.org/popin/data.html>.
World Development Indicators Database. WDI and GDF Online. Jul 2006
<http://devdata.worldbank.org/dataonline/>.
Download