The Post-Keynesian Critique of the Mainstream Theory of the State and the PostKeynesian Approaches to Economic Policy Richard P.F. Holt Southern Oregon University Introduction One very important area where Post-Keynesian economics differs from neoclassical economics is in public policy. Neoclassical economists believe in the efficacy of markets in most situations. As a result, they tend to oppose government interference in market economies. On the other hand, from a Post-Keynesian perspective, it is not unusual for markets to fail. In such instances, government actions are necessary to improve economic performance and social welfare. This leads not only to different approaches to economic and social policies, but also to a different view of the state and its responsibilities in providing economic stability and overall well-being for its citizens. It is also important to emphasize that for Post-Keynesians the purpose of an economy is to serve the needs of people, not the other way around. Economic development and public policy should be based on improving the overall standard of living, and should reflect the values and goals of equity and social justice as well as efficiency. This chapter provides a critique of the mainstream theory of the state by looking at the Post-Keynesian responses to neoclassical economics and their approaches to public policy starting with the Great Depression. In mainstream economics the state plays a minimal role. In contrast, Post-Keynesians look at the state as playing an integral and vital role for the development and stability of markets and achieving sustainable 1 economic growth. Besides providing a critique of the mainstream view of the state, the chapter shows the development of Post-Keynesian approaches to public policy. The final section discusses some tensions that exist today between Post-Keynesians and their approaches to public policy. The Mainstream View of the State and Public Policy Building on the writings of Adam Smith, neoclassical economists believe that a laissezfaire economy of competitive markets will channel all self-seeking and profit-oriented behavior into a socially beneficial outcome that will support the “natural liberty” of individuals (Smith, 1937, p. 14). The consequence is that the state’s role should be quite limited. Government interventions, taxes, subsidies and regulations all misdirect capital and diminish the contributions of individuals. In addition, government action usually restricts markets, which reduces the rate of capital accumulation and the division of labor and the level of social production. Smith believed that the state should be given only three duties: First, the duty of protecting the society from violence and invasion of other independent societies; secondly, the duty of protecting, as far as possible, every member of the society from the injustice or oppression of every other member of it, or the duty of establishing an exact administration of justice; and, thirdly, the duty of erecting and maintaining certain public works and certain institutions, which it can never be for the interest of any individual, or small number of individuals, to erect and maintain; because the profit would never be repay or expense to any individual or small number of individuals, though it may frequently do much more than repay it to a great society ( Smith, 1937, p. 651). This has been interpreted today by mainstream economists as meaning that the state has four legitimate roles in the economy: 1) government needs to make sure that there is competition and that no firm is able to exert monopoly power in the market. This prevents firms from acquiring both economic and political power; 2) government 2 intervention is needed in cases of externalities and for producing public goods; 3) government intervention is necessary when consumers and firms do not have sufficient information to make informed decisions; 4) the government needs to protect by laws private property and contracts. The main policy conclusion of neoclassical analysis, both in macroeconomics and microeconomics, is that in the absence of imperfections market economies will move towards an equilibrium position that is stable and optimum. Equilibrium prices always clear the market for consumer goods and factors of production. This equilibrium cannot be improved upon by government intervention in the economy. Whenever some outside force like changes in consumer preferences affects the market it is assumed that the economy will move to a new equilibrium point. There is never a problem with the real world transition from an equilibrium point to another, except for the possibility of some transaction costs, which are usually minimal. Efficiency for mainstream economics comes through substitution effects working through the “invisible hand”. When market imperfections do exist, the neoclassical solution is to remove the imperfection. In cases like this the government can play a role of removing the imperfection. Neoclassical economics uses the criteria standard of Pareto optimality. This implies that government policies to redistribute income either directly or indirectly by raising taxes on some people to provide goods and services to others should be very limited. Under the assumptions of utilitarianism we can never know that any redistribution will improve total utility, yet we do know that some people are made worse off because their taxes have gone up. In the neoclassical framework, these higher taxes will have undesirable substitution effects – since taxes reduce the rewards for working 3 and producing (Whereas for Post Keynesians the income effects of taxes would actually encourage work and savings). Another example from the neoclassical paradigm is deficit expenditures, which are assumed in the neoclassical model to create a “crowding out” effect. Higher government expenditures will be offset by less private expenditures and vice versa. The conclusion of mainstream economics is that free markets with minimal government intervention provide maximum benefits to all, which creates the greatest possible good for its people and the economy. We are now able to draw a number of key characteristics that define the neoclassical approaches to public policy and their theory of the state: Individuals make choices and decisions independent of others and are primarily concerned with their own self-interest and are generally in a better position to judge what is in their interest than their government. Individuals act rationally and can calculate the probable outcomes of every decision needed to maximize the expected utility of all possible outcomes. Even if this might not be true in all cases, it averages out over time to be true. Markets are generally competitive, which increase the overall social welfare measured by economic growth. Government intervention, except for some exceptional cases, limits the social benefits of competitive markets. Equilibrium analysis leads to optimum market outcomes and allows factors of production, such as wages and profits, to equal their marginal productivity. State involvement can reduce individual liberty. Laissez-faire policy prescriptions generally provide the best approach for maximizing both personal freedom and prosperity. A Post-Keynesian Critique of Mainstream Theory of the State and Public Policy In contrast to the neoclassical view, Post-Keynesians see the state role as integral and vital for economic growth and increasing the overall standard of living. They reject the view that capitalism operating solely under market forces is a self-adjusting economy that 4 inevitably leads to full-employment and low rates of inflation. Due to the precarious nature of advanced capitalism, the state has a responsibility for the overall performance of the macro economy and to develop policies that will mitigate economic problems and lead to social justice. The Post-Keynesian critique of the mainstream theory of the state starts with questioning the basic beliefs of neoclassical economics and replacing them with what they see as more realistic assumptions of how people and a capitalist economy actually functions in the real world. Here are six major tenets in which Post-Keynesians differ from neoclassical economics: A recognition that the future is uncertain, rather than being known or known with some probability distribution. This makes acting “rational” as defined by neoclassical economics not possible in many cases. Individual decision-making is dependent on social factors, such as human relations, conventions and habits, rather than on individual rational choice. Economic analysis should focus on economies moving through historical time rather than economies that effortlessly reach some equilibrium point. Most markets are imperfectly competitive in the real world, and their results deviate substantially from the competitive world. Economic public policy should focus on growth rather than the efficient allocation of resources as the most important economic issue, and recognize that income effects are more important than substitution effects in many instances. A theory of the state should be concerned with distribution issues both at a macro and micro level for achieving economic stability and social justice. Market forces by themselves will not achieve these goals. Several key policy conclusions follow from the Post-Keynesian world-view. For Post-Keynesians, the state may need to take a larger role to provide what the private sector cannot or will not provide (Pressman 2006). At the aggregate or macroeconomic level, the state needs to assure full employment and stable prices. But state action is also 5 needed at a microeconomic level. This is especially true for merit goods like social security, health care, and education. Besides helping to bring social justice, these goods also stabilize and grow the economy. To see the development of Post-Keynesians approaches to public policy and their critique of the mainstream theory of the state we need to turn to John Maynard Keynes for our starting point. In The General Theory (1964) he challenged the foundations of neoclassical economics by explaining how and why Great Depressions are possible within an advanced capitalist system that is driven by finance. Changes in Keynes’s Approach to Public Policy and the State It can be argued that up to the 1930s Keynes followed a more traditional path toward public policy, but with The General Theory he exhibited a new “vision” of economic theory that would have significant public policy ramifications, besides changing the direction of economic theory (Davidson, 1994, p. 4). Robert Skidelsky suggests that the Great Depression of 1929-32 had a dramatic impact on Keynes and his way of looking at the world. He states: “Keynes abandoned for good the belief that markets were automatically self-correcting. In a notable shift in moral perspective, he started to place less emphasis on efficiency, more on duty” (Skidelsky, 2009, p. 65). In the 1930s Keynes was entering a period where inaction was unacceptable to deal with the world-wide economic crisis. He believed that economists needed to be more engaged with public policy. Keynes in his earlier writingsi started to question the stability and predictability of market outcomes, but it is during the Great Depression that we see him coupling his doubts about free markets with new economic polices. Peter Clarke points this out in his biography on Keynes (2009, p. 103): 6 “…he had no doctrinaire reason to advocate state intervention; his whole education as an economist taught him that it was generally best to leave things to be sorted out by the free play of market forces. But what if the market seemed to be failing to perform as the textbooks prescribed? What was the best option under such conditions? The orthodox answer was to show patience. Keynes’s answer was to opt for second-best expedients”. Responding to his critics on the type of public policy needed to deal with the economic crisis, Keynes bluntly stated: “We do not know what will be the outcome. We are – all of us, I expect – about to make many mistakes.” (1963, XXI, p. 239). He recognized that with uncertainty and the magnitude of the different economic problems the world was facing in the 1930s that new and bold policies were needed and that some would work and others would fail. But he had no doubt that action was required to deal with the human misery that was apparent and new policies were needed to create stability in an economic system that was on the verge of collapse. He came to recognize the importance of state intervention. We can get a glimpse of how Keynes looked at the role of government and state intervention during the Great Depression from his comments praising Roosevelt’s method of working “within the framework of the existing system” (Shesol, 2010, pp. 2021). Roosevelt was not interested (nor was Keynes) in destroying capitalism and looked to government policies as a way to “restore, secure, stabilize, and save” the market system. According to Frances Perkins, his Secretary of Labor : “Roosevelt took the status quo in our economic system…[But] he felt that it ought to be humane, fair, and honest, and that adjustments ought to be made so that the people would not suffer from poverty and neglect, and so that all would share” (Shesol, 2010, pp. 20-21). This in many ways sums up Keynes’s economic philosophy on state and public policy goals during the Great Depression. 7 Keynes’s Policy Recommendations Keynes saw the achievement of full employment and dealing with the distribution of market power to provide economic growth, stability and increase the overall standard of living as the primary job of economic policy. As he stated in The General Theory, “The outstanding faults of the economic society in which we live are its failure to provide for full employment and its arbitrary and inequitable distribution of wealth and incomes” (Keynes, 1964, p. 372). Keynes came to realize that it is aggregate demand that drives the overall economy, and that there would continue to be problems of involuntary unemployment unless there were increases in real expenditures to guarantee full employment. In The General Theory Keynes shifts from the Marshallian use of market supply and demand as “his basic tools” of analysis to aggregate functions in a world of uncertainty for understanding the economy and the type of policy recommendations needed for economic stability (Harcourt, 2007, p. 60). This pivotal shift is crucial to understanding a Post-Keynesian approach to micro as well as macro policy and the relationship between the two. Keynes recognized that total demand is affected by income distribution, uncertainty, the psychological habits of investors and consumers (“animal spirits”) and government policies. Keynes was able to see the “big” picture and how aggregate demand determines levels of employment and inflation, but also how supply factors affect demand. He understood the impact of total demand on the distribution of income and government budgets and national trade deficits. The importance of aggregate demand drove his policy views in the 1930s – both domestically and later with international economics. 8 In sum, Keynes came to believe that the foundation of economic policy should be based on generating full employment and stabilize the economy. He questioned classical and neoclassical theory and the belief that endogenous market forces would create full employment with stable and fair outcomes, even in the long run. The constraint of the economy was on the demand side and not supply. State action was necessary. The Role of the State Besides recognizing that in a decentralized monetary economy the market itself would not guarantee levels of aggregate demand sufficient to achieve full employment, Keynes came to believe that the state must step in and provide what private markets cannot. At the aggregate or macroeconomic level, the state should assure full employment and stable prices. But it also needs to deal with coordination problems between aggregate demand and aggregate supply related to such factors as uncertainty and imperfect market structures (Chick, 1983; Davidson, 1994). This leads policy makers to be concerned not only with macro policies of providing a sufficient level of aggregate demand for full employment, but also with the social and equitable consequences of having factors of production unemployed. Keynes came to understand the significant impact that aggregate demand has on supply side factors (labor, resources, entrepreneurship and capital). With low levels of demand more people become unemployed and entrepreneurship lays fallow. For Keynes, inflation’s most corrosive impact comes from price uncertainty, although the adverse effects of anticipated inflation can be compensated by thoughtful and creative 9 institutional structures like income policies. Unemployment, on the other hand, causes an unambiguous loss to society. Output lost from under utilization of capacity is gone forever. Skills and talents may be lost. Long term unemployment can create social problems such as poverty, disease, homelessness, racial antagonism, crime and in extreme cases social unrest and revolution. Keynes argued that the state must carry out economic policies to deal with these economic problems. He looked primarily to macro policies of deficit spending to expand aggregate demand during times of recession to get people back to work. Any attempts to increase taxes or lower government expenditures would make any economic down turn worse by reducing aggregate demand. Keynes’s overall view of the state has been summarized by Pressman (2001, p. 109): Keynes saw the state as a set of institutions working for the public good. It provides public goods and benefits. In particular, the state must make sure that the requisite amount of spending takes place, leading to full employment and robust economic growth. The state must also control the national currency and back it. These are the key policy recommendations of the General Theory. The Classical Response The classical response to unemployment is that it is primarily caused by factors that do not allow markets to be competitive i.e. government intervention, unions, etc. The answer is not more state intervention but less to allow for competition and substitution effects. This position is still held in neoclassical policies today with “New Keynesians” and rational expectations on the assumption that most markets are competitive. Keynes questioned laissez-faire economics. He came to believe it is not the rigidities in markets that created involuntary unemployment. Instead it is the inherent nature and dynamics of laissez-faire markets within industrial economies that are prone to periods of instability and crisis. What was needed to achieve full employment and reasonable levels of 10 economic growth were government policies and an institutional framework that supported high levels of demand with coordinated efforts to deal with supply side efficiency and equity issues. By seriously questioning the assumptions of classical economics, Keynes was able to develop a much richer understanding of how markets work. Some have argued that the short fall in Keynes analysis was in not providing a new microeconomics foundation to his macro analysis. This left the door open for neoclassical economists to interpret his views on unemployment as being caused by wage inflexibility. It was Post-Keynesians such as Joan Robinson, Piero Sraffa and Michal Kalecki that started to address these issues and the relationship of microeconomics to macroeconomics by looking at monopolistic market structures and their effects on business cycles, prices and distribution. Their new approaches to microeconomic allowed Post-Keynesians to provide an alternative theoretical model to neoclassical welfare economics to deal with policy issues such as poverty, discrimination and consumer welfare. Another critique comes from Barro (1974) with rational expectations who argues that Post Keynesian policies will be ineffective. A tax cut and increase government spending might increase demand, but it will also increase the government’s deficit. Individuals will recognize this and save more for expected future increases in taxes to pay for the deficit spending. Besides not increasing aggregate demand the policy has a crowding out effect. The main problem with this argument is that it relies on the assumptions of having rational acting agents in a world of perfect market predictability, which is the foundation 11 of the mainstream theory of the state. Keynes in The General Theory questioned these assumptions, particularly the view that economic agents – consumers and firms – have near-perfect knowledge of economic situations and act “rational”. He came to believe that “people simply lacked the logical ability or rationality to see what was there (Bateman, 1996, p. 56). Besides questioning the rationality principle, Post-Keynesians also question the assumption of certainty. If there is no sound evidence or ability to be able to make rational choices because of uncertainty, then government policies become even more important for they can provide long-term government guarantees and commitments that can influence economic behavior and outcomes in a positive way. (Keynes, 1964 ; Pressman, 2006). Post-Keynesians see the potential of the state to work for the public good. If the state policies guarantee full employment with stable prices, then this is the expectation that will be developed. The state can do this by setting up institutional structures that support these policy goals. Two primary ways are through public investment spending and by converting uncertainty into risk through social programs like unemployment insurance. Macro and Micro Public Investments Keynes recognized the need of public investments as a way of achieving full employment and to guarantee the full utilization of resources for economic growth, particularly during times of recessions (1964, p. 378). Public investments should be designed not just for the increase of aggregate spending, but to increase spending in areas where the private sector is not doing enough for the public good. At the end of The General Theory, Keynes talked about the public investment of education, building hospitals, etc. To this we can 12 add spending to improve the environment, promote greater health, reduce poverty, create jobs with decent wages and working conditions, security in retirement, crime prevention and improve public safety. These policies have a number of different positive effects. They help stabilize the macro economy and reduce uncertainty as well as improving the overall well-being of individuals and increase their productivity while creating a better and more just society. Public Policy and Uncertainty To understand Post-Keynesian approaches to public policy and why state intervention is needed for economic growth and stability it is important to point out the distinction between uncertainty and risk in the real world. This distinction is absolutely essential for a comprehensive understanding of Post-Keynesians’ policy views. In the 1920s, along with Frank Knight (1971 [1921]), Keynes (1973 [1921]) was seriously concerned with the question of risk and uncertainty and the implications for economic decisions. Keynes accepted Knight’s argument of the distinction between risk and uncertainty where risk involves measurable probabilities whereas uncertainty involves unknowable probabilities. Knight pointed out that we could estimate and calculate risk and so insure against it. For example, an insurance company can calculate the risk of a middle age man passing away suddenly as compared to predicting the price of a barrel of oil or wine 20 years from now, which carries with it uncalculated or uncertain probabilities. For Keynes this distinction has major ramifications in the real world of personal and economic decisions. Keynes links the difference between risk and uncertainty to economics in Chapter 12 of The General Theory (1964 [1936]) where uncertainty means that investment cannot depend on some objective assessment of probable outcomes. Instead we are forced to rely on 13 “animal spirits” of the average state of confidence as the driving force behind business investments. Given the importance of investments – both private and public – to achieving full employment, economic growth and overall well-being, the government can turn uncertain outcomes into marketable risk investments that have some assessment value. This will increase the level and stability of investments leading to higher economic growth and employment. There are many ways that governments can and does accomplish this. For example, product liability laws place risk on manufacturers. Workers’ compensation laws shift the risk of workplace accidents from employees to employers. Deposit insurance safeguards individual depositors during a financial crisis. Federal disaster relief helps victims of natural catastrophes. Consumer product safety laws, banking standards, workplace safety regulations are among other policies that reduce risk for average citizens. Large firms have been helped in raising financial capital through limits on the liability of passive investors. If the firm collapses, creditors have no claim on assets of those who simply owned shares of stock in the firm. Keynes’s uncertainty is also related to the unidirectional nature of time (brought out in more detail by Joan Robinson (1974)) where we cannot go back and change our decisions (1937, p. 113). This means that past evidence is not a reliable guide when events happen infrequently or when we are dealing with situations far into the future. Past evidence is also no guide for situations with no prior history. In these cases, expectations are bound to be volatile and uncertain, unless public policy develops rules, conventions or routines to set guidelines for future economic and social decisions. Let’s us turn to the 14 environment as an example to show the Post-Keynesian approach to public policy under conditions of uncertainty. Environmental Policy Many long-term consequences of environmental damage cannot be known because the probability of environmental damage is not attainable without repeated action and the passage of time. We cannot perform controlled experiments with the earth and a parallel earth to see how pollution affects one but not the other, keeping everything else constant. We cannot do the second best thing and use a large sample of past experience to make probability judgments. We are currently experiencing the worldwide consequences of many kinds of pollution for the first time in history. The Post-Keynesian approach to policy recommendations and decisions is very different from the neoclassical. First, they hold onto a form of organicism or holism that recognizes the interdependency and connection between the environment, society and the economy as compared with the mechanical and methodological individualism of neoclassical economics (Dow, 2001). Second, Post Keynesians do not rely on neoclassical marginal analysis since they rely more on notions of path dependency and irreversibility, which plays an important part in understanding the dynamics of environmental and sustainable development (Holt, 2005). Because of the uncertainty of environmental outcomes the work of Post-Keynesians on institutions, knowledge, procedural rationality (Rosser, 2004), all of which look at complex dynamics and the lack of predictability about the future, compels policy-makers to concern themselves with non-market factors and to adopt a more cautionary approach when assessing the environment. By developing policies that deal with complexities in a global ecologic-economic system we can put into place a series of cautionary principles 15 like the Lisbon Principles (Constanza et at., 1999) that establish guidelines and institutional structure to deal with environmental uncertainties that could lead to catastrophic outcomes. As the above example shows, uncertainty has microeconomic policy implications as well as macroeconomic. Post-Keynesians do not see people as being isolated individuals. Rather, they see the interdependence of humans with their society and the environment. This approach has public policy consequences very different from the neoclassical view of looking at individuals as being independent of others, their society and environment. This also provides a very different role for the state as compared to the mainstream theory of the state. Post Keynesians take a pragmatic approach to the role of the state. While they believe in relying on markets where they can achieve a socially desired outcome, there are cases like with the environment where public protection and investments in natural capital are needed. An ideology that values small government above all else may mean foregoing these vital protections and investments. In addition, the recent work of Nobel Prize winners Williamson (2002) and Ostrom (1990) highlights the important role of social cooperation outside of formal governments and markets, as does the work of Bowles and Gintis (2002). This brings home that there are other ways of achieving efficiency and well-being outside of government intervention and the use of market forces. For Post Keynesians results are more important than ideology and take an “open systems approach” that shows an appreciation for pluralism in its methodological approach to public policy analysis (Greenwood and Holt, 2010; Dow 2001). 16 Social Rationality In addition, Post-Keynesians have questioned whether the notion of individual rationality yields optimal outcomes in the real world, or whether there is a social rationality makes everyone better off. The difference between social rationality and individual rationality is clearest in the prisoner’s dilemma, which shows how two individuals pursuing their own best interests wind up in a less than optimal situation. Prisoner’s dilemma situations are common in everyday life. They are the heart of the free rider problem. Like the prisoner who confesses, the free rider does not pay to support public goods that everyone regards as desirable, such as public schools and safe neighborhoods. The free rider assumes that others will contribute and the marginal effect of one less contribution will make no difference to how safe our communities are or how clean our environment will be. But the aggregate outcome of free riding may be a lack of public goods that everyone desires. To get to an outcome that provides a higher optimal outcome might mean moving from what makes individual rational sense to a social rationality where individuals give something up, but society sees an increase in its welfare. This opens the door to government policy—for example, taxes to support public goods. One result of replacing individual rationality with social rationality in Post Keynesian analysis is that macroeconomics has primacy over microeconomics. The behavior of the economic system as a whole is not reducible to the sum of individual parts. Post-Keynesians point out that there are fallacies of composition such as the famous paradox of thrift in The General Theory that undermine the implications of microfoundations in neoclassical economics. Another example is Kaleckian paradox of 17 costs. As Kalecki (1971, p. 26) pointed out, “one of the main features of the capitalist system is the fact that what is to the advantage of a single entrepreneur does not necessarily benefit all entrepreneurs as a class.” While one firm benefits from cutting the wages and benefits of its employees, gaining more in profits, when all firms do this, there is a negative effect on aggregate demand and all firms lose sales and income. What is true of the individual is not always true of the whole. Public Policy and Imperfect Markets Galbraith (1967) was most responsible for pointing out the benefits of imperfect competition, and for exploring the causes and consequences of the dominance of large firms in our economic system today. He argued that the large firm is a consequence of the natural evolution of advanced industrial economies (1967) by taking advantage of economies of scale. Size has advantages, according to Galbraith, “as a means of facilitating technological change by emancipating it from the uncertainties of the market” (Dunn & Pressman 2005. p. 171). Galbraith sees technological change as a main characteristic of the world and a main challenge facing all firms. Technology requires more capital and specialized manpower, and entails a need for planning. Moreover, as production becomes more complex due to technical change, one person can no longer be familiar with all aspects of production reinforcing the development and importance of social over individual rationality. Galbraith’s insights become important in a number of policy areas. For example, the neoclassical policy solution of eliminating government monopolies in providing 18 health care is less convincing when one sees the economic world as dominated by large oligopolies or megacorporations. The question becomes which system is more efficient—government monopoly or private oligopoly with the need of government regulation. Similar issues arise in the policy debate over privatizing social security and education. Post-Keynesian Public Policy Method Compared to the Mainstream In addition to differing on economic theory, Keynes and Post Keynesians share a very different methodological approach to public policy than neoclassical economics. The origin of Keynes’s approach can be found in his father’s writings. In The Scope and Method of Political Economy (1891, p. 83) John Neville Keynes argued that theory and policy have different methodologies. This is because economic science is a branch of logic that relies on theorems that are based on self-evident assumptions. But policy requires much more than just the use logic, it requires a knowledge of history, institutions, politics, and common sense. For Keynes it wasn’t that economic science was irrelevant to policy but that the focus of economic science is by its nature abstract and limited, so the driving interest behind those that do economic theory is different from what policy makers should be focusing on: the role of institutions, political economy, and history. Turning to Keynes (1938) himself: Economics is a science of thinking in terms of models joined to the art of choosing models, which are relevant to the contemporary world. It is compelled to be this, because unlike the typical natural science, the material to which it is applied is, in too many respects, not homogeneous through time. The object of a model is to segregate the semi-permanent or relatively constant factors from those which are transitory or fluctuating so as to develop a logical way of thinking about the latter, and of understanding the time sequences to which they give rise in particular cases. Good economists are scarce because the gift for using “vigilant observation” to choose good models, although it does not require a highly specialized intellectual, appears to be a very rare one. 19 This approach to public policy was similar to the tradition of classical economists like Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and Karl Marx. This method recognized the limitations of theory, the importance of empirical work and the need to have an intuitive and historical sense of the institutional dynamics of the economy at a particular time. Keynes did not disagree so much with classical economists method of public policy as with their theoretical assumptions of a long run equilibrium model with central tendencies. In other words, he made a distinction between pubic policy and economic theory and both should use different methods of analysis. This distinction is important for understanding PostKeynesians approaches to public policy (Colander, 2009). Keynes’s earlier words on public policy, also give us a sense of the limitations he saw in economic theory. First, one gets a sense of the complexity of economics, the importance of relying on more than one model, the “art to choosing” from a variety of models to understand the real world at any one time in history. Keynes seems to suggest the Babylonian mode of thought advocated by such Post Keynesians as Sheila Dow (2001) for economic pluralism. Second, what can be learned from abstract economic theory is limited. We need an awareness of the role of institutions, politics, intuition and normative values in order to come up with good and solid policy recommendations. Public policy for Keynes was an art and not a science that required professionals trained in more than economic theory. He believed state actions chosen by dedicated individuals with high professional standards could help to stabilize capitalism, support economic growth and increase overall well-being. This is in contrast to the view of public policy that logically derives from the neoclassical model and its’ assumptions that economies naturally tend to efficiency and 20 optimum outcomes. This neoclassical approach to public policy is derived primarily from the logic of its theoretical models. Any deviation by looking at historical or political factors for example can be considered as moving away from the “objective” analysis that economics can provide to policy recommendations. Keynes stated his concern with this approach in Chapter 1 of The General Theory: “… the characteristics … by the classical theory happen not to be those of the economic society in which we actually live, with the result that its teaching is misleading and disastrous if we attempt to apply it to the facts of experience” (Keynes, 1963 [1936], p.3). Unfortunately Keynes’s message began to disappear with the rise of neoclassical Keynesianism in the 1940s and 1950s when economists directly related theory to economic policy, blurring the methodological difference between them. The consequence is having economic policy that has not been able to address chronic unemployment, financial instability and world-wide recessions. Policy outcomes can be devastating when driven by incorrect theory. We saw this in the 1970s with stagflation and more recently with the global financial crisis of 2008. Neoclassical Keynesians and Public Policy The classical theory to which Keynes refers in his work provides the foundation for neoclassical thought today and its theory of the state. It is represented in the neoclassical synthesis and the new classical critique of Keynesian economics. Because neoclassical Keynesians never abandoned classical theory, they made it easy for a new generation of economists to go back to classical theory. As Gregory Mankiw stated: “ “General Theory is an obscure book…We are in a much better position than Keynes was to figure out how the economy works… Classical economics is right in the long run. Moreover, economists today are more interested in the long-run equilibrium” (Mankiw, 1992, pp. 560-561). 21 Starting in the late 1930s and into the 1950s economics started to move more in the direction of developing highly mathematical economic models and attempts to derive policy from those models -- much of this in the name of Keynes. Many people accept the version of Keynes produced by neoclassical Keynesian economists such as Paul Samuelson, Robert Solow, James Tobin and John Hicks. They were all wedded to general equilibrium analysis, the neutrality of money and the belief that the economy is governed by a natural long-run central tendency, in contrast to the writing of Keynes outlined above. They emphasized a commitment to “economic science” which meant analytic techniques based on cutting edge work in mathematics and statistics. Because of this emphasis, mathematics sometime drove model building, affecting conclusions about what appropriate policy is needed. For example, in macroeconomics the IS/LM model made it very convenient to determine macro policies from neoclassical theory. In microeconomics, the development of welfare economics, also was used to draw policy recommendations directly from theory without sufficient attention to history, institutions, and present conditions. The consequence was that macro policy began to look like a cookbook in the 1960s and 1970s: change a fiscal policy here and a monetary there and helped by the power of market forces the economy would automatically return to full employment with low inflation. Microeconomic public policy was not any better. It started with the assumption of perfect competition and that any government intervention could only be justified under the limited conditions of market failure. Any other type of policy action would interfere with private choice and lead to an inefficient outcome that was not Pareto optimal. When market imperfections did exist, such as externalities or natural 22 monopolies, polices that allow markets to work freely again or internalize the externality were all that was required. This assumed of course that conditions of perfect competition will actually deliver the outcomes that it promises, and that the assumptions made by neoclassical economics concerning the rationality of human behavior, the structure of markets and general equilibrium are correct. However, these big assumptions made by neoclassicals were questioned by Keynes and have been since by Post-Keynesians. If consumers and firms face a world of radical uncertainty, monopoly market structures where cumulative causation effects (in contrast to forces of equilibrium) determine economic outcomes, then public policy must go beyond fixing a “market failure” to achieve the goals of a “good society.” Government intervention is called for to improve opportunity, maintain floors of consumption and improve fairness (Sen, 1999). Post-Keynesian approaches to public policy and the role of the state incorporate a broader range of market failures than those dealing with efficiency, and thus have a larger role for government. The Evolution of Post-Keynesian Economics and Policy Keynes’s work laid the foundation, but it is important to recognize and appreciate the significant contributions of others to Post-Keynesian economics and public policy. It is fair to say that Keynes never completely threw off the vision of the working of economies in terms of an equilibrium framework. He did, of course, argue that government intervention was needed to help attain a satisfactory full employment equilibrium (internal balance) in each economy…One of the major changes in vision since Keynes’s death about how markets, economies, even whole systems work, associated with Keynes’s followers, especially Kaldor and Robinson, is the concept of cumulative causation. (Harcourt, 2007, p. 64). Nicholas Kaldor and Joan Robinson’s contributions to cumulative causation is just one example of expanding the alternative “vision” for economic theory and approaches to 23 public policy that build on Keynes’ insights. Other influential thinkers include Michal Kalecki, Richard Kahn, and Richard Goodwin. Their work explored the relationships between theory, empirical work and policy based in Keynes’s writings, but they went beyond his insights in many ways. There are also many contemporary Post-Keynesians like Paul Davidson, Hyman Minsky, Geoff Harcourt, and John K. Galbraith who had substantial impact. Among Post-Keynesians there seems to be a general consensus that the primary focus of Post-Keynesian economic policy should be on demand-side management to furnish long-term full employment and stability that allows for economic growth. There is the rejection of scarcity analysis of neoclassical economics and recognition of the importance and implications of income distribution and imperfect market competition on economic growth and social justice. But there are also major differences among Post-Keynesians as to what are the best approaches in various areas of public policy. Public Policy Tensions in Post Keynesian Economics Today As has been shown Post Keynesian approaches to public policy have evolved, but there are some tensions in their approaches, which is captured in a debate that has significant public policy implications. Should policy be based on equilibrium analysis or accumulation cyclical processes that lead to bouts of instability? For Paul Davidson (1994) we should do the former and for others like Hyman Minsky (1975) and Richard Goodwin (1947) we should do more of the latter. It is an important debate for public policy. Minsky (1974) argues that Davidson insists on integrating Keynes’s The General Theory with his earlier book A Treatise on Money. In Minsky’s view, the Treatise 24 adopted a Marshallian equilibrium, approach which is inconsistent with the cyclical nature of The General Theory. According to Minsky: “…[Davidson] still is wedded to the idea that the economic process can be characterized by sustainable equilibriums. His emphasis is upon growth and accumulation as steady rather than cyclical processes and the essential destabilizing impact of evolving financial and cost relations which take place during each temporary equilibrium is neglected” (1974, p. 11). Minsky goes on to say, “uncertainty is of central importance in decision-making because the economy is inherently cyclical” (p.13). More generally, Minsky along with other institutional Post-Keynesians maintain that theory must take account of custom, usages, rules of thumb, conventional beliefs and “transitory and temporary system state” as the economy cycles between boom and bust. These institutional economists argue that the use of equilibrium and marginal analysis ignore the importance of the evolution of institutions in understanding the dynamics of modern capitalism. Another area of controversy concerns the endogeneity of money. Some PostKeynesians have adopted the endogenous approach to money, but emphasize that money can be introduced to the economy through two distinct processes, the portfolio-change process and the income-generating finance process (Davidson, 1994). The first of these processes is more similar to the orthodox money approach: the central bank increases reserves, which changes interest rates and induces subsequent portfolio adjustments. Other Post-Keynesians like Basil Moore have adopted a different approach called “Horizontalist” approach alleging that central banks cannot determine the quantity of reserves, but can only determine the priced at which reserves will be supplied (Moore, 1988). Banks then set retail loan and deposit interest rates relative to the central bank’s 25 target rate and then accommodate the demand for loans and accept the supply of deposits at those administered rates. The money supply is said to be ‘horizontal’ at the loan rate of interest. Some have criticized Moore’s work for downplaying the importance of portfolio changes as well as the influence that this might have on loan interest rate and the willingness to lend (Davidson, 1994). Post-Keynesians also differ on policy approaches to inflation. Davidson has stated that the “existence of continuing inflation in any society involves some redistribution of real income from the weaker to the more powerful groups in an economy and/or its trading partners” (Davidson, 1991, pp. 89,91). The appropriate policies are Tax-based Incomes Policy (TIP) to fight domestic inflation and indexing of the International Monetary Clearing Unit (IMCU) to fight exported inflation. Other Post Keynesians attribute inflation to a variety of causes and would recommend a basket of policies to reduce inflationary pressures should they arise. For Minsky “prices in our accumulating economy are the carriers of profits and vehicles by which a surplus is forced” (1986, p. 254). In a big government, big firms, big labor economy “there are a variety of inflations,” with inflation “mainly determined by the way the economy is run (1986, pp. 265, 260). He attributed inflation primarily to the markup over wages rather than to wage pressure, arguing “the behavior of money wages once the inflation barrier is pierced is more a defensive reaction than a cause” (1986, p.261). Thus, an incomes policy would treat only the symptom but not the primary cause of inflation. Instead a policy that would increase the production of consumer goods would reduce pressures to increase the markup. Minsky believed that TIP was impractical and would interfere with the ability of private firms to set prices that would allow them to service the debt issued to financed 26 positions in assets. This overview of the debate among Post Keynesians cannot be resolved here, but it does show some of the challenges that Post Keynesians must deal with in the future in developing consistent public policy approaches. Conclusion This chapter has identified several key differences between the Post Keynesian and the neoclassical approach to policy issues and a theory of the state. Neoclassical analysis begins with the assumption that individuals are rational and confront a simple world of risk, instead of a messy and complex world of uncertainty. In addition, for neoclassical economists, history is not important; instead all economic analysis is couched in terms of equilibrium outcomes. In contrast Post-Keynesians see individuals living in a world uncertainty where history does matter. In this world the state can play an important role of reducing uncertainty and create an environment that improves economic decisionmaking and performance. Moreover individual rationality and free choice as assumed in the neoclassical paradigm do not always lead to optimal equilibrium outcomes for PostKeynesians. Post Keynesians also adhere to the principle of effective demand. In the macroeconomic world this means that unemployment is a function of the level of demand in the economy. This principle plays an important role in Post-Keynesians approaches to public policy. The essence of the Post Keynesian approach is a set of public investments to provide merit goods and to deal with economic and social problems. Public investments are designed to not just increase spending, but to increase spending in areas where the private sector is not doing enough. These investments may be for public goods such as quality education and health care for all, public safety (including national defense 27 and crime prevention), jobs with decent levels of income and working conditions, security in retirement, and a clean environment. These policies also have a number of different positive effects. They help stabilize the macroeconomy and improve microeconomic performance as well as helping to increase the satisfaction of individuals who live in a nation. 28 References Smith, Adam. 1937. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library. Oliver E. Williamson (2002). "The Theory of the Firm as Governance Structure: From Choice to Contract". Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (3): 171–195. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action Ostrom, Elinor, Cambridge University Press, 1990 Barro, R. (1974). “Are Government Bonds Net Worth?” Journal of Political Economy, 82: 1095-117. Bateman, B. (1996). Keynes’s Uncertain Revolution. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Bowles, S. and H. Gintis. 2002. “Social Capital and Community Governance.” Economic Journal 112, no. 483: 419-36. Chick, V. (1983) Macroeconomics After Keynes (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). Colander, D. (2009) “The Keynesian Method, Complexity and the Training of Economists.” Working paper. Costanza, R., Andrade, F., Antunes, P., van den Belt, M., Boesch, D., Boersma, D., Catarino, F., Hanna, S., Limburg, K., Low, B., Molitor, M., Pereira, J. G., Rayner, S., Santos, R., Wilson, J., and Young, M. (1999), ‘Ecological economics and sustainable govern­ ance of the oceans’, Ecological Economics, 31, 171–187. Davidson, P. (1978) Money and the Real World, 2nd ed. (London: Macmillan). Davidson, P. (1982-3) Rational Expectations: A Fallacious Foundation for Studying Crucial Decision-Making Processes, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 5: 182-97. Davidson, P. (1988) A Technical Definition of Uncertainty and the Long-Run NonNeutrality of Money, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12: 329-37. 29 Davidson, P. (1991) Is Probability Theory Relevant for Uncertainty?, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5: 129-43. Davidson, P. (1994) Post Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory (Edward Elgar). Davidson, P. (1996) Reality and Economic Theory, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 18: 479-508. Davidson, P. (2005) The Post Keynesian School, in B. Snowden & H. Vane, Modern Macroeconomics: Its Origins, Development and Current State (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar), pp. Dow, S. (2001) “Post Keynesian methodology” Holt, R.P.F. and S. Pressman New Guide to Post Keynesian Economics (London: Routlege), pp. 11-20. Dunn, S. & Pressman, S. (2005) The Economic Contributions of John Kenneth Galbraith, Review of Political Economy, 17: 161-209. Eichner, A. (1976) The Megacorp and Oligopoly (New York: Cambridge University Press). Eichner, A. (1978) A Guide to Post Keynesian Economics (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe). Eichner, A. & Kregel, J. (1975) An Essay on Post-Keynesian Theory: A New Paradigm in Economics, Journal of Economic Literature, 13: 1293-311. Galbraith, J.K. (1967) The New Industrial State (Boston: Houghton Mifflin). Goodwin, R. (1947) "Dynamic Coupling with Especial Reference to Markets Having Production Lags", Econometrica. Greenwood, D. and R.P.F. Holt (2010) “Growth, Inequality and Negative Trickle Down, Journal or Economic Issues, Vol. XLIV, Number 2, June 2010, pp. 403-410. Harcourt, G. (1972) Some Cambridge Controversies in the Theory of Capital (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Harcourt, G. (1999) “Horses for Courses”: The Making of a Post-Keynesian Economist, in: A. Heertje (Ed.) The Makers of Modern Economics, Vol. IV (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar), pp. 32-69. Harcourt, G. (2007) “The theoretical and political importance of the economics of Keynes: or, what would Marx and Keynes have made of the happenings of the past 30 30 years and more? In: Forstater, M. G. Mongiovi and . Pressman (Eds.) Post Keynesian Macroeconomics: Essays in honour of Ingrid Rima (London: Routledge), pp. 56-69. Holt, R.P.F. (2005) ‘Post-Keynesian Economics and Sustainable Development’, International Journal of Environment, Workplace and Employment, 1 (2), pp.174-186. Holt, R. & Pressman, S. (Eds) (2001) A New Guide to Post Keynesian Economics (London: Routledge). Kalecki, M. (1971) Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Keynes (1973)[1921] Treatise on Probability. Also published as Volume VIII of The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes (London: Macmillan). Keynes J.M. (1923) A Tract on Monetary Reform. (London: Macmillan). Keynes, J.M. [1936] The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London: Macmillan). Keynes, J.M. (1937) The General Theory of Employment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51: 209-23. Keynes, J.M. 1938. Letter to Roy Harrod. 4 July. http://economia.unipv.it/harrod/edition/editionstuff/rfh.346htm (Accessed 6-11-10). Keynes, J.M. (1963) The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan. Vols. IV, XXI, Keynes, J.N. (1891) The Scope and Method of Political Economy. London: Macmillan. Knight, F. (1971[1921]) Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit (Chicago: University of Chicago Press) Mankiw, N.G. (1992) “The reincarnation of Keynesian economics, European Economic Review, 36, pp. 560-561. Minsky, P. H. (1974) “Money and the Real World: A Review of Article.” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Business: 14, 2 (Summer), pp. 7-17. Minsky, P.H. (1975) John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press. Minksy, P.H. (1986) Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. (New Haven: Yale University Press). 31 Moore, B. 1988. Horizontalists and Verticalists: The macroeconomics of credit money, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Pressman, S. (2001) “The Role of the state and the state budget” In Holt, R.P.F. and S. Pressman New Guide to Post Keynesian Economics (London: Routledge), pp. 102-114. Pressman, S. (2004) The Two Dogmas of Neoclassical Economics, Science & Society, 68: 483-93. Pressman, S. (2006) Kahneman, Tversky and Institutional Economics, Journal of Economic Issues, 40(2): pp. Pressman, S. (2006) A Post Keynesian Theory of the State, in S. Pressman (ed.) Alternative Theories of the State (London: Palgrave/Macmillan). Pressman, S. (2004) What is Wrong with Public Choice, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26: 3-18. Robinson, J. (1974) History versus Equilibrium, in Robinson (1980). Robinson, J. (1976) The Age of Growth, in Collected Economic Papers of Joan Robinson, Vol 4 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell), pp. 122-7. Robinson, J. (1980) Collected Economic Papers, 5 Vols. (Cambridge: MIT Press). Robinson, J. (1953-54) The Production Function and the Theory of Capital, Review of Economic Studies. Reprinted in Robinson (1980), Vol. 2, pp. 114-31. Robinson, J. (1974) History versus Equilibrium, in Robinson (1980) Robinson, J. (1976) The Age of Growth, in Collected Economic Papers of Joan Robinson, Vol 4 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell), pp. 122-7. Robinson, J. (1980) Collected Economic Papers, 5 Vols. (Cambridge: MIT Press). Rosser, J.B. (2001) Uncertainty and Expectations, in R. Holt & S. Pressman (Eds) A New Guide to Post Keynesian Economics, (London & New York: Routledge), pp. 52-64. Rosser, Jr., J.B. (2004) ‘Complexities of dynamic forestry management policies’, Working Paper. Kaldor, N. (1985) Economics without Equilibrium (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe). Keynes, J.M. (1964)[1936] The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt Brace & World). 32 Keynes (1973)[1921] Treatise on Probability. Volume VIII of The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes (London: Macmillan). Knight, F. (1971[1921]) Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Galbraith, J.K. (1952) A Theory of Price Control (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). Davidson, P. (1994) Post Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory (Edward Elgar). Davidson, P. (1996) Reality and Economic Theory, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 18: 479-508. Davidson, P. (2005) The Post Keynesian School, in: B. Snowdon & H. Vane, Modern Macroeconomics: Its Origins, Development and Current State (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar), pp. 451-473. Shesol, J. (2010). Supreme Power: Franklin Roosevelt vs. the Supreme Court. (NewYork: W.W. Norton & Co). Skidelsky, Robert. 2009. Keynes: The Return of the Master. New York: Public Affairs. Clarke, Peter. 2009. Keynes: The Rise, Fall, and Return of the 20th Century’s Most Influential Economist. Sen. A. (1999) Development as Freedom. (New York: Alfred A. Knopf). 33 Like Keynes’s Treatise on Probability ((1973) [1921]) .To classical economists who believed in a handsoff approach to state intervention in the economy, Keynes made his famous remark though before the Great Depression in A Tract on Monetary Reform (1923), the message was still the same for the 1930s though: “In the long run we are all dead. Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in tempestuous seasons they can only tell us that when the storm is long past the ocean is flat again.” (1963, IV, p. 65). i 34