Unit Labor Costs, International Competitiveness, and Exports: The Case of Senegal* Ahmadou Aly MBAYE Professeur Agrégé Faculté des Sciences Economiques et de Gestion (FASEG) Université Cheikh Anta Diop de Dakar BP 16448 - Dakar (Senegal) Tel : (221) 835 27 26 Fax: (221) 824 43 90 Email: ambaye@syfed.refer.sn and Stephen GOLUB Professor of Economics Swarthmore College Swarthmore PA 19081 (USA) Tel: (1-610) 328-8103 Fax: (1-610) 328-7352 Email: sgolub1@swarthmore.edu Final version, May 2002 To appear in Journal of African Economies, Vol 11, no. 2 Abstract : Despite some favorable conditions and a number of policy reforms, Senegal’s participation in the global economy remains tenuous. This paper uses a Ricardian framework to study Senegal’s international competitiveness in manufacturing. Wages, productivity, and unit labor costs in Senegal are compared to those of other developing countries. Senegal’s labor productivity has grown much more slowly than in successful emerging economies. The 1994 devaluation of the CFA franc has dramatically improved Senegal’s international competitiveness but further improvements in competitiveness depend on productivity growth given the constraint of the fixed exchange rate. We find a significant effect of relative unit labor costs on exports, particularly of manufactured goods. Sustained export-led growth, however, requires additional structural reforms. * This research was funded by a grant from the West African Research Association with some additional support from the World Bank. We would like to thank Stephen O’Connell, Philip Jefferson, Larry Westphal, Richard Mshomba and two referees for helpful comments. Senegal and the Global Economy In the 1960s, Senegal, South Korea, Malaysia, and Mauritius all had roughly the same level of gross domestic product per capita. Despite some moderate recent growth, Senegal’s level of per capita GDP has stagnated or even declined over the last three decades. During the same period, the four East Asian « miracle » economies’ per capita GDP increased by a factor of about ten. A number of other countries such as Malaysia and Thailand in South-East Asia, Chile in South America, and Mauritius and Tunisia in Africa had impressive growth rates in the last twenty years or so.1 (Figure 1) In recent years, a near consensus has emerged on the positive effects of export growth and diversification on economic development2. Perhaps most convincingly, the remarkable success of a number of East and South-East Asia countries and a few others have all been at least partly based on integration into the global economy and rapid export growth, particularly of manufactured goods. (Figure 2). There are a number of channels through which exports can foster growth in developing countries, in addition to the static gains from trade according to comparative advantage. First, in an environment of declining foreign aid, exports provide the foreign currency needed to finance imported inputs. Second, labor-intensive exports can contribute to reducing unemployment and thus poverty. Third, and perhaps even more importantly, exports can be a catalytic agent for development through the discipline imposed by competition in the international market, the economies of scale the world market affords, and the transfer of foreign technology and modern managerial techniques.3 Thus, in the last two decades, many developing countries have introduced economic policy reforms aimed at export promotion, although with varying results. In Africa in general, performance has remained quite disappointing (Collier and Gunning 1999, Ndulu and O’Connell 1999). As Collier (1997) argues forcefully, Africa has been unable to take advantage of globalization. Senegal is a case in point: since 1979 various programs of trade liberalization and export promotion have been implemented, with mixed results: a free trade zone which allows exporting firms to benefit 1 The Asian crisis, however serious, does not substantially alter this conclusion. At the height of the crisis per capita GDP declined by about 5-10% in countries such as Thailand, Indonesia and Korea, which hardly reverses the gains of the previous decades. 2 E.g. Dollar 1992, Edwards 1993, Sachs and Warner 1995, 1997--although see Rodriguez and Rodrik 1999 for some doubts about the econometric evidence. 3 Soderling (2000) discusses these issues in relation to Cameroon. Tybout (2000) surveys the empirical literature on manufacturing. 2 from tax breaks; reduction of the fiscal deficit and stabilization of inflation below 5 percent; lower and simplified tariff barriers and elimination of almost all quotas on imports. Following the 1994 fifty percent devaluation of the CFA franc, which has been pegged to the French franc since Senegal’s independence in 1960, the growth rate of Senegal’s exports and output picked up, but they both remain well below the rates observed by the success stories in Asia and elsewhere. Senegal has some advantages relative to other developing countries: political stability, geographic location propitious for access to the European and American markets, and a work force skilled in traditional crafts, and with a talent for and tradition of trading.4 There was considerable optimism about Senegal’s prospects in the decades following independence.5 It is true that Senegal is quite poorly endowed with natural resources, but this can be an additional impetus to industrial development. Sachs and Warner (1997) among others show that a high dependence on natural resources can be detrimental to industrial development and sustained growth. Countries like Taiwan and Mauritius are not well endowed in natural resources either. This paper is part of a longer-term research project that seeks to identify the sources of Senegal’s weak integration in the global economy. Here we focus on macroeconomic cost competitiveness. In other work, we are examining this problem from a more microeconomic perspective, with case studies of selected industries (Golub and Mbaye 2000). We begin with an overview of Senegal’s trading pattern and trade policies, followed by a theoretical framework for analysis of international competitiveness. In our empirical work, we will first attempt to assess the absolute productivity and cost of Senegalese labor in relation to other countries, particular the successful emerging economies. We will then use a trade-weighted relative unit labor cost indicator in a time series analysis of Senegalese exports.6 Senegalese traders’ skills are known even in the United States, particularly in New York City. (“On the Streets of New York,” The Economist, June 19, 1999). For a description of the international commercial network of the Senegalese Mouride brotherhood see Ebin (1992). 5 Mann (1988) identified Senegal as a promising emerging economy. 6 World Bank (1997) also addresses these issues. Our paper differs by providing a more precise definition of international competitiveness and relating this measure to exports. 4 3 II – Overview of Senegal’s International Trade Senegal’s exports are characterized by slow growth and lack of diversification. This is largely rooted in the policies of import substitution, adopted in the first two decades following Senegal’s independence in 1960. Since 1979, however, a series of reforms, liberalizing trade and promoting exports, have been undertaken in the context of various structural adjustment packages. These reforms have had limited success. The financial and economic recovery plan of 1980-85 and the medium- and long-term structural adjustment program (PAMLT) of 1985-1992 included various measures to liberalize the economy but did not modify the fixed parity of the CFA franc to the French franc, given Senegal’s membership in the West African Franc Zone. Only with the devaluation of the CFA franc in 1994 did export growth pick up. The devaluation was shortly followed in 1994-95 by the most far-reaching structural adjustments to date, with the World Bank PASCO program of trade, labor market, and other reforms. Even after 1994, however, export growth and diversification have been insufficient to fuel sustained growth. The growth rate of export volume jumped to 8.2 percent in 1994-95, much improved over the 2.5 per cent rate in 1960-1979, but then fell back to just 3 percent in 1996-98. In comparison, world export volume grew 8.7 per cent in 1994-95 and 6.7 percent in 1996-98 so most of the slowdown in Senegalese export growth cannot be attributed to the disruptions associated with the Asian crisis.7 II- 1- A weak and poorly diversified export sector8 Senegal’s most important exports are currently: --groundnuts and their derivatives (oil, oilcake, and edible peanuts) --fishing and fish products --phosphates and their derivatives (fertilizer, phosphoric acid) --tourism. These four industries accounted for about 80 percent of exports in the 1990s. Overall growth has been sluggish (Figure 2). Labor-intensive manufactured goods are largely absent despite All developing countries’ exports grew even more rapidly during this period: 11.2 percent in 1994-95 and 11.0 in 1996-98 (IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2001, p. 223). 7 4 the abundance of underemployed labor earning subsistence incomes in agriculture and in the urban informal sector. In fact the textile and clothing industries have contracted sharply since the 1970s. Here we briefly summarize some of the issues arising in our case studies of the groundnut, fishing and textile-clothing industries. (Golub and Mbaye 2000) Groundnuts. From the colonial era until the middle of the 1970s, groundnuts were the mainstay of the Senegalese economy; the sector’s contribution to GDP was about 20 percent, and it accounted for more than 70 percent of employment. Most exports are in the form of unrefined oil and oil cake. A government parastatal, the SONACOS, has until recently controlled all stages of production and marketing. Towards the end of the 1970s, a steady decline set in. Senegal’s world market share of peanut oil exports declined from 23% to 14% between 1961-65 and 1986-1988, while that of Asian countries increased from 8% to 32%. The causes of this weak performance can be classified into two categories : exogenous shocks and government policies. The main exogenous shocks have been the decline of rainfall since the 1970s and the fall in demand for peanut oil in European markets, partly connected to fears about aflotoxin, a carcinogen in peanuts. But government policies seem to have been even more important, notably the inefficiency and corruption of the SONACOS financing and distribution of seed grains, and collection and processing of output. The SONACOS oil processing facilities operate at very low capacity and hence high unit cost, but they have not been consolidated for political reasons. Two attempts to privatize the SONACOS have failed due to the unattractive conditions specified by the government. Nonetheless the role of the private sector, both formal and informal, has expanded at the margin in recent years. Informal traders as well as the firm NOVASEN are purchasing, distributing, and processing a larger share of the crop although the SONACOS still plays a dominant role. Fishing. The artisanal (informal pirogue) sector is booming but industrial fishing, particularly on-shore processing, is experiencing grave difficulties, notwithstanding Senegal’s coastal region being one of the richest of the world in terms of fish stocks. The problems of the tuna-processing industry are particularly acute and symptomatic of the difficulties of Senegalese industry. There are only three firms of moderate capacity, down from seven in 1960, and even these three firms face chronic problems of excess capacity and have been 8 See also World Bank (1997). 5 intermittently closed in recent years. Senegalese canned tuna has steadily lost market share in Europe to East Asian tuna despite exemption from import duties of 24 % that the Asian countries must pay. Senegalese tuna processors have high costs even relative to those in Abidjan, and have accordingly seen a further erosion of market share, as tuna boats operating off West Africa tend to prefer to unload their catch in Abidjan, all else equal. Other large onshore industrial fish-processing enterprises are also facing severe difficulties. The problems of the fishing industry are numerous: dwindling stocks of some species due to over-fishing and pollution, problems of conforming to international norms of hygiene, insufficient capital investment in boats and processing facilities, confrontational labor relations and poor management in some cases. Textiles-Clothing. Towards the end of the colonial era and in the decades following independence, Senegal developed a sizable but inefficient import-substituting textile industry. Extremely high protection and pervasive government intervention characterized this industry, as for most manufacturing. The textile industry nearly collapsed in the 1980s under the twin pressures of smuggling and trade liberalization. The formal clothing industry has all but disappeared, with only the booming informal sector remaining. The 1994 devaluation had a short-run positive effect on this sector, but mostly for the relatively capital-intensive sub-sectors (weaving and spinning) rather than the labor-intensive apparel sub-sector. To this date there is little or no foreign outsourcing of clothing production in Senegal by global manufacturers such as occurs in Asia, Latin America, and North Africa. Senegal exports some raw cotton but little else, and the textile industry as a whole incurs a large trade deficit. Exports of clothing are almost nonexistent, while imports of used and new clothes (some of which continue to be smuggled despite the devaluation and trade liberalization) constitute a large part of domestic consumption. International competition in the clothing industry is fierce. Nonetheless, several studies indicate that Senegal has some key advantages: a decline in labor costs thanks to the devaluation of 1994, a location close to Europe and the USA, highly skilled producers in the informal sector (weavers from the Casamance, tailors who custom make beautiful clothes for relatively well-off local consumers). The possibility of sub-contracting from countries like Morocco where labor costs have risen relative to Senegal, could help jump-start production. Unfortunately, Golub and Mbaye (2000) show that there remain grave institutional impediments to progress: the lack of training of personnel and management, unreliable and 6 expensive infrastructure, especially transport and electricity, lack of access to credit, and costly and cumbersome customs and investment procedures, often associated with corruption. In each of these industries, the formal sector faces grave difficulties while the informal sector is booming. Despite endowments and location suggesting potential comparative advantage in these industries, Senegal has severe competitiveness problems, particularly vis-a-vis Asian producers. Our interviews as well as other studies show that there are a number of general features of the business environment in Senegal that contribute to low productivity, high unit costs or uncertainty, all of which discourage investment in formal industry: lack of transparency and corruption, infrastructure deficiencies, lack of access to credit, inadequate training, and confrontational labor relations. It is also important to note that much of Senegal’s exports such as groundnut oil, fish products, and phosphate products are not readily classified as either manufactured goods or primary products. For the most part, they are lightly processed primary products. Certainly, they are mostly not homogeneous primary products for which the law of one price is likely to hold closely. For example, for fresh and processed fish, prices depend on the species, freshness, extent of processing, etc. Product differentiation also characterizes some goods where Senegal has a potential comparative advantage such as clothing and Afro-centric products. Thus, models assuming homogeneous tradable goods are not likely to be appropriate for Senegal. II-2- Trade Reforms with Meager Results Senegal has had few direct barriers to exports, with the exception of some export taxes on groundnuts and gold which were eliminated in 1985. Instead, the impediments to exports arose from the general anti-export bias of the import-substitution regime. Weak export performance has continued in spite of a number of reforms instituted since the 1970s, aimed at trade liberalization and export promotion.9 Senegal instituted one of the first free trade zones in Africa in 1974 in order to encourage assembly and processing of manufactured goods for export, as well as related service activities. 9 See Mbaye (1998) for further details. 7 Firms that secured free-trade status benefited from total exemption of corporate income taxes and other direct taxes. Their imports of capital goods and intermediate inputs entered free of duty. In addition, the tax code was reformed to create a more favorable environment for exports. A number of taxes were eliminated as early as 1979 (including the taxe statistique, the taxe intérieure, and the taxe forfaitaire). With the New Industry Policy of 1986, a uniform customs duty of 15 percent was instituted, and the variable customs duty rates (droit fiscal) were shifted down as follows: d.f. réduit unchanged at 10%, d.f. normal lowered from 40 from 30%, d.f. supérieur lowered from 50 to 35% and d.f. spécial lowered from 75 to 65%. By 1988, the uniform customs duty rate was further reduced to 10 percent and almost all import quotas were eliminated. Nonetheless, the following year, the basic customs duty rate was raised back to 15%, and some products were shifted to a higher droit fiscal rate (taux supérieur) from the reduced rate (taux réduit). Concurrently, preferential exemptions of taxes and import duties were extended to firms outside the free trade zone to increase their competitiveness. In particular, temporary duty-free admission of imports was permitted for firms processing imported inputs, as long as 80 percent of their production is re-exported. On the institutional level, as early as 1981 the government created l’Agence Sénégalaise d’Assurance et de Crédit à l’exportation (ASACE), which insures Senegalese exports against political and commercial risks. In addition, the Centre Sénégalais du Commerce Extérieur (CICES) was established in 1986, to help exporting firms participate in commercial fairs and missions abroad. Finally an export subsidy was instituted, equal to 10% of the value of exports from 1980 to 1983, rising to 15% of export value in 1983-86, and starting in 1986, 25% of value added. This subsidy was eliminated in 1991, however, when it became clear that it was not significantly contributing to export diversification, despite the ever-rising fiscal burden it entailed. In 1994, the CFA franc was devalued 50 percent and a number of accompanying measures to liberalize labor and product were enacted.10 The extent of implementation of these structural reforms was erratic, however. (Berg, 1997) Recently, in January 1999, the common external tariff (TEC) of the West African Economic and Monetary Union (UEMOA), has been put in place. The TEC has considerably reduced and 10 The CFA franc is also the currency of other West and Central African nations, including the West African Economic and Monetary Union (UEMOA) of which Senegal is a member. The share of Senegal’s exports going to other CFA franc countries, however, although rising, is only about 20 percent. 8 simplified the system of import taxation of the member countries, including Senegal. Prior to the TEC Senegal’s tariffs and other import duties could cumulate to about 70%. Now, the ceiling is in principle 22% (20 percent customs duties, 1% statistical tax and 1% prélèvement communautaire de solidarité. This higher rate is limited to final consumer goods; for socially essential goods, the tax rate is zero, for necessities, it is 5%, and for intermediate inputs it is 10%. Nonetheless the application of the TEC has been accompanied by offsetting measures such as the taxe dégressive de protection (TDP) and the taxe conjonturelle à l’exportation (TCI). The TDP only concerns industrial and agro-industrial products, and is supposed to cushion temporarily (for four years) the impact of reduced protection. The TDP has a “reduced rate” of 10 percent for those products suffering a cut in the effective rate of protection of 25 to 50%, and a higher 20% rate for those products having even larger reduced effective protection. The TCI is applied in cases of foreign dumping or when the UEMOA commission judges that there has been an important decline in the world price of the product in question. Also, it seems that the timbre fiscal and other small taxes are still applied. While these reforms have been far-reaching, the effectiveness of these measures was compromised by lack of credibility due to abrupt and frequent changes in policies, erratic implementation, the failure to adopt accompanying measures such as deregulation of the labor market, and administrative hurdles. These problems handicapped firms’ abilities to adjust to the liberalized trade regime through lower costs and higher productivity. For example, it can take years to receive free trade status, and even for firms with such status, the procedures for duty exemptions and other benefits can be lengthy and cumbersome.11 Perhaps most importantly, prior to the devaluation, the increasing overvaluation of the CFA franc, which had been pegged to the French franc since independence in 1960, may have doomed any such microeconomic reforms. Overvaluation is equivalent to a uniform tax on exports and subsidy on imports, thus tending to offset any improvements of other policies on export competitiveness while exacerbating pressures on the import-competing sectors. Our aim is to provide an organizing framework to understand these problems. We have proceeded in two steps. First, we use a Ricardian approach to assess macroeconomic competitiveness that involves comparing Senegal’s unit labor costs to other developing countries. 11 FIAS (1999) documents the various procedural problems confronting a prospective investor. 9 Relative unit labor costs depend in turn on labor productivity, labor costs, and exchange rates. Second, we have undertaken case studies, as summarized above, to further grasp the structural factors that lie behind the slow growth of productivity and exports of tradable goods. The remainder of this paper focuses on the former issue, while a companion paper (Golub and Mbaye 2000) addresses the latter. III. A Ricardian Framework for International Competitiveness In this section, we argue that a Ricardian focus on relative unit labor costs provides a powerful framework for analyzing international competitiveness. Unit labor cost is the cost of labor per unit of output, i.e. the ratio of wages to productivity. Relative unit labor cost is the key relative price in a Ricardian model of trade. International price competitiveness, also known as the real exchange rate, can be alternatively defined as the relative price of domestic and foreign tradable goods (the “external” real exchange rate) or the relative price of domestic tradables and domestic non-tradables (the “internal” real exchange rate). In practice, however, there is often less difference between these two approaches than appears at first. Many empirical models use some ratio of foreign and domestic prices to proxy for the domestic relative price of tradables/nontradables.12 Also, the two models boil down to a similar result: exports and imports depend on the real wage in terms of tradable goods.13 Furthermore, in a world where capital is mobile and production is footloose between countries, it is the relative price of non-tradable inputs, notably labor, rather than outputs that matters.14 Firms will tend to source production in countries where unit costs of nontradable inputs are low. It is therefore of interest to compare both levels and rates of change of labor costs and labor productivity between countries. Hinkle and Nsengiyumba (1999) also observe that external real exchange rates tend to be appropriate when foreign and domestic goods are imperfect substitutes. In the case of Senegal, as noted above, exports are mostly lightly processed primary 12 See Edwards (1988) for example. Hinkle and Nsengiyumba (1999) note the widespread use of external real exchange rates as proxies for internal real exchange rates. 13 See Dornbusch (1980, Ch. 9) for an analysis of the Salter-Swan model. The domestic price of nontradables is a markup of domestic nominal wages (given the productivity of labor in nontradables). On the other hand, the foreign-currency price of tradable goods is exogenous. Thus, the relative price of tradables is inversely proportional to the real wage expressed in terms of tradables. 10 commodities that are likely to be imperfect substitutes for other countries’ products due to quality differences. For these reasons and others, Turner and Van’t Dack (1992) and Turner and Golub’s (1997) surveys of the literature conclude that relative unit labor costs in manufacturing are the best single indicator of competitiveness. Where data are available, Hinkle and Nsengiyumba (1999) also endorse the use of unit labor costs, both for analysis of levels and rates of change of competitiveness. More generally, the Ricardian model provides an appealing framework for the analysis of trade flows (see Golub (1994), Golub and Hsieh (2000) and Carlin et al (2001) for further discussion). This model provides an integrated framework for understanding the macro- and microeconomic factors determining trade flows, as most elegantly shown in Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson (1977) (DFS). The basic idea is that relative unit labor cost is influenced both by sectorspecific variables (productivity and wages) as well as the real exchange rate.15 On a micro level, the Ricardian model has both advantages and disadvantages compared to the Heckscher-OhlinSamuelson (HOS) model, in which comparative advantage is derived from factor endowments. The main advantage is that the Ricardian model allows for technological differences between countries, which in practice seem very significant. There are large and persistent gaps in labor and total factor productivity by industry across countries. Moreover, the HOS model has received lukewarm empirical support (Bowen, Leamer, and Sveikauskas, 1987). It has recently been shown that a key reason for the failure of the HOS model is the failure to incorporate international differences in technology and that when such differences are allowed for the HOS model improves (Trefler 1995, Davis and Weinstein 2001). The main disadvantage of the Ricardian model is that it implies that countries specialize completely in tradable goods production. In practice, import-competing industries contract but rarely disappear completely in the face of foreign competition. To allow for incomplete specialization in a Ricardian context, one would have to introduce other considerations, such as differentiated products. Also, unit labor cost may be an imperfect gauge of competitiveness if quality differences are not measured accurately or if labor is not the only non-tradable factor of 14 Jones (1980) analyzes the implications of footloose factors in a Ricardian model. See also Caves, Frankel, Jones (1999, Ch. 9). 15 Most expositions of the Ricardian model assume perfectly competitive labor markets and hence a uniform wage rate across sectors. But this assumption is easily relaxed in empirical work. 11 production. Despite these limitations, previous applications of the Ricardian model have been quite successful, although they are surprisingly few in number.16 Let ai represent the unit labor requirement (the inverse of productivity), for sector i: (1) ai = Li , Qi where Q is value-added, and L is labor employment. Marginal productivity and hence ai are assumed to be constant with respect to variations in Li. Let w denote the wage and e the exchange rate between home and foreign currencies. If labor is the only factor of production (or that other factor costs do not differ across countries), average costs of production are equal to unit labor costs wi.ai. Expressed in domestic currency, foreign unit labor cost is e.wi*.ai*. International competitiveness in sector i then depends on relative unit labor cost ci: (2) ci = aiwi . ai * wi * e Alternatively, equation (2) can be written (3) ci = ai . wi . ai * wi * e Equation (3) illustrates the decomposition of relative unit labor costs into relative productivity and relative wages converted into a common currency. Thus Senegal’s competitiveness vis-à-vis Thailand could weaken when some combination of the following conditions hold: 1) Labor productivity in Thailand rises relative to labor productivity in Senegal, 2) Senegalese wages increase 16The classic articles are MacDougall (1951), Balassa (1961) and Stern (1962). For a discussion of this earlier literature see Deardorff (1985). Golub (1994) and Golub and Hsieh (2000) are more recent empirical applications of Ricardian model. 12 relative to Thai wages, or 3) The CFA franc appreciates relative to the Thai baht. As Senegalese cost competitiveness deteriorates, exports are predicted to decline. In addition to cost competitiveness, exports could be affected by changes in global demands associated with cyclical movements of foreign aggregate output and by changes in domestic supply unrelated to relative prices. This justifies the inclusion of world demand and domestic supply shocks as explanatory variables in the empirical analysis of trade flows. IV. Labor Costs and Productivity in Senegalese Manufacturing This section present empirical measures of Senegal’s relative unit labor costs in manufacturing, using the decomposition of equation (3) into relative productivity and relative wages measured in a common currency in manufacturing. To compare levels of real outputs and labor compensation across economies, they must be converted to a common currency. Productivity is calculated as manufacturing value added per employee, deflated by the manufacturing value-added deflator and converted to $U.S. at an equilibrium or purchasing power parity exchange (PPP) rate. Wages are defined as total labor compensation per employee, converted to $U.S. at the market exchange rate.17 As is accepted in the literature on international labor productivity and unit labor cost comparisons, PPP exchange rates are used for international productivity comparisons to eliminate the effects of exchange-rate volatility on measures of real output, which should be invariant such exchange-rate fluctuations. But deviations of exchange rates from PPP do affect relative labor costs, so it is appropriate to use the market exchange rate in converting wages. 18 Currency depreciation consequently tends to improve international competitiveness by reducing labor costs relative to labor productivity. Data are annual, 1974-1996. Sources and methods are described in the Appendix. 17The UNIDO INSTAT database used for these calculations defines labor compensation as all payments in cash to employees but excludes social insurance payments by employers. 18 See Hooper and Larin (1989) for further justification of the use of PPP exchange rates for productivity comparisons but market exchange rates for labor-cost comparisons. 13 Figure 3 shows the time path of Senegal’s relative labor productivity and wages vis-a-vis selected competitor countries: Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, India, Mexico, South Africa and Mauritius. Figure 3 is best suited for looking at the evolution over time of Senegal’s wages and productivity of Senegal vis-à-vis other countries, as the scale of the various figures is not held constant. Figure 4 below is better suited for international comparisons of levels of wages and productivity at a point in time. Several patterns emerge from Figure 3. •Prior to the 1994 devaluation, Senegal had an obvious competitiveness problem : in the early 1990s Senegalese relative wages exceeded relative productivity in all cases, implying that Senegal had higher absolute unit labor costs than any of the other countries examined.19 The 50 percent devaluation in 1994 substantially reversed this situation, with Senegalese relative productivity now surpassing Senegal’s relative wages with respect to some but not all competitor countries. Based on Figure 3, the 1994 devaluation approximately returned Senegalese unit labor costs to parity vis-à-vis developing country exporters of manufactured goods. The devaluations of Asian currencies following the 1997-98 crisis undoubtedly offset some of the effects of the CFA franc devaluation, but data to assess this was not yet fully available at the time of writing. •The importance of the peg to the French franc is also apparent. A strong French franc, particularly vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar, as in the late 1970s and late 1980s, entails a real appreciation of the CFA franc, i.e., Senegalese relative unit labor costs tend to rise against countries not pegged to the French franc. Conversely, during periods where the French franc is weak against the dollar, as in the early 1980s, Senegalese relative unit labor costs decline. •Senegalese labor productivity has stagnated since at least 1978. This is manifested by a general decline of Senegal’s relative productivity vis-à-vis the countries shown in Figure 3. Moreover, this poor productivity performance has been accompanied by a stagnation or decline in manufacturing employment, so the slow productivity growth cannot be ascribed to diminishing returns due to rapid growth of employment, as may be the case in Mauritius and Malaysia, for Thus we confirm Devarajan’s (1997) and others’ findings of overvaluation of the CFA franc, although our concept of overvaluation is quite different. It is also consistent with Rama’s (2000) finding of misaligned labor costs in CFA countries. 19 14 example. The slow growth of Senegal’s manufacturing productivity is also studied in Berthelemy et al (1996) and Latreille and Varoudakis (1996). Figure 4 condenses the information in Figure 3, showing Senegal’s competitiveness before and after the 1994 devaluation relative to some of the same developing countries. These calculations reveal wide divergences in Senegal’s relative productivity levels. Senegal’s labor productivity exceeds that of some developing countries such as India and Mauritius, but fall well below those of Korea and Chile. In all cases, however, Senegalese relative wages exceed relative productivity prior to 1994. Despite a generalized decline in Senegalese relative productivity in 1994-96 compared to 1991-93, the reduction in relative wages occasioned by the devaluation entails a substantial improvement in competitiveness. The fundamental dilemma in Senegal suggested by our analytical framework is that slow productivity growth has collided with the fixed exchange rate and labor market rigidities. Low productivity and high labor costs are both in part attributable to labor market rigidities, according to our case studies (Golub and Mbaye 2000).20 In Senegal, unions have been unusually strong, and protected by restrictive labor legislation modeled after France’s. Consequently, unions have to some extent succeeded in blunting the effects of the structural adjustment programs on labor markets. In the context of the structural adjustment program of the early 1980s, the government timidly modified the labor code, in particular article 35 to allow short-term contracts, and article 199 to break the monopoly of the Labor Department in job placement. At that time, however, the unions obtained wage increases in flagrant violation of agreements with the World Bank and the IMF, which led to the suspension of credits. In 1994-95 labor laws were further relaxed, and enforcement has also become more lax. At the present time, our interviews (Golub and Mbaye) as well as other studies (Rama 2000) suggest that the unions’ power has diminished considerably. Despite these changes, some employers cite continued difficulties in shedding redundant labor and the adverse effect of union work rules on productivity. 20 Rama (2000) also analyses labor market rigidities and other causes of wage misalignment in CFA countries. 15 Given these labor-market rigidities and the difficulties of raising productivity rapidly, the lack of exchange-rate flexibility associated with membership in the CFA franc zone is a serious constraint on international competitiveness. Exchange-rate changes can be a less contentious and more effective way of altering relative unit labor costs than nominal wage reductions. V. Relative Unit Labor Costs and Exports In this section we use our calculated relative unit labor cost indicators to study the effects on Senegal’s exports. Senegal’s relative unit labor costs are calculated in terms of a simple average of 9 competitor countries. 21 Figure 5 displays the time series of real exports/real GDP and the index of relative unit labor costs, inverted for ease of visual comparison. Thus, an increase in this variable means improved competitiveness. As expected, there appears to be positive correlation between the two series. Note that the 1994 devaluation sharply improves competitiveness initially, but much of this improvement is eliminated by 1996, reflecting some increases in wages and continued decline in productivity in Senegal, as well as currency depreciation in some of Senegal’s competitor countries. Figure 6 is similar to Figure 5 except that manufactured exports replace total exports. The relationship between relative unit labor costs and competitiveness appears somewhat stronger for manufactured exports than total exports. We have estimated the following baseline equation, loosely based on the Ricardian model in section III and close in spirit to the elasticities approach to trade flows:22 (4) LEXTOT = a0 + a1 LRULC(-1) + a2 LWGDP + Where LEXTOT is the log of the ratio of real export to real GDP, LWGDP is the log of world GDP, and LRULC is the log of the index of Senegal’s relative unit labor costs. We also used as an alternative dependent variable the log of the ratio of real manufactured export 21 The countries are Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, Singapore, Hong Kong, India, Mauritius, South Africa, and Mexico. These countries are Senegal’s most important competitors, particularly in the European market. 16 to real GDP (LEXMAN). The relative unit labor cost variable is lagged one year to reflect order and delivery lags. A rise in LRULC means a loss in competitiveness of Senegalese products on world markets, so that the sign of coefficient a1 is expected to be negative. The second variable (LWGDP) is meant to capture the effects of world demand on exportables and is a2 expected to be positive. We also considered a number of other variables in alternate specifications. For the total export equations we tried measures of rainfall and dummy variables for years of drought as measures of output shocks. To capture the effects of the shifts in the trade regime discussed above, we used the log of the average duty on imports (LTARIFF) as well as a dummy variable for the 1994-98 post-devaluation period (D9498). Table 1 lists the variables in the model and presents descriptive statistics and a correlation matrix. The data are annual, 1970-1998 for total exports and 1974-1976 for manufactured exports. Table 2 reports regressions estimates of variants of equation (4), alternatively using as dependent variables the ratio of total real exports to real GDP (models 1-4), and the ratio of manufactured real exports to real GDP (models 5-7), as well as error-correction representations for total exports (model 8) and manufactured exports (model 9). Lagged relative unit labor costs have the expected effect and are statistically significant in all cases, both for total exports and manufactured exports. Overall, however, the equations for manufactured exports (models 5-7) are markedly more successful than those for total exports (models 1-4). For manufactured exports, the R-squared is much higher and the coefficient on relative unit labor costs is higher and more precisely estimated. That is not surprising since our Ricardian framework is more applicable to manufactured exports than primary products. The variable representing world demand has the wrong sign in all equations and is sometimes significant. This probably reflects the fact that Senegalese exports have declined over time, while world GDP has increased. In models 2 and 6, we have introduced the average tariff rate to capture the effect of the trade regime discussed in section II. While this variable has the expected negative sign, it is not statistically significant. The weak effects of the average tariff variable may be due to erratic implementation of tariff reforms, the frequent reversals of policies in response to budgetary and other 22 See for example Soderling (2000) and Sekkat and Varoudakis (1998) for similar econometric tests applied to African exports. 17 pressures, and complex exceptions. In addition, in spite of the structural adjustment programs, quantitative restrictions on imports were not eliminated until after the 1994 devaluation. We also tried a dummy variable for the 1994-98 period, to capture the more profound nature of the reforms in the post-devaluation era, but this variable had the wrong sign and was insignificant, and the explanatory power of the model did not improve (model 7)23. In model 3, we introduced rainfall as an independent variable, but the coefficient had the wrong sign and was insignificant. This surprising result could be due to the existence of a threshold effect on rainfall of 400-500 mm per year that is necessary for a successful harvest in grains, oilseeds, and cotton, with any excess above this level having little impact on output. However, when we used a dummy variable equal to 1 for drought years and zero for other years, the sign is still wrong and statistically insignificant (model 4). This result could reflect the declining share of agriculture in Senegalese exports (Golub et Mbaye 2000, Mbaye 1998). In all equations, Durbin-Watson and Breusch-Godfrey tests rejected autocorrelation of the residuals. Most importantly, the results show that the effect of relative unit labor costs on exports is robust with respect to the addition of other variables in the model. Unit root tests (using ADF method) reveal that all our series are integrated of order 1. It is well known that in the case of non-stationarity, inferences using OLS can be spurious (Granger and Newbold 1986). Thus we tested for cointegration using the two-stage procedure of Engle and Granger (1987) which showed that these series are cointegrated and thus have a long run relationship. When variables are cointegrated, they can be represented in error-correction form (Engle et Granger 1987). We therefore estimated error-correction models (models 8 and 9), based on models (1) and (5) respectively in Table 1. These results confirm that RULC is an important determinant of exports, as the lagged residuals (RESID) are significant at the 1 percent level, in both cases; moreover, LRULC(-1) is significant at 5% and 10% level in (8) and (9) respectively. We can thus infer a causal effect of RULC on exports. CUSUM stability tests on the residuals confirm the stability of the parameters (not shown to conserve space). While the importance of cost-competitiveness is thus confirmed, the equations leave a substantial proportion of the variance of exports unexplained. As figures 5 and 6 show, the response of exports to the 1994 devaluation has been modest. The devaluation roughly 23 Similar results were obtained for total exports and are not shown to conserve space. 18 restored competitiveness to its 1ate 1970s level, but real export/GDP ratios remain well below those of earlier decades. It seems clear that other adverse structural factors, not fully captured by relative unit labor costs, are blocking export growth. Conclusion In this paper we have studied the macroeconomic determinants of exports to shed light on Senegal’s weak integration into the world economy, despite substantial trade liberalization and export incentives. To do so, we used a conceptual framework based on the Ricardian model of trade. In this model, international competitiveness is measured by relative unit labor costs, which in turn are a function of wage rates, labor productivity and exchange rates. We evaluated the level of Senegal’s wages and productivity in manufacturing compared to those of emerging economies in Asia, Latin America, and Africa. In the years before the 1994 devaluation, Senegal’s competitive position was very weak, i.e., Senegalese wages relative to other countries were uniformly higher than Senegalese relative productivity, implying very high unit labor costs for Senegal. These high unit labor costs reflected low Senegalese productivity growth, the fixed exchange rate of the CFA franc, and the rigidity of Senegal’s labor market. The 1994 devaluation roughly returned Senegalese relative unit labor costs to parity vis-à-vis other emerging countries’ levels. Given very high relative unit labor costs until 1994, it is not surprising that prior to 1994 Senegal had low export growth and did not attract much new investment in export-oriented manufacturing either from local or foreign investors. Using a composite index of Senegalese unit labor costs, relative to a basket of competitor countries, our econometric tests show a significant and robust effect of relative unit labor costs on exports. Our results point to the importance of macroeconomic competitiveness and its underlying determinants, particularly exchange rate policy, labor market flexibility, and labor productivity. The most sustainable and desirable way to improve competitiveness is to raise labor productivity because this raises the standard of living, whereas devaluation and wage 19 reductions lower it. Given the difficulties of raising productivity or adjusting nominal wages quickly, however, it is important to obtain some degree of exchange rate flexibility. While a pegged exchange rate has some advantages, such as providing nominal anchor and reduced uncertainty, this is offset by the danger of overvaluation. In the case of Senegal, overvaluation can arise either because Senegal’s labor costs rise relative to France (and now Europe), or the French franc (Euro) appreciates against other major currencies. Our analysis also suggests that liberalization and tax breaks by themselves are unlikely to be effective if the real exchange rate is overvalued, productivity is low and the general business environment is poor. Complex tax incentives may even be counterproductive by diverting managerial efforts and fostering corruption, thus lowering productivity and increasing uncertainty (FIAS 1999). Senegalese labor productivity has stagnated in the last 25 years. Future research should attempt to determine the sources of Senegal’s low productivity growth and poorly functioning labor market. In related research, we are studying these structural problems through case studies. Our preliminary conclusions based on these case studies are that Senegalese policymakers should focus on structural bottlenecks such corruption, inadequate training, a weak judiciary, and a shortage of credit for small and medium enterprises. These structural barriers affect competitiveness both by lowering productivity and thus raising unit labor costs, and also by contributing to a generally dissuasive environment for investment. 20 APPENDIX Data Sources and Methods Labor Costs and Productivity in Manufacturing: Labor productivity is defined as real value added per employee, and wages are labor compensation per employee. Real value added is obtained as nominal value added deflated by a manufacturing value added deflator. Two alternative methods of computing equilibrium exchange rates for use in productivity comparisons between countries were tried: 1) the average bilateral real exchange rate over the sample period and 2) relative prices of producer durables as a proxy for manufacturing PPPs derived from the International Comparison Project (ICP). In practice, the two methods yielded similar results, and only the results based on the average real exchange rates are reported here.24 The primary data source is the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) INSTAT database, supplemented by the World Bank World Development Indicators on CD-ROM (WDI). Value added, employment, and labor compensation data are taken from INSTAT. The market exchange rate and manufacturing value added deflators were obtained from WDI. In addition, for Senegal, the UNIDO data were supplemented and checked against the CUCI database obtained directly from the Senegalese Département de la Statistique. The UNIDO INSTAT data have several drawbacks. First, the value added data follows the census definition rather than the national accounts compatible definition, used by the United States Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). The main difference is that census value added does not deduct some service inputs from gross output in deriving value added. 24 There are no comprehensive international data on manufacturing PPPs. The best-known and most comprehensive PPP information comes from the Heston-Summers International Comparison Project (ICP) as obtained from World Bank "Stars" diskettes.24 In other work, Golub (1999) used the producer durable PPP from Although producer durables are not necessarily representative of all manufacturing, they have several advantages, at least relative to other readily-available options. 21 Second, labor compensation as reported by UNIDO includes fringe benefits such as maternity pay and payment in kind, but excludes employer contributions to social insurance funds and is thus an incomplete measure of labor costs. The UNIDO database is the most comprehensive source of available data, however, especially for developing countries. Other Variables Total exports, exchange rates and world and Senegalese real GDP were obtained from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators. The average tariff rate was provided by the Senegalese Département de la Statistique. Senegal’s exports of manufactured goods are derived from the CUCI database. Rainfall data were provided by Stephen O’Connell. 22 References Balassa, Bela, (1963) "An Empirical Demonstration of Classical Comparative Cost Theory,” Review of Economics and Statistics 4: 231-238. Berg, Elliot et al, (1997) L’Aide au Développement du Secteur Privé au Sénégal : Considérations Stratégiques , Development Alternatives International, Juin. Berthelemely, Jean-Claude et al, Growth in Senegal: A Lost Opportunity, OCDE Centre de Développement, 1996. Bowen, Harry P., Leamer, Edward E., and Sviekauskaus, Leo, (1987) “Multi-country, Multi-factor tests of the Factor Abundance Theory,” American Economic Review, 77: 791-809. Carlin, W., Glyn, A. and Van Reenen, J., (2001) “Export Market Performance of OECD Countries: An Empirical Examination of the Role of Cost Competitiveness,” The Economic Journal, 111 (January): 128-162. Caves, Richard E., Jeffrey A. Frankel and Ronald W. Jones (1999), World Trade and Payments (New York: Addison Wesley), 8th edition. Collier, Paul and Jan Willem Gunning (1999) “Why Has Africa Grown Slowly,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 13 (3) Summer: 3-22. Collier, Paul (1997) “Globalization: Implications for Africa,” paper presented at IMF-AERC Seminar on Trade Reforms and Regional Integration in Africa, December. Davis, Donald. and Weinstein, David (2001), “An Account of Global Factor Trade,” American Economic Review 91 (5) December 1423-1453. Deardorff, Alan (1985), "Testing Trade Theories and Predicting Trade Flows," in Ronald W. Jones and Peter B. Kenen, eds., Handbook of International Economics, Vol. I, Amsterdam: North Holland: 467-517. Devarajan, Shatayanan, (1997) “Real Exchange Rate Misalignment in the CFA Zone,” Journal of African Economies, 6 (1): 35-53 Dollar, David (1992), “Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly,” Economic Development and Cultural Change: 523-544. Dornbusch, Rudiger (1980), Open Economy Macroeconomics, (Basic Books). Dornbusch., Rudiger, Stanley Fischer, and Paul Samuelson (1977), “Comparative Advantage, Trade and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods” American Economic Review 67 December: 823-839. 23 Ebin, Victoria (1992), “Les Commercants Mourides a Marseille et a New York,” Politique Africaine, Mars 1992. Edwards, Sebastian (1989), Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation and Adjustment, (Cambridge: MIT Press). Edwards, Sebastian (1993), “Openess, Trade Liberalization, and Growth in Developing Countries,” Journal of Economic Literature 31 (3) September: 1358-1393. Engle, R.F. and C.W.J. Granger. (1987). Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica 55: 251-276. Foreign Investment Advisory Service (FIAS) (1999), Senegal: Le Parcours de l’Investisseur, Dakar. Golub, Stephen and Ahmadou Ali Mbaye (2000), “Obstacles to Export-Led Growth in Africa: Industry Case Studies in Senegal,” in process. Golub, Stephen and Chang-Tai Hsieh (2000), “The Classical Theory of Comparative Advantage Revisited,” Review of International Economics 8 (2) May: 221-234. Golub, Stephen S. (1994), "Comparative Advantage, Exchange Rates, and Sectoral Trade Balances of Major Industrial Countries,” IMF Staff Papers 41: 286-313. Golub, Stephen (1999), Labor Costs and International Trade, American Entreprise Institute. Granger, C.W.J. and P. Newbold. (1986). Forcasting Economic Time Series. Second edition, Academic Press , Inc, Orlando, Florida. Jones, Ronald W. (1980) "Comparative and Absolute Advantage," Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics 3: 235-260. Hinkle Lawrence E. and Fabien Nsengiyumva (1999), “External Real Exchange Rates: Purchasing Power Parity, the Mundell Fleming Model, and Competitiveness in Traded Goods,” in Exchange Rate Misalignment: Concepts and Measurement, edited by Lawrence Hinkle and Peter Montiel, World Bank. Hooper, Peter M. and Kathryn A. Larin (1989), "International Comparisons of Labor Costs in Manufacturing,” Review of Income and Wealth 35: 335-355. Latreille, Thierry and Aristomene Varoudakis (1996) “Croissance et Competitivité de l’Industrie Manufacturière au Sénégal,” OECD Development Centre Technical Paper No. 134, October. Lindauer, David L. and Michael Roemer (1994), Asia and Africa: Legacies and Opportunities in Développement, (San Francisco: ICS Press). MacDougall, G.D.A. (1951), "British and American Export: A Study Suggested by the Theory of Comparative Costs, Part I," Economic Journal 61: 697-724. 24 Mann, Catherine (1988), "Lift off: The Next Generation of NICs", International Economy, Nov/Dec. Mbaye, Ali Ahmadou (1998), Promotion des Exportations et Croissance du PIB dans une Petite Economie Ouverte: le Cas du Sénégal. Unpublished doctoral thesis, CERDI, Université de Clermont Ferrand 1. France. Ndulu, Benno J. and Stephen A. O’Connell (1999), “Governance and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 13, Summer: 41-66. Rama, Martin (2000) “Wage Misalignment in CFA Countries: Were Labour Market Policies to Blame,” Journal of African Economies, Vol 9, No. 4, pp. 475-511. Rodriguez,Francisco, and Dani Rodrik (1999), “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-National Literature,” NBER Working Paper 7081, April. Sachs Jeffrey and Andrew M. Warner (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Papers (1): 1-118. Sachs, Jeffrey and Andrew M. Warner (1997), “Sources of Slow Growth in African Economies,” Journal of African Economies, October: 335-376 Sekkat, Khalid and Aristomene Varoudakis (1998), “Exchange Rate Management and Manufactured Exports in Sub-Saharan Africa,” OECD Development Centre Technical Paper No. 134, March. Soderling, Ludvig (2000), “Dynamics of Export Performance, Productivity and Real Effective Exchange Rate in Manufacturing: The Case of Cameroon,” Journal of African Economies 9 (4): 411-429. Stern, Robert M. (1962), "British and American Productivity and Comparative Costs in International Trade,” Oxford Economic Papers 14: 275-303. Trefler, Daniel., (1993). “The Case of Missing Trade and Other Mysteries”. American Economic Review, 85: 1029-46. Turner, Anthony G. and Stephen S. Golub (1997), “Multilateral Unit-Labor-Cost-Based Competitiveness Indicators for Advanced, Developing, and Transition Countries,” Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, International Monetary Fund, December. Turner, Philip and Joseph Van't dack (1993), "Measuring International Price and Cost Competitiveness," Bank for International Settlements Economic Papers, No. 39, November. Tybout, James (2000) “Manufacturing Firms in Developing Countries: How Well Do They Do and Why?” Journal of Economic Literature 38 (1), March: 11-44. World Bank (1997) “Senegal: The Challenge of International Integration”, unpublished document, December. 25 Table 1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix of Variables Annual Data, 1970-1998a LEXTOT LEXMAN LWGDP LRULC(-1) lrainfall LTARIFF Mean 2.40 4.10 13.33 0.92 8.72 -1.72 Median 2.41 4.10 13.33 0.92 8.84 -1.72 Maximum 2.53 4.41 13.50 1.15 9.04 -1.40 Minimum 2.11 3.83 13.13 0.71 5.82 -2.12 Std. Dev. 0.07 0.16 0.11 0.14 0.59 0.17 Skewness -2.09 0.12 -0.14 0.00 -4.55 -0.41 Kurtosis 10.76 2.08 1.89 1.68 22.79 2.88 Jarque-Bera 93.83 0.87 1.57 2.04 533.55 0.80 Observations 29 23 29 28 27 28 Correlation matrix LEXTOT 1 LEXMAN 0.56 1 LWGDP -0.32 -0.76 1 LRULC(-1) -0.47 -0.47 0.56 1 LRAINFALL -0.04 -0.22 -0.048 -0.15 1 LTARIFF -0.31 -0.64 0.6 0.63 -0.16 1 ADF unit root stat on first differences -4.49 -3.77 -4.08 -4.28 -11.53 -4.41 a 1974-1996 for manufactured exports. List of Variables LEXTOT: log of total real exports LEXMAN: log of real manufactured exports LWGDP: log of world real GDP LRULC(-1) : log of relative unit labor cost index, lagged one period LRAINFALL: log of annual rainfall LTARIFF: log average tariff rate DROUGHT: dummy variable for years of drought D9498: dummy for the years following the 1994 devaluation (1994-1998) 26 Table 2 Regression Equations for Total Exports (Models 1-4), Manufactured Exports (5-7), and Error Correction Models for Total Exports (8) and Manufactured Exports (9) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Model 9 LEXTOT LEXTOT LEXTOT LEXTOT LEXMAN LEXMAN LEXMAN D(LEXTO T) D(LEXMA N) Intercept 3.67 (1.90) 3.36 (1.49) 0.32 (1.57) 3.23 (1.29) 17.72 (4.96) 16.68 (4.06) 13.54 (2.30) - 0.036 (0.71) LRULC(-1) -0.22** (-1.98) -0.23*** (-1.77) -0.22*** (-1.97) -0.23*** (-1.76) -0.558* (-3.18) -0.51* (-2.56) -0.71* (-2.88) - - LWGDP -0.08 (0.54) -0.058 (-0.39) -0.046* (-2.94) -0.042 (-0.21) -0.98* (-3.57) -0.91* (-3.03) -0.65 (-1.44) - - -0.014 (0.18) - - - -0.08 (-0.53) - - - - - - - - - -0.082 (-0.89) - - - - 0.020 (0.71) - - - - - - - - - -0.005 (-0.24) - - - - - - - - - - - - -0.28** (-2.02) 0.39*** (-1.89) - - - - - - - -0.087 (-0.10) -3.74 (-0.93) - - - - - - -1.05* (-5.08) -0.92* (-4.06) 0.26 2.05 4.46 0.21 1.53 0.26 2.04 2.73 0.23 1.58 0.27 2.15 3.08 0.30 0.O3 0.72 1.75 26.42 0.26 1.72 0.72 1.69 17.09 0.48 1.67 0.73 1.80 17.71 0.26 1.52 0.53 1.99 13.67 0.11 3.16 0.55 1.93 7.55 0.52 1.95 Dependant Variable Estimates LTARIFF D9498 DROUGHT RAINFALL D(LRULC(-1)) D(LWGDP) RESID(-1) - - Statistics R2 DW F-stat B-G(nR2)b MAPEa 0.26 2.05 2.60 0.20 1.62 a=Mean Absolute Percent Error b=Breusch-Godfrey Statistics t stats in parentheses *significant at 1% level, ** at 5% level, *** at 10% level. 27 Figure 1 Real GDP per Capita, $1995 12000 10000 8000 1960 1985 1997 6000 4000 2000 0 Korea Malaysia Chile Mauritius Tunisia Senegal Figure 2 Export Growth, Annual Average Percentage Change 25 20 15 19 60-84 19 85-97 10 5 0 Korea Malaysia Chile Mauritius Tunisia Senegal 28 Figure 3 Senegal’s Labor Productivity and Wages, Relative to Selected Competitors, Manufacturing Sector Senegal/Thailand 3.50 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 0.00 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 Senegal/ Malaysia 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 0.00 19 78 19 80 19 82 19 84 19 86 19 88 19 90 19 92 19 94 19 96 Senegal/Korea 1.60 1.20 0.80 0.40 0.00 19 78 19 80 19 82 19 84 19 86 Rela tive Pro ductivity 19 88 19 90 19 92 Rela tive Wages 19 94 19 96 29 Figure 3, continued Senegal/South Africa 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 Senegal/Mexico 1.80 1.50 1.20 0.90 0.60 0.30 0.00 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 Senegal/Mauritius 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.00 19 78 19 80 19 82 19 84 19 86 Rela tive Pro ductivity 19 88 19 90 19 92 Rela tive Wages 19 94 19 96 30 Figure 3, continued Senegal/India 6.0 0 5.0 0 4.0 0 3.0 0 2.0 0 1.0 0 0.0 0 197 8 198 0 198 2 198 4 198 6 Relative Productivity 198 8 199 0 199 2 Relative Wages 199 4 199 6 31 Figure 4 Senegal 's Wages and Producti vity, Manufacturi ng Sector Relative to Sel ected Competitors 1991-93 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 Malaysia Mexico Korea Mauritius India 1994-96 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 Malaysia Mexico Korea Productivity Mauritius Wages India 32 Figure 5 Senegal Real Exports/Real GDP v. Inverted Relative Unit Labor Cost Index 120 35 100 30 80 60 25 40 20 20 0 15 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 Relative Unit Labor Cost Index real exports /Real GDP 33 Figure 6 Senegal Real Manufactured Exports/Real GDP v. Inverted Relative Unit Labor Cost Index 120 30 100 25 80 20 60 15 40 10 20 5 0 0 197 4 197 6 197 8 198 0 198 2 198 4 198 6 198 8 199 0 199 2 199 4 199 6 Relative Unit Labor Cost Index real mfg X/real GDP