CONSORTIUM FOR ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL RESEARCH AFRICA GROWTH INITIATIVE PROJECT SOCIAL PROTECTION, POVERTY AND DEVELOPMENT IN SENEGAL November 2013 RESEARCH PAPER Mbaye Diene 1 Contents 1. INTRODUCTION.................................................................................................................4 2. SOCIO-DEMOGRAPHIC CONTEXT AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE ................... 7 2.1 A brief history from 1960 to 2000 ........................................................................................................7 2.2. From the year 2000 .............................................................................................................................9 2.2.1 The socioeconomic situation .........................................................................................................9 2.2.2 The economic policies and performances .................................................................................. 10 3. THE PARADOX OF GROWTH AND RECENT STRATEGIES TO ALLEVIATE POVERTY................................................................................................................................ 12 4. SOCIAL PROTECTION IN SENEGAL ............................................................................. 13 4.1 The government scheme ................................................................................................................... 15 4.2. The basic scheme for the private sector ........................................................................................... 16 4.3. The supplementary scheme for the private sector’s managers........................................................ 16 4.4 Social assistance ................................................................................................................................ 16 5. THE MEASURE OF VULNERABILITY ........................................................................... 17 5.1 Vulnerability to poverty ..................................................................................................................... 18 5.2 Conceptual framework ...................................................................................................................... 20 5.3 Applications ....................................................................................................................................... 21 6. OVERALL POVERTY AND VULNERABILITY IN SENEGAL..................................... 22 2 List of abbreviations DFES: Direction of Forecast and Economic Studies DESP: Document of Economic and Social Policy FGT: Foster Greer Thorbecke Poverty Index NASD: National Agency for Statistics and Demography NRF: National Retirement Fund NSSP: National Strategy for Social Protection (NSSP). PRGF: Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility PRSP: Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper SHS I: Senegalese Household Survey, 1995 SHS II: Senegalese Household Survey, 2001 SPPS: Survey on the Perception of Poverty in Senegal UNDP: United Nations Development Program 3 1. INTRODUCTION Since 2001, Senegal has been ranked among the group of least developed countries (LDCs). This coastal West African nation’s neighbors are five other countries: Gambia, Mauritania, Mali, Guinea and Guinea-Bissau to the south. Since it . It has a 700-kilometer coastline, the country has made seaside tourism a national priority and fishing and tourism become the two biggest contributors to GDP. Senegal has a gross national income (GNI) per capita of $1,070 in 2011 (World Bank, 2013; see also UNDP, 2013). Its low development status is due primarily to its structurally quite weak economy and lack of the institutional and physical infrastructure. In the early years of independence, part of that structural weakness could be attributed to political uncertainties. However, since the mid-1980s, the country has engaged in political reforms that have deepened its democratic system and brought about a significant level of stability. Yet, the country is confronted with a series of economic and social problems that have forced the government to continue to intervene. These problems include poverty, severe inequality in the distribution of income and wealth, illegal immigration, climate change, large government budget deficits and bureaucratic corruption. Unfortunately, government intervention has not had a significant positive overall impact on human development, as evidenced by Senegal’s 2011 rank of 155 out of 187 countries in the United Nations Development Programme’s (UNDP) Human Development Index (UNDP, 2011: 144). In addition, the international business community has downgraded Senegal’s overall business environment, placing Senegal at 157 out of 183 countries surveyed (World Bank, 2012: 5). The same survey shows that Senegal has one of the least favorable business environments in all of sub-Saharan Africa (World Bank, 2012: 5). The structure of the Senegalese economy is not significantly different from those of its West African neighbors, all of which are developing countries. It is marked by persistent poverty, a very large informal sector, severely inadequate infrastructure, and high rates of unemployment, especially among urban youth and rural inhabitants. Additionally, the private sector is relatively underdeveloped and unable to create enough jobs for the many young people who are graduating from the country’s relatively vibrant secondary and higher education systems. Due to various structural problems in the economy, which include corruption, difficulties in accessing production inputs, inadequate access to credit and bureaucratic rigidities, entrepreneurship is stunted, and, as a result, fewer and fewer businesses are being created each year. 4 Besides economic problems, the people of Senegal also suffer from various social ills, which, during the last several years, have been exacerbated by soaring global commodity prices, especially for items that the country must import, such as oil. Senegal’s present socioeconomic situation is mainly a result of rising oil prices, a sharp decline in migrant workers’ remittances and the failure of the country to attract international development aid and foreign direct investment. In February 2012, Senegal successfully undertook peaceful regime change and a new liberal regime came to power. Such a peaceful transfer of power strengthened the country’s democratic credentials, and the Senegalese people expect that the new regime will put in place effective policies to enhance investment (including that from foreign sources) and mainly promote job creation. The new, more stable political environment should also enhance the inflow of foreign investment. The new authorities, including the current President, are former members of the political party that prevailed before. The actual President was even Prime Minister of the former regime. So he probably does not object to most of the economic policies pursued by the former regime, especially the poverty reduction policies. Since Senegal gained independence from France in 1960, the government has produced economic plans designed to ensure social stability and enhance the country’s economic performance. Although post-independence economic planning has achieved some success in transforming the economy, there are still major challenges, most of which can be found in the key sectors of agriculture and energy. In the 1970s, there were severe droughts throughout most of rural Senegal that had a significantly negative impact on farm production. At the same time, government programs to support rural agriculture were terminated as part of the government’s effort to liberalize the economy. The government’s withdrawal of the many programs that were designed to support rural agricultural populations created a situation that encouraged the mass exodus of young people from rural areas. In addition, many farmers were no longer able to access critical inputs for production—the lack of access to financial resources made it very difficult for farmers to purchase necessary equipment, as well as inputs such as fertilizer. The net effect was a sector afflicted by declining output and increased levels of poverty. Concerning the energy sector, the National Electric Energy Company is still unable to provide quality services to customers, primarily due to the obsolescence of its facilities, some of which date back to the 1960s and are not able to meet the demands of a more modern, diversified and 5 complex economy effectively. The government of Senegal continues to subsidize what has failed to evolve into a modern, well-managed and productive public utility. Although the Senegalese economy is relatively diverse, it remains extremely vulnerable to external influences, which include natural disasters, global price instability, and fluctuations in foreign aid and direct investment flows. The rural agricultural sector, which employs a significant part of the country’s labor resources, is highly vulnerable to changes in global commodity prices and variations in annual rainfall. In 2011, Senegal suffered a significant reduction in agricultural production despite the fact that the sector had done quite well in 2010. For example, the contribution of food crops to the GDP decreased from 6.1 percent in 2010 to 4.6 percent in 2011 and that of industrial agriculture fell from 2.5 percent in 2010 to 1.3 percent in 2011 (NASD, 2011: 186). This decline was due mainly to the sector’s inherent weaknesses, which include its total dependence on rain-irrigated farming techniques and low rainfall during that time. In addition, farmers faced significant reductions in inputs, primarily the seeds and equipment distributed to them by various sources, including the government (DFES, 2012: 6). Today, there are calls from many observers, including the international donor community, that the government of Senegal develop and implement necessary policies to significantly improve productivity in the agricultural sector. The industry sector, which accounts for as much as 24 percent of the GDP, revolves around the extraction and processing of phosphates; food processing; and the construction and cement industries. The construction and cement industries are supported primarily by investments made by Senegalese nationals living abroad and by the government. Many Senegalese living abroad are heavily invested in the construction industry—they dominate the market for housing rentals. They send money home to relatives who build houses that are then rented out to individuals and businesses. Remittances from these overseas Senegalese have become a very important contributor to the country’s GDP. Senegal’s Direction of Forecast and Economic Studies (DFES) estimates that remittances in 2011 and 2012 amounted to about 702.5 billion CFA francs and 737.7 billion CFA francs, respectively (DFES, 2012). A survey conducted by the Central Bank of West African States (Banque Centrale des États de l’Afrique de l’Ouest—BCEAO) and the National Agency for Statistics and Demography (Agence Nationale de la Statistique et de la Démographie) in 2011 on the remittances of migrants from the Dakar regions of Diourbel and 6 Louga showed that the remittances of migrants recorded in these three regions are estimated at 395.2 billion CFA francs and that 89.11 percent of this amount passed through the formal sector. On the basis of statistics collected monthly from the banks, these three regions account for 56 percent of the remittances in Senegal (BCEAO, 2011: 35). The secondary sector was very vibrant in 2011, thanks partly to improvements in the supply of electricity, which came as a result of the “Takkal”1 plan and the revival of the company named Chemical Industries of Senegal (CIS). The industry of energy is very important to the Senegalese economy and is considered socially sensitive in the country because the frequent power cuts often cause uprisings in the major cities of the country. Thus, a variety of welltargeted and special public policies have been implemented to help enhance the productivity and effectiveness of the energy sector. The objective of the paper is to study the role of social protection in Senegal. For this aim, we primarily present the socio-demographic and the economic characteristics of the country. Secondly, we present the role of growth in the attempt to alleviate poverty. Thirdly, after a description of the formal social protection schemes existing in Senegal, we analyze and decompose the vulnerability. The aim is to show how social protection can help reduce households’ vulnerability. 2. SOCIO-DEMOGRAPHIC CONTEXT AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE An examination of the evolution of economic policies in Senegal shows that, between 1960 and 2012, the economy went through changes derived from various types of programs initiated by the government in four phases. 2.1 A brief history from 1960 to 2000 From 1960 to 1980, the production of groundnuts (peanuts) was instrumental in improving the living standards of the populations, notably rural women. In fact, income from the sale of groundnuts was the main driving force behind improvements in other sectors of the economy. During this phase, national planning was the country’s main instrument of economic policy. 1 “Takkal” means lightening in the local Wolof language. This plan has gained widespread support from Senegal’s development partners and has contributed to the significant reduction of power cuts in the country. 7 From 1980 to 1990, Senegal was faced with new challenges, including natural disasters, which forced the government to intervene directly in the economy, by investing, and creating national companies. The government adopted a stabilization program and followed it with IMFmandated structural adjustment programs (SAPs). Implementation of the latter, however, produced unexpected adverse social effects such as increases of income inequality and higher rates of poverty, especially among rural inhabitants. Social expenditures were drastically reduced, Senegalese women successfully organized a march through the center of Dakar to protest high prices, most of which were a direct result of the country’s decision to liberalize markets and eliminate government subsidies, especially to the poor. In terms of education, the implementation of structural adjustment programs in that period largely caused deterioration in the quality of elementary education because of the significant reduction of public investments in the sector. In fact, the quality of education declined so much that many parents, particularly the well-to-do, abandoned public schools and registered their children in private schools. In terms of health, the reduction of government spending, especially on public hospitals and clinics, seriously affected the functioning of national health facilities. Many of them lacked equipment and drugs, forcing sick people to come to public hospitals with their own drugs. Child mortality remained high, and diseases such as malaria, diarrhea and pneumonia became pervasive, and tuberculosis continued to spread. Historically vulnerable groups—women, infants and children—were the most affected by the deteriorating health conditions in the country. The devaluation of the CFA franc in 1994, boosted competitiveness and growth in the economy. The devaluation of the CFA franc was supported by the international donor community, especially since this was followed by a dismantling of government price controls and subsidies. However, the devaluation produced significant social upheaval as the price of many essential goods, all of which were imported (e.g., milk, rice, fertilizer and machinery) increased significantly. Nevertheless, the reform program significantly improved economic performance, leading to growth rates in GDP that averaged more than 5 percent during the 1995-2004. 8 2.2. From the year 2000 Since 2000 significant changes appear to the country’s political economy. The ruling Socialist Party (Parti socialiste) lost the presidential election to a new capitalist regime, which now faced a host of enduring social challenges, such as poverty, inequality, illegal immigration and floods in urban areas. During this phase, Senegal launched a series of budget and financial reform programs. While trying to address the critical issues facing the nation, and despite the mixed social and economic results, the authorities still aimed to turn Senegal into an emerging economy within a 10-year period through the implementation of national and regional projects. However, major problems and challenges including a weak private sector, lack of adequate infrastructure, low competitiveness and the recurrence of external shocks (floods, droughts, fluctuating prices of food and oil products and international economic and financial crises) constrained the execution of these economic policies. 2.2.1 The socioeconomic situation Since independence in 1960, Senegal’s population has grown significantly, which has been a major concern for the country’s policymakers. Senegal’s population jumped from approximately 3 million inhabitants in 1960 to about 12.9 million in 2010, 2 representing an annual average growth rate of 3 percent. Senegal’s present population is very young and mostly rural, with 64 percent of it under 25 years old and 57 percent living in rural areas. According to figures released by the National Agency for Statistics and Demography (NASD), the current unemployment rate of 49 percent among young people, most of whom have no access to basic education, is especially worrying. A significant proportion of the unemployed are restless urban youth who are likely to engage in illegal activities such as drug consumption. Most of Senegal’s population is rural and suffers from relatively high illiteracy rates, especially among women. However, rural-to-urban migration continues to increase. The nation’s capital, Dakar, now accounts for about a quarter of the country’s population, representing some 3.4 million people. This population includes a large group of people coming not only from rural areas, but also from countries of the sub-region, particularly Mali and Niger. While most of the 2 See NASD (2010). 9 men migrating to Dakar are looking for jobs, women usually come to the capital city to join their families. According to the Senegalese Households Survey II (SHS II) of 2002, the average age of migrant men and women is 21.8 years and 22.6 years respectively. According to the same survey, the proportion of youth in the total population has increased sharply, with 55.6 percent of the population now consisting of people under 20 years of age. The country’s relatively high population growth rate is expected to inevitably impact the social and economic life of the country. With increased life expectancy and high population growth, the economy is likely to have problems creating jobs for everyone who wants to work, as well as providing for the healthcare needs of a much older population. 2.2.2 The economic policies and performances As early as 2000, policymakers in Senegal became concerned with poverty alleviation and launched a program called Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF), which ended in 2002. It is worth to note that the Government of Senegal became concerned with poverty alleviation very recently and was not in the period of 1990’s. In 2003, a new PRGF was signed for a threeyear period (2003-2005). The implementation of the programs of the second PRGF, significantly increased Senegal’s economy and macroeconomic stability, as shown by the following indicators: Inflation: The government made significant progress in improving price stability. By the end of the last PRGF, in 2005, the inflation rate had fallen to 2.2 percent from 2.61 percent in 2000. By 2003-2005, the inflation rate stood at 1.7 percent. It rose to 6 percent between 2007 and 2008 because of the the international crisis of 2008, but it diminished by 0.9 percent. Over the period 2000 to 2012, average inflation rate fell to only 2 percent (DFES, 2011: 5). Economic Growth: The period 2000-2002 was marked by growth in real GDP of 2.8 percent. Between 2003-2005, real GDP grew at a rate of 6.1 percent, but fell to an average annual rate of 3 percent during the 2006-2010 period. GDP was projected to grow at a rate of 4 percent and 4.2 percent in 2011 and 2012 respectively (AfDB, et al., 2012: 4). State Budget: In terms of public financial management, there have been significant improvements in the tax system, as the tax base has significantly increased as in more 10 formal sector jobs. As a result, tax revenues increased from nearly 16.1 percent of GDP in 2000 to 18.8 percent in 2010 and to respectively, 19.5 percent and 19.7 percent in 2011 and 2012, (AfDB et al., 2012: 6). Compared to their levels in 1994, budget revenues tripled in 2011. During the period, 2000-2002, the budget deficit was approximately 12 percent of GDP. However, during the 2003-2005 fiscal years, the budget deficit had fallen to only 6 percent of GDP. By 2010, it had fallen to below 5 percent. Public expenditures rose sharply from 18.1 percent of GDP in 2000 to 28 percent in 2010 and 28.9 percent in 2012 (AfDB, et al., 2012: 6). Even if Senegal’s economic performances are related to the government policies, it is important to remember that the country did also receive significant assistance from the international community, notably, from its international development partners. For example, in 2010 and 2011, Senegal received $1.016 billion and $928 million net official development assistance from all donors—representing 2.3 percent and 2.08 percent, respectively, of all official aid flows to countries in sub-Saharan Africa (World Bank, 2013: 117). On the whole, most people in Senegal remain relatively poor despite the fact that the proportion of poor people has been falling. It fell from 61.4 percent in 1995 to 48.5 percent in 2002 and to 40 percent in 2006, according to consecutive Senegalese Households Surveys I and II (SHS I was completed in 1995 and SHS II in 2002), and the Survey on the Perception of Poverty in Senegal (SPPS) of 2006. Importantly, the SPPS shows that 65 percent of the surveyed households considered themselves as poor, while 23 percent of these poor households felt they were very poor. In addition, 64 percent of households believed that poverty had worsened over the past five years. Poverty is widespread in rural areas, where its rate varies between 72 percent and 88 percent. In urban settings, it varies from 44 percent to 59 percent. This situation raises questions about the effectiveness of the poverty reduction policies initiated and implemented so far by the government of Senegal. In conclusion, from the economic plan adopted in 1960 to the structural adjustment policies of the 1980s and 1990s to the new sets of policies developed from 2000 to reduce poverty and accelerate economic growth, the country went through several economic and social hardships. This led the former President Wade’s administration (from 200 to 2012) to re-examine their approach to policy design and implementation. Specifically, the government adopted a more participatory approach to public policy—opportunities were provided for stakeholders to provide 11 input into the development of policies and to take a more active role in implementation. Efforts were made to streamline implementation methods and make them more efficient. Perhaps, more important, is the fact that emphasis was also placed on reforming and generally improving economic and political governance. Currently, Senegal is embarking upon three major economic programs: (i) the development of the third Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP III, from 2011 to 2015); (ii) the formulation of the Document of Economic and Social Policy (DESP); and (iii) the formalization of the prospective vision of Senegal in 2025 ( this one is different from “Vision 2025” of the East African countries). These policies include social safety nets. In this paper, we analyze households’ economic characteristics and show how they explain, quite well, the vulnerability of the many Senegalese households to various risks, including the probability of falling into poverty and remaining there permanently, losing one’s job, and failing to secure reliable sources of food. 3. THE PARADOX OF GROWTH AND RECENT STRATEGIES TO ALLEVIATE POVERTY Growth in GDP during the period 1960-1995 was not enough to deal effectively with poverty and the little public resources available were not allocated in an efficient and equitable manner given the fact that during this period, the country was pervaded by relatively high rates of bureaucratic corruption. Many Senegalese, especially the poor, came to see income distribution as relatively unfair (Diene, 2005: 51). The level of economic growth achieved so far in Senegal is still not enough to deal effectively with the country’s multifarious development problems, the most important of which is poverty. In addition, recent growth has been driven by sub-sectors (oil, fish processing, phosphates and cement production as well as tourism and telecommunications) that currently are not able to supply jobs for all of the country’s labor force. Both the primary and secondary sectors remain seriously underdeveloped and still cannot compete globally in terms of quality and price. The low levels of competitiveness in the domestic economy remain major obstacles to the creation of jobs and the higher incomes that households need to improve their living conditions. In addition, serious weaknesses in the export sector, such as the failure to diversify the export mix, continue to adversely affect the potential for economic growth and, consequently, human development. 12 Macroeconomic instability has continued to affect the ability of many citizens to have access to the critical resources (e.g., credit) that they need to engage in productive activities. The poor are especially at risk because many of them do not own real property, which serves as the traditional collateral for loans in many countries that have poorly developed financial systems. In recent years, many organizations have attempted to remedy this situation by introducing the poor to microcredit, which usually does not require the presentation of collateral by the borrower. However, these micro-lending enterprises, the bulk of which operate in the informal sector, have had difficulties securing enough money to meet the needs of demanders of credit. Prevailing uncertainty in the informal sector, the biggest employer of the poor,,especially with respect to access to credit, continues to threaten efforts to help the poor improve their living conditions. The economic growth in Senegal between 1995-2002 did not favor the poor—it did not occur in areas, such as agriculture, that tend to employ a lot of the poor. The economy also continues to suffer from lack of investment, especially in the sectors that employ the poor. Both the agricultural and industrial sectors remain weak and are unable to expand or diversify because they are not attracting significant investment spending. Although Senegal has recorded relatively good economic performance compared to other countries of comparable size in sub-Saharan Africa, since 2000, it still remains a poor country with important needs in terms of infrastructure and human development still remaining to be met. The country remains one of the poorest countries in the world. As a result, in 2000, Senegal initiated a participatory process for the creation of a poverty reduction strategy based on a fairer redistribution of the proceeds from economic growth and the satisfaction of the poorest population’s basic needs. A consensus has been reached on the necessity to mobilize policymakers, national stakeholders and development partners around the reduction of both poverty and exclusion. 4. SOCIAL PROTECTION IN SENEGAL Social protection is “public actions taken in response to levels of vulnerability, risk and deprivation which are deemed socially unacceptable within a given polity or society,” (Norton, Conway, Foster, 2001: 7). Social protection involves also private entities that aime to help households and individuals who face risks or cannot afford to pay some basic needs. Consequently, the involvement of public and private organizations is the first criterion for 13 identifying social protection actions. But this definition of social protection as public and private organization’s actions, does not take into account important information about individuals’ informal actions, such as migrant workers’ remittances and family solidarity, which are important aspects of people’s lives in Senegal. Social protection applies to the following spheres: Health and medical care: Social protection covers all services used to preserve, establish or improve people's health and ability to work, and satisfy their personal needs; Unemployment benefits: Social protection covers the benefits paid to individuals who have lost their jobs because of sickness or any other involuntary reason; Retirement benefits: Social protection covers all services provided to people who have left the labor market due to their retirement; Benefits of occupational accidents and diseases: Social protection covers compensation for occupational accidents and diseases related to professional activities; Family benefits: Social protection covers support benefits for households to allow them to defray their costs and meet the needs of their members; Maternity benefits: Social protection is provided during pregnancy and after delivery; and Disability benefits: Social protection includes any benefits provided to individuals who are unable to secure paid-employment due to an accident or disease. Generally, benefits for survivors are paid after the death of a protected person to the beneficiaries. By extension, the following group of benefits can be added to the definition of social protection: housing assistance, basic education, a system that helps individuals deal with social exclusion, and social assistance. In Senegal, unemployment and sickness benefits are not often taken into account in social security programs, and the social security component is mainly funded by the formal sector. Although those programs do not cover a great proportion of the population, their overall contribution is relatively high. This is the reason why the government has initiated a social protection program, called the National Strategy for Social Protection (NSSP) aiming that social protection reaches as many people as persons possible. The main objective of the NSSP is the adoption of a comprehensive, integrated and well-coordinated political vision on social protection that will facilitate access to risk management instruments and to social protection systems for the country’s most vulnerable groups. The implementation of the NSSP program will increase the access of vulnerable groups to basic social services and economic opportunities in a fair and 14 sustainable manner. The government hopes that the NSSP will contribute to the attainment of the following specific objectives: (i) expansion and diversification of the instruments of social protection and risk management and (ii) the improvement of the capacity of the various sectors of Senegalese society to respond to shocks and risks, especially the most vulnerable groups— women, rural inhabitants and the urban poor. The implementation of these objectives revolves around five priority intervention areas: Improve access to basic services for vulnerable groups; Increase access to risk management instruments and social protection systems; Improve the targeting, monitoring and evaluation of actions aimed at vulnerable groups; Provide a legal, fair and adequate scheme to vulnerable groups to use to defend their rights; and Strengthen mechanisms for direct transfer of resources to vulnerable groups. The NSSP is supposed to be integrated into the national strategies developed for the reduction of poverty, such as the PRSP. Pension plans have existed in Senegal since the colonial period. However, since independence, the government has introduced many reforms into the pension system and today, the country has a mandatory pension system whose design is based on occupational pension schemes. The present pension system in Senegal consists of three schemes: The National Retirement Fund (NRF), which serves the retirement needs of government officials; the Senegalese Provident Retirement Institution, General Scheme (SPRI-GS), whose participation is limited exclusively to private-sector workers; and the Supplementary Scheme for Managers (SPRI-SSM), which is also a scheme for workers in the private sector. 4.1 The government scheme The National Retirement Fund (NRF) is run by the Directorate of Pay, Pensions and Annuities at the Economy and Finance Ministry. It pays retirement, disability and survivors’ benefits, as well as other benefits related to family allowances. NRF was created by Law No. 6135 of 15 June 1961 and covers the following categories of people: Officers of the civil service and agents of the Railway Board under former statutes; 15 Judges; Regular staff of higher educational institutions; Firefighters; Customs and Police Officers; Military personnel of the Armed Forces and the Firefighters; and Widows and orphans of the above categories. 4.2. The basic scheme for the private sector Private-sector employees are covered by a pension scheme managed by the Senegalese Provident Retirement Institution (SPRI). Under the SPRI, retirees receive a payment based on contributions made by them and their employers during the employee’s working life, after allowance is made for the payment of management fees. The pensions of a given period are funded by the levy imposed on the income earned during the same period. Hence, there exists a relationship between the number of contributors and the number of recipients. In order to obtain a pension, one must be at least 55 years old, have ceased work and recorded at least 400 retirement points. The number of points is estimated by dividing the amount of the contributions by a reference wage. This wage is set annually by the Directorate of the SPRI.. 4.3. The supplementary scheme for the private sector’s managers This pension plan is also managed by SPRI and it complements the basic scheme. It covers up to three times the ceiling of the basic plan SPRI but many features are common to both systems. The employers’ contributions are equal to 3.6 percent of their wages, and the employees’ contributions, represent 2.4 percent of their wages. It is necessary to have contributed a minimum of one year to be eligible for the benefits of the plan. In addition, as for the basic plan, one must have completed at least 400 points to get the benefits. 4.4 Social assistance Although there is a great lack of data on social protection in Senegal, recent information collected from the Social Security Fund (SSF) by the National Agency for Statistics and Demography 16 (2010) can provide insight into the scope of social assistance in the country. The SSF is a private structure providing public services to Senegalese people. It allows many people in Senegal to be able to pay for their basic needs. It is composed of 14 branches, eight regional institutions, and two centers for maternal and child health. Its expenditures in 2010 in different social sectors were: (i) Family benefits Family benefits cover mainly prenatal and maternity expenses. The SSF paid out 9.814 billion CFA francs - equivalent to 20 million USD - in 2010 (NASD, 2010), including 312.5 million CFA francs for prenatal allowances and 878 million CFA francs for maternity benefits. In 2010, there were 439,748 recipients of the SSF against 354,500 persons in 2006 and the main beneficiaries of family benefits are dependent children. (ii) Health and welfare benefits Health and welfare benefits cover both public and private workers and uninsured persons. The benefits are to be used for medical care, vaccinations, supplies of generic drugs and other medical needs. In 2010, the number of beneficiaries rose to 17,186 from 16,213 in 2009. For this program, uninsured persons represent 99 percent of beneficiaries in 2009 and 2010. The total benefits paid out were 151.6 million CFA francs. (iii) Pensions In 2010, the number of pensioners and their heirs was 6,201 people, and they received 2.128 billion CFA francs. These amounts are fixed in advance and regularly paid during a given period. 5. THE MEASURE OF VULNERABILITY Social protection measures can contribute to the alleviation of the various vulnerabilities that individuals encounter on a daily basis and help improve the welfare of the poor, as well as enhance economic growth. It is therefore useful to implement social protection policies that promote better relief of poverty. To improve the impact of social protection measures on poverty, it may be necessary to introduce or reinforce reforms, programs or mechanisms of public and private provision of services. The main objective is to show how the structural economic characteristics of households can explain their vulnerability and their exposure to risk, which justifies their need for protection. The specific objectives are as follows: 17 First, identify the main sources of vulnerability for the population and, second, know the population groups that are exposed to higher vulnerability; For these groups, examine the expected role of social protection, as well as sector-based interventions and macroeconomic levels; Analyze the gaps that social protection coverage can fill in order to reduce higher vulnerability and poverty; and Make policy recommendations. 5.1 Vulnerability to poverty The measures of vulnerability to poverty are presented below. The analysis is based on the permanent income hypothesis developed by Friedman (see, e.g., Lachaud, 2006: 18). Households’ welfare is measured relative to the average inter-temporal living standard. The household faces chronic deprivation when this welfare falls below the poverty line. Welfare can change because of unfavorable and adverse shocks, and the risk of changes makes the household vulnerable. Thus, the vulnerability of a household is the probability of poverty at time t1, regardless of its level of welfare at time t0. Then, as shown in Chaudhuri, Jalan, and Suryahadi (2002:5), the vulnerability of household h at time t can be expressed in terms of future expenditures conditional on its characteristics: (1) where : (i) is the level of per capita expenditure of a household h at time t +1; (ii) Xh, a set of observable socioeconomic characteristics of the household h; (iii) (iv) (v) a vector of parameters describing the state of the economy at time t +1; , time-invariant unobservable effects at the household level; , idiosyncratic shocks inherent to some factors, helping in the differentiation of the household welfare (vi) z is the poverty threshold. It is worth mentioning that it is impossible to directly observe vulnerability: Only current vulnerability with respect to future poverty can be assessed. Thus, the probability of poverty depends not only on the household’s average expected expenditures, but also on the fluctuation of 18 the latter, measured by an inter-temporal variance. It is important to distinguish situations where households are poor because of permanent low welfare from temporary deprivation. Despite the scarcity of panel data, following Chaudhuri, Jalan, and Suryahadi (2002) and under certain assumptions, the availability of cross-sectional data can allow the analysis of households’ vulnerability. The starting point of this option is the analytical expression of the determinants of per capita expenditure for household h, summarized by the following equation: (2) where (i) lnch is the logarithm of the per capita expenditures, (ii) Xh, a set of observable characteristics of the household h, (iii) α, a vector of parameters, and (iv) eh, a random term with zero mean, capturing the idiosyncratic shocks that help to differentiate the standard of living of households (Chaudhuri et al. 2002:7). Equation 2 implies that the shocks related to the expenditures for each household are identically and independently distributed in time. Thus, there is the absence of the specific unobservable effects of households that may influence their expenditure over time. This assumption is dictated by the cross-sectional nature of the available data used. Using Chaudhuri et al.’s approach (2002:8), we consider that the variance of eh can be explained by observable characteristics of households, and we use the simple functional form expressed as follows: (3) Under these conditions, Chaudhuri et al. (2002:7) show that, following Amemiya (1977), parameters can be estimated by generalized least squares (Feasible Generalized Least Squares— FGLS) in three steps. (4) The distribution of the log of the expenditure is linked to the probability that a household with characteristics Xh is poor, that is to say, the extent of the vulnerability of the group h. This is formalized in this way (Chaudhuri. et al. (2002:8): (5) In which is the cumulative density function associated with a normal distribution. For the application, the variables included in the regressions are: household size (level and its square); age of the head of household when it’s greater than 17 years; marital status (whether the head of the household is single, married, divorced, polygamous, monogamous, widowed, etc.); a set of 19 dummies for whether the household head is illiterate, has attended primary school, secondary school or tertiary education; whether the head of the household is a man; the location of the head of household (Dakar, other urban areas, rural areas, etc.); whether he is actively occupied, inactive or jobless; and whether he is a salaried worker in either public or private sector, selfemployed in agriculture, self-employed in non-agriculture sectors, etc. 5.2 Conceptual framework Consider the period t (t = 1 or 2), selected between the years 1995, 2002 and 2006 (years of the household surveys in Senegal). The density functions of the distribution of income in periods 1 and 2 are denoted by f1(y) and f2(y) and let be the joint distribution of incomes and households or individuals’ characteristics X. Denoting by gt (y / X) the distribution of income conditional on X and C (X) the domain of values of X, we can write: (6) The term H t(X) is the joint distribution of all the elements of X at time t. We can express the passage from f1 (y) to f2 (y) through on the distributions gt (y / X) and Ht(X). We define this counterfactual distribution: (7) It is the distribution that would be observed during period 1, if the distribution of income conditional on characteristics X had been observed in period 2. This counterfactual distribution can be calculated if we identify the distributions g1(y / x), g2 (y / x) and H1 (X). By altering the joint distribution of socioeconomic characteristics, we can as well define the counterfactual distribution as follows: (8) Note that the following equalities are true: fg1,2(y) = fH2,1(y) and fH1,2(y) = fg2,1(y) (9) The decomposition of distributional changes (f2 (y) - f1 (y)) is: f2(y) – f1(y) = [fg1,2(y) - f1(y)] + [ f2(y) – fg1,2(y)] (10) 20 The first expression of the second member gives the temporal change of income explained by the change of the conditional distribution on characteristics X. It shows how the distribution of characteristics in period 1 could lead to a different distribution of income, if the distribution g (y/x) were that of period 2. The second term is the effect of changes of the endowments that occurred between periods 1 and 2. It is possible to rewrite the equation (5) as: f2(y) – f1(y) = [fg1,2(y) - f1(y)] + [ f2(y) – fH2,1(y)] (11) This gives a decomposition, which is valid for poverty indices. We will apply this methodology using decomposing the vector of characteristics in sub-categories. The advantage of this decomposition is that it takes into account any distribution of living standards and features, not only the distribution average. More generally, this last decomposition formula can be applied to any statistic defined on a distribution of living standards (income, expenses, etc.) and any measure of inequality and poverty based on poverty thresholds (Bourguignon, et al. 2005). 5.3 Applications We use the above-outlined theoretical approach for the links between the characteristics of heads of households and poverty. At time t = 1 or 2, the income of the individual i is determined by: (12) The counterfactual income values between t = 1 and t = 2 are given by: (13) with i = 1, 2, …N1 These values are obtained by simulating the model (15) on the data available at time t = 1. This shows what would be the income of individual i, if the returns on each characteristic were those observed at time t = 2, rather than those observed at t = 1. The yields of the unobserved characteristics contained in the residuals, terms in the distribution of , are constant. Counterfactual values of the error are a bit trickier to build. To import the distribution of residuals from time t = 2 to t = 1, we use the expression (Bourguignon et al. 2005): (14) for i = 1, 2, ... N1 21 Using these counterfactuals, we can find the estimators of the contribution (to total redistributive change between t = 1 and t = 2) of the variation of the parameters Ω and the distributions of residuals. The effect of changing the distribution of individual endowments X corresponds to the complement of the previous two variations: For the empirical analysis, we build an income generation model that allows for distinguishing between the sources of changes in the distribution of income into three forces. The first force is linked to the changes in the socio-demographic features of the households (named the endowment effects or population effects). It comprises of the changes in the socio- demographic structure of the population as the area of residence, age and household composition. The second one comes from the changes in the returns to factors of production (price effects), comprising changes in the returns to factors of production, such as education and experience. The third one comes from the changes of the occupational structure in the population (occupational effects), in terms of wage work, self-employment, unemployment, inactivity, private sector or public sector. The data used come from the following recent surveys: The Senegalese Survey for Monitoring and Perception of Poverty (SSMP) in 2006 on 13,600 households (8,640 from cities and 4,960 from rural areas). The Senegalese Survey for Monitoring and Perception of Poverty (SSMP) in 2011 on 5,953 households. The former is used to evaluate the impact of the socioeconomic characteristics on poverty, and the latter is used to help in the assessment of high vulnerability. 6. OVERALL POVERTY AND VULNERABILITY IN SENEGAL In Figure 1 we show changes of the aggregate distribution of vulnerability according to the thresholds varying from 0 to 1. The incidence of vulnerability is negatively linked to the threshold, meaning that the proportion of the people who have a high probability of being poor decreases with growth of the threshold. 22 Figure 1: Overall Vulnerability in Senegal Sources: Calculations by the authors using the SSMP survey data of 2011 As stated in Chaudhuri et al. (2002:10), the choice of a vulnerability threshold is quite arbitrary. For this reason we use three significant thresholds. First, we take the incidence of poverty as the poverty rate represents the mean vulnerability level in the population. It helps us measure the relative vulnerability. People who are relatively vulnerable have their probability higher than this mean. Finally, we consider people who are highly vulnerable when their probability of poverty is greater than 75 percent. Note that the level of 50 percent is used in Chaudhuri et al. (2002:11), and we tighten the constraint of high vulnerability. Table 1 (see Appendices) shows that while 41.7 percent of the population is poor, 42.5 percent of it remains vulnerable. In other words, the proportion of vulnerable people who have a probability of being poor in 2012 is greater than the poverty rate in Senegal. We also see that 37.8 percent of the non-poor people are vulnerable, and, of them, 38.23 percent of them are relatively vulnerable and 22.3 percent are highly vulnerable. Thus their probability of being poor in 2012 is higher than 75 percent. More than half of the poor households (58 percent) are vulnerable, and 42.1 percent of them are highly vulnerable. In conclusion, the proportion of the vulnerable population is higher than the proportion of the poor. Social protection programs for the reduction of vulnerability in the population may be more urgent for the 42.1 percent of the population who are poor and highly vulnerable. The poverty and vulnerability profiles in 2011 are presented i n T abl es 2 , 3 a nd 4 i n t he 23 ap pe ndi c es . The estimates for the regions and selected demographic and community characteristics are also presented. The decomposition by regions in Table 2 shows the average distribution of vulnerability. It appears that high vulnerability is greater in the rural regions such as Tambacounda, Kaffrine and Diourbel. The capital, Dakar, is one of the cities where vulnerability is not very high although the city has the greatest proportion of the population shares. The spatial distributions of poverty and high vulnerability are tightly correlated, mainly in urban settings where the population is concentrated. This is the case in the regions of Diourbel, Kaolack, Tambacounda and Kaffrine. On the average, the southern regions (Kolda, Sedhiou and Ziguinchor) face lower vulnerability than those of the north and center of Senegal. Table 3 shows that poverty and vulnerability are more common in rural areas. The share in the population of rural households is high (48.5 percent), but the proportions of vulnerable and high vulnerable people are too disproportionate (respectively 64 and 70 percent) compared to that share. Less than 6 percent of highly vulnerable populations live in the capital Dakar. The main explanation can be found in family solidarity among people coming from the same village—these migrants form family or ethnic communities within the city that serve as a form of social insurance against various economic uncertainties. With regard to the gender of the head of households, we can see that, on average, women have a greater mean vulnerability than men. However, families headed by men are poorer and more vulnerable than those headed by women: 69 percent versus 31 percent. There are significant differences on poverty and vulnerability levels between people depending on the marital status of the heads of household. Not only are the married and monogamous people the poorest and the most vulnerable (61.10% ), but they also represent the greatest proportion of the population (52.71%). Single households are less vulnerable, though they represent a very small portion of the total population of the country. The households whose heads do not have a formal education are highly vulnerable and poor in Senegal. This situation can be related to the fact that the low levels of human capital possessed by these heads of household exclude them from access to jobs in the formal sector. In addition,, because they are forced to exist primarily in the informal sector, they usually are not covered by many public protection programs. The distribution of poverty and vulnerability among the Senegalese people is then linked to the levels of education. People with university training and, 24 hence, significant human capital are disproportionately wealthier and less vulnerable than those who have not been formally educated. According to the area of activity, jobless people are on average, more vulnerable and poorer. But some economically active people who have jobs may still be highly vulnerable, probably because of the uncertainty surrounding the stability of their jobs. Besides, some inactive people, such as retired workers, are not as poor as some economically active ones. Depending on the sector in which the head of household is employed, we can see that people working in the public sector are less vulnerable than workers in either the private or informal sectors. However, independent farmers face both poverty and vulnerability more than any other group in the country. We now turn to the comparisons of the current incomes and their counterfactuals. The idea of the counterfactual income is : what would be the household’s income in the period t1 if he kept the same characteristics as those of the period t0? Figure 2: Distribution of current incomes and estimated incomes Density function Percentage of population Sources: Calculations by the authors using the SSMP survey data of 2011 The density functions of living standards (the logarithm of the equivalent adult expenditure) in 2006 and 2011 are plotted in Figure 2 with their respective counterfactuals. It appears that the distribution of income is more unequal in 2006 than in 2011. The estimated income (named EST_2006 in the graph) is obtained by using the coefficients of the regression of income on the household characteristics, and applying them to the same characteristics in 2006. The same with 25 the variable EST-2011 estimated with the coefficients of 2006. The figure shows that if there were no changes in the households’ characteristics from 2006 to 2011, inequality in the distribution of income would be higher in 2011. Figure 3: The FGT (Foster-Greer-Thorbecke) poverty index curves of current incomes and estimated incomes Poverty Index Poverty Line Sources: Calculations by the authors using the SSMP survey data of 2011 The Foster-Greer-Thorbecke curves are shown in Figure 3, where we plot the poverty incidence with varying levels of poverty lines on the horizontal axis. Poverty is higher in 2006 than in 2011. It appears also that the counterfactual estimation of the income (EST_2006) presents less poverty than the two other distributions. It means that if the characteristics in 2011 were the same as those in 2006, poverty would be more reduced in 2011. In Table 5, we present the mean transfer necessary to compensate the difference between real income in 2006 and the counterfactual income, according to different households’ characteristics. The aim is to identify how, on average, a transfer can reduce poverty from the real situation in 2006 to a situation better than that of 2011. We take the average difference between the income in 2006 and the counterfactual in the same year. There is more need for social intervention in rural areas than in urban zones, on average. As we have previously shown, since households headed by males are more vulnerable than those headed by females, it appears that the former need more economic assistance. Their average-income-transfer-need is approximately 0.49. Households headed by widowed persons also need more transfers. Jobless persons need less assistance than inactive persons or occupied active persons. This may be explained by the fact that although social solidarity provides more benefits to inactive persons (children and the aged) 26 than to jobless people, the latter can seek work in the informal sector where they can have various income sources. We also see that obtaining a post-secondary education is a defense against vulnerability. Households whose heads completed only a primary school education need more assistance. Depending on the regions, it appears that Kolda, Diourbel, Tambacounda and the capital city, Dakar, need more social transfers than the others. 7. CONCLUSION As poverty is a hard-to-control phenomenon, individuals can fall in poverty at any time because of their vulnerability. In this study, we identify the link between vulnerability and the socio-economic characteristics of households in Senegal. The policy implications of this study are that the Senegalese government should design and implement effective intervention programs to minimize the exposure of various groups within the country to poverty, as well as make certain that all Senegalese citizens are provided opportunities to accumulate the human capital they need to reduce their chances of falling into poverty. Since vulnerability is the probability that a household will become poor in the future, we use three thresholds as limits for this probability. First, we take the incidence of poverty, as the poverty rate represents the mean vulnerability level in the population. It helps us measure the relative vulnerability. We also consider the mean vulnerability as a threshold which is compared to the probabilities of people who are deemed vulnerable in average. Finally, the threshold of 75 percent lets identify people who are highly vulnerable. We measure vulnerability to poverty, and then estimate vulnerability using cross-sectional data for 2011. There are more vulnerable people than poor people in Senegal and the government must double its efforts to help both categories of citizens. There is an urgent need to assist people who are likely to fall into poverty, by social protection programs aimed at reducing their vulnerability—these people live mainly in the southern regions and in the rural areas of the country. It is also useful to help people accumulate more human capital because education is an important determinant of people’s vulnerability to various economic shocks. As the results of this study show, less educated heads of household are highly more vulnerable than the formally 27 educated ones. Independent farmers in rural areas face both poverty and vulnerability, more than any other socioeconomic group in the country and need assistance. Thus, government programs should target these groups for support in an effort to help them minimize their chances of falling into poverty. 28 REFERENCES Amemiya, T. (1977), “The Maximum Likelihood and the Nonlinear Three-Stage Least Squares Estimator in the General Nonlinear Simultaneous Equation Model,” Econometrica 45(4): 955-968. AfDB (African Development Bank), OECD, Undp, Eca. (2012) “Senegal” in « Perspectives Economiques en Afrique : Promouvoir l’Emploi des Jeunes » Edition OCDE. France BCEAO (Banque central des états de l’Afrique de l’ouest—Central Bank of West African States) (2011), “Report on the Monetary Policy in WAEMU”. CBWAS, Avenue Abdoulaye FADIGA. BP 3108. Dakar - Senegal. Bourguignon, F., Ferreira, F. and Lustig, N. (2005) (eds.), The Microeconomics of Income Distribution Dynamics in East Asia and Latin America (Washington, D.C.: World Bank). Chaudhuri, S., Jalan, J. and Suryahadi, A. (2002), “Assessing Household Vulnerability to Poverty: A Methodology and Estimates for Indonesia,” Discussion Paper No. 0102-52, Department of Economics, Columbia University, New York: http://academiccommons.columbia.edu/catalog/ac:112942 Diene, M. (2005), “La fiscalité indirecte et les inégalités de revenus au Sénégal,” Thèse de doctorat d’état, Faculté des Sciences Economiques et de Gestion, Université Cheikh Anta Diop (UCAD), Dakar, Senegal. DFES (Direction of Forecast and Economic Studies) (2011), Financial and Economic Situation in 2011 and Perspectives in 2012 (Dakar: DFES and the National Agency for Statistics and Demography). DFES (2012), Balance of Payments of Senegal (Dakar: DFES & NASD). Lachaud, J.-P. (2006), “La croissance pro-pauvres au Burkina Faso: L’éviction partielle de l’axiome d’anonymat en présence de données transversales,” Document de travail 126, Centre d’économie du développement, Université Montesquieu-Bordeaux IV, France. NASD (National Agency for Statistics and Demography) (2011), National Accounts Data, 20052011 Edition (Dakar: Government of Senegal). NASD (2010): National Agency for Statistics and Demography, (Situation économique et sociale du Sénégal. Edition 2010. Dakar 29 Norton, A. Conway, T. Foster, M. (2001) Social Protection Concepts and Approaches: Implications for Policy and Practice in International Development. WP. 143 Centre for Aid and Public Expenditure. Overseas Development Institute. London. UNDP (United Nations Development Program) (2011), Human Development Report, 2011 (New York: Oxford University Press). UNDP (2013), Human Development Report, 2013 (New York: Oxford University Press). World Bank (2012), Doing Business 2012: Doing Business in a More Transparent World (Washington, D.C.: World Bank). World Bank (2013), African Development Indicators 2012/13 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank). Acknowledgments: The author acknowledges Pr. Théophile T. Azomahou, from University of Maastricht whose helpful comments help improve the paper. 30 APPENDICES Table 1: Sources of Vulnerability in Senegal Overall Amongst Amongst Amongst Amongst the non- the poor the the highly vulnerable vulnerable poor Fraction poor 0.4161 0.00 1.00 0.5210 Mean vulnerability 0.4248 0.3499 0.5300 0.5234 Fraction vulnerable 0.4638 0.3786 0.5834 1.00 Fraction relatively 0.4682 0.3823 0.5886 0.9907 Fraction highly 0.3088 0.2281 0.4219 0.6595 vulnerable Sources: Authors’ calculations using the SSMP survey data of 2011 vulnerable 31 0.5686 0.9039 1.00 0.00 1.00 Table 2: Distribution of poverty and vulnerability by regions Population Share of share poor Share of share of Mean vulnerable highly vulnerability vulnerable Regions Dakar 10.06 4.36 8.47 6.42 35.01245 Ziguinchor 6.48 9.49 5.49 5.11 35.9986 Diourbel 7.56 6.86 7.36 8.27 43.31282 Saint-Louis 6.94 5.05 7.39 7.56 46.01953 Tambacounda 8.43 8.92 9.62 10.61 49.02045 Kaolack 7.51 9.08 8.0 8.22 43.89468 Thies 7.54 5.33 7.75 7.34 43.17503 Louga 7.12 3.23 6.78 6.04 39.41618 Fatick 6.75 8.36 6.96 6.96 42.75137 Kolda 6.52 8.92 5.42 5.66 36.99589 Matam 6.03 5.73 6.17 6.37 44.07534 Kaffrine 7.31 8.16 8.9 9.68 51.09296 Kedougou 4.8 6.9 4.92 4.52 42.18715 Sedhiou 6.94 9.61 6.78 7.24 42.4543 Sources: Authors’ calculations using the SSMP survey data of 2011 32 Table 3: Poverty and vulnerability within different segments of the population Population Share of Share of Share of Mean share poor vulnerable highly vulnerability vulnerable Areas Dakar 9.05 4.16 7.71 5.71 35.34803 Other urban Areas 42.40 36.62 28.42 24.05 29.28229 Rural Areas 48.55 59.22 63.87 70.24 55.35328 Sex Male 74.94 81.71 68.68 68.88 39.1787 Female 25.06 18.29 31.32 31.12 52.34334 Marital status Married monogamous 52.71 52.16 57.95 61.10 47.08837 Married polygamous 31.43 34.03 31.04 29.00 40.69663 Single 2.91 2.10 2.01 2.07 29.66415 Widow 10.65 10.01 6.49 5.66 27.96989 Divorcee 2.30 1.70 2.51 2.18 44.50977 Sources: Authors calculations using the SSMP survey data of 2011 33 Table 4: Poverty and vulnerability within different segments of the population Population Share of Share of share of Mean share poor vulnerable highly vulnerability vulnerable Without education 69.17 62.27 80.95 86.69 49,92 Primary education 15.35 16.68 9.20 5.84 24,06 Secondary education 12.02 15.58 7.76 6.00 27,93 Tertiary education 3.46 5.47 2.08 1.47 26,09 Occupation Occupied Active 78.92 78.36 80.30 81.28 42,93 Jobless 0.87 0.97 1.04 1.03 54,02 Inactive 20.21 20.67 18.66 17.68 40,21 Sector of activity Public sector 6.15 2.87 2.62 1.41 19,87 Private sector 7.71 5.77 8.54 6.37 45,33 Independent farmer 22.12 28.18 43.85 53.32 80,97 farmer 14.09 10.70 5.96 4.41 18,60 Other dependant 28.84 30.84 19.34 15.78 29,90 Jobless 21.08 21.64 19.70 18.72 40,79 Independent non- Sources: Authors calculations using the SSMP survey data of 2011 Table 5: Mean transfer necessary to compensate the difference between actual and counterfactual income Areas Regions Dakar 0.3693079 Dakar 0.4812556 Other urban zones 0.2154456 Diourbel 0.4926989 Rural zones 0.7076229 Fatick 0.4810859 34 Gender Kaolack 0.4754445 Male 0.4921629 Kolda 0.4981814 Female 0.4743074 Louga 0.4618572 Matam 0.4812046 Marital status Married monogamous 0.4764527 Saint-Louis 0.4702735 Married polygamous 0.4863342 Tambacounda 0.4900141 Single 0.4713576 Thies 0.4632142 Widowed 0.4684898 Ziguinchor 0.4619211 Divorcee 0.4789237 Occupation Level of Education Without education 0.4214347 Occupied Active 0.6271253 Primary education 0.5294708 Jobless 0.3849538 Secondary education 0.3583651 Inactive 0.484036 Tertiary education 0.1658062 Sources: Authors’ calculations using the SSMP survey data of 2011 35