Governance Inseparability in Franchising: Evidences from Case-Studies in France and Brazil Paulo F. Azevedo* and Professor, Dep. of Economics FGV-EESP pfa@fgvsp.br Vivian L.S. Silva* Prof., Dep. of Food Engineering FZEA-USP vivianlara@hotmail.com Abstract The literature of franchising largely relies on the analysis of the transaction between franchisor and franchisees, sometimes also integrating company-owned outlets in the same investigation. We submit that the appropriate design of franchise contracts depends not only on the features of the transaction between franchisor and franchisees, but also on other transactions undertaken by the franchisor, particularly in upstream contracts, a hypothesis known as ‘governance inseparability’. Moreover, some institutional environment features that affect the choice of governance mechanisms in the supply chain may indirectly influence the design of franchise contracts. In order to explore this hypothesis, this paper presents a discrete structural analysis of 21 case-studies of food franchising in France and Brazil. The cases compare franchise chains in each country that share similar business features – e.g. McDonalds’ operations in France and Brazil – in an attempt to control variables related to the product and franchisors’ strategies. The main findings are the following: a) firms choose a portfolio of governance mechanisms to govern their set of transactions; b) upstream and downstream governance mechanisms are complementary; and c) quality regulation and competition policy restrain upstream governance mechanisms, having an indirect effect on the design of the franchise contracts. 1. Introduction The literature of franchising largely relies on the analysis of the transaction between franchisor and franchisees, sometimes also integrating company-owned outlets in the same investigation. We submit that the appropriate design of franchise contracts depends not only on the features of the transaction between franchisor and franchisees, but also on other transactions undertaken by the franchisor, particularly in upstream contracts, an hypothesis known as ‘governance inseparability’. Moreover, some institutional environment features that affect the choice of governance mechanisms in the supply chain may indirectly influence the design of franchise contracts. In order to explore this hypothesis, this paper presents a discrete structural analysis of 21 case-studies of food franchising in France and Brazil. The cases compare franchise chains in each country that share similar business features – e.g. McDonalds’ operations in France and Brazil – in an attempt to control variables related to the product and franchisors’ strategies. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the main argument of governance inseparability and its consequence to the franchising literature. The third section comprises the results of the analysis of the 21 case-studies. First we explore the effect of the risk of brand name loss on the choice of a portfolio of governance mechanisms. Then we describe the existence of plural forms in the transaction between the franchisor and its outlets and how they are complementary to upstream governance mechanisms. At last we look at the effect of * The authors contributed equally to the writing of the paper. Our sincere acknowledge to FAPESP and CAPES for providing financial support as well to all the franchise chains for making the data available. The usual caveat applies. 1 institutional variables on the choice of a portfolio of governance mechanisms. The last section summarizes the main results and speculates about the consequences for future research. 2. Governance Inseparability and Plural Forms There are several private arrangements to govern transaction hazards. The literature of Transaction Costs Economics (TCE), since Williamson (1985), has had the merit of providing a model that, given the characteristics of a particular transaction, predicts the adopted governance structure. Moreover, transaction dimensions (asset specificity, frequency and uncertainty) are to some extent observable, thereby allowing empirical tests of important TCE propositions. The argument initially presented by Williamson (1985) – and maintained in subsequent works (Williamson, 1991; 1996) – matches transactions dimensions to the choice of a singular governance structure (e.g. market, hybrid or hierarchy), which is arguably the most efficient among the set of possible structures in mitigating transactions costs. However, there is empirical evidence that existing governance arrangements influence the organizational choice of newer transactions (Argyres and Liebeskind, 2002). Inasmuch as governance decisions of each transaction seem to be related to each other, the choice of a particular governance structure can not be analyzed isolatedly, a proposition known in the literature as governance inseparability. Williamson (1985) was already aware of the gains from taking into consideration the whole set of transactions in the analysis of governance structures. In his words, TCE “normally examines each trading nexus separately. Albeit useful for displaying core features of each contract, interdependencies among a series of contracts may be missed or undervalued as a consequence. Greater attention to the multilateral ramifications of contract is sometimes needed” (Williamson, 1985: 393). A more general argument recommends that the choice of a governance structure for a given transaction should be inseparable from all other transactions the firm takes part in. The main argument in the literature states that governance inseparability arises because the existence of several contractual commitments with other parties restricts the decision rights about governance choice (Argyres and Liebeskind, 1999). Those commitments constrain future governance choices because a) they may impede switching to a superior form of governance mechanism if the firm is already engaged in other governance structures in a similar transaction to other parties; and b) they may obliterate governance differentiation since the firm is constrained to use the existing type of governance mechanism in other transactions. In a more recent paper Argyres and Liebeskind (2002) identified a case of constraint on governance differentiation in the biotechnology industry. Inasmuch as past choices restrain present options, both constraints on governance switching and on governance differentiation make history relevant for the organizational strategies. This case of path dependence differs from the one based on increasing returns (Arthur, 1989), for which the timing alters the performance of a governance structure because of gains from, for instance, learning and trust. Since past choices influence present and future decisions, existing governance mechanisms should be taken into account when deciding how to govern a newer transaction. We submit that there is another reason for governance inseparability, which does not need the reference to past decisions. The choice of governance structures for the various transactions undertaken by a firm may be interdependent if there is some synergy between complementary mechanisms of governance. This idea apparently contradicts the original insight of Coase (1937), for whom different coordination mechanisms – in his initial proposition, restricted to market and firm – were alternative ways to govern a given transaction. Even though this insight is still one of the main foundations of TCE, governance 2 inseparability also revels that, besides being alternatives, governance structures may also be complementary. For instance, franchising upstream contracts designed to reduce variability of input quality may attenuate moral hazard effects in the transaction between franchisor and franchisee. The literature of franchising offers some cases where governance structures are complementary and, as a consequence, the choice of governance mechanisms should be inseparable. For example, Gallini and Lutz (1992) show that company-owned outlets signal franchisor relevant characteristics, i.e., vertical integration is complementary to franchising contracts. The literature of tapered vertical integration is also based on the notion of some complementarities between hierarchy and other governance structures. For instance, Azevedo (1996) submits that tapered vertical integration may be adopted to improve bargaining position in a hybrid governance structure. Michael (2000) proposes a similar argument, in which tapered integration permits the acquisition of information about the subsequent production stage1, with consequences on bargaining. What are the consequences of assuming governance inseparability in franchising? The prolific franchising literature focuses on the transaction between franchisor and franchisees, sometimes incorporating company-owned outlets in the analysis. Nevertheless if franchising is subjected to governance inseparability, other governance mechanisms may have an effect on either the design of a franchising contract or the decision to not franchise at all. As a consequence, upstream governance structures employed by a franchisor – such as vertical integration on the production of the inputs required by outlets – are missing variables in several analyses about the determinants of franchising contracts. This may explain why different franchise chains govern similar transactions with different governance structures (different contract design or different proportion of company-owned outlets), provided that they have distinct upstream governance arrangements. 3. Empirical Evidences from Governance Inseparability in French and Brazilian Franchising This section consists of a comparative analysis of a multi-case study of food franchise chains in France and Brazil. As it is usual in multi-case studies (Yin, 1989), the data collection was based on semi-structured interviews with chains managers. We compared 21 case studies (seven in France and 14 in Brazil) concerned with five food franchising sectors: 1) coffee shops, 2) fast food, 3) fine products, 4) grills and 5) sweets & chocolates 2. Cases were selected based on brand name value, according to Aaker (1991) due to their stability and relevance, evolution in franchising (in years) and dispersion. Couples of food franchise chains were selected from the same sectors in each market, with an emphasis on the comparative analysis of McDonald’s in both France and Brazil. Our focus on a comparative analysis between France and Brazil is related to their historical and economic relevance in the international franchising as well differences in their institutional environment, regarding for 1 Riordan (1990) emphasized this role of vertical integration, when he defined it as a change in the information structure. 2 In the French market we investigated the French Grill Courtepaille, La Boucherie (both from grills segment), Jeff de Bruges (chocolates) and Comtesse du Barry (specialized in foie gras, a classic product of French cuisine). The group of cases also included operations in the French market of Segafredo Zanetti, an Italian group of coffee shop, and Quick, a Belgian fast food franchise chain. In Brazil, we analyzed four originally Brazilian coffee shops chains (Fran’s Café, Café Pelé, Café do Ponto (owned by SaraLee) and Casa do Pão de Queijo) besides the also Brazilian Habib’s, China in Box, Vivenda do Camarão (fast foods), Bon Grillê (grills), Kopenhagen (fine sweets & chocolates) and Amor aos Pedaços (sweets & chocolates). Our data set also included Brazilian operations of the American The Nutty Bavarian (sweets & chocolates), Dunkin’Donuts (coffee & donuts) and Arby’s (fast food). Finally we also compared the American McDonald’s (fast food) in both markets, France and Brazil. 3 instance legal system, court decisions, quality regulation, competition policy, social norms and consumption habits. Table 1 details the evolution of each chain, with information on business and franchising experience, internationalization and number of franchised and company-owned units. ‘Take in Table 1’ 3.1. A Portfolio of Mechanisms to Mitigate the Risk of Brand Name Loss Several franchise chains strategies – from the way they organize their transactions to innovation efforts – are designed to deal with the trade-off between the costs of shirking and the risk of brand name loss (under-provision of quality by franchisees3). The higher the value of keeping quality standards, the more likely the efforts the franchise chains will direct to overcome franchisees’ incentives to under-provide quality. Nothing new so far. However, this proposition has strong implications on the organizational choice, in both downstream (franchiser-franchisees) and upstream (supply chain) transactions. That is our major point. The same variable (e.g. brand name value) determines the organizational choice of different transactions, with different attributes. The organizational solution in upstream transactions has an effect on the choice of franchise contracts, which is an evidence of governance inseparability. In almost all the 21 cases, when the value of maintaining product uniformity is higher, the franchise chains tend to adopt organizational strategies that prevent free-riding behavior of franchisees. The pay-off of keeping quality standards depends on both the brand name value and the consumer’s sensitivity to variations in the attributes of products. In Barzel’s (1982) seminal argument, brand name has a value because it transmits information about attributes of products that saves consumers’ measurement costs. As a consequence, maintaining product uniformity is worthy as it preserves the brand name capability to transmit information. How sensitive consumers are to the variation in products attributes is also important. In Barzel’s terms, if consumers are quite sensitive (have low measurement costs of product attributes), the seller must incur higher measurement costs to prevent consumers from collecting information themselves. As a consequence, chains will direct efforts to increase quality control, for instance, reducing franchisees incentives to under-provide quality. Among all the cases, Comtesse du Barry and Segafredo, in Europe, and Vivenda do Camarão, and Kopenhagen, in Brazil, are examples of quite sensitive consumers. Due to cultural reasons, French customers are capable of identifying the slightest variance in the foie gras (Comtesse du Barry) and coffee (Segafredo), among other products. Brazilian consumers of shrimps with creams at Vivenda do Camarão are also able to distinguish changes in the skim milk suppliers and shrimp characteristics. Finally, Kopenhagen sells varieties of chocolates as gifts for special occasions, comparable to jewels. Small variations of product attributes also jeopardize its image as a sort of present, for Valentines Day or an engagement proposal for instance. In all these cases franchisers vertically integrate the production of inputs directly related to their brand names, such as foie gras, (Comtesse du Barry), coffee beans (Segafredo in Europe), shrimps (Vivenda do Camarão) and chocolates (Kopenhagen). Also the proportion of company-owned outlets is higher as a consequence, incentives for under-provision of quality are lower , and some innovative efforts are oriented to eliminate franchisees’ tasks that affect the quality of products. In general, there are three ways to avoid the costs related to the misuse of brand name by franchisees: a) reducing the variability of the inputs supplied to chain outlets, by means of governance structures such as hierarchy and hybrid modes in upstream transactions; b) 3 See for instance Bai & Tao (2000); Lafontaine & Raynaud (2002); Azevedo & Silva (2003); Bercovitz (2004); Windsperger et al. (2004). 4 providing better incentives for outlet managers to meet quality standards, by means of governance mechanisms in the transaction between franchisor and franchisees (e.g. higher proportion of company-owned outlets or safeguards in the franchise contract); and c) eliminating tasks performed by franchisees that affect attributes of products, which may be achieved by means of innovation (e.g. ready to use products which do not require any hidden action by franchisees) and organizational strategies (such as central kitchens and pre-cooked meals, which may be interpreted as vertical integration of some tasks originally performed in the outlets). A comparative analysis of coffee shops in Brazil and France is illustrative. Although Brazil is one of the main coffee producers, Brazilian consumers have not developed the capability for distinguishing and appreciating different coffee flavors, different from French consumers. After decades of pricing and trading regulation, Brazilian consumers have been used to low quality coffee and acquired drinking habits that attenuate the effect of coffee flavors. 4 After the deregulation in the early 1990’s, some companies tried to explore all sorts of differentiation strategies, but those based on coffee flavors did not pay-off, and were discontinued. In order to analyze the effect of different consumer’s sensitiveness to product attributes, we compared four Brazilian coffee shops (Café do Ponto (owned by SaraLee), Café Pelé, Fran’s Café and Casa do Pão de Queijo) with Segafredo Zanetti operations in Brazil and Europe. In all Brazilian chains of coffee shops, the franchisor has control on the supply of roasted coffee by means of long term contracts (Café Pelé and Casa do Pão de Queijo), exclusive dealing contract (Fran’s Café) and vertical integration (Café do Ponto). Notwithstanding the control on roasting and grounding, all coffee chains use the spot market to buy coffee beans with negligible control on their quality. Consistently with our proposition, given the low sensitiveness of Brazilian consumers to coffee flavors, which depends primarily on coffee beans, chains do not exert control on the coffee bean market. The comparison with Segafredo Zanetti operations in Brazil and Europe is strikingly. Segafredo Zanetti coffee shops have exclusivity on the distribution of the high-end coffee blend (Nero) of the company, which also sells other blends to restaurants and hotels. In order to strictly control the quality of coffee beans and roasting, Segafredo vertically integrates coffee production on its own farm in Brazil and roasting on its plant in Bologna, Italy, which supplies all coffee shops in Europe. Although Segafredo sells some blends in the Brazilian market, the coffee beans that grow in Brazil are sent to European coffee shops, which is an additional evidence that consumer sensitiveness is an important variable to understand organizational strategies. The cases clearly indicate that the higher the value of keeping quality standards, the more likely the chances for franchise chain to adopt governance mechanism that provide more control on all pertinent transactions. We also observed, that, for a given level of keeping quality standards, the use of governance structures that provide more control on the supply chain (upstream coordination) reduces the need of incentives and control on the transaction between franchisor and outlet managers (franchisees or managers of company-owned outlets). That is basically the idea of governance inseparability, which is investigated in the subsequent sections. 3.2. Plural Forms in Franchise Contracts Plural forms are an important subject in franchising literature. The co-existence of franchised and company-owned outlets in the same chain is a well-known fact, deserving the 4 It is noteworthy that Brazilians tend to consume hotter and sweeter coffee, which reduces the capability to distinguish different flavors. After 15 years of deregulation, the market for premium coffee has been slowly increasing, together with the sensitiveness of consumers to slight changes in coffee beans attributes. 5 great attention it has received from researches. 5 Nevertheless, organizational forms in franchising are more diverse than suggested by the literature. 6 Indeed, in addition to hierarchy form (company-owned outlets) we have observed three different franchise contracts: 1) conventional franchising; 2) partial franchising; and 3) management contract. In the conventional franchising, the franchisor transfers to the franchisee the totality of initial investments of franchised units. In addition, the franchisee pays the franchisor a lump-sum franchise fee as well as a proportion of sales in royalties. In contrast, in the partial franchising, the initial investments of franchised units are shared between the parties. The franchisor hands on the expenses with the building (purchase/rent), retaining the residual rights over it, whereas franchisees are responsible for investments in equipment, furniture and staff. In addition to the regular taxes, the franchisee transfers to the franchisor an additional proportion of sales as a rental fee. Finally, in the management contract the franchisor typically holds the totality of initial investments of the unit, transferring only the management of the franchised unit to the franchisee. In exchange, the franchisee pays the franchisor an administration fee as well as royalties and rental fee, and not necessarily a franchise fee. In this format, the franchisee resembles a manager of company-owned outlet with variable revenues according to unit performance. Table 2 shows the main features and consequences of each governance structure identified. ‘Take in Table 2’ An important difference among the various observed governance structures is their role as a solution for capital restrictions ((Ozanne & Hunt, 1971); (Caves & Murphy, 1976); (Mendelsohn, 1985); (Coughlan et al., 2001)). Whereas in the conventional contract the franchisee is responsible for all investments, in the management contract he or she receives similar high-power incentives without immobilizing his/her own capital. The very existence of this type of franchising contract (management contract) is an evidence that raising capital is not the unique reason to franchise, although it remains important to explain the adoption of the conventional franchising. An other important distinction is the role of each governance structure in providing incentives against shirking and under-provision of quality. Inasmuch as franchisees retain part of the residual claims over variations on unit sales, conventional, partial and management contracts transfer to the franchisee higher incentives to work harder, contrarily to managers of company-owned outlets. Nevertheless the three types of franchising differ in their incentive intensity. Conventional franchising allocates a higher proportion of the residual claims to franchisee, in the form of a return to his or her investments, which implies higher incentives to not shirk. On the other hand, franchise contract is more vulnerable to the moral hazard on quality under-provision than company-owned outlets. These risks are comparatively higher under the conventional franchising, unless, in addition to the payment scheme of this format, franchisee incurs higher specific investments in the outlet (Azevedo & Silva, 2001). By guaranteeing to the franchisor the control over the building location, the partial and management contracts prevent former franchisees from using the same location in a similar activity, free-riding on reputations towards consumers. In order to attenuate these risks, we observed that the conventional franchising uses safeguards such as clauses of ex-post non-competition. Despite such relation, it is noteworthy that in Brazil franchise chains do not fully explore the diversity of franchise contracts, as observed in France/Europe. Whereas in Brazil 5 See Bradach and Eccles (1989), Dant et al. (1996), Bradach (1997), Bai and Tao (2000; 2000a), Azevedo and Silva (2001), Lafontaine and Shaw (2001) and Pénard et al. (2002). 6 One exception is Bercovitz (2004) who also analyzes the choice of multi-unit franchising. 6 company-owned outlets are often combined with a unique franchise contract (in general the conventional franchising), in France franchise chains employ a more complex portfolio of governance structures in downstream transactions (Table 3). We submit that the difference between the two countries is due to jurisdictional uncertainty. This result is better detailed in section 3.4, which deals with the effect of the institutional environment on the choice of governance. ‘Take in Table 3’ 3.3. Governance Inseparability in Upstream and Downstream Transactions As showed in the last section, franchise chains use plural organizational forms in the transactions with their outlets. Not only do plural forms exist and are more diverse than the well known dichotomy of company-owned and franchised outlets, but also the choice of a governance structure for one transaction seems to be related to the choice for the others. Our claim is that organizational choices are interdependent because governance structures are complementary. In addition to governance inseparability of franchisor-franchisee transactions, this section focuses on the role of upstream transactions, exploring the complementarities between upstream and downstream governance structures. Comtesse du Barry (foie gras) and Jeff de Bruges (chocolates) case studies are illustrative. When compared with other chains, Comtesse du Barry and Jeff de Bruges have the remarkable feature of supplying their units with ready-to-eat products7, i.e., they vertically integrate processing activities that could otherwise be performed by either suppliers or the outlet itself. By means of this organizational strategy, the company has better control on quality standards in the outlet level, inasmuch as franchisees do not process or manipulate the final product. The use of governance structures that provide more control on the supply chain allows Comtesse du Barry and Jeff de Bruges to reduce the need for control on downstream transactions. Indeed, Comtesse du Barry and Jeff de Bruges also employ licensing contracts as an alternative mode of governance of outlets. The licencee, under an independent brand name, has full autonomy regarding the entire business format itself. Among all other cases, only Dunkin’Donuts employs a similar marketing channel strategy, combining licensing with company-owned outlets and franchised units. However, their licensees must be located near franchised or company-owned units, which are in charge of the supply of ready-to-eat products to licensees. In such arrangement, Dunkin’Donuts also mitigates the risk of underprovision of quality. The comparative analysis of Grill Courtepaille and La Boucherie (both of them specialized in grills) provides another evidence of governance inseparability in upstream and downstream governances. Although they operate in the same market and share similar business features, Grill Courtepaille and La Boucherie have a quite different proportion of company-owned outlets, respectively 79,2% versus 17,1% in 2004. The reason for this remarkable difference in the level of control on the transactions with their outlets is the governance structure used in the supply chain. Grill Courtepaille counts on a branch of Accor Group (Accor Reste) for the selection of suppliers8, but it does not maintain the decision rights over the choice of suppliers. Even in the case of inputs directly related to their brand name (meat, bread, vegetables, cheese and wine), the franchisees have autonomy to deal directly with local suppliers to explore regional specificities. On the other hand, one of the main competitors of Grill Courtepaille, i.e., the also French La Boucherie, has vertically integrated the supply of its restaurants, particularly regarding its key-products (meat, wine and 7 For those products directly related to their brand name: foie gras and chocolates. Accor Group is the main shareholder of Grill Courtepaille. In fact, Grill Courtepaille restaurants tend to be strategically situated physically closed with hotels from Accor Group. Some suppliers of Grill Courtepaille are shared with Accor hotel chain. 8 7 other inputs related to La Boucherie business format, such as equipment, fittings and marketing materials). Since 2000, Société CAVIAR (Centre d’Affinage des Viandes de Restaurants) is responsible for: 1) selection, control and trading of product; 2) traceability, hygiene and sanitary controls of raw-material; 3) cut meat, and 4) optimization of both distribution and service practices of La Boucherie restaurants. The control on the supply chain – greater in the La Boucherie case – explains why it does not exert the same level of control on outlets as Grill Courterpaille does. 3.4. Institutional Environment and its Effects on Franchise Contracts: A Case of Governance Inseparability The comparative analysis of case studies of France and Brazil allows the investigation of the institutional environment effect on franchising contracts. Particularly we looked at the institutional variables that have a direct effect on some franchisors’ transactions and how they indirectly influence the organizational choice in the other transactions undertaken by the franchisor. In this section we detail the following arguments: a) jurisdictional uncertainty with regard to the enforcement of franchising contracts; b) transaction costs in the capital market and c) competition policy restrictions to vertical arrangements. There is a reasonable consensus about the inefficiency of the Brazilian judiciary and the consequences in economic arrangements9. This feature of the Brazilian institutional environment has direct implications on the choice of governance structures, particularly on the choice of the various franchising contracts (conventional, partial and management) and company-owned outlets. The comparative analysis of plural forms, mentioned in section 3.2, provides an example of this effect. Brazilian jurisdictional uncertainty may be the reason why international franchise chains do not adopt in Brazil the same organizational strategies they do in their original countries. Differently from what is observed in other markets, Dunkin’Donuts, The Nuty Bavarian and Arby’s do not explore the diversity of franchise contracts in Brazil, using only the dual structure of conventional franchising and vertical integration. An exception is McDonald’s, which retains control over building location, as it is usual in its operations all over the world. The McDonald’s position of maintaining its international strategy in Brazil generates conflicts between the company and its Brazilian franchisees. The crisis began in 1996, when the company started an accelerated growth strategy in the Brazilian market, which resulted in a decline of unit sales. Since 1999, when Brazilian currency devaluated, the conflict has worsened. The franchisees that had debts to the company indexed to dollar led the contract to court, resulting in a series of onerous lawsuits in Brazil. By increasing the costs of franchising in Brazil, the conflicts between McDonald’s and its franchisees are the main causes for changing the company organizational strategy towards a higher level of vertical integration, increasing the proportion of company-owned outlets (Figure 1). ‘‘Take in Figure 1’ In short, the jurisdictional uncertainty that affects the costs of franchising has induced a higher level of vertical integration. It could be argued that this is not a case of governance 9 Pinheiro (2005), in an extensive survey, observed that Brazilian jurisdictional decisions are too lengthy, unpredictable and biased towards the weaker part. Arida et al. (2005) argue that the inexistence of a long term credit market in Brazil is caused by the poor guarantees the judicial system offers creditors. Zylbersztajn and Nadali (2003) assert that the location decisions in the agribusiness sector are sensitive to the way the regional courts judge contractual litigations between agricultural producers and food processors. Such inefficiencies are the consequence of the delays and uncertainties regarding the court rulings. 8 inseparability, inasmuch as in each transaction higher cost of contracting increases the likelihood of vertical integration. Nevertheless it is noteworthy that the use of franchising contracts that provide more control to franchisors (partial franchising and management contract) is widespread in France and not observed in Brazil. The higher proportion of company-owned outlets in Brazil reduces the need for control on franchising contracts, which is a possible explanation for the option of conventional franchising in Brazil. The second argument is the transaction costs in the capital market. Brazil has one of the highest interest rates in the world. 10 Macroeconomic foundations are certainly part of the history that explains this anomaly in the Brazilian capital market, but there are institutional variables that contribute to the high transaction costs in this market. Arida et al. (2005) observed that long term credit market has not developed in Brazil because court rulings are biased towards debtors. As a consequence, savings owners do not use long term contracts, which are more likely to be in courts. In contrast, the French capital market is far more accessible. This is another possible explanation of why France presents all types of franchising contracts, contrarily to Brazil, in which the conventional franchising is the absolutely dominant form. An imperfection in the transaction between franchisors and capital lenders imposes capital restrictions that may be solved by the use of a franchising contract (conventional) that attracts capital from franchisees. In France, the role of franchising as an alternative to raise capital is attenuated because franchisors have better access to the capital market. This is another evidence of governance inseparability in franchising11. Finally, competition policy may constrain the choice of governance mechanisms in upstream transactions, having an indirect effect on the design of the franchise contracts. For instance, in France/Europe companies that have more than 30%12 of the market are not allowed to impose vertical restraints to franchised outlets, such as exclusive suppliers or vertical integration of input production. We expect that those restrictions have an effect on the need for control on downstream transactions, in order to preserve the brand name value. However the evidences of McDonald’s in France, a company subjected to that competition policy restriction, suggest, at first sight, that the above proposition is actually false. Inasmuch as McDonald’s can not control the variability of inputs, we expected that it would use a higher proportion of company-owned outlets, which is a form to prevent franchisees incentives to under-provide quality. Contrarily to our expectations, the proportion of company-owned outlets that McDonald’s holds in France is historically quite lower than the one observed in Brazil, even before court rulings raised the costs of franchising (Figure 1). A more detailed look at the franchising contracts and quality regulation in France provides a possible explanation for this result. The variability of input quality, particularly of agricultural products, is quite lower in France than in Brazil due to a more effective French quality regulation. The lower the variability of inputs, the less necessary to exert control on the supply chain. In addition, as already mentioned, franchising contracts in France are more diverse, including forms – such as partial franchising and management contract – that provide better incentives for franchisees to keep up with quality standards. In short, in comparison with Brazil, McDonald’s in France relies more intensely on franchising, by means of types of contracts that provide more control to the franchisor. 10 In 2005 real interest rates were about 13% a year for fixed income securities. The first two arguments explain basically the same empirical regularity: variety of franchising contracts in France and predominance of conventional franchising in Brazil. As a consequence, we can not separate both effects, but they are both plausible arguments based on the idea of governance inseparability. 12 European Competition Policy, according to the Regiment of Exemption 2790, of 1990, establishes that retailing vertical arrangements, among then franchising contracts, are subject to the following clause: companies with a market share that exceeds 30% are not allowed to require exclusive suppliers. 11 9 4. Concluding Remarks There is not much dispute that firms choose a portfolio of governance mechanisms in order to deal with the whole set of transactions they are engaged in. They even choose what is firm and not firm. Less researched, however, are the consequences of not taking governance inseparability into account when explaining firm boundaries and contracts that govern particular transactions. The literature on governance inseparability proposes that former transactions constraint the choice of present governance mechanisms (Argyres and Liebeskind, 1999). In addition we submit that governance choice is interdependent because different governance mechanisms employed by the same firm may be complementary. Franchising is an interesting case where the appropriate design of a governance structure of a particular transaction depends on the other governance arrangements. In a set of 21 case-studies we have gathered evidence that a) franchisors choose a portfolio of governance mechanisms to govern this set of transactions; b) upstream and downstream governance mechanisms are complementary, making the governance decision of each transaction inseparable from the others; and c) quality regulation and competition policy restrain upstream governance mechanisms, having an indirect effect on the design of the franchise contracts. The latter finding is particularly relevant to the case of franchise chains that explore foreign markets, being subjected to different institutional environments. If competition policy, for instance, imposes some sort of restriction to vertical restraints, such as an exclusive supplier to outlets, the franchisor will not be able to reduce quality variation of inputs and, as a consequence, will face greater risk of loss of brand name value. Under the pressure to mitigate hazards related to final product variability, the franchisor may be willing to adopt franchising contracts that provide better incentives for franchisees to provide specified quality standards. If this proposition is correct, existing governance mechanisms should be taken into account in any analysis of the determinants of governance choice. Inasmuch as franchising literature largely relies on the transaction of the franchisor and his/her outlets (franchised or company-owned), with no reference to upstream governance mechanisms, we submit that those studies may have omitted variables. However how the absence of those variables affects current results of the literature is not clear. Actually the huge empirical support of the TCE basic argument (Klein, 2004) suggests that omitting existing governance mechanisms does not have a strong effect on the prediction power of the theory. For future research we suggest gathering information on the whole set of franchisors’ transactions, to empirically test the effect of upstream governance on downstream franchising contracts. It is also recommended to embrace the task of a cross-country analysis in order to capture the effects of institutional environment variability. 5. References AAKER, D.A., 1991. Managing brand equity: capitalizing on the value of a brand name. The Free Press: New York. ARGYRES, N.S. and J.P. LIEBESKIND, 1999. Contractual commitments, bargaining, and governance inseparability. Academy of Management Review, 24, 49-63. _________________________________, 2002. Governance inseparability and the evolution of the biotechnology industry. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, vol. 47, 2, February, 197-219. ARIDA, P., E.L. BACHA and A. LARA-RESENDE, 2005. Credit, interest, and jurisdictional uncertainty: conjectures on the case of Brazil. In: GIAVAZZI, F. and I. GOLDFAJN, Inflation targeting and debt: the case of Brazil. MIT Press (forthcoming). 10 ARTHUR, W.B., 1989. Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. The Economic Journal, March, 116-131. AZEVEDO, P.F., 1996. Integração vertical e barganha. IPE-USP. (PhD Dissertation). AZEVEDO, P.F. and V.L.S. SILVA, 2001. Contractual mix in Brazilian franchising. 5th Conference of the International Society for New Institutional Economics (ISNIE), Berkeley-CA, U.S. AZEVEDO, P.F and V.L.S. SILVA, 2003. Food franchising and backward coordination: and empirical analysis on Brazilian firms. Journal on Chain and Network Science, v.3, n.1, p.33-44. BAI, C.E. and Z. TAO, 2000. Franchising as a nexus of incentive devices for production involving brand name. Working Paper University of Hong Kong. _____________________, 2000a. Contractual mix in franchising as a mechanism for publicgood provision. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 9, 1, 85-113. BARZEL, Y., 1982. Measurement cost and the organization of markets. Journal of Law and Economics, v.25, p.27-48. BERCOVITZ, J., 2004. The organizational choice decision in business format franchising: an empirical test. In: WINDSPERGER, J., G. CLIQUET, G. HENDRIKSE and M. TUUNANEN (Eds.). Economics and management of franchising networks. PhysicaVerlag Heidelberg. 264p. BRADACH, J.L., 1997. Using the plural form in the management of restaurant chains. Administrative Science Quarterly, v.42, p.276-303. BRADACH J.L.; and R. ECCLES, 1989. Price, authority, and trust. Annual Review of Sociology, v.15, p.97-118, Palo Alto, CA: Annual Review. CAVES, R.E. and H.W.F. MURPHY, 1976. Franchising: firms, markets, and intangible assets. Southern Economic Journal, v.42. COASE, R., 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, n.4, November. COUGHLAN, A.T., E. ANDERSON, L.W. STERN and A.I. EL-ANSARY, 2001. Marketing channels. Prentice Hall: New Jersey. CORREA, C., 2003. Dieta amarga. Revista EXAME. Disponívvel em: <http://portalexame.abril.com.br/pgMain.jhtml?ch=ch06&sc=sc0601&pg=pgart_0601_07110 3_57220.html>. Acesso em: 8/11/2003. DANT, R. P., A.K. PASWAN and J. STANWORTH, J., 1996. Ownership redirection trends in franchising: a cross-sectoral investigation. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior and Research, v. 2, n. 3, pp. 48-67. GALLINI, N.T.; and N.A. LUTZ, 1992. Dual distribution and royalty fees in franchising. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, v.8, p.471-501. GAZETA MERCANTIL, 2003. Disputa está acirrada entre McDonald's e franqueados. Gazeta Mercantil, São Paulo, 11, nov. GVconsult, 2005. As melhores franquias do Brasil 2005. Guia das Franquias/PEGN, jun. KLEIN, P.G., 2004. The market-or-buy decision: lessons from empirical studies. In: MENARD, C. and M. SHIRLEY (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics. (forthcoming). LAFONTAINE, F.; and K. L. SHAW, 2001. Targeting managerial control: evidence from franchising. NBER Working Paper Series. LAFONTAINE, F. and E. RAYNAUD, 2002. The role of residual claims and selfenforcement in franchise contracting. NBER Working Paper Series, n. 8868. 11 MENDELSOHN, M., 1985. The guide to franchising. Pergamon Press: Oxford. MICHAEL, S.C., 2000. Investments to create bargaining power: the case of franchising. Strategic Management Journal, v.21, p.497-514. OZANNE, U. B.; and S.D. HUNT, 1971. The economic effect of franchising. US Senate Select Committee on Small Business, US Government Printing Office: Washington, D.C. PINHEIRO, A.C., 2005. Magistrados, judiciário e economia no Brasil. In: ZYLBERSZTAJN, D. and R. SZTAJN, Direito & economia: análise econômica do direito e das organizações. Elsevier: Rio de Janeiro, Brazil. PENARD, T., E. RAYNAUD and S. SAUSSIER, 2002. Dual distribution and royalty rates in franchised chains: an empirical exploration using French data. Working paper ATOM Center, University of Paris 1. RIORDAN. M., 1990. What is vertical integration? In: AOKI, M.,B, GUSTAFSSON and O.E. WILLIAMSON. The firm as a nexus of treaties, London: Sage. WILLIAMSON, O.E., 1996. Mechanisms of governance. Oxford University Press: New York, 429p. ____., 1991. Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 269-296. __________________., 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. Free Press: New York. WINDSPERGER, J. The dual network structure of franchising firms: property rights, resource scarcity and transaction cost explanations. In: WINDSPERGER, J., G. CLIQUET, G. HENDRIKSE and M. TUUNANEN (Eds.). Economics and management of franchising networks. Physica-Verlag Heidelberg. 264p. ZYLBERSZTAJN, D. and L.B. NADALI, 2003. Tomatoes and courts: strategies of the agroindustry facing weak contract enforcement, 7th Annual Conference of the International Society for New Institutional Economics (ISNIE), Budapest, Hungary. 12 6. Appendix Table 1. Summary of Franchised Chains’ Evolution** company segment level of upstream coordination Jeff de Bruges France World sweets & chocolates XXXXX fine products grills C. Barry France World La Boucherie France World G. Courtepaille France grills proportion of company-owned outlet (number of company-owned outlets; and franchised units) years of foundation year of franchising beginning 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 1986 NO NO NO NO NO NO 24.7% 22.9% NO 20.9% (43; 162) 19.1% (43; 225) XXXXX 1908 NO 1975 NO NO NO NO NO NO 15.1% - NO 32.3% (21; 44) 30.55% (22; 50) XXX 1974 NO 1987 NO NO NO NO 52.3% NO NO 25.0% NO NO 17.1% (6 ; 29) 15.0% (6 ; 34) 1961 2000 91.8% 91.9% 90.5% 85.9% NO NO 79.2% (126; 33) 1971 1980 NO 1978 1991 NO NO NO NO NO NO 1964 1992 1965 1997 88% end of Brazilian operations NO NO NO NO NO 1946 (58) 1983 (21) 1955 1991 NO NO NO NO NO 1.0% 1.5% NO NO 1955 1972 1979 1955 1979 1987 20.0% 13.0%*** 40.0%*** 20.0% 13.0%*** 40.0%*** 20.0% 13.0%*** 40.0%*** 20.0% 13.0%*** 40.0%*** 20.0% 13.0% 40.0% 20.0% NO 68.0% XX NO Quick Belgium France World fast food XXX fast food XXX NO Arby’s U.S. Brazil Dunkin’Donuts U.S. Brazil sweets & chocolates XXX McDonald’s World*** France Brazil fast food XXX ** 100% NO 26.9% - NO 34.6% (108; 204) 28.6% (114; 285) 20.0% 16.23% (168; 867)% 73.0% (401; 148) Based on primary data; GVconsult (2004); ABF (Franchising Brazilian Association); and FFF (Franchising French Federation). NO: data not obtained. *** McDonald’s estimate. 13 Table 1. Summary of Franchised Chains’ Evolution** (Part 2) segment level of upstream coordination sweets & chocolates XXX grills XXX fast food XXX fast food XXX fine sweets & chocolates XXXXX fast food XXX sweets & chocolates XXX coffee shops XXX coffee shops X Café do Ponto Brazil Café Pelé Brazil coffee shops C.P. Queijo company A. Pedaços Brazil Bon Grillê Brazil China in Box Brazil Habib’s Brazil Kopenhagen Brazil V. Camarão Brazil N. Bavarian U.S. Brazil years of foundation franchising beginning (years of experience) 1982 proportion of company-owned outlet (number of company-owned outlets; and franchised units) 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 1989 NO 9.8% 11.1% 15.0% 12.2% NO NO 11.9% (5; 37) 1994 1996 NO 66.0% 63.0% 57.0% 51.0% NO NO 74.5% (38; 13) 1992 1994 NO 8.6% 3.0% 9.7% 10.9% NO NO 9.2% (11; 108) 1988 1991 NO 43.0% NO NO - NO 24.0% 31.1% (81; 179) 1928 1992 NO NO NO NO 30.0% NO NO 29.3% (47; 113) 1984 1990 NO 89.0% 86.0% 68.0% 50.0% NO NO 70.5% (31; 13) 1989 1989 1997 NO NO NO NO 43.0% NO NO NO 24.7% (18; 55) 1986 NO NO NO NO NO NO NO 0.29% NO NO 6.9% (2; 27) 0.4% (2; 470) 1972 (32) 1992 NO 13.8% NO NO NO NO NO 1.0% (1; 100) X 1976 (28) 1992 NO 8.9% NO NO NO NO NO 1.7% (1; 56) coffee shops X 1992 (12) 1994 NO 0.0% NO NO NO NO NO 1.7% (2; 115) coffee shops XX 1967 (37) 1987 NO NO NO NO NO NO NO 0.0% (0; 406) S. Zanetti Italy France Europe/World Fran’s Café Brazil Brazil ** 70’ Based on primary data; GVconsult (2004); ABF (Franchising Brazilian Association); and FFF (Franchising French Federation). NO: data not obtained. 14 Table 2. Features of the Governance Mechanisms Identified in French and Brazilian Franchising characteristics governance mechanism investment franchisee: conventional 100% initial investments payments outlet residual risk scheme control claim sharing franchise fee plus franchisee franchisee royalties franchisee and partial franchisor share initial consequences higher risk higher gains in capital and human to resources raising; and in the reduction of franchisee moral hazard prob. in shirking franchisee some risk idem plus rent fee franchisor investments (lower than transferred in conv. to contract) franchisor higher franchisee motivation in work as franchisor (franchisee idem plus management contract administration franchisor: fee 100% initial resembles the manager of companyowned investments hard as desired by franchisor, reducing transfer to risk shared monitoring costs comparing to hierarchy franchisee between form (lower than franchisor partial and contract) franchisee outlet) hierarchy (company- - franchisor - owned outlet) 15 higher risk comparative gains in the control of to franchised brand name franchisor (reducing moral hazards on quality) Table 3. Governance Mechanism Employed According to the Chain Market *** governance mechanism company conventional partial management hierarchy (companyowned outlet) grills • NE NE • sweets & chocolates • NE NE • • NE • • • NE NE • • NE • • • NE NE • • NE • • • NE NE • NE • • • • NE NE • NE • • • NE • NE • NE • • • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • NE • • • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • • NE NE • segment Grill Courtepaille in all markets Jeff de Bruges in all markets Comtesse du Barry target markets other markets fine products target markets other markets grills target markets other markets coffee shop La Boucherie Segafredo Zanetti Quick target markets other markets McDonald’s global standard Brazil Arby’s global standard Brazil fast food China in Box Brazil Vivenda do Camarão Brazil Habib’s Brazil Bon Grillê Brazil grills Dunkin’Donuts global standard Brazil Amor aos Pedaços Brazil sweets & chocolates The Nutty Bavarian Brazil Kopenhagen Brazil fine sweets & chocolates Fran’s Café Brazil Café do Ponto Brazil Café Pelé coffee shop Brazil Casa do Pão de Queijo Brazil *** NE: governance mechanism not employed by the chain. 16 % company-owned Mix contratual (% lojas outlet próprias) 80 Brazil Brasil * 70 60 50 40 30 Mundo** World ** 20 10 França** France ** 0 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Figure 1. Evolution of the proportion of company-owned outlets employed by McDonald’s in Brazil, France and in the World *Forecast of stability for the next years = about 70%. ** McDonald’s estimate. Based on primary data in addition to COOREA (2003) and GAZETA MERCANTIL (2003). 17