May 26, 2007 Dominant Firm and Competitive Fringe This model joins together some aspects of monopoly and perfect competition. The “competitive fringe” of firms behave competitively – they are price takers. The dominant firm, however, profit-maximizes by setting MR = MC and behaves like a monopolist, with one important difference. The dominant firm realizes that the competitive fringe of firms exists and takes into account the amount they will produce. In other words, the dominant firm profit-maximizes using the residual demand rather than the whole market demand curve. Here is an example (discussed in class, but there is more detail here). There is an industry with a dominant firm and 100 firms that make up the competitive fringe. The 100 firms have identical cost curves. The industry demand curve is given by P = 1000 - .005Q. The total cost curve of each of the competitive fringe firms is TC = 600q + q2. The first thing to do is to find the residual demand curve facing the dominant firm. In order to do that, we need to know how much the competitive fringe of firms will produce (their supply curve) and subtract this from the whole market demand curve. MC of each firm in the competitive fringe is MC = 600 + 2q. These firms produce where P = MC, so P = 600 + 2q is the supply curve for each of these firms. Since there are 100 identical firms, q = .01Q. Substituting, we can conclude that P = 600 + 2(.01Q), or P = 600 + .02Q is the supply curve for all of these 100 firms when added together. We now need to subtract this competitive fringe supply from the market demand curve to get the residual demand curve faced by the Dominant Firm. There are 2 critical points – (1) the price at which the competitive fringe will be producing enough to serve the entire market, leaving no residual demand for the Dominant Firm, and (2) the price below which the competitive fringe is unwilling to supply any output to the market (because it is does not cover their costs). Point (1) can be found as the intersection of the market demand curve and the competitive fringe supply curve, or where 1000 - .005Q = 600 + .02Q. This will happen where Q = 16,000 and where P = $920. Point (2) can be found as the point on the market demand curve where the competitive fringe supply crosses the horizontal axis (Q = 0), which is at P = $600. Substituting this into the market demand curve we have 600 = 1000 .005Q, or Q = 80,000. A line joining the point ($920, 0) to the point ($600, 80000) will form the main part of the residual demand curve of the Dominant Firm. Because the slope of this line (rise over the run) will be (920 – 600)/80,000 = .004, the equation of this part of the residual demand curve of the Dominant Firm will be P = 920 - .004Q. The second part of the residual demand curve applies to quantities greater than 80,000 units of output. Beyond this output (and therefore for an equilibrium price less than $600), there is no output from the competitive fringe, so the Dominant Firm now faces the entire market demand curve. The equation of the entire residual demand curve would therefore be: P = 920 - .004Q for Q <= 80,000, and P = 1000 - .005Q for Q > 80,000. The Dominant Firm will profit-maximize by setting MR = MC, with MR coming from the residual demand curve. Because the residual demand curve is twopart, the MR curve will also be two-part. The Dominant Firm’s MR curve will be MR = 920 - .008Q for Q<= 80,000 and MR = 1000 - .01Q for Q > 80,000. There are two possibilities for the behaviour of the Dominant Firm. If the Dominant Firm’s MC curve is low enough to cut the second part (the bottom part) of the MR curve, the Dominant Firm will sell at a low enough price (and a high enough quantity) that there will be no competitive fringe left in the industry. If the Dominant Firm’s MC curve is higher than this, it will cut the top part of the MR curve and the Dominant Firm will profit-maximize by sharing the market with the competitive fringe of firms. In this case, we assume that the Dominant Firm’s MC curve is MC = AC = 500 (so the Dominant Firm has a cost advantage over the competitive fringe). Therefore, MR = MC where 920 - .008Q = 500 or QDF* = 52,500 and P* = 920 .004(52,500) = $710. The profit of the Dominant Firm will be TR – TC = (710 x 52,500) – (500 x 52,500) = $11,025,000. The competitive fringe is a group of price-taking firms. They therefore take the price established by the Dominant Firm and produce the profit-maximizing quantity at that price. Therefore, 710 = 600 + .02Q, so that QCF* = 5,500. Since there are 100 firms in the competitive fringe, each must be producing 55 units of output. Profit for each of the competitive fringe of firms is (710 x 55) – [(600 x 55) + (55 x 55)] = $3,025. We can ask several questions about this solution, and the answers help us to understand the model: (1) What is the Deadweight Loss associated with this equilibrium solution? First, we must determine the “competitive” result. The competitive result comes where MC = P, in other words, where MC crosses the market demand curve. The Dominant Firm’s MC curve is the lowest, so we should use this for the calculations. Imagining that the Dominant Firm supplied the whole market at a price of $500, this would mean the sale of 1000 - .005Q = 500 or 100,000 units. The Dominant Firm/Competitive Fringe equilibrium involved a price of $710 and the production of 52,500 + 5,500 = 58,000 units. The Deadweight Loss is therefore [(710 – 500) x (100,000 – 58,000)]/2 = $4,410,000. (2) Why does the Dominant Firm choose this alternative, rather than charging a price just low enough to drive the competitive fringe out of the market? The highest price at which the competitive fringe could not compete would be $600. At this price the competitive fringe would produce nothing. If the Dominant Firm charged this price, it could sell 1000 - .005Q = 600 or Q = 80,000 units. The profit for the Dominant Firm would be TR – TC = (600 x 80,000) – (500 x 80,000) = $8,000,000. This is a lower profit than the Dominant Firm can earn by sharing the market at a price of $710, so sharing the market is a better alternative. (3) How is the Dominant Firm/Competitive Fringe equilibrium different from the monopoly model? If there were no competitive fringe, the Dominant Firm would set MR = MC, so 1000 - .01Q = 500, or Q* = 50,000. The monopoly price would be 1000 - .005(50,000) = $750. The equilibrium profit would be (750 x 50,000) – (500 x 50,000) = $12,500,000. Here we can see that the competitive fringe (part of the“structure” of the industry) acts to reduce the ability of the Dominant Firm to raise price and earn profits. You can check to see that the Deadweight Loss is lower under the Dominant Firm/Competitive Fringe situation than it would be under monopoly. (4) What would happen in the Dominant Firm model if the Dominant Firm had much lower costs, say MC = AC = $100? In this case, the MC curve would intersect MR in its lower part, so we would have MR = MC: 1000 .01Q = 100, or QDF* = 90,000 and P* = $450. The profit of the Dominant Firm would be (450 x 90,000) – (100 x 90,000) = 40,500 – 9,000,000 = $31,500,000. This equilibrium is now the same as the Monopoly model (because there is only one firm left in the industry).