DUALITY IN MONOPOLY Ilko Vrankić, Mira Krpan University of Zagreb, Faculty of Economics and Business Trg J. F. Kennedy 6, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia {ivrankic, mkrpan}@efzg.hr Abstract: This paper follows our theoretical research on duality in microeconomic theory and applies the duality principles, which rest on the price taking behaviour of economic subjects, on the monopolistic behaviour. The standard approach of deriving the profit function for the monopolist from the production function and defined pseudo production function is accompanied by the alternative approach in which the starting point is the pseudo cost function. Finally, starting from the derived profit function the pseudo production function is recovered and a version of Hotelling’s lemma is given. All results are illustrated with a numerical example. Keywords: duality, pseudo production function, pseudo cost function, profit function, Hotelling’s lemma. 1 INTRODUCTION Rationality of economic agents in microeconomic theory is described by the optimization problems in which convex sets play an important role. The possibility of characterizing them in two ways naturally gives rise to duality in microeconomic theory [3,4]. Duality in microeconomic theory includes derivation and recovering of the alternative representations of the consumer preferences and the production technology. Since duality in this case rests on the price taking behaviour, the question is how can the principles of duality be applied in the case of a monopolistic firm where the single producer has influence on the price which he charges for the product [1,2,5,7]? In this paper we show how the profit function for the monopolist for the given demand function can be obtained by introducing the pseudo cost function [6] and solving the profit maximization problem. The standard approach in which the production function and defined pseudo production function is the starting point is also derived. Finally, starting from the derived profit function we show how the pseudo production function can be recovered. Although Hotelling's lemma, a famous result from the microeconomic theory, defined below, cannot be directly applied in obtaining the monopolist's supply function for the given demand function, a version of Hotelling's lemma is illustrated. 2 FROM THE PSEUDO PRODUCTION FUNCTION TO THE PROFIT FUNCTION The emphasis is on a monopolist whose objective is to maximize profit. The monopolist faces the following negatively sloped inverse demand function [5] p0 wDx0 , (1) where p 0 is the price of the monopolist’s product and w 0 represents the influence on demand of “other variables”, for example income, and D is a function of x0 for which D ' ( x0 ) 0 . The monopolist’s technology is described by the production function x0 F (x) , where x is the vector of inputs used in the production of the monopolist’s product x 0 . Since the total revenue function is described by p0 x0 wD F (x) F (x) wF (x) D F (x) , the profit maximization model for the monopolist in which the quantities of inputs are the choice variables reduces to maks wF (x) DF (x) wx , (2) x where w is the vector of input prices. If we form the pseudo production function [5] F * (x) F (x) DF (x) p o x0 w (3) as deflated revenue function and interpret the parameter w in (2) as the price of the pseudo product, then the known results from duality theory in microeconomics could be applied. It is assumed that sufficient regularity conditions are satisfied so that the maximum exists [1,5,7]. The first order necessary conditions for the profit maximization problem reduce to w F * (x) wi , i xi (4) Therefore, the monopolist will hire the levels of inputs for which the marginal revenue of the F * (x) corresponding input, w , is equal to its marginal cost, wi . An interior solution is xi assumed. It is assumed also that the input market is perfectly competitive so that the monopolist takes input prices as given. Solving the first order necessary conditions leads us to the input demand functions. By substituting the derived input demand functions in the production function, for the given demand function, we obtain the monopolist's supply function. The profit function is obtained by substituting the derived functions in the goal function in (2). To illustrate this procedure, the production function 1 1 x0 f ( x1 , x 2 ) x14 x 24 (5) is chosen [6]. Let us start from the linear inverse market demand function, p0 w(a bx0 ) , (6) for which the pseudo production function is defined as follows 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 F * (x) (a bx14 x24 ) x14 x24 ax14 x24 bx12 x22 . (7) The profit maximization model reduces to 1 4 1 1 4 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 maks w(ax x bx x ) w1 x1 w2 x2 . x1 . x2 (8) First order necessary conditions are expressed by the following system of equations w 1 1 F * (x) a 3 1 b 1 1 w 3 1 w( x1 4 x24 x1 2 x22 ) x1 4 x24 (a 2bx14 x24 ) w1 x1 4 2 4 1 1 F * (x) a 14 34 b 12 12 w 14 34 w w( x1 x2 x1 x2 ) x1 x2 (a 2bx14 x24 ) w2 x2 4 2 4 , (9) x2 w1 . We can express x2 as a function of x1 , x1 w2 Dividing both expressions in (9) gets us to 1 1 1 w w4 w 3 w4 1 x2 1 x1 , whose substitution in one of (9) leads us to x1 4 11 x14 (a 2bx12 11 ) w1 . By w2 4 4 4 w2 solving it we the get monopolist’s demand w2 function for the first input, 1 x1* a 2 w2 w24 1 2 1 1 2 1 1 2 2 . By inserting it in x2 4 w (2 w w bw) 2 2 w1 x1 , we get the monopolist’s demand w2 1 4 1 2 a ww function for the second input, x2* 1 2 2 1 2 1 . 1 2 2 4 w (2 w w bw) The supply function for the 2 aw monopolist, for the given demand function, is then x0* 1 2 1 1 2 2 . By inserting the 2(2 w w bw) derived supply and demand functions in the goal function of a producer, the profit function is obtained, * a 2 w2 1 2 1 1 2 2 (10) 4(2w w bw) 3 FROM THE PSEUDO COST FUNCTION TO THE PROFIT FUNCTION Another method for obtaining the monopolist's profit function for the given demand function is to start from the monopolist’s cost function, c( x0 , w) , which is an alternative way of describing technology [9]. The decision variable in this model of the monopolist’s profit maximization problem is the quantity of production, maks p0 x0 c( x0 , w) maks wD( x0 ) x0 c( x0 , w) . x0 x0 (11) Taking into account the definition of the pseudo production function, F * (x) D( x0 ) x0 y , the quantity of production can be expressed as the function of pseudo production, x0 g ( y) . In this case the profit maximization problem reduces to maks wy cw, g ( y ) y maks wy c* ( y, w ), (12) y where c* ( y, w) can be called the pseudo cost function. The first order necessary condition for the profit maximization problem gives the following equation which needs to be solved to get us to the pseudo production function, c* ( y, w) . (13) y Therefore, profit maximization for the given demand function in this model is characterized by the equality between the price of the pseudo product and the marginal pseudo cost. To illustrate how the profit function for the monopolist can be derived by starting from the pseudo cost function, we start from the chosen production function in (5). The cost function is derived from the model of cost minimization for the given level of production1, w c( x0 , w ) min wx x (14) 1 1 4 4 1 2 subject to x x x0. From the theory of production it is known that the economic efficiency is characterized by f ( x1 , x 2 ) x1 the equality between the marginal rate of technical substitution MRTS and the f ( x1 , x 2 ) x 2 w1 input price ratio [8]. In our case it is w2 x w MRTS 2 1 , from which the long-run expansion path is derived, which describes the x1 w2 wx optimal combinations of inputs at each output level as output expands, x2 1 1 . Substituting w2 it in the constraint, we get the conditional input demand functions, which give the cost minimizing input levels for the given output level, 1 1 1 x1 ( w1 , w2 , x0 ) w1 2 w22 x 02 and 1 x 2 ( w1 , w2 , x0 ) w12 w2 2 x02 , whose substitution in the goal function of (14) gives us the cost function 1 1 c( w1 , w2 , x0 ) 2 w12 w22 ( x0 ) 2 . (15) Our goal is to express it in terms of the pseudo production function and to obtain the pseudo cost function. For the given inverse demand function in (6) the pseudo production function is defined as y x0 (a bx0 ) ax0 bx02 . Therefore, the quantity of production is related to the pseudo production function by the following quadratic equation bx0 ax0 y 0 from 2 which it follows x0 a a 2 4by 2b and the pseudocost function as a function of pseudoproduction function collapses to 1 1 c* ( y, w1 , w2 ) 2w12 w22 ( a a 2 4by 2 ) . 2b Therefore, the following optimization model needs to be solved 1 More on derivation and the properties of the cost function can be found in [8]. (16) 1 1 maks wy 2w12 w22 ( y a a 2 4by 2 ) . 2b (17) The first order necessary condition is 1 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 2w w a 2w w c w. 2 y b b a 4by (18) Solving the equation for y gives the pseudoproduction function, 1 1 a 2 4ww12 w22 bw2 y , 2 4 1 1 2 2 2w1 w2 bw (19) whose substitution into the goal function leads to the same profit function as before, 1 1 1 1 a 2 4ww12 w22 bw2 a 2 w2 a 2 w2 2 2 w 2 w w 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 4 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4(2w1 w2 bw) 4(2 w1 w2 bw) 2w1 w2 bw * (20) 4 HOTELLING’S LEMMA According to Hotelling’s lemma [1,2,5,7,8], the derivative of the profit function for a perfectly competitive, price-taking firm with respect to the product price of a firm is equal to the firm’s quantity supplied. Since the monopolist is not the price taker, the question is how can be Hotelling’s lemma applied in this case. Starting from the monopolist’s profit function and looking at the parameter w as the price of the pseudo product, we can apply Hotelling’s lemma and get the pseudo production function [6], 1 1 1 1 * a 2 2 w(2w12 w22 bw) bw2 a 2 4ww12 w22 bw2 y . 1 1 1 1 w 4 4 2 2 (2 w12 w22 bw) (2 w12 w22 bw) (21) The supply function of a monopolist can be obtained from the pseudo production function for * p0* x0* w(a bx0* ) x0* ax0* b( x0* ) 2 or the given demand function, w w w * b( x0* ) 2 ax0* 0 . So we got the quadratic equation which needs to be solved to get the w supply function, x0* , for the given demand function a a 2 4b x0* 2b 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 4ww w bw2 a a a b (2w w bw)2 w 2b * 2 2 aw 1 2 1 1 2 2 2(2w w bw) . (22) 5 FROM THE PROFIT FUNCTION TO THE PSEUDO PRODUCTION FUNCTION Starting from the profit function for the monopolist, how can we go back and recover the pseudo production function? Since the profit function gives the maximum profit for every combination of input prices, w1 and w2 , and the parameter w, its definition brings us to the following inequality (w, w1 , w2 ) wF (x) DF (x) w1 x1 w2 x2 w1 , w2 , w . (23) Definition of the pseudo production function enables us to rewrite the previous inequality as (w, w1 , w2 ) wF * (x) w1 x1 w2 x2 w1 , w2 , w , (24) from which it follows that the pseudo production function is the result of the following optimization problem F * (x) max y : wy w1 x1 w2 x2 ( w, w1 , w2 ) . (25) By normalizing the price of the pseudo product and dividing all the input prices by w , w w W1 1 ,W2 2 , the previous optimization problem reduces to w w F * (x) max y : y W1 x1 W2 x2 (1,W1 ,W2 ) , W1 ,W2 and (26) F * (x) min W1 x1 W2 x2 (1,W1 ,W2 ) . (27) W1 ,W2 Its solution is the monopolist's pseudo production function. Below we illustrate how to recover the pseudo production function from the profit function. Starting from our derived profit function in (10), the normalized profit function2 is 2 a and the pseudo production function can be obtained as the (1,W1 ,W2 ) 1 1 2 2 4(2W1 W2 b) solution to the following optimization problem F * (x) min W1 x1 W2 x2 W1 ,W2 a2 1 2 . 1 2 2 (28) 4(2W1 W b) The system of equations that expresses the first order necessary conditions follows, 1 1 1 1 f a2 x1 (2W12W22 b) 2W1 2W22 0 W1 4 f a x2 (2W1 W b) 2W1 W2 0 w2 4 2 2 The profit function (1, 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 (29) 1 2 w1 w2 , ) is actually the conjugate function to the pseudoproduction function w w F * (x) if F * (x) is concave [5 ]. More on the conjugacy approach to duality theory can be found in [7]. 1 Multiplying 1 2 quantities of inputs gives x1 x2 1 a2 (2W12W22 b) 4 16 which implies 1 2 2 1 1 a 14 14 a 14 14 b 2 2 2W1 W b x1 x1 and W1 W2 x1 x1 . The product of the corresponding input 2 4 2 1 1 1 1 a b a 1 1 b 1 1 with its price reduces to W1 x1 x14 x24 x12 x22 and W2 x2 x14 x24 x12 x22 . Inserting the 4 2 4 2 given results in the goal function gives 1 1 1 1 a 1 1 b 1 1 a 1 1 F * (x) 2 x14 x24 2 x12 x22 x14 x24 ax14 x24 bx12 x22 , 4 2 2 (30) which is the pseudo production function we started from. 6 CONCLUSION Since duality in microeconomics rests on price taking behaviour, the main idea was to apply the known duality principles to the monopolistic case. In deriving the profit function for the monopolist the standard approach is shown which includes starting from the production function and the defined pseudo production function. We give another approach by starting from the pseudo cost function. Finally, starting from the derived profit function the pseudo production function is recovered. A version of Hotelling’s lemma, important from the empirical standpoint, is given. Application of the duality theory in monopoly to the real data is left for the future research. References: [1] Appelbaum, E. (1975). Essays in the Theory and Applications of Duality in Economics. PhD Thesis. Vancouver:University of British Columbia. [2] Appelbaum, E. (1979). Testing Price Taking Behaviour. Journal of Econometrics, 9: 283–294. [3] Blume, L. E. (2008). Convex Programming. In Durlauf, S. N., Blume, L. E. (Eds.). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. <http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000348> doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0314. [4] Blume, L. E. (2008). Duality. In Durlauf, S. N., Blume, L. E. (Eds.). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. <http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_D000196> doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0411. [5] Diewert, W.E. (1982). Duality Approaches to Microeconomic Theory. In Intriligator, M.D., Arrow, K..J. (Eds.). Handbook of Mathematical Economics (pp. 535–599). Amsterdam: North Holland. [6] Krpan, M. (2011). Dualnost u mikroekonomskoj teoriji. PhD Thesis. Zagreb: Sveučilište u Zagrebu, Ekonomski fakultet-Zagreb. [7] Lau, L. J. (1978). Applications of Profit Function. In Fuss, M., McFadden, D. (Eds.). Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Applications (pp. 133–216). Vol II, Part IV. Amsterdam: North-Holland. [8] Mas – Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., Green, J. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. [9] Shepard, R.W. (1970). Theory of Cost and Production Functions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.