Indonesia Country Paper on Illegal Logging Prepared for the World Bank-WWF Workshop on Control of Illegal Logging in East Asia Jakarta, 28 August 2000 Written by: Neil Scotland (Department for International Development, DFID) with contributions from: Joyotee Smith (Centre for International Forest Research, CIFOR); Hikma Lisa, Marc Hiller, Ben Jarvis, Charlotte Kaiser, Mark Leighton, Laura Paulson, Edward Pollard, Dessy Ratnasari, Ramsey Ravanell, Scott Stanley (Proyek HKM, Gunung Palung, West Kalimantan); Erwidodo (Ministry of Forestry and Estate Crops, Centre for Research and Development); Dave Currey (Environmental Investigation Agency, EIA); Agus Setyarso (WWF - Indonesia) The paper was edited by William Finlayson and Neil Scotland Preface Note: This paper is in draft form. A final version will be prepared after the workshop. Any comments and suggestions on the paper will be gratefully received by the authors. This paper has been prepared for the World Bank-WWF workshop on Control of Illegal Logging in East Asia, held in Jakarta on 28-29 August 2000 by drawing together material from a number of sources in an attempt to present a comprehensive overview of the problem of illegal logging in Indonesia. Those who have contributed are: Neil Scotland (Department for International Development, DFID); Joyotee Smith (Centre for International Forest Research, CIFOR); Hikma Lisa, Marc Hiller, Ben Jarvis, Charlotte Kaiser, Mark Leighton, Laura Paulson, Edward Pollard, Dessy Ratnasari, Ramsey Ravanell, Scott Stanley (Proyek HKM, Gunung Palung, West Kalimantan); Erwidodo (Ministry of Forestry and Estate Crops, Centre for Research and Development); Dave Currey (Environmental Investigation Agency, EIA); Agus Setyarso (Worldwide Fund for Nature, Indonesia). The paper was edited by William Finlayson and Neil Scotland. The authors are grateful for help and comments provided by Erik Meijaard, Rona Dennis and Anne Casson (CIFOR), William McGrath (World Bank) and Agus Purnomo (WWF Indonesia). Note: Various abbreviations that are very commonly used, such as “HPH”, are derived from the Indonesian terms, but are only explained in this text, at their first occurrence, by the English translation. Contents Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 1 Forests and forestry in Indonesia .................................................................................................... 2 Overview ......................................................................................................................................... 4 National evidence: the imbalance in roundwood supply and demand ........................................ 6 Regional evidence: unlicensed sawmills in Sumatra .................................................................. 8 International evidence: Timber harvesting restrictions and rising smuggling .......................... 10 Different manifestations of the illegal logging trade .................................................................... 13 Illegal logging by concessionaires ............................................................................................ 13 Small-scale illegal logging by local people .............................................................................. 14 Large-scale illegal logging by third parties............................................................................... 19 Bending the rules ...................................................................................................................... 20 Illegal logging under regional autonomy .................................................................................. 21 Encroachment by small scale and subsistence agriculture ....................................................... 23 Corporate encroachment ........................................................................................................... 25 Impact of illegal logging on Indonesia.......................................................................................... 28 Economic .................................................................................................................................. 28 Forest fires ................................................................................................................................ 29 Wildlife poaching...................................................................................................................... 29 Social......................................................................................................................................... 30 Beneficial impacts ..................................................................................................................... 30 Government strategy ..................................................................................................................... 32 Prevention ................................................................................................................................. 33 Detection ................................................................................................................................... 35 Suppression ............................................................................................................................... 36 Conclusions and recommendations ............................................................................................... 38 References ..................................................................................................................................... 43 Introduction Indonesia, with about 211 million people, is the world’s fourth largest country by population. It consists of more than 13,000 islands and has some 300 different ethnic groups, who speak an estimated 365 different languages and dialects. Indonesia's forests were once vast, but massive deforestation in recent years has led to serious concern over the future of this important resource. Deforestation has been driven by a number of factors, including a growing population, growing demand for agricultural land, and a forestry development policy which has condoned 30 years of heavy and unsustainable exploitation of the forests by big business. In recent years a new threat has emerged, bound up in the more general problems of corruption and vested interests which cause such enormous public losses in Indonesia every year. The problem is illegal logging, which has always been there, but which has grown to epidemic proportions in the flux of post-Soeharto Indonesia. With dwindling forests, and dwindling respect for the law and central government policy, it is a daunting challenge for the government to try to control this illegal logging, and to minimise the threat it presents to the environment, as well as to the economy, and in fact to many aspects of life in a stable society. This paper describes different manifestations of the problem, and outlines steps taken so far to combat it. It is intended to provide a reflection from Indonesia of the broad underlying issues set out in a theoretical paper, Forest Law Enforcement: Policies, Strategies and Technologies, prepared for the workshop by the World Bank. (McGrath and Grandalski, 2000) The paper comprises several sections. First, it presents an overview of the forest sector in Indonesia. This is followed by an overview of illegal logging as it is experienced here. To illustrate more clearly how the problem afflicts Indonesia, some of its manifestations are then presented, with evidence from a number of local examples. Government strategy is then discussed, with particular reference to prevention, detection and suppression. The impact of illegal logging on the country is then discussed. The whole question is then recapitulated from a historical point of view, and finally some recommendations made. 1 Forests and forestry in Indonesia Forests play an important role in both the formal and informal economies of Indonesia. But in spite of their importance to the nation, Indonesia has allowed massive deforestation to take place in recent years. The latest estimates prepared by The Ministry of Forestry and Estate Crops (MOFEC) present a bleak picture. The annual rate of deforestation has increased until the average for 1985-97 was at least 1.7 million ha, and at the end of this period it is likely to have been even higher, with about 2 million ha lost annually since 1997. Table 1 shows that in 1985-97 Sumatra lost 6.7 million ha of forest, Kalimantan 8.5 million, and Sulawesi 2.3 million. While the latest estimates suggest that there are still about 57 million ha of forest on these islands, only 15% of this area is on non-swampy lowland plains, where the types of forest grow that are of greatest importance both to biodiversity and to the economy. At the present rates of loss, forests will be extinct on the dry-land lowland plains of Sumatra by 2005, and in Kalimantan soon after 2010 (Holmes 1999). Table 1. Summary of forest conversions, 1985-97 1985 Forest (million ha) 1997 % of total land area Forest (million ha) Deforestation % of total land area Decrease 1985(97 (million ha) % loss ha/year Sumatra 23.3 49% 16.6 35% 6.7 29% 558,000 Kalimantan 40.0 75% 31.5 60% 8.5 21% 706,000 Sulawesi 11.3 61% 9.0 49% 2.3 20% 189,000 Maluku* 6.4 81% >5.5 ? >0.8 13% >67,000 35.0 84% 33.2 81% 1.8 5% 150,000 115.9 68.5% c. 95.9 57% 20.5 17% 1,709,000 Papua TOTAL Source: Holmes (1999). *Data for Maluku are preliminary. Loss of the forests will have a very great adverse impact on the economy. Although forestry contributes only a small part of total gross domestic product (GDP), Indonesia relies heavily on export-earning sectors such as the wood-processing industries (tables 2-3). Exports of plywood, paper and sawnwood were all among the highest export earners in the 1990s. Furthermore, while the calculated GDP shows only limited gains from forestry, it does not show the importance of forests to smallholder livelihoods and the informal economy. Estimates of the number of people in the informal sector who depend on the forests for their living vary from a conservative 14 million who actually live in forest concession areas, to 70 million who in some way rely on either direct benefits such as the harvest of timber or non-timber forest products (NTFPs) or on indirect benefits, such as protection from flooding. The sector also generates large numbers of jobs in harvesting, primary processing and secondary processing enterprises. Official government data shows that approximately 260,000 people are employed in Indonesia's licensed sawmills and plymills. Of this total, approximately 52,000 people are employed in sawmills and 208,000 are employed in plymills. Unlicensed sawmills employ an estimated 30,000-40,000 people (NRM, 2000). 2 Table 2. GDP by industrial origin (% distribution, 1993 constant prices) Industrial origin 1996 1997 1998 1999* 15.4 14.9 17.0 17.3 Forestry 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.6 Manufacturing industry 24.7 24.8 25.3 25.9 Wood and wood products 1.4 1.3 1.1 1.0 Paper and paper products 0.9 0.9 1.0 1.0 Non-oil and gas GDP as % of total 91.6 92.0 90.9 91.1 413.8 433.2 376.9 378.1 Agriculture, livestock, forestry and fisheries of which of which Memorandum item GDP (Rp trillion) * Preliminary figures Source: BPS Table 3. Key exports ($m) Item 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Rank in 1999 Clothing 3,226 3,388 3,576 2,876 2,588 3,818 1 Textiles 2,573 2,816 2,975 3,658 4,740 3,418 2 Plywood 3,716 3,462 3,595 3,411 2,078 2,256 3 671 1,011 955 939 1,426 1,966 4 1,391 2,191 2,227 1,988 1,548 1,236 7 Palm oil 718 747 826 1,446 745 1,114 9 Sawn wood 510 454 473 380 164 296 14 40,053 45,418 49,814 53,444 48,847 4,077 − Paper & paper products Processed rubber Total exports Source: BPS 3 Overview Illegal logging takes on many forms, from over-harvesting by licensed concessionaires, to illegal operations run by criminal syndicates, or to encroachment into conservation areas by smallholder farmers. It is a highly contentious subject, embracing as it does issues that include corruption, inequitable distribution of benefits, injustices, and a host of other highly emotive matters. However, despite the complexity of the problem, there are three fundamental factors that are always present in the many manifestations of illegal logging found in Indonesia. The first is a demand for timber which greatly exceeds the sustainable supply. The second is the corruption of the military and police forces, which are themselves heavily involved in the illegal trade. The third is the misuse of forests by politicians for purposes of political patronage. These problems, when taken together ensure (a) that the law is not enforced (b) that no demand for timber goes unsatisfied and (c) that many politicians were complicit in this state of affairs. This section examines these factors and undertakes a preliminary analysis of how the nature of illegal logging has changed over time. The process is intimately related to timber supplies and their progressive decline both in countries supplying timber and in countries importing timber. There has also been a rising demand from domestic processing industries as well as from abroad. The process is also related to the distribution of property rights to forested areas. In the case of Indonesia it is also closely linked to the recent change in the political regime, the new Forestry Law and and the Decentralization process. Under the Soeharto regime the state claimed sovereignty over forested areas and granted 20-year timber concessions over large areas of these “state forests” to urban elites with strong political connections (McCarthy 2000a). Large scale concessions supplied 90% of the official timber supplies up to the late 1980s (Barr 2000). Many concessions were linked to processing facilities whose capacity exceeded the sustainable timber supplies. The enthusiasm for installing new plant arose from the high returns on processing due to log export bans and monopolies in timber export. Barr (2000) reports that in order to provide raw materials for the processing industry, concessionaires went in for undocumented harvesting above their annual allowable cut, repeat harvesting before the approved cutting cycle, or logging in unapproved areas both within and outside their concessions. HPH holders also entered into informal contracts to harvest timber from degraded areas, with the state forestry enterprises that are responsible for the rehabilitation of these areas (Barr 2000). Ascher (1999) and Brown (1999) contend that Soeharto implemented policies to favour the processing sector because the Indonesian-Chinese entrepreneurs who benefited from them in return contributed funds which he used for off-budget spending to further his political objectives. The Indonesian-Chinese entrepreneurs' lack of political power allowed Soeharto to avoid becoming beholden to ethnically indigenous business elites (Ascher 1999). Illegal activities were carried out with relative impunity because powerful networks of patronage (including Indonesian Chinese entrepreneurs and the armed forces) had privileged access to forests and processing opportunities (McCarthy 2000a; Brown 1999). In this way, the forests were sacrificed by the Soeharto regime for political ends. Illegal logging by local communities on their own account also occurred during this period. McCarthy (2000a) provides an example from Jambi province, Sumatra. It shows how this activity was linked to an allocation of forest property rights which criminalised traditional timber extraction by local communities. Traditional adat land rights were nullified by the industrial concessions. Land shortages were created which led to “illegal” logging and “encroachment” by communities into what had been their own land but were now restricted areas. McCarthy highlights the fact that during the Soeharto regime "better enforcement" was always put forward as the solution to illegal logging, to mask the politically sensitive underlying cause, which was the privileged access to forest revenues by powerful networks of patronage. 4 During the 1990s the dominance of concessions began to decline. The government revoked concessions or failed to renew licenses. In addition, concessions were given up when their supply of large-diameter high-value species ran out (Barr 2000). In other cases the profitability of concessions had declined because of the sharp devaluation of the currency (Scotland, 1999) and the scarcity of capital resulting from the economic crisis (Barr 2000). Around the same time a proliferation of smaller sawmills was recorded, as Obidzinski & Suramenggala (2000a) have shown. These new small sawmills obtained timber almost entirely from illegal logging. Some sawmills were licensed for their lifetime, while they held logging permits for only one year (McCarthy 2000b). These new small mills represented an expansion in the processing sector beyond the sustainable yield and were a key factor in the development of illegal logging. The processing industries were increasingly fed from the clear felling that took place under forest conversion permits for large scale plantations (Barr 2000), the issue and use of these permits (known as IPK) being in many cases contrary to the intention of the law. An important development has been the rapid increase of capacity in the pulp and paper sector, which has gone from virtually nothing in the early 1980s to almost 15 million t in 1999 (Sunderlin 1999; Barr, 2000). This development has increased the profitability of IPKs – along with development of technologies for processing small-diameter timber for plywood (Barr 2000). The demand from the domestic processing sector has therefore continued to be an important underlying factor in promoting illegal logging. The nature of the demand and the nature of the processing sector have adapted to the changing nature of timber supplies. The suppliers of timber also began to change in response to the scarcity of capital and the changing nature of the timber supplies. Sawmill owners and independent entrepreneurs increasingly provided financing to illegal groups, which could employ manual logging methods and provide cheap raw material for sawmills and pulp mills. Barr (2000) reports that even concession holders also in some cases financed illegal logging groups. A likely hypothesis is that the demand for timber from illegal logging groups during this period has been linked to the increasing competitive advantage of manual logging methods when the profitability of large-scale logging with heavy machinery has been declining because of the factors mentioned above. The costs of manual logging were declining because of the plentiful supply of cheap labour released by the economic crisis. However, no legal role for small-scale foresters existed at this time. In this way the legal framework may have encouraged illegal logging. McCarthy (2000b) shows how powerful networks at the provincial and district levels have supported illegal logging. Timber entrepreneurs and sawmill owners at the district level have obtained legal immunity by making payments to local officials and the army. These networks of power and interest made it highly improbable that regulations would be implemented at the local level. Not only was it an illegal type of logging that was providing their income, but also, under the current legal framework, the benefits from legal logging accrued largely to the central government. These findings emphasise the political and legal underpinnings of the illegal logging problem, both in Jakarta and at the local level. Demand from abroad also became important in this period. Sizer & Plouvier (2000) report the increasing demand from Asian (particularly Malaysian) timber companies. They attribute this to the log shortages faced by timber industries in Japan, Korea, mainland China, Taiwan, Malaysia, Thailand, and the Philippines. They also claim that more effective law enforcement and tax increases in Malaysia and logging bans in a number of Asian countries have increased Malaysian investment abroad. Malaysian companies have apparently obtained capital through family and business networks and by listing on the Kuala Lumpur stock exchange (Sizer & Plouvier 2000). While many of these companies are increasingly tapping forests in Africa, the Asian monetary crisis led many to source timber from places closer to home, and the border with Indonesia in Borneo provided a particularly convenient point of access. In theory a number of recent changes should be conducive to the control of illegal logging. The new political regime has publicly stated its commitment to controlling illegal logging and stamping 5 out corruption. The new Forestry Law of 1999 takes a first step towards addressing some of the underlying causes analysed above. For one thing it begins to create a legal framework for community forestry, which may provide an opportunity to take advantage of the probable increase in the competitive advantage of small-scale forestry. Decentralization allows provinces to design their own fiscal policies and retain a larger share of revenues from local natural resources, so that arguably it should encourage them to enforce sustainable forest management. What effect these new developments will have in practice is however unclear. Early experiences recorded in case studies given below, indicate that these changes on their own, without supporting policies and institutions, are unlikely to be successful. National evidence: the imbalance in roundwood supply and demand Illegal logging is essentially driven by supply and demand. The export-oriented wood-processing industry has been allowed to expand without any reference to the sustainable supply of timber, while domestic demand, in a country of more than 200 million people, has been almost entirely neglected. Access to the resource has been unrestricted, and since the official log supply is controlled almost entirely by the export industries, domestic needs have come to be met largely by illegal logging. In recent years there has also been a marked increase in illegal exports of roundwood and sawnwood of the more desirable species. By comparing official roundwood production data with the reported exports, minus the sum of imports and apparent domestic consumption, it becomes evident that there is an annual discrepancy in the order of tens of millions of cubic metres between the official roundwood production figures and the apparent output from the wood-processing sector. Estimates of this discrepancy can only be given as rough (but sufficiently good) approximations, since they depend on a number of uncertain variables, particularly the extent of domestic demand and the volume of timber smuggled out of the country. Evidence of the discrepancy is shown in table 4 below. Table 4. Estimated timber supply-demand imbalance 1997/98 1997/98 Log supply (‘000 m3) 29,500 Log supply equivalent from imports (‘000m3 rwe) 20,427 Log supply equivalent from other sources (‘000m rwe) 1,600 Total supply (‘000m3 rwe) 51,527 3 Domestic demand (‘000 m3 rwe)* 35,267 Log equivalent of exports (‘000 m rwe) 48,873 Total demand (‘000m3 rwe) 84,140 Net wood balance (‘000 m3) -32,613 3 * estimate **Adjusted to account for pulp processed into paper Source: Central Statistics Bureau (BPS), Ministry of Forestry and Estate Crops, quoted in ITFMP (1999) 6 The imbalance between supply and demand could be said to have arisen because woodprocessing mills are licensed by the Ministry of Industry and Trade, while forest exploitation is licensed by MOFEC. At a deeper level, the trouble is that there has been little or no co-ordination between these two ministries over the exploitation of the country’s forests, and this administrative shortcoming has had a part in producing the vast over-capacity that can now be seen in the industry. Even in recent years, the government has continued to encourage rapid development of industry with scant regard to the supply of roundwood which the remaining forests are capable of sustaining. Although plywood manufacturing is still predominant, the pulp and paper industry has been encouraged in recent years to expand aggressively. In 1991, the installed capacity for pulp manufacture was 1.1 million t per annum, but by 1999 this had risen to 4.9 million t per annum. The production of one tonne of pulp requires about four cubic metres of roundwood, so the total volume of roundwood required by the pulp industry, at close to 20 million cubic metres per annum and rising, is quite staggering. The imbalance problem can therefore be set out as follows: 1. The natural forest has a limited capacity to supply roundwood. 2. The requirements of the processing industry have been allowed to exceed the forest’s capacity to supply them. 3. Export-led growth strategies have been pursued, but meeting domestic demand has not been given adequate attention. 4. The combined needs of a large and growing domestic market and an export-oriented industry have placed an intolerable strain on the forests. 5. The establishment of industrial forest plantations has not proceeded anything like quickly enough to meet the shortfall in demand. 6. Forest clearance (actually, or more often fictionally, for either forest plantations or estate crops) has been used to provide a short-term additional supply of roundwood. 7. The remaining shortfall between the legal supply and total demand has created a niche in the market which has been filled by illegal loggers. The industry and the domestic market are now totally dependent on this supply of roundwood. It is bound to prove itself unsustainable. Problems caused by the imbalance between the processing capacity and the sustainable supply are compounded by the political connections (and powerful lobbying power) of the major timber groups, who have worked hard to protect their operations. A study by Brown (1999) showed that the largest 10 timber groups held 47% of the 51.3 million ha allocated as production forest under concessions in 1997/98. Table 5 shows these holdings and the connections of the owners. With good access by the owners to the top of government, changing the status quo in forestry has been, and still is, very difficult. The wealth of these groups makes them powerful forces even now after the New Order has fallen. 7 Table 5. Ranking of timber groups by concession holdings, 1997/1998 Group name Number of concessions Concession area (million ha) Barito Pacific 52 5.0 Djajanti 29 3.4 KLI 19 2.8 Alas Kusuma 19 2.7 Inhutani I 3 2.6 Bob Hasan Group 12 2.1 Armed Forces/Army 7 1.8 Korindo 8 1.6 Kodeco 3 1.1 Sumalindo 9 1.1 Sub-total 161 24.2 Total (including others) 464 51.3 Top 10 as % of total 35 47 Source: Brown (1999) As the gap between the supply and the requirements of the processing industry grows wider, so the forces driving illegal logging will grow stronger, and the vested interests behind the problem will become more deeply entrenched. Evidence from the province of Jambi in Sumatra shows that unlicensed sawmills and those who supply them with timber have the backing of members of the military and the bureaucracy (see box 1), and there is evidence of a repetition of this pattern in many other parts of Indonesia, including the involvement of local police in an incident in January 2000 in which two people from Telapak and the Environmental Investigation Agency (EIA) were taken hostage in Central Kalimantan after exposing an illegal logging racket. In late May the Minister of Defence, Mr Juwono Sudarsono, warned that the military and police were facing an acute shortage of funds, and that this was compromising their efforts to act as a professional security force. He said that state financing covered only 25% of the military's requirements, and warned that this shortfall in funding would push soldiers (and police) into supplementing their incomes by alternative means, often outside the law. This is consistent with the the huge network of business activities (both legal and illegal) controlled by the military, which many experts argue nullifies its ability to operate as a professional fighting force. Budgetary constraints and recession may have made many legal military businesses unprofitable, and pushed the security forces further into illicit activities, including illegal mining and logging. This may be one reason for the upsurge in lawlessness in the forest sector since 1998. Regional evidence: unlicensed sawmills in Sumatra The entrenched nature of illegal logging and the difficulties likely to be faced in tackling the problem were made clear by a recent survey of unlicensed sawmills around the Bukit Tigapuluh National Park, conducted in 1999 by the Worldwide Fund for Nature (WWF). 8 Bukit Tigapuluh National Park straddles the border between the provinces of Jambi and Riau in Sumatra. The park covers about 127,000 ha, of which on the Riau side roughly 57,000 were formerly classified as “limited production forest” and 37,000 ha are “protection forest”, while on the Jambi side a further 33,000 ha are “protection forest”. The area is rich in biodiversity, with 700 recorded plant species, 246 of which are used by indigenous communities in and around the park. There are also 59 species of mammal and 192 species of bird in the park. Among the mammals living in the area are the highly endangered Sumatran tiger (Panthera tigris), Sumatran elephant (Elephas maximus), clouded leopard (Neofelis nebulosa), oriental small-clawed otter (Aonyx cinera), and Malayan tapir (Tapirus indicus). The park and the surrounding forest concessions are threatened by illegal logging. The survey, conducted by the local office of the WWF, discovered 25 unlicensed sawmills in the immediate vicinity of the park. The sawmills visited typically had between one and four saws with a capacity to process between five and ten cubic metres of roundwood per day. The estimated annual processing capacity of these sawmills is therefore about 230,000 cubic metres of roundwood. These sawmills have no official supply of timber, and therefore rely upon an illegal supply from the surrounding forests, some of which lie in the national park and some of which are on concession land. Gangs of illegal loggers, some local and some from further away, commonly use the infrastructure developed by concessionaires to gain access to the forest and then transport illegally felled timber to their markets. By logging in areas already disturbed by concessionaires, illegal loggers take the future crop trees and damage the residual stand, often to a point where no future harvest will be possible. Typical management arrangements for a sawmill in the area include the provision of capital by the local business community, with the backing of either government employees or members of the military. The involvement of uniformed officials as backers – and particularly members of the security forces – effectively puts the mills beyond the reach of the law. The logging gangs themselves are often made up of people from the forest fringe communities who lost access rights to the forest when industrial harvesting licences were granted to logging companies in the 1970s and 1980s. The combined pressure of concessions and illegal logging in the same areas results in widespread deforestation and land degradation. Table 6. Backing for illegal sawmills south of Bukit Tigapuluh National Park Backer Number of sawmills Police 1 Armed Forces / Army 13 Regional Public Works Department / Service 2 Regional Forestry Department / Service 3 Private backing 1 Unknown 5 Total 25 Illegally felled logs are sold to the mills at prices well below their market value. In an interview, a resident of Seberida on the Riau side of the park boundary revealed that in early 1999 he received Rp 250,000 (US$30 at the prevailing exchange rate of Rp8,300:$1) per cubic metre of meranti sold to 9 the local sawmills. In other interviews, respondents revealed that the black market price at the end of 1998 was about Rp 380,000 (US$45) per cubic metre, falling to Rp 280,000 (US$35) in the first quarter of 1999. The world price for meranti at the end of 1998 was reported to be about US$110 per cubic metre, and even allowing for the fact that illegal loggers rarely handle premium grade timber, the price they receive for their harvest is excessively low. It is indeed a great folly to allow a resource as valuable as Indonesia’s forests to be degraded for as little as US$30 per cubic metre of roundwood. From the above account it can be seen that the illegal felling problem is deeply entrenched. The institutions that are supposed to be responsible for the sustainable management of Indonesia’s forests and for upholding law and order are heavily involved in the trade. The weak nature of the state institutions, and the reluctance to bring errant civil servants and soldiers to task for graft and corruption, mean that it is likely to take many years to bring about the changes in governance that are required to eliminate the problem. International evidence: Timber harvesting restrictions and rising smuggling There is a strong international dimension to the problem of illegal logging, related both to the direct demand for timber in international markets, and to policies in other countries which restrict the domestic supply of timber, leading to spill-over effects in neighbouring countries which do not have effective controls, with potentially adverse environmental consequences. By effectively enforcing sustainable management of her forests, Indonesia could prevent the adverse effects of international demand. Unfortunately however, controls are lax in Indonesia, making her forests a prime target for illegal exploitation by foreign entrepreneurs. At least some of the international trade in illegal Indonesian timber is the result of policies to restrict the harvest of timber in neighbouring Asian countries. Restricting harvesting is just one option that can be used to assist in balanced long-term forest conservation. However, harvesting bans and restrictions tend to treat the symptoms of poor policies and management, rather than directly correcting the underlying conflicts and problems that have led to misuse and non-sustainable exploitation. A surprising number of countries in the Southeast Asian regional have imposed restrictions on timber harvesting in natural forests as a result of severe environmental degradation. The restrictions now in place are presented in Table 7 below. Trade data show that Asian countries are a significant market for Asian timber producers, which compounds the pressure exerted on countries with no restrictions when restrictions are introduced elsewhere. 10 Table 7. Asia-Pacific timber harvesting restrictions Country Current regulations or restrictions Australia Through Regional Forestry Agreements implemented in the late 1990s large areas of indigenous natural forest have been set aside as reserves. China A log quota and policies designed to encourage plantation development were deemed inadequate for forest conservation in China, which introduced a logging ban in natural forest areas in 1998. The ban will be phased in over a 10 year period. Indonesia No restrictions Malaysia Unknown. Roundwood production from the natural forest has reportedly been declining. New Zealand Logging restrictions were first imposed in parts of New Zealand in the 1970s. Criticism of environmental policy in the 1980s led to further restrictions on commercial logging post-1987, most recently extended to the West Coast State-owned productions forests, which are due to be removed from production. Philippines After suffering massive deforestation throughout the 1970s and 1980s, the Philippines has now implemented logging bans covering natural forest in more than 70% of its 77 provinces. Sri Lanka Sri Lanka closed large areas of its natural forest to commercial interests in 1995. Over 22% of the country's timber supplies now come from unknown sources. Thailand Concern over deforestation followed by a landslide tragedy which claimed 373 lives prompted the Thai government to impose a logging ban in 1989. Nevertheless, deforestation has continued, and has increased in Thailand's neighbouring countries. Vietnam Rapid forest loss prompted the government to introduce a logging ban extending to large tracts of natural forest in 1997. Source: Papers presented at the seminar on the Efficacy of Removing Natural Forests from Timber Production as a Strategy for Conserving Forests, Noosa, Australia, 14 May 2000. The problems associated with foreign companies operating in Cambodia have been well documented (Global Witness, 1999). What is less well understood is the impact of Malaysian (and to a lesser extent Chinese) companies' operations on the forests of Indonesia. The greatest regional impact in the medium term is likely to come from China's recent decision to introduce logging restrictions. There is anecdotal evidence that this policy is already leading to an upsurge in imports of timber from Burma, Cambodia, Laos and Vietnam. Illegal shipments of timber destined for China have also been intercepted in Maluku and Papua in eastern Indonesia. The magnitude of this aspect of the illegal timber trade in Indonesia is not yet well understood, but it is likely to be significant and could become more so given Indonesia's long and porous borders and weak law enforcement. It is already well known at least that there is an illegal cross border trade in timber from Indonesia to Malaysia, and to a lesser extent China. Indonesia has recently reintroduced log exports, and some argue this has allowed an increase in smuggled timber due to the ease with which the necessary documents can be forged. The secretary-general of MOFEC, who has been overseeing the Indonesian government's efforts to control illegal logging, has identified several major routes through which timber is smuggled out of the country: from Jambi and Riau to peninsular Malaysia and Singapore; from West Kalimantan to Sarawak; from East Kalimantan to Sabah; and from Maluku and 11 Papua to China. His investigation into the trade, which he estimates costs the Indonesian government $8−10m every month in lost revenues, has been hampered by leaks from within his office, and logging gangs have been tipped off in advance of raids on their operations. In mid-June efforts to control the cross-border theft on the island of Borneo led to a tense stand-off between the respective police forces of both countries (despite the alleged complicity of both countries' security forces in the trade). According to press reports Indonesia and Malaysia have now agreed to set up a joint inquiry into the trade, but with the complicity of the security forces on both sides of the border, inadequate law enforcement (Indonesia's 1000 km-long border with Malaysia is policed by only 30 officers), and the suspected heavy dependence of the Sarawak and Sabah wood-processing industries on Indonesian timber, there are considerable impediments to bringing this cross-border trade under control. In field studies in Kalimantan, researchers were told that Malaysia is a key destination for timber from the area. Obidzinski & Suramenggala (2000b) found that in Malinau, East Kalimantan, timber traders were selling planks and squared logs to buyers who, reportedly shipped the timber to the border crossing with Malaysia. This required payments to officials along the route of about three million rupiah for 20–30 cubic metres of timber, which is about 8–12% of its selling price at the Malaysian border (Obidzinski & Suramenggala 2000b). In Berau, the larger mills, which process large-diameter (40–50 cm) red meranti and keruing, sell their entire output outside the area- much of it reportedly ending up in Malaysia. Wadley & Dennis (paper in preparation) note that timber harvested by community co-operatives in western Kalimantan was apparently destined for Malaysia. Casson's (2000) discussions with timber suppliers and buyers in Central Kalimantan appeared to indicate that Malaysia is a key destination for timber from the area and that from Malaysia it is shipped to China, Japan, Taiwan, Hong Kong, Belgium and Holland, the latter two acting as clearing houses for the European market. While the reported destinations cannot be verified, they are consistent with the secretary-general’s reports of cross-border trade. 12 Different manifestations of the illegal logging trade This section examines different aspects of the illegal logging problem, and illustrates them from studies made by organisations in Indonesia. Although no comprehensive survey data exist, some of the ways in which illegal logging manifests itself are known to be more widespread than others, and therefore more important to tackle. Some may be driven by injustice, necessity, or opaque property rights and a lack of tenurial security, so that if solutions are not to bear harshly on poor people, measures may be needed that go beyond simple forest protection by better policing. Illegal logging by concessionaires Forest exploitation in Indonesia is based on a system of forest concession licences (HPH) issued for a period of 20 years. Although they only have 20-year rights, concessionaires are obliged to manage the forest on the basis of a 35-year cycle, under the Indonesian Selective Cutting and Planting System (TPTI). It is a system of selective felling designed to ensure re-growth of the logged-over stand in time for the next felling. The concessionaires must submit an annual cutting plan to the regional office of MOFEC, specifying where felling is to take place. The ministry approves these plans and is supposed to ensure that the annual cut remains within pre-determined sustainable limits. Even where it is strictly applied, as is very seldom the case, the system is a rather primitive and imperfect method of yield control, but at worst it should leave a forest capable of eventually regenerating itself. The system is in fact subject to widespread abuse, which is in effect a form of illegal logging. Self-reporting and the complicity of inspectors allow concessionaires to under-report the amount of timber they harvest, so while records show that the harvests of timber remain within the legal limit, in reality substantially larger volumes are removed. This abuse results in the removal of seed trees and immature growing stock and in excessive damage to the residual stand. It undermines the potential of the forest to recover and yield a second harvest, even on a much longer cycle than the intended 35 years. To illustrate the likely extent of this form of illegal logging, Hariadi Kartodihardjo (2000) examined log production statistics for the period 1977–98. His estimate of the illegal harvest is based on the difference between the real and the reported production, and he found that annual average unreported production was in the region of 12.8m m3 per annum. Over-harvesting degrades the residual forest, making it easier to justify conversion to other uses, such as industrial forest plantations (HTI), oil palm, or rubber (see also Corporate encroachment below). Timber obtained from authorised clearings for conversion is very valuable, as it can be marketed to the pulp industry, and attracts only very low taxes and levies. Apart from the initial overcutting, the sequence of forest degradation and loss is legal, and is encouraged by a series of perverse incentives which reward the perpetrators of this environmental destruction at every step in the process. Illegal logging by concessionaires also includes encroachment into other concessions, protection forest areas, and national parks. All types of encroachment are encouraged by inaccurate maps, which leave overlapping claims unresolved and may be used to excuse opportunistic attempts to obtain illicit timber. Even this excuse is not always used, and for example in Central Kalimantan one concession was found to have laid a road straight through poorly stocked heath forest in its own concession and to have begun operating deep into a neighbouring one. The presence of the other concessionaires means that encroachments do not always go unopposed, but where they succeed they undermine the management plans drawn up for neighbouring concessions,. There is less opposition in national parks, where only under-funded conservation staff need to be pacified. Inaccurate maps sow confusion over the exact boundaries, which allows incursions to be 13 made deep into the parks. This confusion is used to explain what has happened in both Kerinci Seblat National Park and Gunung Leuser National Park in Sumatra. Once a log-transport infrastructure has been laid out by concessionaires encroaching into a protected area it is easy for unlicensed loggers to gain access (see Small-scale illegal logging by local people, below). Illegal logging by concessionaires is encouraged by the many perverse incentives, including the requirement to manage a 20-year concession on a 35-year cycle, the absence of secure tenure, and the frequent reallocation to other uses (such as plantations and transmigration schemes) of forest that has been logged over early in the management cycle. These features negate the possibility of managing the concession over a second felling period and encourage "management" aimed only at short-term gain. Frequent and ill-considered changes to government policy in the sector, such as the recent proposal to nationalise all forest concessions, have the same effect. Although mills and concessions are controlled by the same companies, the concessions are often seen as only a secondary aspect of a timber group’s overall business, and are compelled to provide timber for wood processing plant regardless of the impact on the concession, however short-sighted this attitude may be. Small-scale illegal logging by local people Timber harvesting without a licence is illegal, and until recently the law explicitly made it impossible for forest fringe communities to obtain rights to exploit the forest which they had once thought was their own. Under the Soeharto New Order industrial policy, huge areas were granted to big business and export-oriented industries, and village lands (often including the settlements themselves) were incorporated into forest concessions drawn on old and inaccurate maps. Overnight, timber resources once taken for granted were – according to the law – placed beyond reach. This sort of law of course invites “unlawful” behaviour by its victims. Subsequently, among forest fringe communities, the introduction of chainsaws, the erosion of informal local laws, and the arrival of the market economy have increased both the desire and the ability to harvest timber for commercial gain. Illegal logging by these communities has then greatly increased the threat to the continued existence of the forests. Disregard of the law becomes in itself part of a great social malaise. A somewhat similar state of affairs may arise in areas that are put under protection for purposes of nature conservation, particularly the national parks. The government’s motivation is entirely different, but the effect on the local communities may be much the same. It becomes illegal for them to use the forest, especially to gain a living from logging. Similar problems are well known to conservationists in many countries, and different solutions have been found, adapted to the particular circumstances of each case. “Small-scale” logging is possibly the most difficult to tackle, given the large number of operators and the diverse motives (including poverty and a lack of alternatives) that drive them. The problem is also complicated by the frequent involvement of outside capital and by backing from the police and military. Cases have been documented where loggers end up in debt to middlemen, and must continue logging to pay back loans by deductions from the low wages they earn for their labour. In other cases, however, timber harvesting simply provides an occasional and supplementary form of income, undertaken free from the interference of outside parties. In surveys undertaken during the last three years the Proyek Hutan Kemasyarakatan Gunung Palung (Proyek HKM) has found examples of both of these outcomes. Case study: Trends in Small-Scale Illegal Logging from the Gunung Palung Region of West Kalimantan1 1 This section is based on the work of the Proyek Hutan Kemasyarakatan, Gunung Palung, West Kalimantan. The authors are acknowledged in the foreword to this report. 14 Gunung Palung National Park (GPNP), covering 90,000 hectares, is the only national park in Kalimantan that encompasses a continuous gradient of ecosystems, from montane cloud forest to coastal mangroves. The park also contains the largest remaining area of lowland forest in the province, and due to low hunting pressure hosts high densities of endangered mammals such as clouded leopards, sun bears, proboscis monkeys, and the largest population of wild orang-utans in Kalimantan. As with many of Indonesia’s protected areas, there are numerous threats to GPNP and its associated buffer-zone including a high incidence of illegal logging and wildfires. The park also suffers from poor management, and as a result of short-sighted regional land use planning, the majority of its forested buffer zone is currently destined for conversion to oil palm. In an attempt to help conserve the park, Harvard University's Laboratory of Tropical Forest Ecology was invited to implement an integrated conservation and development project in 14 communities living along the north-west corner of the park. In 1998, the resultant project–Proyek HKM Gunung Palung–carried out a village census in 11 communities and a more detailed household survey among six. This was followed in late 1999 by interviews with forty illegal loggers. Two separate studies of illegal logging intensity were also conducted over the same period, in which tree stumps were identified to species level, assigned an age, and their diameter measured. Data collected in 1990/91 in the four villages of Benewai Agung, prior to the commencement of Proyek HKM, when compared to data collected in the 1998 socio-economic survey, reveals a dramatic increase in the number of households involved in logging. In all four settlements, both the total number and percentage of households earning a substantial portion of income from logging increased across the study period, indicating that logging is increasingly important as a source of local income, and that population growth and migration alone have not caused the rise in total number of households logging. Table 8. Logging activities in Benewai Agung Total number of households receiving a substantial part of their income from logging (legal and illegal) Percentage of total households 1991 1998 % increase 142 235* 65% 27% 38%* 41% * The figures include only households whose primary source of income is logging. The later survey indicates that an additional 9% of them earn a substantial, but not primary income from this source. If this is taken into account, the estimated percentage of households receiving a substantial part of their income from logging is 47%, or a 74% increase. Source: Data for 1991 from Salafsky (1993). The increasing importance of illegal logging has come at a time of massive job losses in the legal forestry sector. At the time of the 1991 survey, at least six timber concessions were active in the region. By 1998, none were active and the loss of legitimate opportunities to work as a logger means that the actual increase in localised illegal logging is greater than the 41% increase reported in the survey. Not only has there been an increase in the number of households logging, the amount of timber sold by local, small logging teams has increased substantially. Groups are working more often, for longer periods of time, and, with the widespread availability of chainsaws, are able to harvest larger volumes of timber (see table 9). 15 Table 9. Changing logging intensities 1990-91 1999-2000 Forest Type Swamp Swamp Swamp, Lowland, & Hill Dipterocarp Team Size 6 5.4 4.6 Tool for Felling Trees Hand Axes/Chainsaws Chainsaws Chainsaws Average Trip Length (days) 14-21 38.3 29.4 Average Volume Sold 10-20 50.3 40.6 Price Received per m3 Rp. 15,000-35,000 Rp. 40,000-350,000 Rp. 40,000-350,000 Average Revenue Rp. 200,000-400,000 Rp. 5,249,714 Rp. 5,465,033 September to January Year-round Year-round per team per trip (m3) per team per trip Time of Year Logging Occurs Source: Data for 1991 from Salafsky (1993). In the past, logging teams were small in size (4-6 people), from local communities, and performed all of the associated tasks, from felling and skidding to marketing. Recently though, in addition to these groups, large, well-organised teams have begun logging in the region. Businessmen from as far afield as Sarawak in Malaysia finance powerful local operators to recruit and manage logging teams. Bosses contract groups to complete different tasks; one team to build railways, another to fell trees, others to pull wood to waterways, and a team to float wood down river. These groups can be as large as 90 individuals, often attract workers from other regions, and typically stay in the forest for months at a time. This emerging trend, with its associated increase in financing, affects the level of damage associated with illegal logging in the area (parameters such as harvesting intensity, area utilised and species selection greatly differ). Large, well-organised groups fell a far greater number of trees than smaller, independently financed groups have in the past. Additionally, large groups are able to enter much further into forests to extract timber. While smaller groups tend to fell trees within a few hundred metres of rivers, larger groups have been observed up to eight kilometres from rivers (table 10). Table 10. Changing logging intensity (1981-1999) (1981-96) (1997-99) Small (4-8) Large (30+) Harvesting intensity (trees/ha) 2.41 8.41 249 Average stump distance from river (m) 282 1554 451 Percentage of stumps more than 500 m from river 20 97 385 Logging team size (number of people) 16 % change A clear distinction between logging group size is the selection of timber species. Larger groups focus on a limited number of species and can quickly remove nearly all mature trees of those species in a stand. In study site II loggers cut 80% of the basal area of ramin (Gonystylus bancanus) greater than 35 cm dbh from an area of 150 hectares, over a period of two years. Unchecked, this high logging intensity could lead to extirpation of valuable timber species–as in the case of gaharu (Aquilaria malaccensis) and belian (Eusideroxylon zwageri) –and lower the value local people place on standing, mature forest. Income Levels and Wealth Community members report a surprisingly large income from illegal logging activities. In 1999, average earnings for labourers (excluding chainsaw operators) was approximately Rp510,000 per trip. The average logging trip length was 29.4 days and villagers reported working an average of six trips per year. Therefore, in 1999, the mean yearly logging income for labourers was Rp3,060,000. Chainsaw operators reported earning approximately 4-5 times that salary, or a conservative estimate of Rp12,240,000 in the same year. From informal discussions with local logging bosses and loggers, Proyek HKM estimates that logging bosses sell illegal timber to sawmills for twice the price paid to villagers. It should be noted that logging bosses may finance more that one team at a time. Although the income earned by illegal loggers is seemingly high, a generated wealth score from the 1998 survey reveals that loggers are disproportionately poor (see graph 1). When divided into wealth categories, logging families were over represented among the poorest families. Additionally, logging families were less likely to be considered wealthy in their communities. The logging survey also found that 92% of loggers reported being in debt to either their logging bosses, money lenders, food and petrol shops, or to many of these people at the same time. Graph 1. Wealth classes in the survey area Source: LTFE (1998). Baseline Socio-economic Status Report 60 % in Wealth Category 50 L o g g e r : Po o r 40 O v e r a ll: Po o r 30 L o g g e r : w e a lth y 20 O v e r a ll: W e a lth y 10 0 Ma ka mu r M a ta n R a y a R a n ta u Pa n ja n g Sedehan S e m a n ja k T o ta l V illa g e Local Causes Three major local causes of illegal logging have been identified in the course of the studies, namely the ease of access to the forest, the physical infrastructure left behind by forest concessions formerly active in the area, and local economic conditions. 17 Ease of Access Local communities have easy access to forests in and around the park, and few physical barriers exist to bar their entrance. In 1998, over 8,500 people lived within a day’s journey of the north-west corner of the park. Furthermore, a paved road constructed in 1992 has significantly increased ease of access for communities from further afield. There are effectively no deterrents preventing villagers from entering protected forests, few guard posts and checkpoints exist around the park, and those built are typically unmanned. Rivers providing access to forests and transportation for illegal wood are rarely patrolled and never guarded. As a result, local forests are treated as an open, free resource. No external costs are associated with illegal logging - no taxes are paid and weak law enforcement means that no pressure is exerted on loggers to stop their activities. The absence of law enforcement means that villagers believe they may log illegally with impunity, and the involvement of local police and the military in the trade further feeds local perceptions of the weakness of state laws. Although locals acknowledge state ownership of forests, villagers often state that they have the right to utilise forests close to their communities. Local people have traditionally utilised nearby forests for timber and NTFPs, and believe that the state does not have the authority to supersede local rights. Scaling up the practice of timber harvesting for domestic purposes into commercial operations requires little additional investment. Capital-intensive methods of harvesting, such as building logging roads and hiring trucks are costly and infrequently used in the area. Loggers instead construct a low cost temporary wooden rail line (jalan kuda-kuda) without the use of metal rails, ties, or chainsaws. These rails can be used to profitably extract wood as far as three kilometres from waterways. Other methods, such as using bicycles or large carts, can efficiently transport wood upwards of ten kilometres without the need for motorised equipment. Chainsaws are widely available locally - many villagers own their own, and those that don't can easily rent. Any additional capital needs can be met by local logging bosses, money lenders, and outside business interests, and with eight local sawmills and numerous wood traders in the area, there is never any problem marketing timber. The Legacy of Forest Concessions At least six companies were granted timber concessions in the GPNP region. Operations began in the late 1960s, but by the mid-1990s all but one had abandoned the area. These companies left behind an infrastructure which has fostered the development of an illegal logging industry in the park area. Most importantly, the companies built sawmills in the region, many of which are still active today. Legal sources of timber have sharply declined and sawmills now accept illegal timber to keep operating. The companies also cleared vegetation from riverbanks and constructed logging roads, both of which have improved the ease of access to remaining forested areas. Employment by timber companies was once an important aspect of the local economy, and attracted migrants into the area. Many of the young men who came in search of work from other regions in West Kalimantan have settled permanently in the area and along with many longer standing residents of the area consider logging to be their occupation. When the concessionaires left the area in the 1990s many such people were left without jobs and had little choice but to begin illegally logging local forests. Local Economic Conditions The change from an economy based on barter to a market economy based on cash within the last twenty years has also promoted illegal logging. Residents of the area now need a cash income, of which there are few sources. Logging can provide a steady source of relatively high income for individuals that have little capital. Working in sawmills, fishing, collecting NTFPs and sharecropping all pay, however these activities generally do not pay as well as logging. Buying additional farmland 18 is expensive and beyond the financial means of most villagers, while Indonesia's recent economic crisis, which resulted in high inflation and further unemployment, has put an additional squeeze on the area. Concluding Remarks From the results of our studies, it is clear that the local reliance, scale, and intensity of illegal logging has increased greatly over the past ten years. We conservatively estimate that local villagers in surveyed communities sold over 30,000 cubic meters of wood from the GPNP and its buffer zones in 1999. As sources of timber continue to decline, illegal logging is expected to penetrate further into the core zone of the park, reducing habitat quality for endangered species and increasing the chance of catastrophic wildfires. Without radical changes in forest policy, management, and the political will to reduce illegal logging, both the future of local protected forests and the people who currently depend upon them look bleak. Large-scale illegal logging by third parties Incidents of large scale logging by third parties have recently been well documented in the media. There is a blurred distinction between illegal logging by third parties and illegal logging by local people, discussed above, since in both cases the loggers themselves are poor, mostly local people. Timber exploitation for commercial gain is nearly always orchestrated by local businessmen, government officials, and the security forces. The difference between this type of illegal logging and what is thought of as “local” lies in the degree of outside organisation, the scale of operation, and the distribution of the benefits. A well known example of this “third party” type of logging is to be found in the Tanjung Puting National Park in Central Kalimantan, especially famous for its many primates, including the orangutan. It has been the focus of considerable international, national and local press concern. Two NGOs, the Environmental Investigation Agency (EIA) and Telapak Indonesia have investigated the illegal logging and have provided detailed information in two campaign reports. Illegal logging in Tanjung Puting National Park was initially directed at Ramin, but has now moved on to other species as a result of growing local scarcity. Ramin is a tropical hardwood which occurs in lowland freshwater swamp and peat swamp forests. It commands a high international price and as a result has been highly sought after to a point of dangerous over-exploitation. Its use in luxury items means that ramin products sell for anything between $600-$1,200 per cubic metre. In interviews with EIA/Telapak, an official of the company suspected of backing illegal logging in the park, PT Tanjung Lingga, talked of plans to export ramin blinds to the United States for $1,200 per cubic metre. Despite this high value, the EIA/Telapak found that loggers in the national park were paid only Rp25,000 for every cubic metre of ramin hardwood. In other parts of the park, interviews revealed that chainsaw operators received Rp12,000 for each tree felled, while lorry drivers received Rp10,000 per cubic metre, and teams of labourers Rp25,000 per cubic metre. Local logging bosses buy timber for around Rp50,000 per cubic metre, then sell it on to sawmills for approximately Rp250,000 per cubic metre. The inequitable distribution of income from the trade is self-evident (EIA/Telapak, 1999). An investigation by EIA/Telapak in the Leuser ecosystem found similar inequities, with logging teams tied to local sawmill owners on highly unfavourable terms. Loggers work in two-man teams, are provided with a chainsaw and fuel, and typically borrow Rp150,000-Rp200,000 per week for food and cigarettes. The assistant is paid Rp10,000 per day. Provided production targets are met, at the end of an average week's work the team leader will earn approximately Rp175,000 after re-paying credit from the sawmill owner and paying his assistant (EIA/Telapak, 1999). 19 Besides documenting the illegal activities in print, on video and in photographs, these NGOs have fought an active campaign through the media, the donor community and the Indonesian government. To date at least eight foreign film crews have visited the park. Such high-profile campaigning and detailed information has elicited promises from the government to stop illegal logging in the park, and to use the law to hold responsible the third party alleged to be organising the logging, the businessman Abdul Rasyid (EIA/Telapak, 2000). These promises have come from the President, two successive Ministers of Forestry and Estate Crops, the Attorney General, and the former Governor of Central Kalimantan. Nevertheless, despite occasional shows of activity against some sawmills and loggers, illegal logging has continued, illegal sawmills have reopened, and Abdul Rasyid’s operation has remained relatively untouched (EIA/Telapak, 2000). The logging in Tanjung Puting has become a test case which raises important questions as to the actual ability of central government to protect National Parks, which remain under its jurisdiction despite decentralisation. Central Kalimantan is recognised by many as being governed by “moneypolitics” and Mr Rasyid has been appointed to the Peoples Consultative Assembly (the national parliament’s upper house) since revelations of his illicit business activities first came to light. Many incidents have occurred which show that judicial decisions in the province can readily be bought. Such a climate of corruption has considerably benefited the illegal activities which have been going on under the noses of the military and the forest department. It has been made clear for more than two years that many officials are actively involved in the logging, sometimes as sponsors of illegal logging gangs. Of even greater concern in the Tanjung Puting case has been the way in which it illustrates in Central Kalimantan, and by inference in other parts of Indonesia, just how a powerful local figure has been able to use his wealth and influence to remain beyond the reach of the national law. Under a package of regional autonomy measures due to be implemented in 2001, regency and provincial governments will receive considerable devolved powers, but if powerful local figures are able to exert such a strong influence over the local parliaments, bureaucracies, courts and security forces, then it is likely that the legislation will also further empower these people, put them further beyond the reach of the reform forces in Jakarta, and result in a further rise in illegal logging in the era of autonomy. Bending the rules As well as the misuse of IPK permits by big business (see Corporate encroachment), another method of wrongfully exploiting forest resources has come into existence under the 1999 Forestry Law. This particular abuse lies firmly in the grey area between illegal logging by local communities and illegal logging by third parties, described above. Local communities can be organised into cooperatives for opening forested areas for agriculture or plantations (often cocoa and coffee). Under the new law, the co-operatives are then entitled to IPK for harvesting the timber existing on these lands before conversion to agriculture or plantations. IPKs for up to 100 ha can be given out at the district level. Since March 1999, the total of applications for IPKs from co-operatives in Berau has been for more than 11,000 ha (Obidzinski & Suramenggala 2000a). Small scale entrepreneurs in Berau, who organise co-operatives explained to Obidzinski & Suramanggala (2000a) that their operational strategy is to identify places with good supplies of BBS timber, negotiate with local communities who may claim rights to these areas, and begin logging before the permit is received, in order to present the authorities with a fait accompli. Obidzinski & Suramenggala (2000a) conclude that this implies that timber exploitation rather than conversion to other uses is the main objective. This report is consistent with the admission by entrepreneurs that payments are made to forestry and security officials (police) who visit the site before granting the IPK, although such payments are not legally required. Entrepreneurs told Obidzinski & Suramanggala (2000a) that payments of about ten million rupiah are required for setting up a co-operative. These funds are increasingly provided by organisations whose stated objective is in fact to assist 20 communities obtain permits for establishing co-operatives. Facilitation fees equivalent to 19% of the selling price for BBS timber are paid to these organisations. Obidzinski & Suramenggala (2000a) were told that political parties competed to sponsor such organisations, presumably with the objective of winning political support at the local level. Although no concrete evidence exists to support such allegations, they raise the possibility that the rapid increase in community co-operatives may be being driven by investments from outside the communities and that the motivation behind these investments may be political as well as financial. A similar system, based on local co-operatives, is reported by Wadley & Dennis (paper in preparation) from areas bordering the Danau Sentarum National Park, West Kalimantan, near the Malaysian border. In this area however, it is mainly selective logging of valuable species that is being done at present, although some small-diameter timber is also removed. This logging is apparently financed by Malaysian entrepreneurs and the timber is trucked across the border into Malaysia. Wadley & Dennis report that although co-operatives claim they have IPK permits, they were unable to produce them. None of the co-operatives even claimed to have export permits. Illegal logging under regional autonomy In April 1999, in compensation for the wrongs and insensitivities of Soeharto era development policy, the government of President B.J. Habibie passed legislation creating a timetable and framework to decentralise Indonesia's authoritarian and highly centralised government. The legislation was introduced to defuse the increasingly assertive secessionist movement which had crystallised around the existing provincial structures in the resource-rich regions of Sumatra, Kalimantan, Sulawesi and Irian Jaya (Papua). In the more open environment of post-Soeharto Indonesia, local politicians and community leaders in these regions have been able to voice their resentment of the central government's control over revenues from timber, oil, gas, and other mineral resources. Although it is too early to determine whether the legislation will prove sufficient to appease this deep-seated resentment, it is at least clear that if Indonesia is to survive as a unitary nation-state, changes must be made to the balance of power between the centre and the regions. Law 22/1999 on Regional Autonomy and Law 25/1999 on the Fiscal Balance between the Central and Regional Governments set out the broad arrangements for decentralisation. It is proposed that the regency (Kabupaten) and municipality (Kotamadya) governments will be vested with considerable powers. There have been questions over the capacity of regency governments to perform the complex range of new duties required of them by the new legislation. Although the provincial tier of government has largely been bypassed by the legislation, practicalities (and its stronger capacity) make it likely that it will in fact play an important role under the decentralised arrangements. Despite its alleged flaws, some analysts believe the legislation has the potential to strengthen democracy. Government will be brought closer to the people, helping to create "miniature democracies" with a triangle of accountability joining local electorates, parliaments and executive bodies, or so the theory goes. The greatest threat to this ideal lies in "crony capture" of local institutions and the creation of fiefdoms that will replicate only the worst aspects of current central government structures and practices, such as the problems in Central Kalimantan described above. Given that Indonesia has about 350 regencies, it would be next to impossible to control policy, steer reform and ensure legal certainty under this worst case scenario. To date, efforts to eliminate the systemic legislative flaws which so encourage corruption in Indonesia have focused almost exclusively on central government (and at that have had little impact) leaving institutions lower down in the government hierarchy unaffected. The programme of decentralisation proposed is almost unprecedented, and no country, developed or developing, has ever set out to decentralise so many services, in so many sectors, in so short a time. This apparently over-ambitious programme has led to deep uncertainty, and there is little reason to believe these massive changes will work smoothly when they take effect next year. To meet the deadline a punishing (and unfeasible) schedule has been set to review all government functions, capacity, and staffing, including the transfer of up to 500,000 civil servants from central to local 21 government. Local government finance must also be completely overhauled. Amid the administrative confusion and centralised bureaucratic resistance which has surrounded this decentralisation process, there has been a growing tendency for local government officials to take the initiative into their own hands and in particular to take unilateral action to assert their authority over natural resources in their jurisdictions. With emboldened local politicians asserting their rights to manage natural resources, the central government has been left with diminishing control. As a result there are growing signs of tension between central and regional governments. While the centre can attempt to influence the regions through policy statements, it is the regions that have de facto control and hold the stronger bargaining position. Many local governments have sensed this turn in their favour, and are asserting their newfound (but as yet unofficial) authority by staking claims to greater involvement in the management and taxation of local business. Attempts to strong-arm high-profile foreign investment projects (particularly mining interests) in remote areas have received widespread coverage in the media. Conflicts surrounding mining projects such as Freeport in Papua, Newmont Minahasa in North Sulawesi, and Kaltim Prima Coal and Kelian Equatorial Mining in East Kalimantan have received widespread analysis and attention. What is less well known is that the forestry sector and forest exploitation are facing a similar set of challenges and issues. In the forestry sector, which in many ways has always been beyond the reach of the central administration by virtue of the remote location of the concessions, the strong political backing enjoyed by major concessionaires, the involvement of the military (in both legal and illegal forest exploitation), and the de facto control exerted by local interested parties. To generate much needed income, local governments appear to be levying unofficial taxes on illegal timber – which effectively legalises the trade. In parts of Kalimantan there are anecdotal reports of Regents (Bupati, who hold the state executive power in each Kabupaten) taxing shipments of timber that leave the areas under their jurisdictions. There are also reports of attempts to levy unofficial taxes on NTFPs produced by smallholder farmers in Lampung. In Central Kalimantan, Casson (2000) reports that one district head has imposed a tax of Rp 125,000 per cubic metre of timber transported by ships to destinations outside the regency, without the nationally required documents. This imposition is said to have yielded a revenue of Rp 21.6 billion during April and May 2000 compared with an annual revenue of Rp 5 billion raised by the previous district head (Casson, 2000). The tax has since been increased to Rp 160,000 per cubic metre, and is expected to be increased further, given that it is still lower than the tariff that applies to truly legal carriers (Rp 192,000). As it is now implemented, the tax may be acting to some extent as a disincentive to illegal logging. Casson (2000) reports, for instance, that timber buyers complain that it has increased the price they have to pay for timber. On the other hand environmentalists strenuously oppose the tax, claiming that in effect it legalises illegal logging, given that the district head is reportedly trying to ensure that once the tax is paid, illegal timber is accepted in other Indonesian ports. If he succeeds, this will counteract the disincentive effect of the tax by reducing the unofficial payments illegal operators have been paying in these ports. For a tax to reduce incentives for illegal logging effectively, it would have to be high enough to bring the profitability of illegal logging into line with that of legal logging. This is unlikely to be achieved by merely equalising local “taxes” with those paid by legal carriers. Illegal logging may be cheaper than logging by concessionaires because of the nature of the technology. In addition, other significant rents are generated by illegal logging which would also have to be mopped up by the tax. Dissipation of rents in theory would reduce unproductive rent-seeking activity and therefore incentives for corruption. However, as Cohen (1988) points out, studies in economies susceptible to corruption show that excessively high penalties for illegal activities stimulate avoidance methods and therefore corruption. The implication is that taxes have to be supplemented with a greater commitment to reducing corruption. The significant revenues collected at the district level from taxes 22 on illegal logging show that effective enforcement will require commitment at the district level to the sustainable management of forest resources. Available estimates of rents (ie, earnings received without productive activity) from illegal logging do not appear to capture all unofficial payments. However they indicate that unproductive rent-seeking activity comprises a significant part of the economic activity generated by illegal logging. Given that the recipients of unofficial payments include the police, army and government officials, the estimates also indicate that a wide variety of people at the district and provincial level, in addition to company employees, may be benefiting unproductively, which implies that illegal logging may be difficult to eradicate unless mechanisms are identified for dissipating these rents. Preliminary estimates indicate that unofficial payments made by large sawmills in Berau amount to about 50% to 75% of wage expenses, while in the case of medium-sized sawmills they are about 20% of the wage bill (Obidzinski & Suramanggala 2000a). Small sawmills in Malinau were estimated to be paying out just over 50% of their wage bill, or 16% of total running costs, in unofficial payments (Obidzinski & Suramenggala 2000b). Timber traders in South Aceh and Kalimantan made unofficial payments during transport of their products, equivalent to about 10% of their sales revenues. In the case of community co-operatives, in addition to the unofficial payment of Rp 10 million made to obtain the IPK permit, facilitation fees amounted to about 12% of their wage bill (Obidzinski and Suramanggala 2000a). Encroachment by small scale and subsistence agriculture Encroachment by smallholder farmers into forest areas is both a serious and an emotive issue. While each farmer clears only a small area of land, the net impact of many farmers clearing small plots or practising shifting agriculture (swidden, or slash and burn) is very damaging to the natural forest. However, this particular form of unlicensed logging and forest clearance is practised by people who are often poor and rarely have any choice over the way in which they earn a living. Clearing land by burning, which is the usual method, contributes to the annual haze which covers parts of Indonesia, Singapore and Malaysia, but small farmers have in the past been used as scapegoats for the larger and more destructive fires set by large plantation companies. At low population densities shifting agriculture is sustainable and sometimes enhances the biodiversity of an area. With growing populations it becomes a less efficient way of cultivation. Studies have found that it is extensive in terms of its land requirements, which reflects the circumstances of abundant land, in which the system evolved. Although land is no longer abundant, use of this system of cultivation is still widespread, in part simply because those who practise it have few alternatives. The absence of secure title provides a further incentive to clear forest land and establish crops. This is particularly true in the face of external threats, including that of land being taken up by central government projects such as industrial forest concessions. Transition to a market and cash-based economy has also contributed to the environmental impact which small-scale agriculture has on the natural forest. The cultivated plots were formerly left fallow on a rotation typically of 10−15 years. This allowed secondary forest to recover before farmers returned to recultivate the area. The need for cash income now encourages farmers to plant cash crops, particularly rubber, on the fallow. The productive life of these plantations is longer than that of the old fallow, meaning that farmers must continually clear new areas of pristine forest (Norindra, 1993). Case study: Bukit Barisan Selatan National Park, Lampung2 2 This section draws heavily on work done by S. Suyanto (1999). 23 A study of fire and deforestation in the north-eastern fringes of Bukit Barisan Selatan National Park in Lampung has revealed two sources of deforestation in the study site: the establishment of coffee gardens by smallholder farmers and illegal logging (Suyanto, 1999). The establishment of coffee gardens has greatly increased with migration into the area, in part inspired by the profitability of coffee production. The population of Lampung has increased dramatically since the 1970s. In 1971, the province had a population of 2.8 million people, but by 1997 this had risen to 6.9 million. A large proportion of the population are dependant on smallholder agriculture to make a living. Lampung lies in the main coffee-producing area of Indonesia, and migrants to Lampung have been drawn to coffee cultivation by buoyant domestic coffee prices. It is estimated that between 1977 and 1998 the real domestic price of coffee increased by 11% per annum. From 1990-98, the real domestic price increased by 25% per annum (Suyanto, 1999). The combined pressures of population growth, demand for agricultural land, and rising coffee prices have resulted in large encroachments into the protected area, with resulting forest loss. Gintings et al (1999) estimate that natural forest now covers only 34% of Bukit Barisan Selatan National Park. Population pressure in the area surrounding the park is very high, resulting in encroachment into the protected area. The settler communities are not indigenous to the region - most are migrants from other parts of Lampung or Java. These migrant communities, some of which are permanent and some of which are seasonal, all practice frontier agriculture, which requires clearing land. In Indonesia, the conversion of natural forest to agricultural uses has often utilised fire in land clearing. Smallholders and large-scale plantation managers prefer to use slash-and-burn methods in land clearing because it is cheap and easy (Tomich et al 1998). According to official statistics, fires damaged 100 ha of the study site in October 1997. However, Suyanto (1999) estimates by the study suggest the true area could be closer to 500 hectares. Forestry officials blamed slash-and-burn cultivators for starting the fires in order to clear land for coffee gardens. This appears to be the likely cause, although careless behaviour by illegal gangs operating in the area may also have contributed. Interestingly, there was no evidence of fires spreading to existing coffee gardens, suggesting that the community-based communal laws designed to regulate use of fire served their intended purpose. On the other hand, local laws provide no incentive for farmers to prevent fire spreading to natural forest, and in fact burning forest considerably eases the task of clearing new coffee land in the following year. The study demonstrates the impact which smallholder encroachment into protected area can have on forest cover. While those practising slash and burn agriculture often have little choice, the aggregate impact of their actions is detrimental to Indonesia's environment. If protected areas are to be maintained then strategies to mitigate the impact of smallholder agriculture will have to be given consideration. Simply condemning these activities as illegal will not address the factors which underlie the problem, and attention will need to be given to providing diversionary activities and forms of employment which fully compensate for loss of livelihood resulting from conservation policies. 24 Corporate encroachment Encroachment into forest areas by corporate interests is a serious problem in Indonesia. It takes many forms, including encroachment into national parks and conservation areas, which has been well documented in the Leuser ecosystem. Sometimes encroachment is outright illegal, sometimes it is backed up by the correct permits but in areas for which permits should not have been allocated to commercial land uses – for example, a study in the Gunung Leuser National Park found that 80% of the area allocated for commercial forestry was on land which should by law be classified as conservation and protection areas. We must include as “encroachment” cases in which no law has been broken but which have resulted from administrative mistakes, with very bad environmental and social consequences. There is a range of perverse incentives that encourage corporate encroachment into the forest estate. A common one is that weak property rights over forested land provide ample incentive to replace forest with plantation crops and so obtain the stronger land title which accompanies such developments. In addition, companies that develop plantations commonly receive windfall profits from the sale of cleared timber. Until 1998, industrial forest plantation projects (as opposed to agricultural tree crops like rubber or oil palm) had the added boon of (highly perverse) subsidies from the reforestation fund, which in fact encouraged the clearance of natural forest. Some of the “forest plantations” that have resulted are of extremely poor quality; their purpose was not to grow wood efficiently so much as to acquire title to land and obtain clear-felled timber. The problem which encroachment has been presenting in recent years can be measured in the national timber-production statistics by the growth in the importance of timber from clear-felling operations. In 1994/95 timber from clear-felling operations (IPK) made up 20% of the total official log production, and by 1997/98 the figure had risen to more than 34%. There is an alarming lack of transparency with regard to clear-felling statistics, and it is not known what area of forest this in fact covers. Table 11. Roundwood production (000 m3) 1994/95 1995/96 1996/97 1997/98 1998/99 Natural production forest 17,309 16,944 15,268 15,598 10,179 Conversion forest 4,709 5,398 8,021 10,038 6,056 Total production (incl. other sources) 24,027 24,850 26,069 29,149 19,027 19.6 21.7 30.8 34.4 31.8 Conversion forest as % of total Source: Ministry of Forestry and Estate Crops, Forest Utilisation Statistics 1997/98 and 1998/99 Figures for the development of cash crop plantations also give an indication of the pressure brought to bear by the expansion of plantations (table 12). 25 Table 12 Plantation development, 1970-99 Area ('000 ha) Year Small Holders StateOwned Private Production ('000 tonnes) Total Small Holders StateOwned Private Total 1970 0 86.6 46.7 133.3 0 147 69.8 216.8 1980 6.1 199.5 88.9 294.6 0.8 498.9 221.5 721.2 1990 291.3 372.2 463.1 1,126.7 377 1,127.2 788.5 2,412.6 1995 658.5 404.7 961.7 2,025 1,001.4 1,613.8 1,734.7 4,350 1996 738.9 426.8 1,083.8 2,249.5 1,133.6 1,706.9 1,909.6 4,750 1997 813.2 448.7 1,254.2 2,516.1 1,292.8 1,800.3 2,287.4 5,380.4 1998 892 484.8 1,403.1 2,779.9 1,245.7 1,698.7 2,061.5 5,005.9 1999 972.7 489.8 1,494.5 2,957.1 1,326.6 1,830.9 2,501.5 5,659 Source: Casson (2000) Any resumption of expansion in the palm oil sector after a recovery from the low prices in 1998/99 is likely to result in further encroachment into the remaining forest estate. This encroachment may not be illegal, but it is nevertheless a significant threat to the remaining forest estate. Sumatra is the main palm oil producing region of Indonesia, but attempts to develop the more eastern regions of the country have resulted in some developments in Kalimantan and Papua. Casson (2000) argues that ethnic unrest and poor infrastructure have discouraged oil palm investment in eastern Indonesia, but that companies have shown an interest in obtaining timber from the clearfelling licences issued as part of the investment agreement, which in part explains why many of the companies that have been granted investment licences in eastern Indonesia have strong links with the timber and pulp industries. Breach of contract is also an issue, since companies receive a licence to clear timber and develop plantations. Simply stripping the land of timber is not the end of a plantation company's legal responsibilities, yet Casson reports that in West Kalimantan, up to March 1999 the government had issued permits for the development of 871,211 ha of oil palm, but only 18,278 ha had been planted. This can in part be explained by social unrest in the province, but it may also be because clear-felled timber is the main objective of these “investment” projects. Barr (2000) also claims that the national increase in IPK permits is in response to the decline in timber supplies from HPH concessions, and that it is not uncommon for IPK-holders to abandon the sites once commercial timber has been removed. Obidzinski & Suramanggala (2000a) report that cases of “plantation” companies motivated mainly by timber extraction were widely publicised in the local press in Berau. This is all consistent with the rapid increase in IPKs at a time when the world price of palm oil has been falling sharply and the share of oil palm in Asia's edible oil market has been declining (Casson, 1999). While this paper is primarily about illegal logging, another violation of forest law–arson–is also associated, on a very large scale, with oil palm developments. Fires in August 1999 and in March and July 2000 have been linked to oil palm developments (including those involving some Malaysian companies). There have also been violations of land-use classifications. MOFEC reports that 4.1 million ha of land has been converted to plantations since 1982. Of this total, 3.3 million ha was on land classified as “conversion forest”, but 166,532 ha was on “limited production forest”, 455,009 ha on “production forest”, and 129,449 ha on forest land designated for other uses. The land classified as “production forest” and “limited production forest” is supposed to be part of the permanent forest estate, and their use for oil palm plantations represents a significant and undesirable encroachment. 26 In Riau, MOFEC data show that about 1.25 million ha have been converted to plantations since 1982–more than three times as much as in any other province. The presence of two large pulp mills in Riau gives rise to the suspicion that the object of clearance is not to develop plantations, but to obtain clear-felled timber, upon which the pulp mills depend for a supply of raw materials. The second largest area of forest cleared since 1982 is also in a province with a large pulp mill development–East Kalimantan, which lost 400,000 ha under IPK clearing permits. The pulp industry is a particularly interesting example of corporate encroachment into the forest estate. In recent years, as the large-diameter logs required for plywood have become harder to find, the major timber groups have turned their attention to pulp and paper production. Typically mills are granted a limited supply of timber from the natural forest, which they can clear to make way for the timber plantations (HTI) upon which their operations must depend in the long term. The pulp industry has expanded aggressively throughout the 1990s, rising from an installed production capacity of 1.1 million t of pulp in 1991 to 4.9m t in 1999. One tonne of pulp requires about 4 cubic metres of roundwood to produce. In many cases, plantation development has not proceeded apace with the expansion of the industry, and pulp mills have come to depend on logs recovered from clear-felling operations in the natural forest. Up to last year, only 21% (1.1 million ha) of the 4.9 million ha allocated for pulp plantations had been planted. As a result the volume of roundwood coming from clear-felling permits (IPK) rose from 20% of the official timber supply in 1995/96 to 10 million cubic metres, or 34%, in 1997/98. In 1998/99 clear-felling operations accounted for about 32% of official timber production, according to official statistics. The use of fire to clear debris from land after these clear-felling operations is one of the main causes of the vast conflagrations which recur annually in Sumatra and Kalimantan. 27 Impact of illegal logging on Indonesia Huge potential revenues are being lost at a time when the central government’s economic policy is heavily emphasising the need to strengthen the domestic revenue base. The wood-processing industry, which is an important employer and export earner, faces an uncertain future as its supplies of raw material dwindle, and the many people who depend on forests for a livelihood in the informal economy are becoming increasingly vulnerable as a result of forest loss. The diminishing efficacy of the protective functions bestowed by forests is resulting in increased erosion and flooding of cities and agricultural land, and the “charismatic” animals that draw tourists to Indonesia and which are emblematic of the country are faced with extinction. Traditional institutions, customs and spiritual beliefs are also jeopardised as a result of rapid and uncontrolled forest loss. Some of these impacts are examined in detail below. Economic There are no officially published estimates of what illegal logging is costing Indonesia in terms of lost revenue. Basing his calculations on the current forest taxes and fees, the secretary-general of MOFEC estimates that the annual loss of revenue amounts to $96-$120 million. However, for many years Indonesia has undervalued its timber resources by protecting the domestic market for roundwood, a fact which is reflected in the current rates of stumpage fee and obligatory reforestation fund payments. If timber was valued at world market prices, the revenue would be greater, and so too would the calculated losses from illegal logging. A study published in 1997 concluded that Indonesia was losing about $2 billion every year in lost revenues. Of this total, $1.2 billion was as a result of low taxes levied on the official roundwood harvest, and $600 million was as a result of non-payment of tax on an estimate of the illegal harvest at that time (Scotland, 1997). Illegal logging has risen sharply since that study was completed, and so the losses stemming from illegal logging are likely to have risen even higher. The costs of public subsidies advanced to enterprises which damage the forest must also be factored into more comprehensive calculations of the cost to the state of illegal logging. Barr (2000) argues that pulp producers have to a significant degree been motivated to invest large amounts of capital in high-risk projects because the Government of Indonesia has provided substantial capital subsidies for pulp and paper projects. Providing forest industries with cheap raw materials (through low levies and other mechanisms) also encourages waste and inefficient use, which in turn result in further resource degradation, and from the early 1990s, direct subsidies issued by the Ministry of Forestry and Estate Crops from the reforestation fund to help firms establish pulpwood plantations also inadvertently encouraged clearance of the natural forest. The Ministry of Forestry typically provided industrial forest plantation projects with 14% of the project's total cost in the form of equity capital and 32.5 percent in the form of an interest-free loan with a repayment period of 10 years. In addition, plantation companies were permitted to draw on loans from the DR fund at commercial rates to finance 32.5 percent of the project's expenses. This arrangement effectively allows the firm establishing the plantation to commit only 21 percent of the overall investment from its own funds (Barr, 2000). These generous financing arrangements encouraged companies to apply for licences to clear land and attempt to develop (often unsuccessfully) pulpwood plantations at state expense. The Indonesian government has also provided indirect subsidies to environmentally damaging investments through the weak regulation of the nation's financial system (Barr, 2000). Most of Indonesia's major forest and plantations enterprises are owned by large conglomerates with investments in a range of other sectors. Many of these conglomerates control their own banks. In the years leading up to the financial crisis, the government regularly failed to enforce its own laws in the commercial banking sector, particularly when they threatened to constrain the lending practices of banks owned by groups with ties to state elites. Indonesia's largest timber conglomerates and oil palm companies have taken advantage of this weak regulatory environment to obtain large sums of finance well below commercial lending rates. They have done so most significantly through the allocation of 28 related-party loans above the government's legal lending limits, the misappropriation of Central Bank liquidity credits, and the use of financial mark-up schemes (Barr, 2000). Many of these debts will never be repaid and will instead be written off at state expense. Forest fires Illegal logging is compounding forest loss in a number of ways. In some cases it leads directly to the denudation of land, but more commonly it degrades forest that has already been logged over, eliminating the prospect of a recovery in the logged-over stand, and making conversion to other land uses appear more attractive than awaiting the second timber harvest. Logging in protected areas makes their forests more vulnerable to damage or destruction by fire. Studies have shown that fires in logged-over forests cause more damage than those in unlogged forest because of the additional fuel, in the form of rotting wood and logging slash, which litters the floor after logging. Perverse subsidies which encourage land clearance, and the manipulation of legislation to allow land clearing are also linked intimately to the problems posed by forest fires. Fires are the favoured method of clearing land in Indonesia, and in dry years, such as 1997/98, caused enormous damage. Estimates of the area burnt in the forest fires of 1997/98 vary considerably according to source. The National Planning Board (Bappenas) reports that in 1997/98 the areas burnt were: Sumatra, 1.7m hectares; Kalimantan, 6.5m hectares; Java, 0.1m hectares; Sulawesi, 0.4m hectares; and Papua, 1.0m hectares. Areas burnt included 0.1m hectares of montane forest, lowland forest (3.3m hectares), peat and swamp forest (1.4m hectares), agricultural and open grassland (4.5m hectares), and timber plantations and estate crops (0.3m hectares). It is estimated that during the 1997/98 fires, over 700 million tonnes of carbon was released into the atmosphere from the burning of peat. This elevated Indonesia to one of the largest polluters of carbon in the world, and have prompted sarcastic observations that the major product of Indonesia's forest sector is not plywood, pulp, paper or sawnwood, but haze, carbon and smoke. On the basis of a benefit transfer model employed by Bappenas total losses resulting from the 1997/98 fires were placed at approximately $9.3 billion. A large part of this cost can be attributed to the various forms of illegal logging, encroachment and abuse of legislation outlined earlier in this report. Wildlife poaching Wildlife poaching is a significant and tragic side effect of illegal logging as well as other encroachments into the remaining forested areas. Indonesia is world-renowned for its biodiversity. It lies astride the Wallace Line, the transition from Asian to Australasian flora and fauna, and it has many endemic species. West of this transitional zone, there are the “charismatic” species associated with the Greater Sunda Islands, including the orang-utan, Sumatran tiger, several species of gibbon, Javan and Sumatran rhinoceros, the Sumatran elephant, and the clouded leopard. Unfortunately these species, all slow to reproduce and demanding of large territorial ranges, are prized as pets, for pseudo-medicinal purposes, and as trophies. The increased human–animal contacts resulting from logging, encroachment, and habitat loss has resulted in their numbers plummeting, and in many cases extinction is now a serious possibility. Orang-utans, tigers and elephants are all severely endangered as a result. In the Leuser ecosystem, conversion of land to oil palm and illegal logging have jeopardised the existence of the last remaining viable population of Sumatran elephants; fragmentation of the habitat has resulted in turn in fragmentation of the population, and small herds now live in isolated islands in numbers which are not sufficient to maintain a genetically healthy population over the long term. The main threat to orang-utan survival is habitat destruction and the secondary effects of this destruction, which include an increase in the pet trade, poaching for food, and human–animal conflict. With current rates of habitat destruction and forest loss, the orang-utan populations are falling by more than 1,000 every year, a rate of loss that will lead to extinction within five years if urgent steps are not taken. In the Leuser ecosystem alone, a survey has found that an estimated 2,785 29 orang-utans out of a total population of 5,350 have died as a result of human encroachment into their habitat. In 1992 there were thought to be only between 400 and 600 Sumatran tigers left in the wild. Rampant poaching and rapid habitat loss now threaten to send the species the way of the Balinese tiger, which became extinct in the early 1900s, and the Javan tiger, which died out in the 1980s. Tigers are killed for their bones, which are valued for use in Chinese “medicine”. Skins also command a high price on the black market, and cubs are still captured alive for sale as pets. The eradication of tigers also has an adverse impact on human populations living on the margins of forest areas because tigers prey on the wild boar, which rise in numbers if tigers are removed. Wild boars are a very serious pest to subsistence farmers living in forest fringe areas. Human–animal conflict results in many tigers being killed each year, but the great majority of encounters between people and tigers are the result of ever shrinking tiger habitat. Social Illegal logging also has many adverse social impacts. Loggers work for poor wages and are often in debt to their middlemen bosses. In the event of crackdowns on illegal logging it is the poor and vulnerable at the bottom of the pyramid who lack the means to escape justice, and those who reap the greatest benefits from the violation of forest laws go unpunished. This too has a very negative social impact and undermines faith in state justice. The operations of illegal logging gangs sometimes divide communities between those for and against them. In the long run such conflicts can undermine rural support networks, customary (adat) laws governing natural resource use, and ultimately lead to weaker social ties between neighbours. Logging can also result in conflict between neighbouring communities. It has been reported that the rush to claim small community concessions for clear-felling in East Kalimantan has resulted in conflicting claims on the same area of forest being made by neighbouring communities. Work undertaken by loggers and sawmillers is heavy and dangerous, and there are no health and safety regulations to offer protection. For example, a CIFOR study found that employees of Central Kalimantan sawmills were paid only Rp 30,000-50,000 per day for their hard and dangerous work. Many cases were reported of workers losing their hands while manning band saws. Loggers operate chainsaws under similarly dangerous circumstances. Beneficial impacts Illegal logging also generates some very beneficial social and economic benefits. The importance of employment generated by illegal timber harvesting in rural economies should not be underestimated. Illegal operations generate considerable employment both for villagers and for migrants from surrounding areas, particularly as chainsaw operators and other labourers, in floating wood down the rivers, and as truck drivers, sawmill operators, and administrators, in addition to those who provide services, such as food vendors and mechanics. For what it is worth – and if a wide net is cast it is plausible enough – McCarthy (2000b) reports that one informant estimated that each chainsaw provided employment for 200 people. Although a full accounting of the employment generated by illegal logging is not available, some preliminary estimates of particular operations are provided by case studies, as follows. Detailed calculations of wages in Obidzinski & Suramenggala's (2000a) sawmill survey in Berau indicate that 28 sawmills of various sizes employed about 605 people, earning wages ranging from Rp 225, 000 to Rp 1,000,000 per month. About 29% of these were permanent employees. In some cases food and housing were provided in addition to wages. Obidzinski & Suramenggala (2000b) estimated that some small sawmills in Malinau were employing a total of about 56 people, with monthly earnings of about Rp 268,000. These earnings are comparable to the official minimum wage in East Kalimantan of Rp 233,000. 30 Selective-logging teams surveyed in Berau each consisted of about six or seven people. Monthly earnings ranged from about Rp 300,000 to Rp 500,000 each, while the leader was estimated to receive about Rp 750,000 (Obidzinski & Suramenggala 2000a). Income from logging groups is subject to work stoppages, equipment breakdowns, accidents, bad weather, and adverse floating conditions. Many loggers therefore consider these earnings as only supplementing those from their other activities. Income from logging BBS (soft, small-diameter) timber appears to be much higher than from selective logging, presumably because of the higher rates of timber extracted in these operations. Teams engaged in it consisted of about 8 to 11 workers, with monthly earnings of about Rp 900,000 (Obidzinski & Suramenggala 2000a). In South Aceh, according to McCarthy (2000b), logging teams comprised 6 to 15 workers. Some villagers earned Rp 20,000 to Rp 30,000 per day in 1998 transporting logs. Although the work was dangerous, it provided a valuable survival strategy particularly during the economic crisis and during periods when income from other sources had declined (McCarthy 2000b). 31 Government strategy Non-governmental organisations and donors active in the forest sector in Indonesia have been expressing concern about malpractice and environmental destruction since the early 1980s. The extent of the illegal logging problem facing Indonesia first came to light in early 1999 and has since been given high profile media coverage as the result of a campaign run by Telapak/EIA. Concern over forest destruction was first raised at a diplomatic level by donor countries grouped in the Consultative Group on Indonesia (CGI) forum in Paris in July 1999, and again in February 2000. In the February meeting of the CGI the government agreed to form an Inter-Departmental Committee on Forests (IDCF) and to take action on eight points that have been identified as crucial for saving Indonesia's remaining forests from rapid liquidation. The eight points 3 for action are: 1. To invite co-operation and co-ordination of other ministries to impose strong measures against illegal loggers, especially those operating within national parks, and closure of illegal sawmills. 2. To speed up forest resource assessment as a basis for National Forest Programme (NFP) formulation. 3. To evaluate the policy in conversion forest and put a moratorium on all natural forest conversion until the NFP has been agreed. 4. To downsize and restructure wood-based industries to balance between supply and demand for raw materials, and most importantly to increase competitiveness of Indonesia’s wood-based industry. 5. To close heavily indebted wood industries under control of the Indonesian Bank Restructuring Agency (IBRA) and link proposed debt write-off to capacity reduction. 6. To connect the reforestation programme with the existing forest industries and those under construction. 7. To recalculate the real value of timber. 8. To use the decentralisation process as a tool to enhance sustainable forest management. Although the IDCF has now been formed, there has so far been little contact with other government departments that have mandates giving them an influence over developments in the forest sector. This is particularly true of the judiciary, the military and the police. The government is also under pressure to reform the forest sector for budgetary reasons. Illegal logging costs the state billions of dollars every year. The Memorandum of Financial and Economic Policies sent to the IMF on 20 January 2000 sets out broad guidelines for economic policy over the next three years. The government states, in consideration of receiving loans worth $5 billion, an intent to "improve greatly natural resource management, arrest the long-term deterioration in the environment, and ensure the sustainable use of natural resources for future generations". Furthermore, fiscal reforms set out in the same document are designed to strengthen the domestic revenue base and reduce the budget deficit. In the budget for 2000, announced on the same day, the government stated an intent to follow a package of measures designed to strengthen the country's weak tax base and achieve fiscal sustainability to reduce its reliance upon external sources of finance. With rising sovereign debt (forecast to be $157.2 billion, or 91% of GDP by the year end) the government can ill afford to squander the billions of dollars which are lost each year to illegal logging. 3 Quoted from the keynote address by the Minister of Forestry and Estate Crops to the Consultative Group on Indonesia, Jakarta, 2 February 2000. 32 Since the government made its commitments in the CGI forum in February, several steps have been taken to combat illegal logging, although these efforts have to a certain extent been thwarted by the wider problems facing the legal system. The government now acknowledges that illegal logging involves a large and varied set of dispersed interests. Illegal logging is therefore not merely a problem of forest management or a problem for MOFEC, but rather part of a multi-dimensional, national problem. A national commitment along with consistent implementation is therefore needed in order to effectively combat it. Prevention The government has publicly stated its commitment to controlling illegal logging and the illegal trading in forest products, and to stamping out corruption. A number of policy initiatives and measures have been launched, particularly over the last two years. These include: 1. Making a commitment to eliminate illegal logging and corrupt practices. 2. Revising forest laws and legislation, including promulgation of the new Forest Law, No. 41/1999. 3. Making alterations to the procedures for allocating and monitoring timber concessions. 4. Imposing a moratorium on the issue of new clear-felling timber harvesting licences (IPK) (but not existing licences). 5. Imposing a moratorium on forest conversion. 6. A revision of administrative and monitoring procedures for logs transport (SAKO and SAKB). 7. Closer involvement with local communities and NGOs. 8. Reform of revenue collection arrangements. 9. Establishment of national and regional collaboration and co-ordination in law enforcement. 10. Co-operation with neighbouring countries, particularly in relation to controlling illegal logging and the cross-border trade in illegal timber. The new Forestry Law, No. 41/1999, which replaced the Basic Forestry Law of 1967, takes a first step towards addressing some of the underlying causes of illegal logging, as well as outlining legal action against violations of forest law and the penalties that may be imposed. Law No. 22/1999 on Regional Autonomy, and Law No. 25/1999 on the Fiscal Balance Between the Centre and the Regions, may in the longer run also provide direct incentives for local government and local constituencies to control illegal logging. By allowing provincial and district government greater flexibility to design fiscal policy and retain a larger share of revenue generated from the exploitation of local natural resources, it will arguably provide local incentives to uphold the principles of sustainable forest management. Since the early 1990s, the Indonesian government has taken a number of steps to tighten the enforcement of forestry law and legislation. Despite these efforts, there are still many companies and forest concessionaires that are not complying with the law. There is strong evidence that powerful networks have been supporting illegal logging at both provincial and national levels. Timber companies and sawmill owners at district level have obtained legal immunity by making payments to local officials and the army. These powerful networks of vested interests have made the implementation of regulations at the local level a very haphazard and complex undertaking. The government's commitment to tackling the problem is also reflected in the establishment by ministerial decree of an inter-agency team (P2LPHHI), to combat illegal logging and the illegal trade in forest products. Team members come from a number of agencies including MOFEC, the National Police and the Navy. The team is chaired by the secretary-general of MOFEC, Mr Suripto. In line 33 with this commitment, the government has been undertaking a systematic and consistent investigation into corrupt practices in the forest industries. Documentation on corruption and illegal practices involving former president Soeharto and his family and friends has been passed to the Attorney General, and although no trials have yet taken place, the former president's close friend and associate Mr Mohamad (Bob) Hasan has been held in special detention since early April as a result of the team's efforts. The government has also considered re-imposing export bans on roundwood and rough sawnwood in order to help control illegal logging and the illegal trade in timber. Prohibitively high export taxes on these two products were repealed in 1998 after being in place since the early 1980s. Any discussion about re-imposing bans or restrictions always creates controversy, and many critics argue that the true objective of these policies is to protect and promote the domestic timber processing industries, rather than to improve the enforcement of forest laws. Other countries in the region have also imposed restrictions on log exports and are retaining more of their logs for their domestic processing industries. Those in favour of trade restrictions argue that banning the export of unprocessed logs helps to reduce opportunities for malpractice (Richardson, 1981). Logging restrictions in many Asian countries arise from concerns about the present rates of forest destruction. In many cases, they are more specifically due also to concerns about illegal logging. Recently, there has been strong pressure from MOFEC to re-impose an export ban on logs. Steps are also being taken to tackle the international dimensions of the illegal trade in timber. According to Mr Suripto, Malaysia and Indonesia have agreed to form a joint fact-finding mission to investigate the cross-border trade in illegal timber between the two countries (The Jakarta Post, 14 July 2000). The joint mission is expected to investigate and collect evidence on illegal logging and the timber trade in the region in which, it is alleged, Indonesian and Malaysian companies are engaged under the protection of military and police personnel from their respective countries. The bilateral joint fact-finding mission will include officials from the police and military of the two countries as well as officials from the forestry ministries and local administrations. In spite of these efforts, there has been no progress towards prosecuting any of the powerful individuals engaged in the cross-border trade. The failure of efforts directed at both prevention and suppression of the problem is also bound up in the broader problems facing Indonesia's legal system. A corrupt judiciary and the widespread involvement of state officials and the military puts the wrongdoers beyond the reach of the law. Only those without wealth and power can be brought to justice, while the rich people who organise, finance and benefit the most from the trade evade prosecution. The resulting difficulties in prosecuting those behind the trade (ie, suppression tactics) appear to have undermined the motivation of those responsible for policing the forest. Why bother trying to prevent illegal logging if those behind the trade cannot be stopped anyway? There have been localised reports of increased law enforcement, but these appear to be isolated incidents and there is little evidence of a general campaign in other parts of the country. There is one field study that reports improved enforcement along the waterways in East Kalimantan by which timber is transported to the Malaysian border (Obidzinski & Suramenggala, 2000b). Police and navy units unfamiliar to sawmill owners are reported to be patrolling these areas along with joint inspection teams from the Departments of Immigration, Forestry, and Trade and Industry, although the impact of these new teams is unknown. This heightened state of alert does not appear to be replicated elsewhere, and in Central Kalimantan for example the EIA and Telapak have taken video footage of log rafts passing police and marine posts on the river leading out of Tanjung Puting National Park, and illegal sawmills which process this wood operate on the riverbank adjacent to these outposts of law enforcement. Also, in West Kalimantan, logs are blatantly transported by trucks on a daily basis across the border into Sarawak (Wadley and Dennis, 2000). The basis of all enforcement activities is legislation, but the Indonesian government lacks the capacity to enforce existing legislation. This incapacity does not explain why unlicensed sawmills can process stolen timber next door to security posts, but it does prevent adequate patrols and investigations being undertaken in more remote areas. 34 Capacity to enforce forestry legislation is limited by a number of factors, including inadequate human resources, weak judicial support to field staff, inadequate legislation, a failure to vest enforcement powers in appropriate agencies, and a lack of resources for field enforcement personnel. The number of forest guards (jagawana hutan) is reportedly only one for every 20,000 ha of forest (ITTO 1990; Callister 2000). It is unrealistic to expect forest guards to be able to police such vast areas adequately. They also lack the equipment, funding and facilities required to do their jobs. Infrastructural support and facilities for forest officers in the field are very poor, so that they may even have to rely on concession holders for basic needs such as transport and housing. This puts the officers into an excessively dependent relationship with the concession holders and creates an environment conducive to collusion and corruption (Callister 2000). Protection for officers who do attempt to enforce the law is non-existent, leaving them with little choice but to comply with the status quo. Another problem hindering enforcement is that forest staff in the field often feel themselves to be socially or professionally outranked by the people they have to deal with in the logging companies, so that it is difficult for them to exert any sort of authority over the company staff. The more senior forest officers are usually based in central offices and field positions are usually regarded as inferior. While efforts to prevent illegal logging by the conventional methods of enforcement, patrols and prosecutions have been limited by these obvious constraints, there have been almost no attempts to reduce illegal logging by more innovative policies which address the fundamental causes of the problem. Meaningful reform has yet to take place in the sector, and no efforts have been made to promote forms of forest management which might discourage illegal logging, or which might at least make adjustments for some illegal logging when setting the annual allowable cut. Government policy has yet to address the problem of excess capacity in the timber industry, and the pulp industry is actually still being allowed to expand in spite of growing awareness of the folly of clear-cutting natural forest, and the illegality which this is promoting (see Corporate encroachment below). Action on the points raised in the CGI forum would go some way to addressing the underlying causes of illegal logging, but to date progress towards these objectives has been limited. Other fundamental issues, such as land rights, land security, greater equity and greater community involvement in managing forest resources, remain minor items on the policy agenda, with only lukewarm commitment from within MOFEC and the government in general. Detection The government has no systematic procedure for collecting and analysing data on illegal activity. Efforts to tackle illegal logging in the national parks and the cross-border trade in stolen timber have been based so far on information provided by donors, student groups, NGOs and researchers. For example, on 5 May 2000, activists from the local branch of the Indonesian Student Front and a number of other NGOs in Pontianak, West Kalimantan, foiled a smuggling attempt involving 35 containers of logs without legal documents which were on board a vessel bound for Singapore. This, the first successful challenge to the smuggling of timber out of the province, was made possible only after the activists temporarily took a number of local officials hostage, including employees of the customs and excise office, the provincial forestry office, and the port administration. It is not that the government does not have the means for detecting illegal logging. Recently a ship belonging to a powerful backer of illegal logging in one of Indonesia's national parks was intercepted off Karimun island in Riau (see below). Incidents like this are heartening, but if the problem is to be tackled comprehensively then detection must be based on more than just intermittent reports from provincial officials, NGOs and donors. Problems with detection are hampered by the complicity of local officials, often the same ones as should be arranging for action to be taken against illegal loggers. The involvement of elements of the military and the police also intimidates officials who would otherwise take action. This means 35 that any future system of detecting illegal activity in the forest sector will need to be insulated against the possibility of subversion by officials guilty of involvement in the trade. Detection has been improved by the P2LPHHI team. As a result of this improved detection there has recently been more open official acknowledgement of the problems posed by the smuggling of stolen timber to overseas destinations, and of military involvement in the trade. The secretary-general of MOFEC has gone on record to state that Malaysian timber companies under the protection of the Malaysian military are alleged to have sponsored illegal logging and timber smuggling in East Kalimantan in collaboration with Indonesian logging firms, which in turn are backed by Indonesian military personnel. Timber smuggling activities along the Malaysia-Indonesia border in East Kalimantan is thought to have been going on for at least 10 years. It is estimated that every month about 100,000 cubic metres of illegal timber are smuggled out of East Kalimantan into Malaysia through the port of Tarakan. Cartridge cases and military rations identical to those used by the Malaysian army were allegedly discovered during raids conducted in the border region of East Kalimantan, and Malaysia has claimed to have found standard-issue Indonesian military boots with TNI (Indonesian military) markings in Sarawak. Both of these finds have been taken as proof of cross-border incursions related to illegal logging. Suppression While many of the issues raised in the CGI forum and in broader economic policy require longer-term action and a more considered approach, prosecuting those responsible for flagrant illegal logging does not. For this reason, illegal logging was singled out by the government and the CGI as an opportunity to act immediately, demonstrate intent and send a clear signal of “commitment to change” in the forest sector. As a result, test cases of well documented incidents of organised logging in national parks, more specifically the Gunung Leuser and Tanjung Puting National Parks, were identified as a point for immediate action. Elevation of these systematic and flagrant abuses of environmental law to the status of test cases has raised important questions as to the actual ability of the central government to protect the national parks, which will continue to remain under its jurisdiction next year despite the introduction of a legislative framework for regional autonomy. Efforts to prosecute those behind the illegal logging in these parks have failed. In the case of Gunung Leuser, the situation is hopelessly complicated at present by the separatist uprising in Aceh, but in Tanjung Puting it is much more clear cut. Despite repeated promises from the President, two successive Ministers of Forestry and Estate Crops, the Attorney General, and the former Governor of Central Kalimantan, the man allegedly behind the illegal logging, Abdul Rasyid, remains free. Despite occasional shows of activity against some sawmills and loggers, illegal logging has continued in the Tanjung Puting area, illegal sawmills have re-opened and Abdul Rasyid’s operation has remained relatively unscathed by the controversy raging around it (see Illegal logging by third parties below). Officials from MOFEC were also reportedly denied access to a sawmill owned by Mr Rasyid, and threatened with physical violence. Since coming under public scrutiny Mr Rasyid has been elected to represent Central Kalimantan in the upper house of the national parliament, the People's Consultative Assembly, and attended its recent annual session. The problems of pushing this high profile test case through Indonesia's legal system illustrates the difficulties which the government faces when trying to prosecute any cases involving breaches of the forest laws. In outlying areas, corruption and a growing resentment of Jakarta-based laws and policies means that powerful individuals can escape prosecution, even when Indonesia's most powerful politicians support it. Under such circumstances steering the reform process and enforcing the law are next to impossible, and for this reason efforts to reduce illegal logging must be linked to the broader national programmes aimed at judicial reform and the elimination of corruption. In the meantime the formation of the P2LPHHI team, with the strong personal backing of the secretary-general of MOFEC, has already done something to strengthen the central government's position with regard to the suppression of illegal logging. In a recent joint operation a ship was 36 impounded that had been attempting to smuggle logs out of the country through Tanjung Balai on Karimun Island in Riau. It was later found to have sailed from Central Kalimantan and to be owned by Mr Rasyid. The team has also undertaken special operations and inspections in a number of provinces afflicted by illegal logging. To date, 29 ships carrying 45 containers with some 210,272 cubic metres of stolen timber have been seized. The seizures took place in Jakarta, places in West and Central Java, Surabaya and Gresik in East Java, Sorong in Papua, and various places in Riau, Jambi, Lampung, West Kalimantan, and North Sulawesi. In addition, the team has impounded vehicles carrying a total of 109 logs and equipment used for logging on the West Kalimantan-Malaysia border. However, the difficulties faced by officials who attempt to act against illegal logging and the shipment of stolen timber were again demonstrated after the seizures in Java, and it appears that even central government is not able to escape the intimidation and coercive methods used by logging syndicates to bring honest local government officials to heel. After the seizures in Jakarta, hundreds of dock workers from the Sunda Kelapa schooner port (the main port of entry for timber into Jakarta) descended on the ministry and began a threatening and at times violent demonstration. This show of strength, which passed unchallenged by the police, was designed to intimidate government officials, and there is a strong suspicion that the demonstrations were organised and paid for by the businessmen behind the illegal logging. Similar protests were reported at other ports in Java. 37 Conclusions and recommendations We hope to have shown that the problem of illegal logging in Indonesia is complex one and of the utmost intractability. At the same time, a major part of the Indonesian problem is its urgency. The significance of illegal logging is that it is destroying the forests. If any substantial part of the remaining rainforest is to be saved, effective action must be taken before the last of it has disappeared. The pessimistic view is that this is impossible, as reform is taking place so slowly that it cannot achieve enough in the few remaining years that are available. The optimistic view is that a reforming, more honest and democratic government is in place, that it is steadily gaining power, and that already some gains have been made. In what follows we go back over some of the main features of the problem, and try to make a few suggestions as to what can be done. One thing at least is clear, and cannot be too strongly emphasised: a strategy based only on improved enforcement is unlikely to work, and it must be supported by policies that address the underlying causes. We have made a preliminary analysis of these causes in a dynamic context, ie showing how they change over time. Clearly however much further work is necessary to fully understand the intricacies of this problem and design solutions that can be effectively implemented. The case studies that we have referred to are consistent with the importance placed by many other researchers on demand-side factors. They show that the issue is complicated by the fact that demand from abroad has become a significant factor in addition to the increasing domestic one. We have raised the issue of whether the legal framework in the past may have encouraged illegal logging, by providing no legal role for small-scale manual logging and no fiscal incentives for control and management of forest resources at the district and provincial level. The case studies show that although employment in the illegal sector is unpredictable and dangerous, it provides employment to a wide range of people with few other alternatives. These people supplement their incomes from illegal logging and use it as an income diversification and risk reduction strategy. Policies to stamp out illegal logging will have to take this trade-off into account and provide alternative livelihood strategies. The case studies also show the key role that has been played by interested parties at the district level in controlling what goes on in the forests, indicating that decentralisation of control over forest resources, if correctly implemented, can play contribute to solving the problem. While decentralization and the new forestry law are moves in the right direction, we also illustrate that the laws on their own, without supporting policies and institutions, may in fact be exacerbating illegal unsustainable management of forest resources. The danger is noted that local government, for all its obvious advantages, may be just as corrupt as any central one has been. We have gone some way towards explaining why a strategy based primarily on better enforcement has had relatively little success. Illegal logging appears to be driven by a large and varied set of dispersed interests, united only by the desire to make money. The line between legality and illegality is often unclear, and some illegal operators have functioned with a fig leaf of legality, or even purported benevolence, as in their support for community plantations. Some of the people who are formally responsible for enforcement at local level have benefited illegally from their high capacity to subvert enforcement directives from the centre. These characteristics of the illegal system make enforcement difficult and costly (Cohen 1998). There are demands for illegally logged timber of a wide range of species and end uses. Policies for bringing demand into line with sustainable supply will have to consider demand from not only the sawn timber and plywood sectors, but also other growing sectors like pulp and paper, which apparently lead to greater environmental havoc (Barr 2000). In particular, the available data highlight the important role of demand from abroad and show that policies confined to bringing domestic industrial capacity in line with domestic sustainable yield are unlikely to control the illegal logging problem. 38 Recommendations Despite the complexity of the problem, there are a number of steps which the could be taken in the short to medium term to begin addressing the problem. These measures have been structured around three key elements of any law enforcement strategy – prevention, detection and suppression. Prevention Prevention is the basis of any law enforcement strategy. Successful prevention requires political commitment, a sound policy framework, and well co-ordinated action between the agencies responsible for enforcing the law. Short term Political will. Immediate, high level commitment from national, provincial and district government structures to address problems in the forest sector. Co-ordinated response. Encourage early interaction between forest management and forest protection staff. Strong deterrent. Increase perceived risk of illegal activity through quick wins on detection and enforcement. Innovative solutions. Provide political and legislative backing for community forest management and evaluate the potential of this type of management model to mitigate forest law violations and environmental bad practice. Long term Further research. If control is to be sustainable, better (more comprehensive) understanding of the problem is needed. Comprehensive and sustainable solutions cannot be based solely on anecdotal evidence. Further research. Analyse existing policies to establish if they are causing illegal logging and increased rural vulnerability. Establish who benefits, who loses and what incentives are created which induce illegal activity and environmental degradation. Further research. Comprehensive analysis of proposed policy actions is needed to avoid unwanted consequences. 39 Industry restructuring. Steps should be taken to rationalise the balance between the supply and demand for timber, including international demand for timber. Governance. Corruption and systemic weaknesses in the legal system need to be addressed to discourage abuse of power leading to violations of environmental law. Governance. Policy action must consider the political economy of forestry, and the manner in which political agendas are linked to illegalities. Governance. A review should be conducted to determine how the on-going process of decentralisation can be used to combat illegal logging, and also to highlight the dangers which it presents to environmental good practice. Governance. Introduce a system of independent inspection for forest concessions. Good policy. Policies need to be drafted to ensure that loggers and enforcement staff are provided with incentives to operate within the bounds of the existing law. Innovative management. Give greater consideration to innovative measures which may reduce illegal logging, including addressing problems with land tenure and ownership, granting local communities a greater role in management and law enforcement, and possibly even legalising certain types of illegal logging, as currently defined, in restricted areas Public education. A public relations programme is needed to change the views of both the government, the public, the judiciary, and the state security apparatus. International initiatives. There is a need to strengthen regional co-operation in suppression of illegal logging, both from government to government and among private sector entities. Transboundary agreements should be set up to develop a system to collect transparent information on the international trade in timber, which should be placed in the public domain. Good business practice. Codes of conduct for the investment industry and multinational companies should be established. The potential for certification and chain of custody monitoring and trade to provide incentives not to log illegally should be reviewed. Good business practice. Legislation to ban the purchase of illegally harvest wood should be drafted. Detection 40 Detection is the second major element of an enforcement strategy. There are a variety of ways to detect illegal logging – a particularly important aspect of the debate for Indonesia revolves around the merits (or otherwise) of investing heavily in expensive, high-technology solutions when simple, less costly, labour-intensive methods would perhaps be more appropriate and effective. Good policy. Organisations responsible for fighting illegal logging must be identified, and a clear division of responsibilities, equipment needs, staffing and areas of co-operation established. Good management. Operational practice must be defined, including how to handle confiscated material, management systems, inter-agency co-ordination protocols and practice, and training requirements. Political will. More vigorous action backed by stronger political will. To do this increased awareness among politicians and policy makers is needed along with specific policies targeted at country and regional levels. Increased public awareness is also essential. Governance. There is a pressing need for reliable documentation verified by a third (independent) party. A comprehensive log tracking system and a clear and systematic procedure for collecting and managing information is also necessary. International co-operation. The potential for making use of international assistance needs to be evaluated, including the potential for regional approaches, bilateral initiatives, and NGO involvement. Co-ordinated approaches. Donors should avoid individual initiatives and consider coordinated, sector-wide approaches to assistance. International co-operation. Regional experience offers some interesting lessons for Indonesia. In Cambodia, a computerised tracking system has been developed to monitor illegal logging, corruption and arson. A system has been developed to facilitate the flow of information from the provinces to the central government, leading to charges being brought against illegal loggers. Good information is being recovered from areas where the “fear factor” has been overcome – not everywhere – demonstrating the importance of providing adequate protection for those involved in combating illegal logging. Good policy. Government resources will always be inadequate, and civil society must be drawn into detection networks. Basic training to this end is required on the law, basic forest legislation, and basic guidance on how to gather evidence. Independent civil society monitoring. Third party monitoring has been successful in both Cambodia (through Global Witness) and in the Philippines (through Multi-Sectoral Forest Protection (MSFP) committees, which involve rural populations and local NGOs). 41 Suppression Suppression is reactive. If prevention and detection work, very little suppression is needed. It is still, however, an important part of any strategy to combat illegal logging. Strong institutions. Authority must be clearly designated and a lead agency identified. The agency will need to have some central co-ordination with a strong regional and local presence. It may be necessary to create and adequately finance an organisation which deals specifically with forest crime. Cross-sectoral approach. Suppression strategies must be linked to the judicial system, local government and the media. Governance. Suppression must take place in a transparent and impartial manner. Capacity building. Training is required in a range of skills, including in pursuing criminal investigations and resource management laws. Capacity building. Training is also required for prosecutors and judges to gain a heightened understanding of the issues which arise in crimes related to the exploitation of natural resources. Quick wins. Test cases are a vital first step to moving forward. High profile test cases brought to a successful conclusion will provide a strong symbol of determination to tackle the problem and will begin the process of rebuilding confidence among the agencies responsible for enforcing the law. 42 References Ascher, W. 1999. Why governments waste natural resources. Policy failures in developing countries. The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London. Barr, C. 2000. Will HPH reform lead to sustainable forest management? Questioning the assumptions of the "sustainable logging" paradigm in Indonesia. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Barr (2000). Profits on Paper: The Political-Economy of Fibre, Finance, and Debt in Indonesia’s Pulp and Paper Industries. To be published as a chapter in Christopher Barr (forthcoming) Banking on Sustainability: A Critical Assessment of Structural Adjustment in Indonesia’s Forest and Estate Crop Industries, CIFOR and WWF-International, Macroeconomics Program Office. Brown, D. 1999. Addicted to rent: corporate and spatial distribution of forest resources in Indonesia. implications for forest sustainability and government policy. Report No. PFM/EC/99/06. UK Tropical Forest Management Programme. Jakarta. Callister, Debra. J. 2000. Illegal tropical timber trade: Asia Pacific. A traffic network report. Traffic Oceania, Sydney. Casson, A. 1999. The hesitant boom: Indonesia's oil palm sub-sector in an era of economic crisis and political change. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Casson, A. 2000. Illegal logging in Central Kalimantan, Indonesia. Draft paper. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Cohen, M. 1988. Monitoring and enforcement of environmental policy. Deutscher Bundestag. 1990. Protecting the tropical forests: a high priority international task. Deutscher Bundestag, Bonn. EIA/Telapak (1999). The Final Cut: Illegal Logging in Indonesia's Orang-Utan Parks. Environmental Investigation Agency, London. EIA/Telapak (2000). Illegal Logging in Tanjung Puting National Park: An Update on the Final Cut Report. Environmental Investigation Agency, London. ITFMP (1999). Illegal Logging in Indonesia. ITFMP Report No. EC/99/03. Jakarta, Indonesia. ITFMP/WWF (1999). Laporan perkembangan sawmill di Wilayah Selatan TN. Bukit Tigapuluh dan di sekitar area KPHP Pasir Mayang. ITFMP Report No. PFM/KPHP/98/10. Jambi, Indonesia. Ginting et al. (1999) Laporan Penelitian Budidaya Tanaman Kopi di dalam Kawasan Hutan dan Pengaruhnya Terhadap Fungsi Hutan di Propinsi Daerah Tingkat I Lampung. Departemen Kehutanan dan Perkebunan. Global Witness (1999). Crackdown or Pause: A Chance for Forestry Reform in Cambodia? Global Witness, London. Holmes, D. (1999). Deforestation in Indonesia: A Review of the Situation in 1999. Forthcoming paper. Kartodihardjo, H. (2000). Forest Management by Concessions. Paper presented to Removing the Constraints: Post-CGI Seminar on Indonesian Forestry. Jakarta, Indonesia. LTFE, Harvard University. 1998. Baseline socio-economic status of communities participating in the project community-based forest management of buffer zone forests at Gunung Palung National park, West Kalimantan. Unpublished project report. p. 22. McCarthy, J.F. 2000a. The changing regime: forest property and reformasi in Indonesia. Development and Change Vol 31, 91-129. McCarthy, J.F. 2000b. Wild logging: state agency, district networks of power and interest and biodiversity conservation in South Aceh, Sumatra. Unpublished manuscript. McGrath and Grandalski (2000). Forest Law Enforcement: Policies, Strategies and Technologies. Forthcoming paper. NRM (2000). Review of BPS Forestry Sector Data Analysis. NRM, Jakarta, Indonesia. 43 Noegroho, A. (2000). Extent and costs of the 1997/98 forest fires and drought in Indonesia. Paper presented to Removing the Constraints: Post-CGI Seminar on Indonesian Forestry. Jakarta, Indonesia. Norindra (1994). Rainforest and Resource Management. The Indonesian Institute of Sciences (LIPI), Jakarta, Indonesia. Obidzinski K. and Suramenggela I. 2000a. Comparative social economy and ecological impact of small scale logging in East Kalimantan. Draft paper. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Obidzinski, K. and Suramenggala, I. 2000b. Small scale timber industry and community forests in the Malinau area, Bulungan. Draft paper. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Poore, D., Burgess, P., Palmer, J, Rietbergen, S., and Synott, T. 1989. No timber without trees. Earthscan, London. Rose-Ackerman, S. 1999. Corruption and government: causes, consequences and reform. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Salafsky, N. 1993. The forest garden project, an ecological and economic study of a locally developed land-use system in West Kalimantan, Indonesia. PhD dissertation, Duke University. Scotland (1997). Economic Rent in the Indonesian Forest Sector Volume 5: Financial and Management Implications. Indonesia-UK Tropical Forest Management Programme, Jakarta, Indonesia. Scotland, N. 1998. The impact of the Southeast Asian monetary crisis on Indonesian forest concessions and implications for the future. Report No. SMAT/EC/98/02. UK Tropical Forest Management Programme, Jakarta. Sizer, N. and Plouvier, D. 2000. Increased Investment and trade by transnational logging companies in Africa, the Caribbean and the Pacific: implications for the sustainable management and conservation of tropical forests. WWF Belgium, WRI and WWF International. Sunderlin W 1999. The effects of economic crisis and political change on Indonesia's forest sector, 1997−99. 15 November 1999. http://www.cgiar.org/cifor/ Suyanto, S. 2000. Fire and Deforestation in the North-Eastern Fringes of Bukit Barisan Selatan National Park, Lampung. Paper presented at the joint workshop for the Asian forest fire and its environmental impacts in Tokyo, March 7, 2000. Tomich, T.P., Fagi A.M, de Foresta H., Michion G., Murdiyarso D., Stolle F and van Noorwijk M. (1998). Indonesia's Fires: Smoke as a Problem, Smoke as a Symptom. Agroforestry Today, 10 (1): 4 - 7. Wadley R. and Dennis, R. (2000) ....... Paper in preparation. WWF/ITFMP (1999). Laporan Perkembangan Sawmill di Wilayah Selatan TN. Bukit Tigapuluh dan Sekitar Area KPHP Pasir Mayang. Indonesia-UK Tropical Forest Management Programme, Jakarta, Indonesia. 44