Foreign Exchange Rate Indexation Liquidity Facilities Outline of Proposed Concept: Although a liquidity facility could protect infrastructure projects financed with longterm local-currency loans from default induced by local-currency interest rate volatility, such a facility would not be likely to encourage an extension of tenors in countries that are currently characterized by the availability of only short-term local-currency financing. Opinions vary as to the factors that keep lenders in many countries from offering long-term financing, but the correlation between high exchange rate volatility and short-term markets suggests that lenders prefer to keep their commitments short to enable them to exploit opportunities to shift assets from one currency to another. Although many local borrowers cannot repay the full amount of their short-term loans at maturity, even partial repayment coupled with appropriately timed currency conversion can produce significantly higher returns than a strategy based on exclusively investing within the host-country. The opportunities to increase returns by means of a foreign-exchange based strategy vary from country to country. For example, an analysis of quarterly interest rate and foreign exchange data from 1995 through 2004 for Brazil and the Philippines indicates that a Brazilian investor with perfect foresight (and no transactions costs) would have switched currencies twelve times, while a Philippine investor would have preferred to remain in pesos throughout the period. For the Brazilian investor, such a strategy would have increased returns from 33% to 40% during 1995-2004 and by much larger amounts for the periods 1997-2004 (from 23% to 37%) and 1999-2004 (from 21% to 50%). It is possible that lenders in countries with short-term financing markets can be induced to lend on a long-term basis if they are guaranteed a sufficient percentage of foreign exchange gains. For example, a long-term local-currency loan could specify that principal payments (and the outstanding balance of the loan) will be indexed to a percentage of the change in nominal foreign exchange rates between closing and the payment date. For example, if the lender were offered 50% of gains and the FX rate moved from 2.0 : 1 at closing to 3.0: 1 at the payment date, the payment would by increased by 25%, an amount reflecting one-half of the change in the FX rate since closing [(3.0+2.0) / 2 = 2.5; the payment is, therefore, multiplied by 2.5 / 2.0 = 1.25]. Although the proposed structure might appear to be overly favorable to local lenders, from the standpoint of an infrastructure project that requires long-term financing to offer economically-feasible tariffs, it could be preferable to US dollar financing (which may be its only realistic alternative). If the project were financed with US dollars, the local currency value of its debt service payment in the above Bob Sheppard Co-chair, Experts Group on Public / Private Risk Sharing Projfin@bellsouth.net 1 example would increase by 50% – not 25% – and the increase would apply to both interest and principal, not to principal alone, as in the proposed structure. (On the other hand, a portion of these advantages is offset by the fact that local currency interest rates tend to be higher – often much higher – than US dollar interest rates.) A sharing of 50% of foreign exchange gains with local lenders can increase lenders’ expected returns from the “domestic only” rate to a rate closer to the “best” rate that would be produced by skillfully-timed currency conversions. In fact, to achieve an appropriate rate, it is likely that lenders will need to accept an interest rate slightly lower than the prevailing local market rate. For example, in the Brazilian example for 1997-2004, an interest rate 2% below market and a 50% sharing of FX gains would produce returns to lenders of 30%, rather than the 23% returns produced by a “domestic only” strategy. In the case of the Philippines, a 1% discount from the market rate and a 50% sharing of FX gains would raise returns for the 1995-2004 period from 11% to 15%. To protect an infrastructure project financed with a long-term, floating-rate localcurrency loan embodying this FX indexation structure, a liquidity facility should be used to mitigate against both interest rate and FX volatility. As in the case of a foreign exchange liquidity facility, the liquidity facility would function as a revolving loan, with outstanding amounts repaid from the project’s cash available for distribution when interest rates have fallen. Amounts owed to the liquidity facility would be subordinated to the senior debt that was used to finance the project. An FX rate indexation liquidity facility could be provided by a host-country government (either directly or by guaranteeing amounts advanced by local financial institutions) or by a multilateral agency (either directly or by guaranteeing an undertaking by the host-country government). The fact that the ultimate beneficiaries of the liquidity facility would be local financial institutions would, in most circumstances, lessen the need for support from multilateral agencies. Benefits: This structure will provide substantial benefits to host-country governments, project sponsors, and lenders: Host-country governments would benefit because the structure will promote needed investment with a contingent financial commitment tied to risks that are partially within the control of the government itself. The structure may provide sufficient incentives for local lenders to offer longterm local-currency financing in countries where it would otherwise be unavailable. The fact that FX indexation will be based on movements of the Bob Sheppard Co-chair, Experts Group on Public / Private Risk Sharing Projfin@bellsouth.net 2 nominal FX rate provides a high degree of certainty that the structure will work to lenders’ benefit. The structure enables local lenders to provide longer-term financing without the risk of interest-rate induced default and its consequence of lengthy restructuring negations. The structure may enable project sponsors to obtain and utilize long-term local currency financing, thus avoiding much of the currency mismatch risk entailed by US dollar financing. Obstacles to Date: The two major obstacles to offering this structure are: 1. Due diligence: A substantial amount of analysis would be needed to convince project sponsors and liquidity facility providers that the structure will function properly under a wide variety of economic circumstances. The proposal offered here is a sketch; it does not represent the type of detailed analysis that underlay the concept of a foreign exchange liquidity facility before its first use. 2. Reputation risk: Many financial and governmental institutions are cautious about advancing new ideas that might fail in a very public manner. Here the risk is not that a transaction might encounter difficulties sometime after closing; it is that investors would not accept the proposed structure or might demand unacceptably high pricing after it was known in the market that the structure was being marketed for a specific transaction. As in the case of a foreign exchange liquidity, a new, very different structure is an experiment, the results of which will not be known until an actual attempt is made to implement it. Recommended Next Steps for Implementation: A host-country government should decide to provide such a liquidity facility and select a demonstration project with a sponsor willing to accept a loan or offer securities with the proposed structure. Implementation would entail the following steps: Selection of an appropriate infrastructure project sponsored by a domestic or international firm that is willing to devote effort to implementing a new structure Evaluate both the local bank market and the local capital market as possible sources of financing using this structure (This will entail an evaluation of market participants’ understanding of and comfort with infrastructure project financing, as well as their ability and willingness to extend financing of the tenor required to make the project feasible.) Bob Sheppard Co-chair, Experts Group on Public / Private Risk Sharing Projfin@bellsouth.net 3 Decide on a strategy to use in structuring the FX rate indexation loan and/or securities and in approaching selected local financial institutions; either: o Approach local financial institutions during a pre-marketing period to explain the FX rate indexation structure and solicit comments (at the risk of structuring a transaction that is more favorable to lenders than is in fact necessary to obtain their participation), or o Structure the transaction without feedback from lenders, obtain ratings for the transaction (see below), and present lenders with a fully-structured transaction (With this second approach, lenders will tend to limit requests for changes in the transaction to items that are in fact deal points from their perspective.) Determination of the form in which the host-country will provide the liquidity facility – through a direct commitment from the Ministry of Finance or other governmental agency, through a government-owned development bank, etc. Structure the liquidity facility – establish conditions under which it may be drawn, repayment terms, interest rate on outstanding balances, etc. Seek appropriate national scale ratings from local and/or international rating agencies Arrange financing and close the transaction Bob Sheppard Co-chair, Experts Group on Public / Private Risk Sharing Projfin@bellsouth.net 4