FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND SUBNATIONAL EXPENDITURE POLICY Luiz de Mello,1 International Monetary Fund I. INTRODUCTION The need to improve the quality and efficiency of government spending has placed subnational governments at the forefront of service delivery, particularly in the social sectors. In many countries, it has been recognized that subnational governments have an important role to play in the implementation of public policies aimed at fostering social and human development. The key argument for reliance on subnational governments for service delivery is that they are closer to the intended beneficiaries of public programs. For this reason, subnational governments are believed to be better equipped to extract information on local preferences and needs more effectively than the central government, and to be more accountable to local residents. With greater voice in the design and implementation of public policies, local residents can also benefit from greater choice in the goods and services delivered to them by the government. Reliance on subnational governments, or the private sector, for the delivery of public goods and services is nevertheless not without pitfalls. Fiscal decentralization may lead to the wasteful duplication of expenditure functions among the different levels of government and poor governance, thereby reducing the quality of public services and the overall efficiency of the government. An open policy question is whether the central government should rely more 2 heavily on subnational governments for the design, rather than simply the implementation, of public programs in general, and in the social sectors in particular. In this case, rather than acting as agents of the center, subnational governments would enjoy greater policymaking autonomy. In most countries, the share of subnational outlays in total government spending has increased reflecting their more active role in service delivery, and, in some cases, greater policymaking autonomy in the design and implementation of public policies. Nevertheless, the central government still has an important role to play, even when subnational governments are key providers of public goods and services. The central government is often called upon to finance provision, including in some cases the equalization of expenditure capacity among subnational jurisdictions; to avoid shortfalls in the financing of critical social services; and to provide technical assistance to subnational jurisdictions. In a nutshell, this paper is aimed at, first, reviewing the international experience with the decentralization of government spending to subnational governments and to the private sector, with special emphasis on the social sectors, including education, health care, social assistance and welfare, and housing. A second objective of the paper is to discuss the main challenges facing subnational governments in the design and implementation of public programs, including the earmarking of revenues, as well as economies of scale and spillover effects in the provision of public services. 1 The author is now at the Economics Department of the OECD. Mailing address: Economics Department, OECD, 2, rue André Pascal, Paris 75775 Cedex 16, France. Tel.: (33-1) 45248752, e-mail: luiz.demello@oecd.org. 3 The paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews the conventional distribution of expenditure functions among the different levels of government and discusses recent developments in this area. Section III presents some cross-country data on spending shares among different levels of government. Section IV focuses on education, health care, housing and infrastructure, and social assistance and welfare. Section V discusses pending issues and policy implications. II. THE FISCAL ROLE OF SUBNATIONAL GOVERNMENTS: THE “OLD” AND THE “NEW” Public finance theory has traditionally assigned a limited role to subnational governments in the design of social policies. The key argument is that, based on the Musgravean functions of government, the fiscal role of subnational governments is limited to allocative efficiency, whereas the central government should focus on income redistribution and welfare, as well as on macroeconomic stabilization. Based on the principle of subsidiarity, the public goods and services that should be provided by subnational governments are those which generate benefits that can be internalized by those jurisdictions. Accordingly, activities such as waste disposal, street maintenance, primary education, and urban transportation have been devolved or decentralized to subnational governments in most countries. Delegation/decentralization is considered the most effective way to deliver these services because their benefits are mostly local and there is little scope for economies of scale and interjurisdictional spillover effects in their provision. 4 The role of subnational governments in the provision of public goods and services has been affected by a variety of factors. These include demographics, technological changes in communication and transportation, for instance, and the development of market institutions, which allows for more active private sector involvement in service delivery (Wildasin, 1998). Moreover, it is often difficult to clearly define the benefits and beneficiaries of specific programs. For example, the benefits of public spending on primary education are known to be local but, from the point of view of poverty alleviation, they are national in scope. Economies of scale, particularly in administrative functions, may call for a more centralized management of service delivery even when services are provided locally. More recently, public finance theory has reassessed the assignment of expenditure functions among the different levels of government based on principal-agent considerations. What matters in this case is not allocative efficiency from the point of view of internalizing the benefits of provision within the jurisdictional boundaries of the provider, but the response of different layers of government to incentives for efficient, cost-effective service delivery. The consideration of the principal-agent nature of decentralized service delivery has highlighted a finer distinction between delegation and decentralization. Delegation is preferred when subnational governments are best suited as agents of the center and when clear incentives for efficiency gains can be put in place. In addition, when expenditure functions can be unbundled, rather than treated as a whole, each layer of government can perform the role that best reflects its preferences and needs or comparative advantages. For example, because primary education can be used as a tool of 5 poverty alleviation, as mentioned above, national governments often provide financial support to ensure a minimum level of provision in all jurisdictions, while day-to-day management responsibilities are assigned to local governments or school boards. Transportation services may be provided locally subject to regulations issued by the central government. In line with their changing role in service delivery and program design, subnational governments have played a more active role in redistributive policies.2 Traditionally, it had been argued that the effectiveness of subnational redistributive policies depended on taxpayer mobility. Factor mobility may prevent subnational governments from using the tax system for the purpose of redistribution, and locally-funded transfer payments may attract potential claimants from neighboring jurisdictions, thereby discouraging local funding for these programs. More recently, the recognition that taxpayer mobility may be more limited than expected has provided some justification for subnational redistributive policies, particularly in terms of expenditure, rather than taxation, policies. The central government should nevertheless remain at the forefront of redistributive policies. In some cases, it may be better to use intergovernmental grants to address differences in average income levels in various subnational jurisdictions than to use taxes and transfers to individuals (McLure and Martinez-Vazquez, 2000). 2 The role of subnational governments in macroeconomic stabilization, another classical function of government according to Musgrave, remains limited. To avoid macroeconomic disarray due to decentralization, as highlighted in the literature (e.g., Ter-Minassian, 1997; de Mello, 2000), it has been recognized that the central government plays a crucial role in imposing hard budget constraints at the subnational levels of government. 6 III. SUBNATIONAL GOVERNMENT SPENDING: AN OVERVIEW Subnational governments, including middle-tier jurisdictions, such as states and provinces, and local governments, are important providers of public goods and services. Fiscal decentralization indicators vary considerably among regions but, in more decentralized countries, such as large federations, subnational governments account for over 36 percent of total governments spending on average, or approximately 14 percent of GDP (Table 1). A sizeable share of subnational spending is financed through local revenue mobilization, but subnational governments also rely heavily on grants and transfers from higher levels of government, which account for nearly a third of their revenues on average. Interestingly, subnational governments tend to rely on grants and transfers regardless of their size, measured in terms of ratios of expenditure to GDP and total government spending. An interesting question is how the changing role of subnational governments in service delivery has affected the composition of government spending among different tiers of government (Table 2). Internationally comparable information on public expenditure by function for the different levels of government is limited. In general, education and health care account for a large share of subnational expenditures, particularly in the case of middle-tier jurisdictions. Housing also accounts for a large share of local government spending, in addition to education and health care. Over time, middle-tier governments have devoted a growing share of their total spending to health care programs. Interestingly, although social security and welfare continues to weigh more heavily on central government budgets, these programs have accounted for a 7 growing share of local governments spending over time. Local government spending on housing, already high in relation to local government spending, has increased over time. Cross-country indicators of fiscal decentralization should be interpreted with caution. Subnational fiscal data are often less reliable than those of the central government and, more importantly, the quantitative indicators reported above do not allow for a more in-depth analysis of the qualitative aspects of intergovernmental expenditure arrangements. For instance, the rise in local government spending on social security and welfare programs, as noted above, may be due to the delegation of service delivery functions to these jurisdictions, rather than greater autonomy in the design and implementation of their own welfare programs. Moreover, based on the data at hand, it is not possible to ascertain how much of subnational spending is financed through grants and transfers from higher levels of government, rather than local revenue mobilization.3 Intergovernmental grants and transfers differ considerably in their nature, and hence the incentives they create at the local level. For instance, local governments tend to have greater autonomy in service delivery and in program design when spending is financed through block, rather than matching or earmarked, grants. 3 The GFS does not provide data on earmarked grants and transfers to, and within, subnational governments. 8 IV. THE INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE A. Education International experience varies on the role of subnational governments in the provision of education services. In many countries, particularly in OECD member countries, the central government plays a key role in financing and standard setting, rather than service delivery, including personnel management, budget preparation, procurement activities, and administration. Centralized financing and standard setting is justified on the grounds that education programs can be used as a poverty-alleviation instrument and as a means to equalize expenditure capacity among subnational units. Outlays on education tend to account for a large share of subnational budgets, particularly at the local level. Decentralization beyond the public sector is also common in many countries, where partnerships with the private sector have been encouraged and fully managed by subnational, particularly local, jurisdictions subject to the parameters set by the central government.4 In the developing world, unlike most industrial countries, the central government typically plays a more active role in service delivery due primarily to capacity constraints at the subnational level.5 Also, the decentralization of 4 Among OECD countries, the main education decentralization programs are GrantMaintained-Schools (United Kingdom); Charter Schools (United States, also in New Zealand and Canada), and Future Schools (Australia). According to the General Accounting Office of the United States, based on the study of Dade County (Florida), Prince William County (Virginia), and the Edmonton school district (Alberta, Canada), these decentralization programs have a positive impact on the adoption of innovative managerial and teaching practices, as well as the responsiveness to local preferences and needs (Rondeau, 1997). 5 For instance, in Mexico, 65 percent of all schools and 75 percent of those in basic education (preschool and primary education) were federally funded and controlled until 1992 (Juarez, 1999). Federal involvement in education was unequally distributed across the country, but the (continued…) 9 education services to subnational jurisdictions has been motivated by the need to take account of regional diversities, particularly of an ethnic and linguistic nature, in many industrial and developing countries. Subnational governments may play an important role in personnel management in the education sector. The decentralization of education programs typically begins with the delegation of administrative functions, particularly personnel management, to subnational governments. In the United Kingdom, the United States, and Canada, among other countries, emphasis has been placed on school districts, rather than local governments for the decentralization of personnel management functions. When greater personnel management autonomy is granted to subnational governments, it is important to avoid the risk of overstaffing and excessive discretion over pay in the course of decentralization, particularly if governance is poor at the subnational level. In some countries, unionization and issues related to civil servants’ benefits and entitlements have created resistance to decentralization efforts (i.e., Venezuela).6 Moreover, in a labor-intensive sector such as education, subnational budgets become excessively dependent on the central government’s personnel policy when teacher’s salaries are set by the center. In many countries in Latin America, this situation created unfunded mandates at the federal government designed education policies, set the academic calendar, and assigned textbooks and other activities. After 1992, when a comprehensive decentralization program was implemented, the states were granted autonomy to control and operate all schools in basic education, subject to federal funding and regulation. 6 In 1994, Venezuela implemented a decentralization program in the education sector by unifying the federal, state, and municipal school networks (pre-school, primary and secondary education) and transferring the respective assets and personnel to the states, which would be responsible for service delivery. See Tracy (1996), for more information. 10 local level and led to the implementation of special transfer programs to finance subnational payroll outlays (i.e., Colombia). In Brazil, income differentials among subnational units resulted in sizeable pay inequality between state and municipal schools and sometimes within the same state. This problem has nevertheless been mitigated, at least in part, due to the earmarking, since 1998, of 60 percent of primary education spending to teacher’s salaries.7 Financing arrangements vary across countries. In general, education programs are financed by the center, even when implemented by subnational governments. When subnational cofinancing is required, some countries earmark subnational revenues to avoid financing shortfalls, in addition to the grants and transfers received from higher levels of government. In Brazil, for example, 15 percent of state and municipal revenues are earmarked to finance primary education programs. In other countries, local education budgets may be financed entirely through grants and transfers from higher levels of government. In many cases, transfers are formula-based and take expenditure needs into account, particularly when the equalization of subnational expenditure capacity is pursued. Functions are costed subject to the minimum standards set by the center.8 Other countries also rely on the decentralization of service delivery to strengthen cost recovery through the collection of user charges and fees for the provision of some services (i.e., contingency fees, and (subsidized) school fees, among others) (Litvack and 7 For more information on the decentralized service delivery in Latin America, see ECLAC (1998), and Burki, Perry and Dillinger (1999). 8 In Brazil, for example, a national minimum spending level per primary school student is set annually with a federal top-up grant to subnational governments that cannot afford the minimum spending level set by the center. See de Mello (2001), for more information. 11 Seddon, 1999). Willingness to pay for service delivery is believed to increase when the services are provided by local governments. Other cost recovery schemes such as community financing have also emerged as means for the central government to reduce the fiscal burden of education service provision.9 A critical policy question is whether subnational governments are more efficient than the center in the provision of education services. Efficiency gains can be assessed when education attainment indicators (i.e., literacy rates and school enrollment rates, among others) are improved for the same consolidated spending level as a result of decentralization, or, alternatively, when the same indicators can be achieved through lower spending. Simple correlations between education attainment and decentralization indicators are typically weak and should be interpreted with caution because they do not control for other determinants of education attainment.10 Neither do these indicators capture the more qualitative nature of decentralization, which could explain differences in attainment for countries with similar subnational spending shares. For efficiency to be boosted, it is important to know whether 9 Community financing has been an important aspect of decentralization in countries where governments have been unable to meet the demand for education services. In this case, community-funded schools have coexisted with the public school network to offer schooling with particular religious, ethnic, political, or other orientations. With the exception of Bolivia and Nicaragua, community financing has been less widespread in Latin America than in Africa and Asia (Bray, 1996; ECLAC, 1998). See also de Mello (2004), for cross-country evidence on the association between fiscal decentralization and social capital. 10 See Baldacci, Guin-Siu, and de Mello (2003), for cross-country evidence on the efficiency of government spending on education and health care. 12 service quality improves through the decentralization of service delivery, access to education services is facilitated, and spending reaches the target population.11 Anecdotal evidence suggests that the quality of services provided by subnational governments tends to be lower than those provided by higher-level jurisdictions, particularly in the developing world, but it is hard to control for all determinants of quality, in addition to decentralization. In industrial countries, where empirical evidence is more readily available, pupil performance, measured in standardized test scores, tends to improve through greater local government autonomy in education policymaking. Unfortunately, data inadequacies often prevent the use of this more sophisticated methodology in the developing world, where more ambitious decentralization programs are being, or have been, implemented. In Brazil, recent research has shown that the states in which public schools are free to manage their budgets and appoint the headmaster, as well as to implement participatory management schemes, tend to have lower repetition and dropout rates, and their students tend to have better test scores.12 There is some empirical evidence that quality can be improved when subnational 11 More sophisticated methods of measuring efficiency gains in the education sector consist of comparing test scores in a given school district relative to a control group in another district that has not been affected by decentralization, after controlling for other observable determinants of school performance, such as class size, and socio-economic indicators. 12 A study of the Curumim Program (Paes de Barros, Mendonça and Soares, 1998), implemented in the state of Minas Gerais, Brazil, suggests that test scores, enrollment and repetition rates, as well as age-grade gap indicators have improved in a sample of pupils in primary schools that participated in the program, after controlling for other determinants of school performance, such as parents’ educational background and occupation, and number of books at home, among others. 13 governments, particularly at the local level, enjoy greater autonomy in program design and implementation with increased use of demand-driven, result-oriented, participatory administration in public schools.13 In Latin America, this trend has been referred to as the municipalization of the education sector, as has been particularly noteworthy in Brazil and Chile (de Mello, 2001).14 Overall, it has been suggested that improvements in school systems depend heavily on empowering local authorities to adapt programs to local conditions (Dalin, 1994). Information on access and the incidence of public spending is scarce, particularly at the subnational level. A key determinant of efficiency in the provision of education services is targeting, or whether public outlays on a given program actually reach the intended beneficiaries. Benefit incidence studies indicate that that the poor reap a disproportionately small share of the benefits of public spending on education, further underscoring the need to target these outlays more accurately. Information on incidence rates by government level is even scarcer, and the correlation between decentralization parameters and incidence rates tends to be weak. The information reported in Table 3 shows that, for instance, in the case of primary education, for the same level of expenditure decentralization—measured as the ratio of 13 The most common participatory administration schemes in Brazil are the School Council, available in 1997 in over 37 percent of the nearly 42,000 schools funded by state governments, and the Parents and Teachers Association, available in nearly one-third of states schools. See Parente and Lück (1999), for more information. 14 Chile is an example of increased private-sector involvement in the education sector in the developing world, where subsidized private schools now account for over one-third of total school enrollment. Competition among schools to attract students has increased because funding is based on grade-adjusted school attendance. However, there is evidence that decentralization has not by itself removed inequalities between jurisdictions of different incomes (Parry, 1997). 14 subnational spending to central government spending—the share of public spending accruing to the lowest income quintile is almost twice as high in Argentina as it is in Pakistan. In the case of public spending on secondary education, which tends to be less pro-poor than spending on primary education, both countries have similar incidence rates. This suggests that the design of education programs is more important than intergovernmental spending levels per se, and that other factors, such as the share of private spending on education and school improvement programs, also play an important role in determining incidence rates across countries. B. Health Care As in the case of education, decentralization in the health care sector may enhance the efficiency of public spending through improved service quality and coverage. Decentralization of health care tends to be more complex than in other sectors because diseconomies of scale tend to discourage subnational provision of costly curative health care services and spillover effects tend to discourage the provision of preventive health care, particularly immunization and epidemiological control, by subnational governments.15 15 In Brazil, for instance, municipal joint ventures have been developed in recent years to generate economies of scale in administrative activities, including hiring new staff, licensing private health care providers, and procurement. More recently, efforts have been made to strengthen the institutional framework within which these ventures are created (Ribeiro and Costa, 1999). According to the Brazilian Ministry of Health, as of July 1999, there are 143 intermunicipal ventures in Brazil, covering a total of 1,740 municipalities. 15 The objectives of decentralization in the health care sector also vary significantly between developing and developed countries. Few developing countries have long-term experience with health sector decentralization and reform packages have seldom been evaluated. The focus of decentralization in the developing world tends to be on increasing the coverage of the public health care system, particularly in rural areas and in less developed regions, and on securing additional sources of finance from subnational jurisdictions. This has been the main elements of decentralization in Latin America, for instance, since the early 1990s (i.e., Brazil, Mexico, Colombia, Bolivia). Private-sector providers coexist with the public health care system, privatepublic service quality differentials are sizeable, and the incidence of public spending tends to be better than that of education because the better-off tend to rely on private health care providers. Developed countries, on the other hand, typically focus on efficiency gains through decentralization outside the public sector. This includes the increased use of co-payment schemes, delisting of entitlements, shifts toward the public contracting model, separation of provision and management from purchasing functions, contracting out of hotel functions and other supporting services, and private capital investments. The experience of the OECD countries has been diverse.16 Health care is one of the largest sectors in OECD countries, and accounts now for over 8 percent of GDP on average. Recent health care reforms in many OECD countries have focused on increasing private-sector involvement in service delivery, as well as institutional and managerial restructuring, consolidation and regionalization of purchasing functions, and consolidation of health care 16 See OECD (2003), for further discussion. 16 institutions through mergers and vertical integration of services (Ranade, 1998).17 In many countries, there is widespread public opinion support for national health insurance schemes (i.e., Canada, Germany, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Sweden, the United Kingdom). As a result, proposals to privatize the funding of health care have faced opposition and attention has focused on improving the allocation of funds to health care providers within the framework of public funding. Efficiency gains have also been sought by improving consumer choice as an incentive toward greater competition and cost-effectiveness among service providers.18 Financing plays a crucial role in the decentralization of health care. Most health care services provided publicly are financed by the central government through general taxation, often in conjunction with the social security system. As in the case of education, many countries resort to earmarking of revenues to finance health care, particularly in the developing world (i.e., Brazil, Colombia).19 In general, subnational governments rely on block grants from the center, The New Zealand government’s proposal to institute “managed competition” in the purchasing and provision of care—undertaken in 1991 at the same time as reforms in the United Kingdom—was motivated by a relatively fragmented funding system, rising levels of user charges and ensuing barriers to access, long waiting lists, and overcapacity of rural hospitals. The reforms were also motivated by public opinion support for greater private sector involvement in service delivery, and by the overall pro-market reforms that were implemented at the time in New Zealand. 17 18 See Hurst and Jee-Hughes (2000), for a discussion of performance indicators in health care systems in OECD countries. 19 In 2000, legislation was passed in Brazil requiring the states and municipalities to earmark 12 percent and 15 percent, respectively, of their revenues (net of intergovernmental transfers) to finance outlays on health care (Afonso and de Mello, 2002). Per capita transfers to subnational governments were also introduced to finance the provision of preventive health care. In Colombia, a share of central government transfers to the municipalities is earmarked to finance health care spending. In Bolivia, 3.2 percent of central government transfers to municipalities (continued…) 17 often based on historical input costs, rather than on equalizing grants based on per capita expenditure needs and standardized costs. Input-oriented budgeting tends to bias public spending towards curative, rather than preventive, care. In the developing world, financing shortfalls are common, and intergovernmental grants are often aimed at financing capital outlays and fail to take into account the need for recurrent spending associated with expensive curative care programs (i.e., operations and maintenance). Moreover, despite the effort to increase spending on health care in the course of decentralization, financing formulas have seldom included equalization components in many countries.20 Because of the need for alternative sources of finance for the provision of health care, many countries have introduced fees and user charges, which are more widespread in the case of health care than education. In many countries, these revenues are collected in separate funds, not often consolidated in the government accounts (i.e., transition economies).21 Increased cost recovery through user are earmarked to finance the provision of a priority benefits package for mothers and children (Bossert, 2000). 20 In an attempt to equalize spending capacity in the course of decentralization, a horizontal equity fund (Municipal Common Fund) was set up in Chile reassigning up to 60 percent of the revenues of wealthier municipalities to their poorer counterparts using a formula based on population and municipal income (Bossert, 2000). 21 Bossert (2000) shows that per capita spending on health care increased during decentralization in Chile and Colombia. Although wealthier municipalities spent more on a per capita basis than poorer municipalities, the gap between them narrowed over time, resulting in more equitable allocations among the subnational jurisdictions. 18 charges, as well as reliance on the private sector to provide health care services, may affect the access of certain social groups to these services.22 Empirical evidence of a positive impact of decentralization on the quality of publicly-provided health care services is limited. Anecdotal evidence of a relationship between decentralization and the quality of publicly-provided health care is available in a number of countries (i.e., Gilson, 1997, Kolehmainen-Aitken, 1998). However, it is not easy to isolate the determinants of successful decentralization programs (Bossert, 1998).23 As in the case of education, more sophisticated statistical methods to assess decentralization-driven efficiency gains in the health care sector would require comparisons between countries that have implemented comparable decentralization programs in the sector relative to a control group of countries where similar programs have not been implemented, and controlling for additional observable determinants of health status. Quality assessments based on opinion surveys among the users of health care services are not readily available in many countries. Information on the incidence of public spending on health care is limited (Table 3) and suggests that, as in the case of education, the decentralization of spending on health care is weakly 22 Community financing has been a prominent feature of health care decentralization in Bolivia after 1994 (ECLAC, 1998). However, local governments continue to rely heavily on the central government for financing. 23 Incidentally, using panel data for low- and high-income countries in the period 1970-1995, Robalino, Picazo, and Voetberg (2001) show that fiscal decentralization, defined as the ratio of total local government expenditure to total central government expenditure, is associated with lower infant mortality rates, particularly in less developed countries. 19 correlated with incidence rates. For example, data available for Chile show that almost a third of public spending on health care accrue to those in the poorest quintile and subnational governments account for only 2 percent of central government spending on health care. Rather than dismissing a relationship between decentralization and incidence rates, it is important to take into account other factors affecting the ability of subnational governments to reach the poor, as well as the financing mechanisms for subnational spending. In many countries, gender and ethnicity remain important determinants of access to health care services. In other countries, where formal access to services is universal, long surgical waiting lists and the prevalence of informal user charges, among others, are good indicators of limited effective access to services. C. Social Assistance and Welfare Delegation is more widespread than decentralization in the provision of social assistance and welfare programs. It is agreed that subnational service delivery is useful in reducing poverty and in the provision of social safety nets, particularly when poverty indicators vary considerable within the country. Nevertheless, the role of subnational governments in the implementation of social assistance programs has been limited to the extraction of information on local needs and preferences and to administrative tasks in income certification and personnel management, among others. Subnational funding of social assistance and welfare programs is confined almost exclusively to developed countries.24 24 For example, in the United States, the state of California has traditionally provided income support transfers to low-income individuals. Outlays on health care and welfare programs account for slightly over 30 percent of the state’s general fund budget. The state also requires (continued…) 20 The effectiveness of subnational governments in providing social assistance programs depends on how efficient they are in reaching the targeted beneficiaries relative to higher levels of government. Program financing and design are known to affect the incidence of decentralized spending, as suggested above. In the case of welfare programs, particularly income transfers to households and individuals, means-testing is often difficult, particularly for the poor working in the informal sector, and categorical targeting—based on broad individual and household characteristics strongly correlated with poverty—may not be easily applicable to all social assistance programs. In general, when subnational governments play an active role in the implementation of welfare programs, financing is provided by the central government through block grants. Funds are allocated to subnational jurisdictions based primarily on poverty incidence rates, rather than on how successful these governments are at reaching the poor and at reducing poverty. Empirical evidence on the incidence of subnational social assistance programs is limited in the developing world. Ravallion (1999) analyses an poverty-alleviation program in Argentina (Trabajar II) to assess performance in reaching the poor and to measure the relative contributions to the program’s performance—before and after reforms—of the center’s counties to provide cash transfers to all indigent individuals who do not qualify for state assistance. Most social welfare programs in California are administered by local governments. State agencies set overall policies, benefit levels, and eligibility criteria, and monitor local governments (Geen and others, 1995). In Spain and Switzerland, subnational jurisdictions are free to set benefit levels and eligibility conditions for most central government-financed welfare programs. 21 provincial reallocation and decentralized targeting. Galasso and Ravallion (2000) use data on the implementation of a partially decentralized food-for-schooling program in Bangladesh. In this program, the central government decides on the intercommunity allocation of funds, while local governments focus on intracommunity assignments. They find that targeting is somewhat propoor, and local capture does not seem to be sizeable. Anecdotal evidence available for Brazil’s Bolsa-Escola program—a transfer payment granted to poor households to keep at school school-age children who might otherwise drop out of school to work—points to high incidence rates. The program, originally designed and funded by a few subnational governments, has now motivated the implementation of a federally-funded school attendancelinked income transfer program. Some subnational governments in Brazil also have their own income support programs. D. Housing and Infrastructure Subnational provision of housing and infrastructure services has been carried out predominantly through the devolution, rather than decentralization, of expenditure functions. Important deterrents to the decentralization of housing and infrastructure expenditure functions to subnational governments are the sunk costs involved in funding these programs in view of subnational governments’ more limited revenue mobilization capacity, including borrowing, and the spillovers associated with these services. These spillover effects would reduce the incentives for subnational service delivery, as in the case of social assistance and welfare programs. In fact, in many countries, government provision of housing and infrastructure services is justified as social assistance instruments and service delivery tends to be subsidized. 22 Many countries intervene in the housing market, particularly in the developing world. This is because domestic capital markets are often shallow and to ensure the provision of shelter for poor households who would not have access to long-term credit from the domestic financial system, when available. Subsidized credit is often provided by the central government, through its financial institutions, and subnational governments often participate as agents of the central government in identifying target groups (i.e., Colombia) and building housing financed through transfers from the center. Examples of subnational government-financed housing projects are limited in number. In Brazil, for example, richer states have their own housing programs, particularly in the area of slum upgrading and urbanization. The decentralization of infrastructure services has some elements in common with that of education and health care. As in education, unbundling is relatively easy in the case of infrastructure services and, as in health care, high provision costs would make programs unaffordable to most subnational governments. Financing for costly infrastructure investment is often provided through block or matching grants from higher levels of government and subnational governments become agents of the center with limited policymaking autonomy. As in education, the decentralization of infrastructure services often goes beyond the public sector, through partnerships and contracting-out arrangements with the private sector (i.e., water and transport companies). Cross-border joint ventures among subnational jurisdictions have been encouraged in many countries to maximize economies of scale and to internalize the externalities associated with the 23 provision of regional public goods. In France, for instance, small communes contract out service delivery to private regional water companies, and contiguous municipalities often create regional associations to manage services such as waste disposal. Peru attempted to decentralize much of its road network to provincial and municipal governments but then failed to provide financing for operations and maintenance (Gutman, 1999). This resulted in widespread deterioration of the network and, ultimately, recentralization (Burki, Perry, and Dillinger, 1999; Humplick and Moini-Araghi, 1996). In Brazil, the privatization of water and sanitation services has been delayed due to disagreement over the jurisdictional power of states and municipalities in the provision of these services, particularly in the case of large metropolitan areas, where the water and sanitation networks straddle local government borders. There is some empirical evidence that decentralization increases subnational spending on infrastructure projects, but the correlation between decentralization and performance indicators in the infrastructure sector is less clear-cut. The cross-country evidence reported by Estache and Sinha (1995) suggests that decentralization is associated with higher spending on infrastructure projects, particularly in the developing world. Decentralization tends to increase both total and subnational spending on infrastructure possibly because of differences in local preferences. Moreover, using cross-country data, Humplick and Estache (1995) estimate the impact of decentralization on the performance of several infrastructure projects, including roads, electricity, and water. Using different measures of decentralization in each sector, the authors find that at least one performance indicator improved in each sector under examination as a result of decentralization. Nevertheless, the correlation between decentralization and performance was not strong in general. 24 V. PENDING ISSUES AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS The choice between administrative deconcentration and full decentralization depends on incentives. Principal-agent considerations, rather than the Musgravean classical functions of government, have now become the main theoretical benchmark for the assignment of expenditure functions to subnational levels of government. Subnational governments have become important providers of public services in sectors where activities can be more easily unbundled and incentives for performance can be more effectively put in place. Education is a case in point. Decentralization tends to be more difficult in sectors with significant spillover and economies of scale effects, such as infrastructure development and social welfare. Decentralization can lead to the creation of unfunded mandates. In certain cases, expenditure functions are decentralized to subnational governments without a commensurate assignment of revenue sources.25 In other cases, greater private-sector involvement is sought in the provision of public services to eliminate unfunded mandates at the central government level but the required principal-agent structure of incentives is not in place. In this case, private-sector involvement may be deterred by lack of an adequate regulatory framework, particularly pricing regulations. The infrastructure sector is a case in point. Moreover, the quality of services may 25 In transition economies, many social services were provided by state-owned enterprises. With privatization, unfunded mandates were created and local government budgets were not adjusted for these new responsibilities, thus creating unfunded mandates or unmet local demands (Gupta and others, 2003). 25 suffer as a result of decentralization when the center fails to set minimum standards for privatesector and/or subnational providers. Again, principal-agent incentives can be strengthened through adequate enforcement and performance monitoring, as well as the choice of financing instruments, such as reliance on matching grants and conditionality on block grants based on the fulfillment of explicit, quantifiable performance objectives, among others. Open-ended, gapfilling block grants and lump-sum transfers seldom create strong incentives for costeffectiveness and efficiency in service delivery. Greater private sector involvement in service delivery, and the need to increase cost recovery through the restructuring of publicly-provided services, may prevent the poor’s access to social services. Central governments may also set minimum standards beyond the means of some subnational governments, thus raising operating costs and discouraging service delivery. Decentralization has been motivated in many cases by theoretical, rather than empirical, considerations. The measurement of efficiency gains in decentralized service delivery remains open to empirical investigation, particularly in the developing world, where decentralization programs have been more ambitious and implemented more recently. The impact of decentralization on access to, and incidence of, public programs is harder to measure. Most empirical evidence, often predominantly anecdotal, focuses on the education and social assistance sectors. A crucial question that requires careful empirical study is whether decentralization results in significant innovations in program design and management, and changes in financing arrangements. 26 Vested interests may be a deterrent to decentralization. For decentralization to be successful, there must be willingness on the part of central government to share power and on the part of local governments and communities to assume new responsibilities. In many countries, civil servants have objected to decentralization efforts for fear of status loss when decentralization involves a transfer of personnel from the center to subnational governments. Fear of loss of benefits, including pensions and a variety of nonpecuniary entitlements, has deterred decentralization programs in many countries. Central government officials may also be reluctant to transfer functions to subnational governments for fear of loss of control and political prestige. A precondition for successful decentralization is good governance at the implementing level. There is some evidence in the literature that decentralization is correlated with corruption (Pritchett and Kaufmann, 1998; Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobatón, 1999; de Mello and Barenstein, 2002). Although decentralization tends to expand the volume of the service delivered, greater subnational spending on social programs does not generate efficiency gains when accompanied by overprovision of public service to local elites (Bardhan and Mookherjee, 2000). Table 1: Summary of Subnational Expenditure Functions Health Care Traditional assignment Primary schooling Preventive care Conventional financing General taxation, input-based block grants, equalization grants Output-orientation, rewards for extended coverage, penalties for poor performance; user charges apply in certain cases General taxation, input-based block grants, capitation, equalization grants Output-orientation, rewards for extended coverage; user charges apply in certain cases Universal in most countries for primary education; user charges apply in certain cases; access depends on coverage of service provision network; enrollment rates vary across and within countries. Rates vary by type of program (typically higher for primary education); limited empirical evidence, particularly at subnational level Universal in most countries for preventive care (basic health package in some cases); access depends on coverage of service provision network Increasing over time for personnel management and local curriculum development. Emphasis on school-level and community-based management. Increasing for personnel management and administration. Increased diversity in financing options and private-sector involvement. New financing options Access to services Incidence of public spending 1/ Subnational policymaking autonomy Rates vary by type of program (typically higher for preventive care); limited empirical evidence, particularly at subnational level 1/ Defined as the share of public spending reaching the intended beneficiary. Social Assistance and Welfare Only as agents of central government Block grants Infrastructure … Market-orientation; concession and privatization; user charges and price subsidies apply in many cases (i.e., urban transportation) Access varies according to type of service; access depends on coverage of service provision network Increased use of categorical and regional targeting in certain cases; access depends on coverage of service provision network; enrollment rates vary across programs. Rates vary by type of program; middle class capture in poverty alleviation programs; limited empirical evidence, particularly at subnational level Delegation rather than decentralization. Subnational-financed programs are more common in industrial countries. Mainly as agents of higher levels of government Block and matching grants Rates vary by type of program (typically higher for sanitation services) Delegation rather than decentralization. Central government subsidization combined with subnational service delivery is more common in the developing world. Limited intervention in the housing market in industrial countries. - 27 - Education - 28 - Table 1: Decentralization Indicators, 1980-97 (period averages, in percent) 1/ Number of Size Fiscal decentralization 2/ Subnational Tax Nontax Vertical Subnational autonomy autonomy imbalances spending in percent spending in percent of GDP of total gov. spending Countries Africa 42.7 26.1 31.4 2.1 7.6 14 Asia 34.6 23.1 39.5 3.4 13.8 9 Latin America and Caribbean 49.5 23.8 28.4 3.3 14.7 16 ... ... 30.5 1.0 1.5 2 OECD 3/ 41.3 18.0 40.4 14.7 30.8 24 Transition economies 53.5 11.0 34.7 9.6 30.3 17 Large federations 4/ 48.9 19.2 32.0 13.5 36.5 13 World 45.0 19.5 35.1 7.7 21.2 82 Middle East Sources: Government Finance Statistics, IMF. 1/ Unweighted averages. 2/ Tax (nontax) autonomy is defined as the share of subnational tax (nontax) revenues in total government revenues. Nontax revenues include primarily royalties, fees, penalties, and user charges. Vertical imbalances are defined as the share of grants and transfers from higher levels of government in total subnational revenues. 3/ Includes Israel. 4/ Comprises India, Malaysia, Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Germany, Spain, Switzerland, and United States. - 29 - Table 2. Selected Social Spending by Government Level, 1970-2000. (In percent of total government spending by government level, period averages) Education Social Spending Health Social Security Care and Welfare Housing Sample Size All countries Cental government Middle-tier governments Local governments 13.5 28.7 22.0 8.7 15.3 12.2 19.6 12.9 9.6 4.6 3.3 14.0 108 15 44 Federations 1/ Cental government Middle-tier governments Local governments 7.3 25.4 20.9 7.4 18.0 8.0 33.7 10.2 8.4 1.9 3.3 12.2 13 8 7 Latin America and Caribbean Cental government Middle-tier governments Local governments 25.8 36.3 16.7 16.6 14.0 8.2 21.7 4.8 2.6 13.7 3.7 8.9 20 3 4 OECD 2/ Cental government Middle-tier governments Local governments 8.3 25.5 18.7 9.0 19.3 10.8 34.1 12.6 14.8 2.4 2.8 12.3 23 7 14 Source: Government Finance Statistics; and IMF staff calculations. 1/ Based on the classification of federal states available from Elazar (1995). 2/ Excludes the new members admitted in the 1990s. - 30 - Table 3: Decentralization and Benefit Incidence of Public Spending. Percent share of public spending accruing to: 1/ Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 Decentralization indicator 2/ Year of incidence data Health care Chile Colombia Indonesia Romania 32.0 27.4 11.5 12.2 26.0 25.6 16.1 14.8 21.0 18.7 19.3 20.2 15.0 15.9 24.4 24.3 6.0 12.5 28.7 28.6 0.02 0.22 0.26 9.59 1992 1992 1990 1994 1.82 0.20 0.78 0.51 2.09 1993 1990 1992 1992 1991 1.82 0.20 0.78 0.51 2.09 1993 1990 1992 1989 1994 Primary education Argentina Chile Colombia Guyana Pakistan 37.0 35.7 39.4 28.9 19.3 23.2 26.9 26.2 24.9 22.7 15.4 18.1 19.4 18.5 21.9 15.0 12.6 10.8 19.0 21.2 9.4 6.7 4.3 8.6 14.9 Secondary education Argentina Chile Colombia Indonesia Romania 22.0 23.5 20.6 5.4 18.3 20.8 24.1 26.8 10.6 21.7 21.4 21.0 25.3 16.5 21.7 21.4 18.1 17.7 25.5 20.7 14.5 13.3 9.6 42.0 17.6 Source: GFS and Davoodi, Sachjapinan, and Kim (2001); and IMF staff calculations. 1/ Refers to income quintiles, where Q1 denotes the lowest (poorest) quintile. 2/ Ratio of average local and/or middle-tier government spending to average central government spending by sector between 1970 and 1985. - 31 - References Afonso, J.R., and de Mello, L., 2002, “Brazil: An Evolving Federation,” in V. Tanzi and E. Ahmad Managing Fiscal Decentralization (New York: Routledge). Baldacci, E., Guin-Siu, M.T., and de Mello, L., 2003, “More on the effectiveness of Public Spending on Health Care and Education: A Covariance Structure Model,” Journal of International Development, Vol. 15, pp. 1-17. Bardhan, P., and Mookherjee, D., 2000, “Corruption and Decentralization of Infrastructure Delivery in Developing Countries,” Institute for Economic Development Discussion Paper No. 104 (Boston: Boston University). Bray, M., 1996, Decentralization of Education: Community Financing (Washington, DC: World Bank). Bossert T.J., 1998, “Analyzing the Decentralization of Health Systems in Developing Countries: Decision Space, Innovation and Performance,” Social Science and Medicine. Bossert, T.J., 2000, Decentralization of Health Systems in Latin America: A Comparative Study of Chile, Colombia, and Bolivia (Boston: Harvard School of Public Health). Burki, S.J., Perry, G.E., and Dillinger, W.R., 1999, “Beyond the Center: Decentralizing the State, World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies, (Washington, DC: World Bank). Dalin, P. and others, 1994, How Schools Improve: An International Report (New York, NY: Cassell). Davoodi, H.R., Sachjapinan, S., and Kim, J., 2001, “How Useful are benefit Incidence Studies?,” World Bank, unpublished manuscript. de Mello, L., 2001, “Social Spending in Brazil: Education and Health Care,” in Brazil: Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix, Country Report No. 01/10 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). de Mello, L., and Barenstein, M., 2002, “Fiscal Decentralization and Governance: A CrossCountry Analysis,” in G. Abed and S. Gupta Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). de Mello, L., 2004, “Can Fiscal Decentralization Strengthen Social Capital?,” Public Finance Review, Vol. Vol. 32, pp. 4-35. - 32 - ECLAC, 1998, La Descentralización de la Educación y la Salud. Un Análisis Comparativo de la Experiencia Latinoamericana (Santiago de Chile: ECLAC). Elazar, Daniel J., 1995, “From Statism to Federalism: A Paradigm Shift,” Publius, Vol. 25, pp. 5–18. Estache, A., and Sinha, S., 1995, “Does Decentralization Increase Spending on Public Infrastructure?,” (Washington, DC: World Bank). Galasso, Emanuela and Martin Ravallion, 2000, “Distributional Outcomes of a Decentralized Welfare Program,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2316 (Washington: World Bank). Geen, R. and others, 1995. “Income Support and Social Services for Low-Income People in California,” (Washington, DC: World Bank Institute). Gilson L., 1997, “The lessons of user fee experience in Africa,” Health Policy and Planning, Vol. 12 , pp. 273-85. Gupta, S., Leruth, L., de Mello, L., and Chakravarti, S., 2003, “The Size and Scope of Government in Transition Economies,” Comparative Economic Studies, Vol. 45, pp. 55476. Gutman, J., 1999, “Decentralizing Roads: Matching Accountability, Resources, and Technical Expertise”, in Burki, S.J., Perry, G., and Dillinger, W., Beyond the Center: Decentralizing the State, Latin American and Caribbean Studies, Viewpoints No. 19636 (Washington, DC: World Bank). Humplick, F., and Moini-Araghi, A., 1996, “Decentralized Structures for Providing Roads: A Cross-Country Comparison.” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1658, (Washington, DC: World Bank). Humplick, F., and Estache, A., 1995, “Does Decentralization Improve Infrastructure Performance?” in Antonio Estache, ed., Decentralizing Infrastructure: Advantages and Limitations, World Bank Discussion Paper Series, No. 290 (Washington: World Bank). Hurst, J., and Jee-Hughes, M., 2000, “Performance Measurement and Performance Management in OECD Health Systems,” Labor Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers No. 47, (Paris: OECD). Juárez, G.M., 1999, “Decentralization of Education and Institutional Change: A Look at Mexico,” Harvard University, unpublished manuscript. Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobatón, 1999, “Governance Matters,” World Bank Discussion Paper Series No. 2196 (Washington: World Bank). - 33 - Kolehmainen-Aitken, R. 1998. “Decentralization and Human Resources: Implications and Impact,” Human Resources for Health Development Journal, Vol. 2, pp. 1-17. Litvack, J., and Seddon, J. (eds.), 1999, “Decentralization Briefing Notes,” World Bank Institute. McLure, C.E, and Martinez-Vazquez, J., 2000, “Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations and Local Financial Management,” (Washington, DC: World Bank). OECD, 2003, OECD Economic Outlook No. 74 (Paris: OECD). Paes de Barros, R., Mendonça, R., and Soares, M., 1998, “Uma Avaliação do Impacto do Programa Curumim Sobre o Desempenho Escolar,” Discussion Paper No. 542, February 1998, IPEA, Ministry of Planning and Budget, Brazil. Parente, M.M.A., and H. Lück, 1999, “Mapeamento da Descentralização da Educação Brasileira nas Redes Estaduais do Ensino Fundamental”, Discussion Paper No. 675, October, 1999, IPEA, Ministry of Planning and Budget, Brazil. Parry, T.R., 1997, “Achieving Balance in Decentralization: A Case Study of Education Decentralization in Chile,” World Development, Vol. 25, pp. 211-225. Pritchett, Lant, and Daniel Kaufmann, 1998, “Civil Liberties, Democracy, and the Performance of Government Projects,” Finance and Development, Vol. 35 (March), pp. 26–29. Ranade, W. (ed), 1998. Markets and Health Care: A Comparative Analysis (London/New York: Longman). Ravallion, M., 1999, “Monitoring Targeting Performance When Decentralized Allocations to the Poor Are Unobserved,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 2080 (Washington, DC: World Bank). Ribeiro, J.M., and N.R. Costa, 1999, “Consórcios Municipais no SUS”, Discussion Paper No. 669, September, 1999, IPEA, Ministry of Planning and Budget, Brazil. Robalino, D.A, Picazo, O.F., and Voetberg, A., 2001, “Does Fiscal Decentralization Improve Health Outcomes? Evidence from a Cross-Country Analysis,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 2565 (Washington, DC: World Bank). Rondeau, J.-C., 1997, “The Decentralization of the Decision Power in the School Systems,” Télescope, Vol. 4. Ter-Minassian, T., 1997, Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice (Washington: International Monetary Fund). - 34 - Tracy, M., 1996, “To transfer power or to transfer responsibility: educational decentralization in Venezuela,” International Journal of Education Development, Vol. 17, pp. 145-162. Wildasin, D., 1998, Fiscal Aspects of Evolving Federations: Issues for Policy and Research, Vanderbilt University, mimeo.