The Interpretation of Trust in Empirical Research Two examples: trust in ethnic and social conflicts in Eastern and Central Europe Mária Székelyi - Antal Örkény - Ildikó Barna1 For the sociologist, the radical social change which took place in Central and Eastern European countries in the last ten years sharply raises the question what mental consequences the structural and ideological changes after 1989 had on everyday thinking and whether the patterns of values and behavior, attitudes and cultural conventions required by altered social relations have developed. This analysis focuses on the issue of the trust principle. The aim of this study is to illustrate, on some possible examples, how the phenomenon of trust in society can be operationalized and analyzed by the means of empirical sociology. Spheres of Interpretations for Trust Trust is understood as a social (socialpsychological) mechanism, which can influence our social behavior significantly and can serve as a psychic link between our motives, beliefs and the goal to be achieved. The counterpart of trust is the psychological status of distrust, which detaches and questions the reciprocal relationship between the individual and the society (or simply, others) and undermines the actor’s belief in the meaning and success of his or her actions. Instead of further definition we accept as a work hypothesis Barbara Misztral’s interpretation, which defines three spheres within the phenomenon of trust: a) Firstly, trust is a common good (and social value) which ensures the cohesion of society and is a prerequisite for community existence based on reciprocality. Such an interpretation of trust carries ideological connotations and is an essential element of idealized community status as a moral principle: “civic community as marked by a social fabric of trust and cooperation and reliant upon the activities of the public spirited citizenry” (Tocqueville, 1968). In this interpretation the principle of trust is theoretically related to the notion of social order. This tradition can be discerned in Toennies’ works, for whom trust, like respect and belonging, is a virtue which penetrates the personal and familiar nature of traditional (Gemeinschaft) communities, compared to the impersonalized and formalized trust relation within Gesellschaft societies. A counterexample is Durkheim’s theory, which states that it is the very characteristic of modern societies that society run by a moral order, which derives from individual interests and which is able to integrate society on the basis of personal commitment to collective standards and rules. This order assumes 1 Paper prepared for the workshop on "Trust and Honesty", Collegium Budapest, 25-26 May, 2001. 2 cooperation between the members of society at all levels which certainly requires regularity across institutions and customs, predictability, order and trustworthiness. b) Secondly, trust is an important building block of collective behavior as well as the operation of social organizations and institutions. “For Weber, one of the preconditions for the success of modern capitalism was the transition from personal trust to impersonal trust. It is exemplified in the abstract and universal trust of the Puritan entrepreneurs, who were loyal to their calling, without considering what benefits it would secure for them… This mutual trustworthiness was their social capital, which benefited the group and in the longer run established the framework underlying capitalist relationships.” (Misztral, 1996:55) The Weberian objective- and value-rational behavior relies on the existence of trust, deriving from individual and collective interests and can have an important role in various types of legitimation of relations and institutions. In contrast with manifestations of trust permeting traditional and charismatic social relations and thus basically deriving from irrational considerations, trust working in capitalism essentially relies on rational considerations, permeates both objective- and value-rational behavior, assumes the mutuality of obligations and relations, and strengthens the reciprocity-based nature of relations. Apparently, the increasing bureaucratization of modern society and the widening of its formal rational operation could mean that the subjective, affective resources of relations, including trust, lose ground. Weber emphasized, however, that simultaneously or, in fact, complementing and supporting this process, “the mutual agreement gradually establishes itself as an order based on a belief in its legitimacy. Consequently, this belief in the binding power of the rule or trust in the validity of the rule becomes routinized as a universal trust in the principle of the legal-rational bases of associative relationship.” (Misztral, 1996:59). An example of a different interpretation of instrumental trust is Talcott Parsons’ theory. Parsons interpreted the problem of trust as an integrative mechanism for the social system. The stability of the social system is seen as a result from conceptualizing role sets in terms of inherent reciprocity and tendencies toward equilibrium. Trust is an instrumental mechanism of the social system, an essential source of social integration, and an attitudinal base for individual and institutional solidaristic relations which interweave this system. “As an aspect of actors’ value-orientations which commits them to norms of reciprocity and complementarity, trust also plays an integrative role. An integrated system is thus a system in which actors are trustworthy in the performance of their role, which in turn contributes to the stability and orderliness of the system. They are trustworthy because of the solidarity of their collectivity, which imposes discipline upon them but also helps them to ‘live up to these kind of expectations’ and cope with the uncertainty of less clear situations.” (Parsons, 1951:193) The most important areas within the instrumental form of trust are the prominent institutions of social integration, i.e., trust and distrust manifesting in the operation of the political system, trust existing or absent in law, in rule of law and in respect for law, trust/distrust underlying economic (market) exchange relations and trust or distrust toward state institutions and roles (police, army, state administration, welfare systems). Moreover, trust runs the solidaristic organizations and institutions of this system, finally, the principle of trust interweaves the venues of collective identity as well as the various mechanisms of socialization. c) Thirdly, trust can be also interpreted as an individual personality trait and a psychological device which provides safety for people in their interactions with others (people or institutions), increasing the predictability of their actions. This 3 approach explains the notion of trust from the aspect of individual behavior, and considers individuals’ manifestations of trust to be an important element of futureoriented micro-level social decisions. Micro-level personal trust is closely related to the person’s motives, the maximum realization of personal objectives and interests, the maximum concentration of existing – material and psychological – resources and the demand that the individual’s expectations and the behavior of other people should meet in the course of cooperation with others. The interpretation of personal trust is closely related to the patterns of social behavior described by utilitarianism, rational choice and game theory, and particularly to the reduction of the risk factor which always underlies interactions and exchange relations. “Rational individuals place trust only, when both potential gains are bigger than potential losses and trust relations are supported by negative sanctions.” (Misztral, 1996:78) It is the trust element of exchange relations, which offsets the constrained nature of formal and legal sanctions. On the other hand, if the rational calculation of goal achievement is not able to reduce the role of risk factors to the minimum, or the rational actor sees factors of uncertainty which exceed the aspects of rational action, trust can be a psychological resource which not only expands the pool of resources for the actor but also poses moral obligations for his partner. However, personal trust can also be mutual, when it works as social capital, which ensures the regulation and predictability of relations (Coleman, 1990). Finally, what we call self-confidence is a specific manifestation of personal trust. In this case trust is directed toward ourselves, strengthening and confirming other resources used in achieving our goals and works as an important drive for success and self-realization. The three different interpretations correspond to the macro-, mezzo- and micro-level manifestations of distrust, or, to put it in another way, to the normative, instrumental and personal levels of trust. For empirical research, the three above-mentioned levels above can be grasped with different approaches and models. a) The first level models mainly the general trust potential of systems, which is closely related to the question of legitimacy and macro-level value-choices. In Central and Eastern European a lot of researches have been being carried out since the 1990s to measure and examine the level of social trust toward institutions which are most characteristic of public choices, policy making, the value system, the value choices and the existing structure. b) As to the second level the scope of empirical surveys is much more limited. Two areas are worth mentioning as examples: on the one hand, all analyses which aim to explore behaviors with respect to the institutionalization of social norms (normconforming or norm-breaking) and the trust or distrust which manifests in such behaviors; on the other hand, surveys which see the occurrence of trust and distrust in relation to social solidarity. An example of the first area can be some research projects related to respect for and conformity to law, or, indirectly, researches on the black and gray economies, the question of corruption, gratuity, etc. c) We have the least empirical sources on the personal manifestation of trust. Maybe we can rely most on network researches in this area, or socialsychological experiments which aim to explore the social micro-world can be also put into this category. Trust plays an important role in the routine-like functioning of social contacts and relations, making interactions and social institutions predictable. This is true when the 4 principle of trust manifests under consolidated social circumstances. In this aspect the routine-like operation of everyday relations or institutions seems to be the best venue for analysis. Trust can have a particularly great role under circumstances when social change reaches a critical mass, and the risks (or haphazard events) caused by these changes make the situation of either the individual or society unpredictable. Regime changes in Central and Eastern Europe provide a good field for analysis from this aspect: on the one hand, a hypotheses testing the prevalence of the trust principle in altered interpersonal or social relations can be created; on the other hand, trust can be analyzed in light of the role it had in reducing the risk factors and distrust brought about by the radical transformations. There is a third aspect, however, which should be noted when observing the prevalence of trust in Central and Eastern Europe. If trust is defined as a kind of individual or collective resource or social capital, it can have an important role in alleviating the scarcity of resources, which manifests in social, political and economic relations. This scarcity of resources was particularly characteristic of the economic, political and social changes which took place after 1989, therefore it may be worth analyzing the prevalence (or, on the contrary, the absence) of trust in the light of this fact. Two Examples Below we are going to illustrate with the examples of two empirical analyses how trust or distrust interweaves social changes which occurred in this region and the resulting new social relations. The two examples share the property that originally the researches did not focus on the examination of the trust/distrust phenomenon. However, rethinking the research design gives an opportunity to define and operationalize the phenomenon of trust in a different context, and construct, in both contexts, explanatory models reflecting the complex nature of the manifestation of trust. 1. Ethno-Trust Our first example analyzes the reciprocal relation and conflict between ethnic and political trust in an ethnically mixed environment. The survey took place in Transylvania, where tensions within the functioning of collective trust are observed in the relation between majority Romanians and minority Hungarians. Under the title “Carpathian Project” an empirical sociological research was carried out between 1997 and 1998 in order to explore the relationships between ethnic minorities living in the Carpathian Basin and the majority groups of the given countries. The prime dimension of the researches had been the conflict potential which exists between majority and minority groups in each country. Besides the standard socio-demographic measures, dimensions serving as explanations for conflict potential were auto- and hetero-stereotypes, ethnocentrism, national identity, prospects and the perception of social distance. The description of research dimensions shows that the survey did not focus directly on measuring and explaining trust. It can be assumed, however, that distrust deriving from ethnic differences is a source of ethnic conflict. In the model to be described next we are going to attempt to explain the development of mezzo-level trust and distrust on the basis of general trust in institutions, ethnocentrism 5 which is assigned to ethnicity, social distance from groups embodying ethnic dissimilarity and the perception of anomie reflecting the ‘mental status’ of the country. Numerous empirical studies justified that the lack of fulfillment for heightened expectations resulted in radical loss of trust in political and social institutions in the Central and Eastern European countries which went through regime change. In contrast, ethnic divideness may result that the general trend of losing trust is broken by trust in the institutions representing the interests of one’s own ethnic group. We wish to make the picture of general political trust loss more detailed by describing the factors underlying institutional trust which can be characterized with contradictory trends,. In this model we also try to operationalize trust/distrust manifesting in different venues of society.2 This example is limited to one country or region of the original Carpathian Project survey, namely, to Transylvania.3 The dimensions of the model are: a) Spheres of trust Trust in institutions. Respondents were asked to judge the effects of various politicians and organizations on the conflict between Romanians and Hungarians. It is considered a sign of general loss of trust if the respondent said that each or most of the five offered Hungarian or Romanian agents induced the ethnic conflict. We should ask, however, whether the loss of trust is symmetrical in the ethnic dimensions, i.e., Hungarians and Romanians can be characterized with equal loss of trust when they speak about the political agents which can be assigned to either their own or to the other ethnic group. Micro-level trust capital. Using the standard method in network research, it was measured in three different ‘life situations’ how many people the respondent could rely on. One situation enumerated acquaintances and friends who could be asked to have an eye on their flat temporarily left empty, the second enumerated those who could be asked to lend money in need, finally, the third one enumerated those whose advice and influential participation to help in difficulties the respondent could count on. Trust in ethnic groups. This aspect was measured in two dimensions. One of them was limited to the relationship between Romanians and Hungarians, including ethnocentrism (increased trust in one’s own group and increased distrust in the other group). The other dimension represents social distance perceived from the other ethnic groups living in Transylvania. Macro-level trust. In this dimension three questions were used to create an aggregate variable, which indicates judgment on the anomic status of society. These questions tested people’s trust in the rule of law and impartial justice. Political trust. This dimension is applicable to Hungarians only since the relevant questions were asked from them only. In this dimension it should be noted that (1) the political priorities of the respondents’ personal and the most important political organization of Hungarians in Romania (RMDSZ) are mirror images to each other, and (2) political trust in RMDSZ is of a very high degree, although the order of its political objectives diverts from that of people whom it aims to represent. This attempt is necessarily constrained, since for micro-level trust, trust capital embodied in the personal network will be measured with network size. Macro-level trust will be grasped through the perception of anomie. 3 The sample consisted 717 Romanians and 1090 Hungarians living in Transylvania. 2 6 b) Dimensions of personal life situation ethnic group membership local majority or minority position age settlement type of habitation social status satisfaction/frustration In the first step we sought the answer to the question whether Hungarians and Romanians living in Transylvania constitute groups in similar ways if the concept of grouping is trust in agents who are committed to represent one’s own or the other ethnicity. The answer was given through cluster analysis. Table 1: Trust in agents representing one’s own or the other group (cluster centers and cluster size) Distrust in the other group Distrust in one’s own group Proportion of clusters, percent General distrust 3.66 3.17 2.6 Asymmetrical 3.30 0.40 60.1 Hungarians Self-accusing 1.79 2.57 1.3 General trust 0.59 0.01 36.1 Total 2.31 0.36 100.0 General distrust 4.44 3.48 11.4 Asymmetrical 4.16 1.31 24.6 Romanians Self-accusing 0.98 2.78 7.5 General trust 0.03 0.03 56.5 Total 1.62 0.94 100.0 The first group is characterized by general distrust, since respondents included in this group have no trust in more than three of the 5 agents offered for each group, which also have a significant role in ethnic policy-making.4 Members of the fourth group, characterized by general trust, represent the counterpoint to the first group. It is characteristic of the second group, which received the label ‘asymmetrical’, that they have trust in agents representing their own ethnic group, while they have no trust in the agents of the other ethnic group. A counterpoint to this group can be found in the group of the ‘self-accusing’, who show stronger trust in agents of the other ethnic group than in their own representatives. Cluster centers in the above table also show that significant differences can be found between Hungarian and Romanian group-means of distrust, although the four groups were formed among Hungarians and Romanians along a similar logic. Generally, it is true that Hungarians tend to have more distrust (2.31) than Romanians (1.62) if they are asked about agents of the other group, while Romanians are more self-critical toward the 4 Again, it should be emphasized that basically the survey aimed to explore ethnic relations. Consequently, testing was performed on political actors (agents) who have a decisive role in political public life in general as well as in an ethnic aspect. 7 representatives of their own group (.94). Therefore Hungarians living in minority tend to be asymmetrical, while Romanians living in majority tend to be self-critical in their judgments. It seems that the dimension of trust/distrust is less deformed by the ethnic motive for Romanians, while trust feeds on ethnic identity for Hungarians. It is also supported by the fact that 60 percent of Hungarians fall into the asymmetrical group, while self-critical people can be hardly found among them. In contrast, most Romanians (57 percent) are permeated by general trust (in both Romanian and Hungarian agents), and the proportion of the self-accusing (8 percent) cannot be disregarded either. The strength of general trust and distrust organized on an ethnic base is related in different ways for Romanians and Hungarians, therefore the explanatory models below, which aim to explore sources of trust, should be formed separately for the majority and minority groups. Romanians The table below shows the marked groups found within Romanians in Transylvania when the frame of reference is specified as trust in agents committed to represent one’s own ethnic group and trust in agents representing the other ethnic group. Table 2: Clusters drawn along institutional trust in one’s own and the other group among Romanians (cluster centers and cluster size) Distrust in the other group Distrust in one’s own group Cluster size, percent General trust 0.03 0.03 56.5 Self-accusing 1.25 2.66 9.3 General distrust 4.35 1.99 34.2 Total 1.62 0.94 100.0 It is clear that with this technique we come to the well-known picture: the majority of Romanians tend to have trust in institutions, while the proportion of those who tend to have general distrust toward political institutions cannot be disregarded (nearly onethird). In this analysis we also sought the answer to the question what fuels trust or distrust among Romanians in Transylvania and what makes them turn self-critically toward the political representatives of their own group. The method used to seek answers was discriminant analysis.5 Trust in institutions, tinted with ethnic motives, is explained through a combination of variables, one of which grasps sentiments and the other describes social status. Ethnocentrism had the greatest weight on the discriminant function expressing sentiments, followed by social distance perceived from other ethnic groups living in Transylvania, finally, a dissatisfaction indicator for general frustration also appeared here. 5 Like factor analysis, this procedure creates aggregate variables which compress explanatory variables in discriminant functions (aggregate indicators) on the basis of the best estimation of which groups the respondents should belong to. 8 Table 3: Structure of the discriminant function aggregating the sentiments of Romanian respondents, structure matrix Function Ethnocentrism .860 Social distance .463 Satisfaction –.315 Naturally, the high values of this function demonstrate a sentiment full of ethnocentrism, dejecting dissimilarity and dissatisfaction with life in general characterizing respondents who have no trust in political institutions. People who are free from these sentiments, which we can justifiably call negative sentiments, have increased general trust; however, this can lead to self-accusation in extreme cases. This model serves as a pragmatic political moral: if political forces in an ethnically divided society make efforts to strengthen ethnocentric sentiments and the rejection of dissimilarity in certain groups, they have to consider that general trust in institutions may lose ground. Table 4: Means of the sentiment-aggregating discriminant function in Romanian groups representing different degrees of trust Function General trust –.141 Self-accusing –.590 General distrust .379 However, the degree of trust may be influenced by not only sentiments but also objective social position, which was aggregated from social status, age and the settlement type of habitation, again, by discriminant analysis. Table 5: Structure of the discriminant function aggregating the social position of Romanian respondents, structure matrix Function Local majority position .603 Social status .438 Age Settlement type (+ village) –.402 .296 According to the model, the prime determinant of social position is whether Romanians live in local majority or minority. Social status and age also have great weight on the function. The settlement type of habitation has a lesser role. Therefore the discriminant function represents a scale whose positive extreme shows Romanians who live in a settlement with Romanian majority, have high social status, are young and tend to live in an urban milieu. 9 Table 6: Means of the discriminant function aggregating social position in Romanian groups representing different degrees of trust Function General trust .000 Self-accusing –.397 General distrust .237 The table shows well that, while sentiments had a significant role in the development of general trust, social position does not specify the existence of trust: among respondents who tend to have general trust we can found people from any segment of the social space. However, the group that shows general distrust can be definitely characterized with young respondents who have high status and live in cities with Romanian majority. The latter group has a counterpoint in the self-accusing, who have more trust in the Hungarian than the Romanian agents, which can be significantly attributed to their local minority position. Finally, we seek the answer to the question whether sentiments or social position has a stronger effect on the degree of trust. Again, the answer can be sought through discriminant analysis by embedding the discriminant functions, which aggregate sentiments and social position into this new model. Table 7: Structure of the secondary discriminant function for sentiments and social position among Romanian respondents, structure matrix Function .793 .529 Dissatisfied, ethnocentric, great social distance Local majority position, high status, younger, living in a village The positive extreme of the secondary discriminant function represents urban youth with high social status and who see relations from the safety of local majority full of hostile sentiments, while the negative extreme represents contrary features. It should be noted that sentiments have a greater weight on this function than social position, i.e., sentiments have a stronger effect on degrees of trust than social position. Table 8: Means of the secondary discriminant function in Romanian groups representing different degrees of trust Function General trust –.177 Self-accusing –.767 General distrust .427 Through the secondary discriminant function we can give a real profile to spheres of trust: the group which tends to have general distrust can be characterized with hostile sentiments and, unfortunately, high social status, local majority position, and relatively young age. The counterpoint to this group is not the group blessed with general trust but the group which sees its own political system self-critically. The profile of respondents with general trust is not very marked, due to the fact that people from every social level 10 can be found in this group. The rejection of negative sentiments, however, is more markedly present in this group. Hungarians Trust interwoven with ethnic motives works in an entirely different way among Hungarians living in a global minority position than seen among Romanians who belong to the majority society. It is proven by cluster analysis, through which we sought groups with different degrees of trust among Hungarians in Transylvania. Table 9: Clusters drawn along institutional trust in one’s own and the other group among Hungarians (cluster centers and cluster size) Distrust in the other group Distrust in one’s own group Cluster size, percent Asymmetry 3.11 0.26 66.1 General trust 0.09 0.03 26.9 General distrust 3.24 2.53 7.1 2.31 0.36 100.0 The most populous group is that of people who have asymmetrical trust, i.e., they have almost the maximum trust in Hungarian agents, while they have absolutely no trust in Romanian agents. A group with general trust can be also found among Hungarians, although their proportion is somewhat smaller than among Romanians. The proportion of the group, which shows general distrust, is small like among Romanians The variables of the discriminant analysis, which aggregates Hungarian sentiments, differ from the former Romanian model. Satisfaction and social distance perceived from other ethnic groups living in Transylvania did not fit on any of the discriminant functions and therefore were omitted from the model. In contrast, national identity had a significant role. Hungarians in Transylvania got into the diaspora-position. Partly because of this fact they live in the dual grip of national identity, and are forced to experience the conflicts between culture- and state-national identity every single day, since they are Romanian citizens and belong to the Hungarian ethnicity at the same time. 6 If respondents think in the state-national dimension, they exclude themselves from the ‘body’ of the Hungarian nation; if they follow principles of the cultural nation, they question their status in Romania. The variable, which compares the respondent’s political priorities with RMDSZ objectives, is also an important building block of the discriminant functions. It can be considered a general tendency that Hungarians in Transylvania think that the most important objectives of RMDSZ are the expansion of education in the Hungarian mother tongue, and achieving cultural and territorial autonomy, although the objectives which they set for themselves are reducing inflation, eliminating unemployment, improving living standards and weakening corruption. Within this general tendency there 6 National identity was operationalized in 9 questions. Factor analysis showed two latent dimensions underlying these questions. One of them was culture-national identity, defined by self-definition, love of Hungarian culture, Hungarian mother tongue, membership of a church with Hungarian liturgical language, descent and respect for the Hungarian flag; the other one was state-national identity, determined by citizenship, birthplace and habitation. 11 are groups, however, which see RMDSZ objectives to be closer to their own priorities, while others perceive a greater distance from them. This distance, perceived between one’s own political priority and that of RMDSZ, was built into discriminant analysis as one of the explanatory variables. (Note: Positive judgment on the actions of RMDSZ within the Romanian government and its effect on the position of Hungarians in Romania was so unanimous that the model dropped these two variables.) Finally, principal component, which aggregated negative stereotypes about Romanians, was also included in the model. Table 10: Structure of the discriminant functions aggregating the sentiments of Hungarian respondents, structure matrix Function 1 Function 2 Support of RMDSZ objectives .188 .519 Ethnocentrism .662 –.016 Culture-national identity .489 .337 –.181 .450 .208 –.690 State-national identity Negative stereotypes about Romanians The first function of discriminant analysis drew a ‘separatist’ axis whose positive extreme represents ethnocentrism, the exclusiveness of culture-national identity, contempt of Romanians and moderate acceptance for the political objectives of RMDSZ, which had an active role in the Romanian government when interviews were made. The second discriminant function shows an ethnically cooperative view: its positive extreme represents the rejection of negative stereotypes about Romanians, a structure of dual national identity and aloofness toward RMDSZ objectives, which is accompanied by a slight rejection of ethnocentrism. Table 11: Means of discriminant functions aggregating sentiments in Hungarian groups representing different degrees of trust Function 1 Function 2 Asymmetry .151 .000 General trust –.406 .243 General distrust –.435 –.553 Separatism is characteristic of respondents with asymmetrical trust capital who trust Hungarians only and have no trust in Romanians. They see themselves to be superior to Romanians, and are in fact able to force back their material difficulties, which certainly became more severe with the regime change. This group is more or less identifying itself with the objectives of RMDSZ, which are rich in ideological motives. Ethnic cooperation is the coexistence strategy of people blessed with general trust. On the other hand the small group which can be characterized with general distrust does not find source of strengthening trust in either ethnic separatism or the strategy based on ethnic cooperation. 12 The constituents of the discriminant function, which aggregates social position, are the same as variables found in the explanatory model for Romanians. Table 12: Structure of the discriminant function aggregating the social position of Hungarian respondents, structure matrix Function Social status .974 Settlement type (+ village) –.468 Local majority position –.191 Age –.062 The discriminant function embodies a scale whose positive extreme represents citydwellers who have high social status, most of them living in local minority position. The role of age on the discriminant function is not too significant – the positive extreme represents respondent who are slightly younger than the average. Table 13: Means of the discriminant factor aggregating social position in Hungarian groups representing different degrees of trust Function Asymmetry .000 General trust –.210 General distrust .422 Only groups showing general distrust and general trust can be characterized with a profile, which is marked with respect to social position. The entire spectrum of the social space can be found in the most populous group showing asymmetrical trust. People who have low social status and live in villages with Hungarian majority support general trust, while respondents with high status, mostly living in cities with local minority show general distrust. Testing the effect of functions aggregating sentiments and social position on trust, it can be found that, unlike Romanians, social position has an insignificant role for Hungarians. Table 14: Structure of the secondary discriminant function for sentiments and social position among Hungarian respondents, structure matrix Function 1 Function 2 Ethnic separatism .996 .002 Ethnic cooperation –.039 .973 High status, minority position, city-dweller –.284 –.368 With the combination of sentiments and social position one of the discriminant functions draws the separatist axis, while the other draws the cooperative axis, and both of them are complemented with low social status and majority position of relatively little weight. Accordingly, the differences in dispersion of the secondary discriminant 13 functions among groups representing different degrees of trust are very similar to what we had when aggregating sentiments. Table 15: Means of the secondary discriminant function in Hungarian groups representing different degrees of trust Function 1 Function 2 .137 .000 General trust –.408 .202 General distrust –.396 –.519 Asymmetry Cooperation is the source of general trust, or, conversely, trust is the source of cooperation, while general distrust underlies the overvaluation of one’s own group. We can conclude that for Hungarians who live in a global minority position the variables describing social and demographic heterogeneity are not able to cut across effects which derive from the homogeneity of ethnicity or nationality, e.g., trust potential. It indicates that in the background - provided by the sociology of knowledge of the trust relationship - between majority and minority we can find considerations which may seem to be irrational, and which are stronger than the considerations of everyday rationality relying on social status, settlement type and age. Levels of Trust in Transylvania In relation to the models describing how the micro-, mezzo- and macro-levels of trust are built on each other we would like to emphasize again that the survey did not deal with the topic of trust directly, thus the operationalization of various levels of trust is quite occasional. We hold that the description of models is important because they can illustrate how various levels of trust are built on each other if the ethnic dimension is included as an independent variable. Within this combination of models micro-level trust was measured by the size of personal networks, the mezzo-level was measured by trust in different political agents and institutions, finally, macro-level was measured by views about the anomic condition of society. At the mezzo- and micro-levels an ethnic motive was also included: at the mezzo-level political agents committed to represent one’s own and the other ethnic group were distinguished, while the micro-level model included the number of network members who come from the other ethnic group. Models show how these three trust levels are built on each other. 14 Figure 1: Path model of anomie among Hungarians and Romanians in Transylvania Hungarians .09 .96 Distrust in the Hungarian agents Hungarian network –.09 .09 .24 Romanian network Anomie .28 .20 .23 Distrust in the Romanian agents –.14 Romanians –.05 .32 .06 60 Hungarian network Distrust in the Romanian agents .04 Romanian network .05 –.12 .99 .05 .67 Distrust in the Hungarian agents Anomie .05 .04 The explanatory power of the path models is extremely modest, however, the beta values of the indicated paths are always significant. In this analysis we do not wish to go all the way or analyze both models to the end; we would like only to direct attention to the relationship indicating how and to what degree the presence of the ethnic motive can deform the stratification of trust levels. For Romanians, institutional-level distrust increases the perception of social anomie, which is not influenced by the ethnic motive: when trust in institutions - representing either one’s own or the other group - is absent, it will equally strongly increase the anomic sentiment. For Hungarians, the situation is different. If they trust their own agents, then it is less likely that they see Romanian society to be anomic, and if they have no trust in Romanian agents, they are much more likely to perceive anomie. For Romanians, judgments on agents committed to represent one’s own and the other group strongly correlate (trust in one’s own institutions influences trust in Hungarian agents with a strength of beta=0.67). For Hungarians, this connection is much weaker, since the beta value here is only 0.28. 15 Micro-level trust is loosely related to the perception of social anomie, and we can find a significant direct path for Romanians only. It indicates that openness in the micro-sphere (extensive personal network) decreases the perception of anomie. For Romanians, the micro-level is hardly related to the institutional level. We can pinpoint only one tendency, which also applies to Hungarians: ethnic trust manifesting at the micro-level also increases trust in the agents of the other ethnicity at the institutional level. For Hungarians, the openness of the personal sphere strengthens distrust in the agents of the other ethnic group (beta=0.20), unless it is combined with mixed ethnic composition of the network. We can conclude that Hungarians’ living in global minority indicates trust capitals with ethnically asymmetrical organization. In contrasts, for Romanians, due to their majority position the anomic sentiment could be hardly grasped with trust levels, tinted with ethnic motives, which implies that their structures of thinking are much less deformed by the ethnic motive. 2. Social Trust The second example describes the sphere of personal trust and examines reasons for trust (or distrust) in the uncertainty relations generated by regime changes in Central and Eastern Europe. Changes, which occurred after 1989 can be also interpreted as increased, distrust in the previously existed social and political relations and trust in the new political and economic values. The legitimacy of the new political and economic order relied mostly on this trust capital: people were not able to calculate the predictable consequences of regime change rationally, but their trust in new values, institutions and political actors helped to alleviate the tensions and weaken uncertainty. Numerous empirical analyses proved that the political elite which led regime change and the values of regime change which they represented (such as liberalism, democracy, pluralism or market economy) had significant trust capital within the majority part of the society in the early 1990s. (It is not altered by the fact that the severe social consequences of regime change significantly eroded this trust capital later.) In contrast, a cross-national comparative survey on the judgment on social justice carried out in 19917 had already shown that a high degree of distrust in people who most successfully benefited from changes, i.e., new entrepreneurs, managers and bourgeoisie, manifested in almost all Central and Eastern European countries. In the following analysis we seek the roots of this contradiction and try to find out whether distrust, which manifested very early and is still characteristic, has material-existential explanations, or value conflict or socialpsychological reasons. Moreover, we try to find the answer to the question whether distrust in the ‘conspicuous’ winners of regime change undermines political legitimation for the entire system. According to the various trends of sociological theory, the interrelation of trust and political legitimation is not self-evident. In the concept of rational legitimation, which 7 The survey covered 5 countries: the Eastern part of Germany, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Bulgaria and Russia. Data were first collected in 1991 and then, in the second phase, in 1996. (In the original survey of 1991 eight other Western and Eastern European countries were also included.) The explanatory model underlying the relationship of trust and political legitimation was created for the entire Central and Eastern European region so that changes over time could be also tracked. 16 derives from the Weberian tradition, trust is not considered as the sine qua non of political legitimacy, while the interpretation attempts deriving from Durkheim’s traditions start from the importance of moral order, and thus they attribute outstanding importance to trust in everyday social interactions. This model is not able to grasp general social trust but operationalizes only a segment of it: to what extent the enrichment mechanisms manifesting in society, i.e. ways to material success can be considered legitimate. The model contrasts this aspect with political legitimation, defined with approval/rejection of the new system of political institutions and principles, which emerged after the regime change. The elements of the model were as follows. Political legitimacy. Respondents were asked to judge whether (1) democratic elections really mean alternative choices and (2) the principle of equality before the law prevails, and finally (3) to what extent ‘the powerful’ care about the opinions of ordinary people. From the answers given to the three questions an indicator was created whose great positive values represent the approval of the system, while great negative values represent the rejection of it. Trust in ways of enrichment under market economy conditions. Respondents were asked to judge the role of personal efforts (hard work), talent, or uninhibited behavior and unjust external economic conditions in enrichment. From the four answers a trust indicator was created whose positive values show the approval of ways to enrichment and negative values show distrust in the way of enrichment. Macro-level value preferences. Since macro-level meritocratic values became a decisive element of social relations and institutions after the regime change, it was assumed that the approval or rejection of these values is closely related to the political legitimation and to trust in success. The indicator was created from four variables by principal component analysis. The positive values of the principal component express that the respondent thinks that the prevalence of meritocratic values (respect for hard work, free inheritableness of personal and private property and achievement based distribution) is desirable (sollen), and thus radical changes in value preferences are also desirable (difference of sollen and sein). Micro-level value preferences. Like at the macro-level, support for micro-level meritocratic principles was tested through this indicator. The principal component included four variables: wages should correspond to abilities and efforts and the desirable degree of change as opposed to current income distribution, which is not meritocratic enough. Satisfaction/frustration. Numerous empirical studies proved that satisfaction or dissatisfaction with one’s personal life situation considerably influences the degree of legitimacy. Satisfaction was measured with four items: satisfaction with income, living standards, the current political system and life in general were aggregated into a principal component. Social status. It is assumed that the degree of political legitimacy depends on whether regime change provided status advantages or disadvantages for respondents. Social status was measured through the aggregation of education, occupational prestige and income. Finally, we also wanted to track changes over time in the model, thus two dates of the research were included (1991 and 1996). The above described dimensions were drawn in a path model explaining the intensity of political legitimation in Eastern and Central Europe. 17 Figure 2: Path model of political legitimation in Central and Eastern Europe Status –.11 .13 .88 –.07 Macro-level meritocratic preferences .17 Satisfaction .20 .23 Trust –.08 Year .09 Micro-level meritocratic preferences -.09 –.13 .20 Political legitimation 18 The model successfully explained the development of political legitimation (R²=0.12). Although it is not the most important connection, it should be concluded that the degree of political legitimation, if the effects of all other factor are controlled, decreased between 1991 and 1996 in the region. This political legitimation, which weakens over time, most strongly connects to trust in ways to success and enrichment. The more one thinks that personal merits underlie enrichment, the more he can identify with the new political system. Personal satisfaction also has an advantageous effect on the degree of political legitimation. The approval/rejection of meritocratic values does not influence political legitimation directly. However, the path model clearly shows that both macro- and micro-level preferences for meritocratic values weaken trust in the rich and thus in political legitimation. These indirect effects are not self-evident, since we would expect that the approval of meritocratic values have a favorable effect on the legitimacy of the entire system because the system overtly relies on meritocratic values. The key to understand this phenomenon is hidden in the degree of personal satisfaction. However, there are more complex paths from satisfaction to political legitimation: personal dissatisfaction (which tends to characterize respondents with lower status) increases affinity toward both macro- and micro-level meritocratic values. We can possibly find its explanation in the socialpsychological phenomenon that respondents’ dissatisfaction seems to be associated with the belief that they would deserve more – because they are talented, make great efforts, carry great responsibility and because achievement based distribution should prevail at the macro-level. And if so, they would get more and would not be dissatisfied. However, the world is unjust, and those who raid and seize and are corrupt, whom injustices in the economic system allow to play their tricks, will be rich instead of the worthy (respondents themselves). It leads to distrust in enrichment and consequently it increases political de-legitimation. This picture is not essentially influenced but only tinted by the path, which leads from status through meritocratic values to political legitimation. High status, behind which satisfaction has no marked profile, i.e., we can find both satisfied and dissatisfied people in this group, makes the approval of micro-level meritocratic values more likely. It certainly reduces trust whether it goes along the approval of macro-level meritocratic principles or affects trust directly. Therefore we have to say that in the region value preferences and the coordinates of relationship with social stratification had not crystallized by 1996 so that people could be able to take stands without assigning a key role to satisfaction with personal life situation in forming their opinions. We can expect an increase in trust only if it is supported by the personal satisfaction of the respondent. Trust, which is one of the major explanations of political legitimation, relies primarily on personal satisfaction rather than value preferences. This model also pinpointed a particular effect, which is independent of the status and satisfaction of people living in the region. By 1996 the proportion of opinions that macro-level meritocratic value did not prevail decreased, which increased, although moderately, trust in the rich. From the model describing the combination of trust and political legitimation, we also tried to elaborate a pragmatic message. We examined whether trust capital influences ‘political action’. Political action means only that the respondent would vote in the parliamentary elections to be held that weekend.8 8 The model was tested for one year only, namely 1996. 19 Figure 3: Path model of electoral behavior in Eastern and Central Europe .26 Trust .16 Political legitimation .97 Voting in parliamentary elections In this model the relationship between trust and political legitimation is stronger than it was in the former path model because this model does not include the variables which strengthen political legitimacy through increasing trust. However, the relationship which shows that stronger political legitimation encourages participation in the elections is much more important. Trust has no direct effect on electoral behavior, however, its indirect effect is remarkable. If the rich are seen as a pack of tricksters and corrupt people, than it casts a shadow on the legitimacy of the entire system and makes people indifferent toward political actions. 20 Literature Coleman, J. 1990: Foundation of Social Theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press Csepeli, Gy., Örkény, A. and Székelyi, M. 2000: Grappling with National Identity. How Nations See Each Other in Central Europe. Budapest, Akadémiai Kiadó Durkheim, E. 1957: Professional Ethics and Civil Moral. London: Routledge Durkheim, E. 1964: Division of Labour in Society. New York: Free Press Giddens, A. 1990: The Consequence of Modernity. Oxford: Polity Press Mason, D. and Kluegel, J. R. with Khakhulina. L., Mateju, P., Orkeny, A., Stoyanov, A., Wegener, B. 2000: Marketing Democracy: Changing Opinion About Inequality and Politics in East Central Europe. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield Misztral, B.A. 1996: Trust in Modern Society. Cambridge: Polity Press Örkény, A. and Liebig, S. 1999: “Normatív legitimáció és igazságosság” (Normative Legitimacy and Social Justice), In.: Szociológiai Figyelő, 1999:1–2, pp. 129–140. Örkény, A. and Székelyi, M. 1999: “Igazságosság és társadalomkép” (Justice and Society as it is Perceived), Századvég, 1999: Winter, pp. 87–113. Örkény, A. and Székelyi, M. 1999: “Justice and Legitimacy: Post-Transformation Trends in Eastern Europe”, in Kolosi, T., Tóth, I. Gy. and Vukovics, Gy. (eds.) Social Report 1998, Budapest: Tárki, pp. 541–564. Örkény, A. 1997: Hétköznapok igazsága. Igazságossági felfogások egy nemzetközi összehasonlítás tükrében. (Everyday Justice. Perception of Social Justice in a Comparative Perspective) Budapest: Új Mandátum Kiadó Parsons, T. 1951: The Social System. New York: Free Press Tocqueville, A. de 1968: Democracy in America. London: Collins Tönnies, F. 1988: Community and Society. New Brunswick: Transaction Books Weber, M. 1958: The Protestant Ethics and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons Weber, M.1968: Economy and Society. Berkeley: University of California Press