Land-Use Regulation & Housing Affordability in France

advertisement
LAND USE REGULATIONS,
Housing (un)affordability and other socially undesirable impacts
First, I would like to thank the American Dream Coalition for this invitation (…)
I’m here because two years ago, I released for a French Think Tank, the Turgot Institute, a
full study reviewing the housing public policies in France. As the study was deeply
appreciated, it became a book.
Advertising...
One of the purposes of the study was to understand why we experienced such an
unprecedented housing bubble. When the study was ordered, we thought that our study would
mainly emphasize monetary phenomenon, or issues relative to credit practices, just like the
one which exist in the USA. We expected that land use regulations would be one factor
among others. It appeared to be, by far, the main factor explaining our bubble.
CAUSES OF THE REAL ESTATE BUBBLE IN FRANCE
Did we have a real estate Bubble in France, like in some parts of the USA? The answer is
obviously: Yes. The median multiple (using net disposable income) of real estate deals on the
territory began to diverge from its historical mean of 2.9 (which was observed, within a 10%
fluctuation range, between 1965 and 2000), at the beginning of the new millennium, and
reached a whopping range of 4.6 to 5.0 in 2007, according to various sources (The following
graph uses ratios relative to gross disposable income so figures are a bit lower, from 2.5 to
4.2) .
Gross median multiple ratio – 1936 to 2008
This bubble was especially remarkable because it was the first time it reached such intensity,
but also because for the first time, it was not an “urban bubble” or a “Paris Bubble”. Prices of
existing or new homes peaked in the same proportions either in central metro areas or in rural
cities as far as 30 miles from these metro areas. They peaked in many metro areas with 50 000
inhabitants and more, not only in very big dense areas like Paris or Lyon or Azure Coast.
This graph shows that house prices increased 90% faster than households’ revenues between
1997 and 2007. In non inflation-adjusted prices, it corresponds to a whopping 140% gross
increase.
index of median home prices / median net household revenue, 1965 = 1
Most publications explain this only by an increase in demand favoured by low credit rates. Of
course, this explanation is half true, since average fixed rates to households were divided by a
two fold between 1997 and 2005 (from 8.6 to 4.3%). This fall of credit rates allowed
borrowers to lengthen the maturity of their loans, and, at equal revenue, a typical household
could borrow about 50 to 70% more than it could before. Many analysts stop their reasoning
here. “That’s demand, period”.
Every good economist should react to this by saying that if the supply was not constrained, an
increase in household’s solvability would result in an increase of housing supply, since early
signals of price hike would bring newcomers on the market. Especially, housing market has
very low barriers to entry, isn’t prone to the formation of monopolies… This didn’t happen.
We can see that, despite price increase begun in 1998, the supply began to soar only in 2004,
and remained far under historical records.
Supply didn't follow demand
between 1999 and 2004
How can we be sure that most part of the housing bubble comes from land use regulations?
First, if the gross price of homes and flats grew by 140% in the ten years of the bubble,
construction costs only grew by 30% in the same time.
Orange and green curves: condo and house prices
purple curve: construction costs.
It’s about 10% more than inflation. It can’t explain a 100% price hike on every home, new or
ancient. Construction costs grew at a much slower rate than CPI between 1965 and 1997, the
current trend inversion comes mainly from some regulatory strengthening in public housing,
and some workforce shortages in some particular housing jobs. Not something really relevant
compared to the global price increase.
But when I studied the share of land into the price of new homes, I discovered that raw
developable land prices increased 6 times in the same period, though the costs of technical
land development (sewage, electricity and other networks, roads and so on) only grew in the
same proportions than construction costs. In fact, in most areas, land prices were the same in
Euros in 2007, than they were in our good old Francs in 1997 (1€ # 6.5 Francs). On coastal
areas, the prices increased from 10 to 12 times. Only in some very isolated and economically
very depressed rural areas, we didn’t see such prices increases.
Agricultural land didn’t follow the same trend. Even at more than 15 miles from big metro
areas’ fringes, developable land is as much as 200 times more expensive than agricultural
one. At the fringe of big cities, the factor can jump up to 500 or 1000 times.
The latest point that convinced me that we were experiencing a “land oriented bubble”, was
the discovery that in most housing programs with multiple lots, small lots were sold at much
higher rates, in Euros per square meters, than bigger one. This shows the presence of a
“regulatory penalty”, as first described by US economists Glaeser and Gyourko. This penalty
corresponds to the price of a theoretical zero square foot lot on an operation.
Price of serviced lots = f (surface)
We don’t have, in France, national databases with free access that could have allowed me to
compute precisely this regulatory penalty. But some examples coming from real operations
show that this penalty, in rural towns neighbouring (20-30 km) big cities, could represent
about one third of the total cost of the home in 2006, much more than in 1998 or 2000. And,
sometimes, it may be more.
Do we have a tough land use regulation in France?
The answer is, once again, yes.
The current frame of our regulation comes from a 1967 law, which allowed cities to
promulgate zoning plans. That doesn’t say that there was nothing before: there were rules that
“protected”, i.e. prevented from being built, agricultural land. But the 67 law marked the
beginning of the application of zoning laws in France.
You will say: how a regulation promoted in 1967 could produce some real estate price frenzy
only since 1997 ? This argument is often raised by people who don’t want to hear about the
responsibility of zoning laws in real estate bubbles. The answers are multiple.
First, general economic theory reminds us that you must have high demand and a constrained
supply to get prices becoming mad. The two conditions were not met together until the late
nineties. Inflation, and thus interest rates, was high in the late 60s, in the 70s and during the
80s, when central banks decided that inflation had to come back under control. High interest
rates didn’t allow too long lending times, so the maximum prices people could afford for
homes wasn’t so high. In the beginning of the nineties, most western economies (USA, UK,
France, Germany, Sweden…) were slightly depressed, and the real interest rates (the
difference between gross rates and CPI rates) remained high.
You need both factors to get a bubble started: high demand fuelled by low credit rates, and
tough development regulations. Interest rates determine how much you CAN pay for your
home, but regulations strength determines how much you WILL pay, somewhere within the
range between zero and what you can pay.
Second point, the focus of the land use regulations shifted from early times to now. In the first
times of their applications, so called “sprawl” wasn’t a great issue out of the circles of
professional planners. So the regulatory tools to prevent sprawl were there but the elected
councils weren’t eager to use them too much. Zoning plans were used to try to separate
housing activities from other ones. So the first plans that were made in the 70s didn’t really
limit or restrict access to developable land. And most of the smaller cities didn’t make zoning
plans, because it wasn’t mandatory.
Let’s add that the 60s and 70s were, in France, the golden age of public housing
constructions, generally with regulatory “exemptions” from the 1967 common law... As the
dominant ideology was that state had to do something to provide dwellings to low wage
families, it made it on a wide scale (state was not heavily in debt in those times).
Let’s come back to our regulatory zoning purposes.
In the late 80s, we began to see a shift into the purpose of regulatory zoning. Environmentalist
movements became to sue cities councils whose zoning plans didn’t address environmental
issues enough, from their perspective. They were greatly helped by additions of successive
layers of European and National laws over the 1967 framework. The new layers reinforced
the obligation to preserve natural and agricultural land from being built. Coastal laws, Wet
zone laws, biodiversity laws, natural zones preservation laws… In the same time,
environmentalists were successful to push “sprawl” as the ultimate evil in many politicians’
minds. So zoning plans became progressively anti-sprawl plans, too.
All this stuff came mostly during the 90s and turned the regulatory process of building a new
zoning plan into a real mess.
In the USA, Glaeser and Gyourko showed that the crucial variable that explained most of the
bubble in the USA was the necessary time to build homes from scratch, on a raw land. When
you put a long bureaucratic regulatory step for the sole purpose of making a raw land
authorized for building, you’re likely to push up prices when demand soars.
In France, the necessary time to shift from an old zoning plan to a new one, when the old one
didn’t fit any more the current needs of the city, was estimated to about 18-24 months in the
80s. Now, three years is the minimal time frame to put these new plans to birth. But if some
environmentalist associations put the city’s project into litigation, the process can last much
longer. I saw some small cities struggling in 7 years of judicial battles, just to add +- 50 acres
of new developable land into their plan. For example, it took 6 years to the 20 cities of the
metro area of Nantes (#800 000 inhabitants, ranking #10 in France) between the beginning
and the end of the elaboration of their latest plan, brought to life in late 2007.
Of course, for some limited purposes, the law provides some “quick change” possibilities. But
even with those tools, you have to spend at least 6 months to put very small amounts of land
into the building market. And even for those limited development openings, you can face
judicial procedures, so a one year time frame for small changes is closer to reality.
So the process of building a new zoning plan is such a hassle that new cities’ councils don’t
want to engage too often into it. Once per election cycle is the great maximum, and a plan
must last at least 10 to 15 years. So you have to forecast in advance the amount of land you
will have to use to meet the housing needs of your population.
The plans that came into applications in the early 2000s were built during the mid 90s: at this
time, the rhythm of new construction was driven by high interest rates, and nobody could
forecast a big drop in interest rates. So many councils didn’t put enough land with immediate
availability in their plans, and if some of them put some land for “future” availability, with
“quick change” processes available, it was generally not enough to follow the huge increase in
demand driven by credit rates. So the price of land started to soar from 1998 to 2007.
CONSEQUENCES OF THE REAL ESTATE BUBBLE
Estimation of the planning penalty In France:
I used the same “rough edged” calculation formula than Randal O’Toole used to determine
the planning penalty paid by US house purchasers to sellers in his “planning penalty” report
released for the ADC and the Cato Institute a few years ago. For the year 2005, the house
price index, relative to the households’ revenues, reached a value of 170. If you assume
conservatively that values within the range of 90-110 are historically normal, that 10
additional points could be attributed to a slight increase in building costs, and that historical
prices doesn’t include any share of planning penalty, it leaves us with 50 points on 170, about
30% of the total, that can be attributed to the planning regulations.
There were about 800 000 housing deals concluded during this year, at a median price of
192 000 Euros (# 215 000$ Purchasing Power Parity Adjusted at this time). If our land use
regulations have been closer to the one existing in Dallas or Houston, every French household
purchasing a home could have saved 57 000 Euros or 64 000$. The total sum transferred from
purchasers to sellers in 2005 was about 46 Bn Euros.
Who are the “winners” and the “losers” of the planning penalty?
People generally feel richer when their homes see their market value increasing. But are they
really? People who sell an overpriced home win nothing if they have to buy an overpriced
home in the same time. Except that transaction fees and taxes are generally calculated from
this overpriced tax base… The first purchasers are clearly the losers in this situation. On the
opposite, people who own several houses and who can sell them just to reduce their real estate
inventory are neat winners. So are landowners whose land has been promoted from “non
developable” to “developable” and thus sold it at a good price to developers. Though no
statistic corroborates this view, it’s not exaggerated to say that the group of home purchasers
is, in average, less wealthy than the group of home sellers.
So the planning penalty transferred in 2005 about 2.7 % of our GDP from a less wealthy set
of population to a wealthier one. Not exactly what one calls “fairness”...
46 Bn Euros are 9 times more than the money that France devotes to the minimal social
revenue for the poorer families, or twice the amount of subsidies devoted to public and private
housing.
Anti-sprawl laws generate “rural sprawl”
The law of unintended consequences strikes again through the observation of the effect of
anti-sprawl laws on population growth. Here’s a map of the country surrounding the city of
Nantes, but I could have Chosen Montpellier, Rennes, Lyon or many others to illustrate my
point (see a map of fastest growing areas below).
Fastest growing metro areas, 1997-2006
On the following map of the Nante's region, The two biggest yellow zones are Nantes and
Saint-Nazaire metro Areas. Nantes and its region experienced a neat positive migration flux
from people coming from more expensive places, mostly from Paris.
Near Nantes : small towns are growing faster than big ones...
As you can see, Nantes and Saint nazaire grew, but slowlier than the department's average.
But now, see the number of red and brown circles surrounding Nantes. Most of these cities
are small, from 1000 to 15 000 inhabitants. They grew up to 45% in just 7 years during the
bubble.
Though these small cities experienced the same land price hike (# 6 times in 10 years) than
bigger ones closer to Nantes, they remained the only place where middle wage families could
afford a lot to build a home.
But such small cities were not prepared to see their population growing so fast. Despite a
widening of their tax base, they can’t face the induced expenses in new schools, new school
bus lines, new swimming pools and sport facilities… Remember that in France, many of these
amenities are nearly exclusively provided by the public sector.
So some housing programs in these small cities have just become rural dormitory-cities.
Roads leading to big urban Areas like Nantes or Saint-Nazaire (#150 000 inhabitants) are
overly congested and have sometimes badly deteriorated, since neither structures nor
crossings were originally made for the traffic levels we’re experiencing today. Anti-sprawl
laws, by making more difficult to find affordable homes in the boundaries of big metro areas
or at their immediate fringes, created anarchic development in rural areas which were not able
to bear such unprecedented growth.
Corruption of political life
For the first time, the 2006 activity report of our central agency for corruption prevention
noticed that urban zoning laws and land use regulations were becoming a major source of
concern, as the difference between farmland and land for housing grew.
Of course, the phenomenon can’t be quantified, but officials refer to it as “not any more
anecdotal”.
Other Environmental effects
Zoning law didn’t prevent our urban landscapes from being messed up by big “soviet like”
buildings, generally erected in the frame of big public housing programs from the 50s to the
70s, which obtained special derogatory rights because of their “social purpose”.
One of the mass public housing program built in the 60-70s
And these are not the ugliest you can find...
More interestingly, it looks like beautiful landscapes’ preservation tends to be endangered
when the land is under the threat of being too severely protected by the zoning laws. One
example : great wildfires generally occur from beautiful woods that could be classified as
“natural reserve”, or anything approaching. Most of them are considered as arsons.
Why is there a political demand for such zoning laws? Who makes a living from zoning
laws?
People tend to love freedom for themselves but fear freedom for others, because “others”
could make a bad use of this freedom. Zoning laws are the political answer to this demand.
People well connected use the “democratic process” to maximize freedom to use their own
land according their own goals, when the land use plan is elaborated. Then they try to limit
this ability for others, either because of inherent NIMBYism of human nature, or in order to
maximize the gain they can get from these regulations.
This demand is addressed first by local elected, who generally see in zoning laws a good way
to protect their own interests, and, eventually, to harm their local opponents. Second, a huge
bureaucracy emerged either in big cities, or ingovernment agencies, under the pretext of
“expertise”, which must absolutely legally be associated to the democratic process of
elaborating plans, or is in charge to enforce them.
Since the 80s, when European laws made more difficult for French state to do things that can
be normally made by private contractors, the bureaucracy which “made” plans just turned into
a bureaucracy which “supervises” the private consulting firms which are paid to elaborate
plans. So there is a huge and influential private sector taking advantage of state made zoning
laws, which is efficiently lobbying to extend them. Crony capitalism is always the best ally of
socialism.
How many people are involved in this heavily state generated business? It’s impossible to
figure it out exactly. My very own rough calculations comes to a very conservative estimate
of at least 30 000 people (full time adjusted) under public job contracts, living from zoning.
And it doesn’t include private contractors, full time or occasionally working for zoning
purposes.
Things becoming worse: towards new urban disasters ?
This lobby is far more efficient than the very few economists who dare to examine the role of
land us regulations in the economy. Even if some politicians start admitting, very smoothly,
that there is a regulatory problem with our land use regulations, they remain inaudible. There
is absolutely no doubt, in the view of the two main political parties in France, that sprawl is
evil, and must be fought. And the recent carbon dioxide Frenzy has led to the creation of new
regulatory powers which carefully tend to impose their own anti sprawl views to cities, even
if cities would like to deregulate, or even simply relax regulations aimed at limiting sprawl.
Until the end of the 90s, even if big cities were bound under tough regulations to elaborate
their plans, at least they were under competition to create the most entertaining places to
attract people. This could lead some peripheral suburbs to adopt less severe restricted policies,
which at least provided some oxygen to home builders.
This ability is disappearing through an insidious process, namely “intercommunality”. For
instance, the 22 cities of the metro area of my living town of Nantes have been “strongly
convinced” to elaborate “joined plans”, under an exhaustive “coherent sustainable
development scheme”. What’s the result? There are still about 17 300 hectares (#40 000
acres) of farm land at the fringe of Nantes Metro Area. The sustainable development plan
imposes that this amount shall never go under 17 000. So, at least for the next 15 years, there
are only 300 ha (#750 acres) of new farmland available for new buildings. So few for a nearly
1 million people metro area! Metropolitan areas like Rennes even decided to impose a green
urban boundary around them.
Many metro areas across the country are currently adopting such mandatory “sustainable
development schemes”.
New buildings will only be made on brownfields, or on existing homes, in the frame of
publicly driven operations of “urban renewal”. The current motto of planners is: “we have to
rebuild the city over the city”. It sounds beautiful, but will surely turn many of our cities into
new urban disasters.
The Austrian Economist Friedrich Hayek famously stated that no planners, no experts, can
handle all the criteria that every individual decision requires. Even worse for planners, they
can’t evaluate how subjective valuations of every individual criterion can change with time.
So they tend to give importance only to the criteria that are important to them, and to the
politicians they’re advising. In the 50s and 60s, they focused mostly on the quantitative need
for new dwellings, so they created dehumanised soviet-like suburbs which today are
concentrating all the problems of poverty and frustration of our society. They created more
than 700 so called “urban ghettos”, urban disasters with awfully degraded dwellings, lack of
basic equipments like libraries, high schools, and so on… The spiritual children of these early
planners now say us that they will reinvent the town. They promise us new “ecopolis” just as
our elders were told about “radiant cities”. It's time to be afraid !
A city built upon “sustainable” principles in UK...
Sustainable, really ?
An “Ecopolis” project near Lyon.
Is smart growth sooo smart ?
Planners tell us that leaving free market forces at work on land use matters would lead to
anarchy and environmental disasters. But, seriously: When private developers fail so
miserably, they tend to do it once. Perhaps twice or three times, because sometimes several
competing bad projects are brought to markets simultaneously. But never has any business
driven under undistorted market laws generated more than 700 failures ! And nobody says we
should let build anything without some environmental requirements. But environmental
concern must not become a pretext to prevent anything from being built.
As Hayek said, market acts as a “decentralized planner”: private developers are careful to
bring to the market developments that market wants. So they have to take in account what’s
existing. So called “market anarchy” is only the expression of the impossibility to valuate
how individual preferences will change over time. Price system is the way people make
compromises between what they would like to have in an ideal world, and what they can
afford according to their revenues. Markets are the best tools to make these millions of
individual adjustments possible.
Another consequence of the current planning frenzy, and this will be my conclusion, is that as
soon as economy will recover – and if none knows when it will happen, it will happen – and
therefore demand for houses will soar again, then, we will know another housing bubble, and
another housing bubble crisis, with all its disastrous social issues.
Knowing all we now know about the deadly economic, political, environmental and social
effects of zoning regulations, we should take the opportunity of currently falling prices to
scrap down all these regulations, because house owners won’t be as much concerned by the
loss of value of their homes, since it’s happening all the same. We should enact land
regulations that let owners decide what to do with their land.
(Thank you for your attention)
© 2009 - Vincent BENARD
Images credits : INSEE, Conseil Général des Ponts et Chaussées, Etudes foncières,
CODELA, COURLY.
Download