The Settlement of Rural Migrants in Urban China—Some of China’s Migrants Are Not “Floating” Anymore Rachel Connelly Economics Department Bowdoin College Brunswick ME 04011 USA connelly@bowdoin.edu Kenneth Roberts Economics Department Southwestern University Georgetown TX 78626 USA robertsk@southwestern.edu Zhenzhen Zheng Chinese Academy of Social Science Beijing PRC zhengzz@cass.org.cn March 2010 The Settlement of Migrants in Urban China—Some of China’s Migrants Are Not “Floating” Anymore 1: Introduction The sweeping economic and social changes affecting China are compressing into a few decades the transition from a predominately rural agricultural society to an urban society based in manufacturing and services. The pioneers in this transition have been the millions of Chinese migrant workers who have left their rural villages to work in the cities. These labor migrants form the vast majority of what the Chinese call the “floating population” (liudong renkou), the official term for all of the people who are away from their place of permanent household registration.1 At first, most of these labor migrants were men who planned to return home after a few years, but women now comprise nearly half of all rural migrants. Recent evidence shows that not only are more women migrating, but they are going after marriage, often with their husbands and children. As migrants increasingly migrate as families, they are more likely to settle in their urban destinations. The goal of this paper is to investigate the issue of permanent settlement in Chinese urban areas. In a major review of international labor migration, which scholars argue provides the best model for understanding rural to urban labor migration in China (Cai, 2001; Fan, 2004; Roberts, 2000) , Sassen (1999: 142) found an important similarity over time and space was “the formation of permanent settlements for a variable share of migrants … even when there are high return rates and even when a country’s policies seek to prevent permanent settlement.” In this paper, we consider which factors 1 This term has a long and meaningful etymological history, one that is suggestive of the importance of place and belonging in Chinese society. The character liu, which means to flow, when combined with min or people, came to mean drifters or refugees. When combined with mang, which in traditional times meant to be forced to leave one’s land, the word liumang becomes “hooligan.” Thus, the term floating population in Chinese evokes the idea of the outsider, the unsettled (Chen, 1998). determine settlement, and what types of people are most likely to settle in the Chinese context. To accomplish this goal, our study uses the 2000 Chinese Census, the 2005 One-percent Population Survey, and the 2001 Chinese Urban Labor Survey (CULS). The 2001 CULS data collection effort, which focused on five large cities and specifically targeted migrants in a separate sampling frame, yielded 500 migrant interviews in each city and included dimensions of settlement beyond length of stay. We argue that self employment, coresidence with family members, remittances, and current hukou status are all aspects of the settlement process, in addition to length of stay. We explore each of these aspects in this initial portrait of the new settlement of the Chinese rural migrants in urban areas. The next section explores theoretical approaches to the issue of settlement and Section 3 applies those theories to factors affecting settlement in China. Section 4 provides a statistical portrait of the interrelationship among the various aspect of settlement, followed in Section 5 by a multivariate approach to three of the identified aspects of settlement. Section 6 concludes the paper. 2: The Role of Settlement in Migration Theory 2.A: Neoclassical Theory and Return Migration The focus of migration theory has been on the causes and consequences of movement from one place to another, so it is only natural that standard migration theory has assumed permanent migration as the norm and return migration as the anomaly. Yet close examination of any migration process shows a very large proportion of migrants do return to their place of origin, whether they are legal immigrants to the United States or guest workers to European countries (Dustmann, 1996). 2 Neoclassical economics views migration and return as rational decisions that weigh the costs and benefits of staying in the destination versus returning to the origin. In situations where a significant wage gap between sending and receiving areas persists over time, a simple application of neoclassical theory can only view returnees as failures, unable to reap the benefits available to them in the destination (Constant and Massey, 2002). Neither the surge of circular labor migration around the world in the last several decades nor the remittances that these migrants send home fit into this simple formulation of return migration as a permanent migration that has gone bad. A more sophisticated application of neoclassical theory that is consistent with circular migration brings intentions to return into the analysis. These intentions are reflected in behavior during migration: “it is the expected return which links the economic behavior of the migrant in the host country to the economic situation in the home country” (Dustmann, 1996). Thus, because wages and the opportunity cost of leisure are higher in the destination, migrants with an intention to return will work harder while there, and older migrants will invest less in destination-specific human capital. Within this model, the reason migrants intend to return is a strong preference for residence in the community of origin combined with the difficulty earning a living there. Migrants may have a target level of savings to attain while working in the destination that they intend to consume in their rural home, either because the costs of that consumption are lower at home or because the utility they expect to receive from consumption there is higher (Orrenius, 1999). Alternatively, the “bright lights” of the city may lead migrants to change their minds and want to stay to enjoy the broad range of available consumption opportunities, and if they are young and better educated they can benefit from spillover learning opportunities as well (McCormick and Wahba, 2005). 3 The “new economics of labor migration” takes a different, but not inconsistent, approach to the issues of return and circulation. The target may be to accumulate savings for investment because of market failure at home, or the goal might be to diversify sources of household income across sectors and space to reduce risk. Remittances fit nicely into this model, not only for altruistic purposes or investment but as a form of coinsurance between persons at the origin and the destination, and should increase with the potential for investment there or the insecurity of employment in the destination (Taylor, 1999). Since remittances are monetary manifestations of the ties of the migrant to home, return migration should increase with the strength of the same factors that increase remittances. 3.B: Backing into Settlement: Cumulative Causation and Networks An alternative formulation of staying versus returning looks not at intentions but at outcomes, for “settlement has a funny way of creeping up on immigrant workers who intend to stay only a short while” (Hondagneu-Sotelo, 1995: 1). Not returning is conceptualized as a postponement, not as a change of heart: “the migrant workers who entered the various European destination countries, who were seen and saw themselves as temporary migrants, were in reality settling” (Ganga, 2006: 97). Dustmann (1996) examined return intentions of foreign workers in Europe and their realization over the subsequent nine years: 11 percent intended to return and had, 31 percent didn't intend to return and had not, and 55 percent intended to return but had not. The probability of actual return increased with age at entry and decreased with years of residence in the destination. These same results were found in a study of return migration from the United States, with each additional year of residence lowering the probability of return more than the previous (Reagan and Olsen, 2000). 4 Several factors have been found to be important in determining whether a strategy of circular migration turns into settlement, including gender, the presence of family, networks, and employment. Both men and women initially intend to return, but women’s preferences seem to change more: “women gain greater personal autonomy and independence, becoming more self-reliant as they participate in public life and gain access to both social and economic resources previously beyond their reach” (Hondagneu-Sotelo, 1995: 146). While male labor migrants often face discrimination in the destination and seek to return home to regain status, “research shows consistently that gains in gender equity are central to women’s desires to settle, more or less permanently, to protect their advances” (Pessar, 2003: 29). Family and networks interact to produce settlement. Generally, younger parents who bring their children find them to be a point of entry into the destination society; the presence of children “forces the parents to take into account the necessity of liaising, for the first time or in new ways, with services and institutions at the place of residence” and to develop new social networks (Ganga, 2006: 102). Their children are more exposed to the host population than are parents, and this assimilation has spillover effects, increasing the probability of their parents staying in the destination (Dustmann, 1996). A study of migrants who intended to return but had not found that three of the six principal reasons they gave for not returning were related to their children (Ganga, 2006). A final reason for staying is connected with employment. “Return” is usually thought of by the migrant as going back to the place of origin, but that may not be an option if there are no jobs there except in low-return agriculture. If migrants move instead to a regional city – the solution envisioned by Chinese urban planners who promote the small-city policy – they may see no advantage of moving at all since “it is 5 the same old factory work” (Ganga, 2006). Even so, it is unlikely that low-skill factory workers can stay in the destination indefinitely, either because they cannot continue to work so hard or because of employer preference for younger workers. The occupation that does seem to keep migrants in the destination is successful entrepreneurship (MoranTaylor and Menjívar, 2005). Entrepreneurship provides independence, potentially higher income, control over work pace, and the opportunity for spouses and children to work together to earn income. In sum, the major factors highlighted by theory affecting settlement, whether intentional or not, are the costs and benefits of consumption in the origin and destination, considerations related to family and children, the development of networks, employment opportunities (particularly self employment), and risk. The following section will apply this analysis to China. 3: Changing Patterns of Migration in China For a country which once had one of the most restrictive migration policies on earth, China has developed a remarkably positive attitude toward urbanization during the last decade. At the 16th Party Congress in 2002, President Jiang Zemin said “all institutional and policy barriers to urbanization must be removed and the rational and orderly flow of rural labor guided” (Jacka and Gaetano, 2004: 48). His pronouncement was recognition of two realities, one urban and one rural. At the urban level, many scholars believe that China is under-urbanized and that economies of agglomeration are unexploited (Liu, Li and Zhang, 2003). At the rural level, the solution to poverty is increasingly seen to lie in the city – in permanent migration and urban citizenship – rather than in labor-intensive agriculture. This has been called the “the third liberation” 6 of the Chinese peasants, after land reform and the household responsibility system (Sun, 2005). China classified 36.2 percent of its population as urban in 2000, growing to 43 percent in 2005 (Li and Plachaud, 2006). While there is some confusion regarding urbanization levels as a result of urban sprawl and shifting administrative boundaries, the inescapable conclusion is that more than half of the Chinese population, some 870 million people, will be urban within a decade (United Nations, 2006). Most of the growth in cities has come from increasing rural to urban migration. The 2000 census and the 2005 One-percent Population Survey show the size of the “floating population” grew from 144 million to 147 million, and the interprovincial segment of this population grew even faster, from 42.4 million to 47.8 million (Wang, 2006). The annual migration survey of the Ministry of Agriculture shows an even greater proportional increase in interprovincial migration, from 21 to 40 million between 1999 and 2003 (Du, Park and Wang, 2005). Despite the growing numbers of migrants in Chinese cities, the issue of migration is usually considered separately from urbanization because of the assumption that this migration is temporary. The popular image of Chinese migration is that it is dominated by men who leave their wives and children at home while they work in the cities. In fact, the 2005 One-percent Population Survey shows that 49 percent of the migrants are now women2, and a longitudinal survey in nine provinces found that after 1996 the migration rate of young women exceeded that of young men (Mu and van de Walle, 2009). Even when the migration of women is acknowledged, the assumption is that most of these women are young and unmarried, and that they will return to the countryside after a few years to assume their adult status as wives and mothers. 2 Authors’ calculation. 7 This assumption no longer reflects the current reality of China’s rural to urban migration. Jacka (2006: 275) writes, “There are thousands of rural women living in Beijing and other cities who are older than the typical dagongmei (maiden workers), are married and have children, and are either self-employed or care for their children while their husband earns an income.” Survey research from the mid-1990’s already found that significant numbers of migrants came with their spouses. In Shanghai, analysis of surveys of the floating population yield estimates that one-fifth to one-third of migrants were accompanied by a spouse during the 1990s (Fudan University, 1997; Roberts, 2002; Wang and Shen, 2003). A 1995 survey of migrants in Beijing, Wuhan, Suzhou and Shenzhen found that one-third were accompanied by a spouse (Knight, Song and Jia, 1999), while a 1999 survey in Beijing and Shanghai found that 44 percent of migrants were with their spouse (Wu, 2004). A rural survey of returned migrant women in Sichuan and Anhui provinces found that two-thirds of their migration episodes had occurred after marriage, that four-fifths of married women had children by the time they took their first trip, and that half of the married women migrated with their spouse. Of these, about one fourth brought their children with them (Roberts, et al., 2004). The presence of family in the city is conducive to long-term stays and settlement, but data on whether this is, in fact, occurring are difficult to obtain. Surveys of returned migrants in the late 1990s in Anhui and Sichuan (Bai and He, 2003), and in those two provinces plus Hebei, Hunan, Shaanxi and Zhejiang (Zhao, 2002), found average durations of stay in the destination were between three and four years. Rural surveys, however, miss those migrants who had not yet returned and so might understate settlement. A 2005 survey undertaken in urban areas of Zhejiang province found 45 percent of migrant households had been in the city for over three years, and that 72 8 percent of married migrants lived with a spouse (Qi and He, 2005). A study by People's University showed that the majority of the 3.5 million migrants in Beijing had been there an average of five years (Xinhua, 2007). Urban surveys, however, might also understate settlement by truncating duration, for it is impossible to know how much longer the longterm residents will stay. Most recently, the National Bureau of Statistics provided summary data from surveys of the floating population spanning a decade: the proportion staying less than a year fell from 51 percent to 23 percent between 1993 and 2003, while those staying more than five years rose from 6 percent to 40 percent by 2000 (Nielsen and Smyth, 2007). Table 1 uses the 2000 Census and the 2005 One-percent Population Survey to compare the percent of male and female migrants who report being in their current destination for five or more years. In all but three provinces, the proportion of long-term migrants has increased during this five-year period. While the percent varies by province, from a low of 23 percent in Zhejiang to a high of 52 percent in Heilongjiang, on the average of about a third of both men and women are spending extended periods of time in their destinations. There have been few studies of the intentions of migrants to stay in Chinese cities. A 2006 survey in Beijing found that nearly half of the 2,532 migrants surveyed expressed a strong desire to stay (Hu 2007). A Fujian survey found that, if given a choice, 46 percent of migrants planned to return home after earning enough money, 21 percent wanted to stay where they were, and the rest wished to move elsewhere or were undecided (Zhu, 2007). As discussed above, costs and consumption opportunities emerge as important factors that both discourage and encourage potential settlement in Chinese cities. The 9 gap between rich urban and poor rural is wide in China, and is expensive for a migrant to live in the city relative to their income. The average migrant wage nationally was 5,444 yuan in 2002, compared to average expenditure of urban residents of 6,930 yuan (Zhu, 2007). A survey by the National Bureau of Statistics found migrants earned a monthly average of 966 yuan and spent 463 yuan, two-thirds of it on food and accommodations (Xinhua, 2006c). In the Fujian survey, most migrants earned 500 to 800 yuan per month, and only 29 percent said they earned enough money to support their family in the city (Zhu, 2007). Sometimes having a spouse in the city can save money. A survey of migrants in Zhejiang province records one migrant’s reasoning: “We can both find jobs and live on only one person’s income, so that another’s income can be saved. If only one works in the city, he will have to spend the same or even more – pay same amount of rent, eat out, which is more expensive than cooking at home, and he might feel lonely, so he will spend a lot of money in recreation. In the end, there will be nothing left over” (Qi and He, 2005: 6). This rationale probably lies behind the result of a study of returned migrant women in Anhui and Sichuan, which found that many of the women who accompanied their migrant husbands were unemployed: 12, 16 and 22 percent respectively on their first through third trips (Roberts, et al., 2004). It is ironic that one of the most important predictors of settlement, having a spouse in the city, would be an element of a strategy to save money for eventual return, but this phenomenon is completely consistent with the “backing into settlement” approach discussed above. One of the biggest expenses and one of the last barriers to settlement with any real force is housing. Urban China has experienced a remarkable process of privatization of housing and a surge in property values. Most of the residents in a survey of housing in 10 13 cities had been able to purchase their subsidized rental units at heavily discounted prices; between 1988 and 1999 space doubled and the proportion of dwellings with toilets increased from four to 33 percent. Two-thirds of migrants, on the other hand, lived in rented housing, paying an average of 250 yuan rent per month in provincial-level cities. They had much less space than residents, and only six percent had toilets. In Beijing, rent for this substandard housing was more than one-fourth of migrants’ household expenditure (Sato, 2006). A significant proportion of migrants live at their place of employment, whether in restaurants, hair cutting salons, stalls, construction sites or factory dormitories. For young women in coastal boomtowns same-sex dormitories have been factors contributing to their isolation and limited duration in the city. However, young women increasingly socialize with and marry coworkers; in response this and labor shortages in South China (Wang, Cai and Gao, 2007), factories have recently begun to provide dormitories for married couples. There also has developed a burgeoning apartment rental market for young couples, who with a combined income of 1,500 yuan can afford to pay rent of 150 to 400 yuan (Zhang, 2009). If housing is losing some of its force as a barrier to settlement, the same can not be said for children’s education. Whether in surveys of migrants or in the popular press, the education of migrant children is seen as a huge problem in China. The Ministry of Education estimated that in 2004 there were 6.4 million children of compulsory school age living in the cities with their parents and another 22 million remaining in rural areas (Xinhua, 2006a). School attendance for migrant children is now mandatory, but the fiscal responsibility of their education falls upon local governments in the destination. Despite widespread publicity and official decrees, urban schools continue to charge migrants 11 additional fees: the National Bureau of Statistics found 17 percent of migrants surveyed brought children with them, paying an additional 1,226 yuan in fees above regular tuition (Xinhua, 2006c). Many others send their children to migrant schools, which are frequently of poor quality. Children of migrants living in urban areas are much more likely to not complete 9th grade (the final year of compulsory school in China) compared with non-migrants and compared with children in the rural areas.3 Cho (2009) provides an account of one middle-age migrant woman's struggle to settle in Harbin. A particularly interesting and sad part of the account is that the children she had brought with her completed only primary school because they began to work in the city, and now they are relegated to menial jobs. This phenomenon will serve to perpetuate the gap between urban and migrant school completion rates. In the discussion above, the requirements of urban life and education affect settlement negatively because of their additional costs. But it is these same factors that in many cases attract migrants, whether because of the “bright lights” of the city or enhanced opportunities for education and mobility. This is especially true of migrant women: of migrants surveyed in Hebei, more women than men envied urban life, wanted their families with them, and “were more eager to abandon rural life and settle in the cities” (Song, 1999: 88). Migrant women in Beijing “tend to see a future in the city as holding greater potential for development than life in the countryside … significant, and possibly growing, numbers of migrant women wish to stay away from their ‘home’ in the countryside for as long as possible”(Jacka, 2006: 141). Opportunities for employment, both at the origin and the destination, are obviously important factors affecting settlement. Most of the young migrants have come straight from school and never farmed for a living; they perceive farming to be a dead 3 Authors’ calculation from 2000 Chinese census. 12 end when so many other opportunities are available. They can do hard manual labor in the cities while young, but not forever. Cai and Wong (2007) studies migrants’ intentions to stay permanently in nine cities in the Pearl River Delta area in 2006. Using willingness to give up their land as a proxy for the intention to settle, they found that those with more education were more likely to want to settle. Education and training provide mobility for some, but for most migrants the route to success in an urban area is entrepreneurship. Employment in commerce was found to be a significant determinant of longer durations of stay in Shanghai for married women (Roberts, 2002), and was related to intention to settle in Fujian (Zhu, 2007). The survey of returned women migrants in Anhui and Sichuan found those working in commerce were both more likely to be accompanied by their husbands and to have engaged in multiple migrations (Roberts, et al., 2004). The instability of employment was a major factor given by Fujian migrants for wanting to return. It was the main reason they offered for not giving up their land, which would occur if they changed their hukou or didn’t farm it. The land is also seen as a place to return to when old (Zhu, 2007). These reasons for ties to home – insurance for unemployment and for old age – are highlighted in the new economics of labor migration literature. Whether they actually impede settlement remains an unanswered question. Finally, increased time in the city seems to decrease the likelihood of return in China, as it does in studies of migration and settlement in other countries. Zhao (2002: 382) surveys returned migrants, and finds “the probability of settlement rises as migrants accumulate time in the city.” Ren (2006) examines Shanghai data from 2000 and 2003, and concludes that the longer migrants stay in the city the higher their probability of long-term residence. While these data sets are not longitudinal, the factors that link 13 duration and settlement are similar to those identified by the longitudinal European studies discussed in Section 2 above. 4: A Statistical Portrait of Migrants in Five Large Cities In order to gain a better understanding of settled migrants in urban areas in China we consider data from the Chinese Urban Labor Survey (CULS). The data were collected between November 2001 and January 2002 by the Institute for Population Studies of the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences in the five cities of Shanghai, Wuhan, Shenyang, Fuzhou, and Xian. Urban households were surveyed using a proportional sampling frame. The migrant population in the same cities was surveyed with a separate survey instrument and a separate sampling frame. The migrant sampling frame used the information in the 2000 Chinese Population Census to identify 60 neighborhoods in each city where a high proportion of residents were migrants. Once the neighborhood was selected, the administrative records of the neighborhood committee were used to construct a sampling frame of all registered migrants. This method excludes short-term migrants who have not registered for temporary residence permits, but includes substantially more migrants than would have appeared in survey using only the urban household sampling frame. Table 2 compares the length of stay variable for each of the five cities in the 2000 Census and the 2001 CULS.4 The CULS has a very different distribution of duration than the 2000 Census, with many more long-term migrants in the CULS. Since our goal 4 Our working sample is 2,541 rural-to-urban migrants. The 44 migrants who reported their current hukou status was rural but that at age 16 it was urban were reclassified as having a rural hukou status at age 16, because ……….. After that reclassification, the 449 respondents who reported their hukou status at age 16 was urban were omitted, in order to exclude urbanites who had moved from one city to another. Preliminary analysis showed that the omitted group of urban-to-urban migrants were quite different from the rural-to-urban migrants. For example, the average years of education of urban-to-urban migrants was 11.6 compared to 8.4 years for the rural-to-urban migrants. 14 is to study determinants of settlement, the oversampling of long-term migrants is not unwelcome, but we cannot assume the distributions of duration presented below is representative of the full migrant population in the five cities. 4.A: Length of Stay Table 3 presents the percent of migrants surveyed in the CULS by length of time they report having lived in this city. The duration information provided by the CULS allow us to distinguish between moderately long tenures and very long tenures, whereas the final category in the 2000 Census is “more than five years” and in the 2005 Onepercent Population Survey is “more than six years.” A substantial number of registered migrants have been in the five CULS cities for four or more years. Wuhan, Shanghai and Fuzhou are similar with 61 percent, 60 percent and 56 percent respectively in the city for four years or more. Shenyang, with 35 percent, has the lowest percent of long-term migrants, and Xian is in between with 48 percent. In all five cities, of those who have stayed four years or more most have been there between four and ten years. These migrants would have come between 1992 and 1997, years correspond the surge in migration after Deng Xiaoping’s Southern Tour. At the other end of the spectrum, Wuhan, Shanghai, and Fuzhou are again quite similar, with about 18 percent of the migrants there for less than two years. Shenyang’s migrants are more recent, with 36 percent of them having lived in there for less than two years, and Xian is in between, with 27 percent of the migrants there for less than two years. 4.B: Age of Migrants Table 4 shows the mean age of men and women migrants by length of time in the city. On the average women migrants are a few years younger than men in each city. As one might expect, migrants who have been in each city longer are older, but not as much 15 as would be expected if they had all come at the same age. Thus, it appears that migrants who have stayed longer came to the city when they were younger. In Xian, the average age of women who have migrated in the last two years is almost 28, while the average age of women who have been in the city two to four years is 25. This data supports a finding from a survey of returned women migrants in Anhui and Sichuan, that in recent years more women in all age cohorts, including older women, are joining the migration stream (Roberts, et al., 2004). 4.C: Marital Status and Location of Residence of Migrant Spouses, Children and Parents Table 5 shows that the majority of both men and women in the CULS migrant sample are married, consistent with recent studies that show that marital status is not an important determinant of migration after controlling for age (Mu and van de Walle, 2009). Shenyang is the outlier, with fewer migrant women and a lower percent of these women married, but for some cities and durations, the proportion of married women migrants exceeds that of men. The proportion married increases with time in the city; while clearly related to age, it may also be a result of a higher propensity to stay in the city if married. Table 6, Panel A shows that most married women migrants in these five cities are there with their husbands, and that only the most recent arrivals are migrating without them. Men are less likely to be accompanied by their wives at every category of duration. Nevertheless, well more than half of the male migrants are in the city with their wives. Table 6, Panel B shows that most married migrants have children under 16 years old, regardless of time in the city. There is a slight decline in the percent with children in the “10+ years” category, which is probably because their children are older than sixteen 16 years of age. This is unlikely to occur in the first three duration categories, as the mean age of migrants in those categories is around 30 years. While at least two thirds of the married migrant women are in the same city as their husband and more than half of the married migrant men are in the same city as their wife (Table 6, Panel A), Panel B shows that far fewer are accompanied by their children. This is made possible by the care provided by family at home: the survey of female rural labor migrants in Anhui and Sichuan found 76 per cent of the women who had children by the time of their first migration had left them with grandparents (Roberts, et al., 2004). In the CULS data, the proportion accompanied by children increases with time in the city, with more than a third of women in the city four to ten years (the modal category in terms of number of migrants), and half of women there over 10 years accompanied by one or more of their children. Table 6 Panel C explores coresidence with the parents of adult migrants. It shows that while the majority of these rural-to-urban migrants have living parents, very few of their parents have moved to the urban areas. Based on the average age of the migrants, these parents are in their fifties and sixties and are remaining in the rural areas, caring for grandchildren and continuing to work the land. Mu and van de Walle (2009), analyzing data from a longitudinal survey of households in nine provinces, find a significant increase in time spent working on the farm for women in the 51 to 60 age cohort. 4.D: Remittances As discussed above, one of the main reasons for migrating is to send remittances back to rural family members. Table 7 explores differences in the patterns of remittances by time in the city. Panel A focuses on the percent of migrants who report sending any remittances home, while Panel B examines remittances as a proportion of the annual 17 income of those migrants who send remittances. Panel A columns one and two use the full sample of rural to urban migrants. The percent of men who send remittances is higher than the percent of women and does not seem to be a function of length of time in the city. This is probably because married men are less likely to be accompanied by their spouse than are married women, and so are sending remittances to their rural wives. Columns three and four examine the proportion of married migrants with spouses in the same city who send remittances home. We find that significant gender difference remains. Comparing columns three to five and four to six, we find as expected that the proportion sending remittances home is much higher for migrants whose spouse is not in the same city. The proportion of migrants sending remittances is particularly high for males who have been in the city for two to four years. It may be that those men who stay beyond the first two years are those who find stable employment that provides enough income that they can successfully save and provide remittances. Table 7 Panel B shows that male migrants who send any remittances send a larger percentage of their income home than do women. This gender difference in the proportion of income remitted disappears when the sample includes only married migrants who are accompanied by their spouse. Comparing columns three to five and four to six we see that those married migrants who are not accompanied by their spouses remit a substantially higher percent of their income than those with accompanied by their spouses. Nevertheless, remittances by married migrants with spouses in the city are still between 15 and 20 percent of their annual income. These remittances may be used to support other family members, to pay school fees for migrants’ children, or to build a rural home (Ma, 2004). The high level of remittances is consistent with migrants maintaining strong ties to their rural communities and extended family members. 18 4.E: Self Employment We discussed above that studies in China and elsewhere associate successful entrepreneurship with migrating with a spouse, longer durations, and eventual settlement. Table 8 examines the relationship between duration of stay and self employment, and shows that the percent of migrants who are self employed increases with their length of stay in the city. This statement is true for both women and men and in all five cities, though there are substantial differences across the cities. Shenyang has the lowest proportion of self-employed migrants, 28 percent of the men and 30 percent of the women. Shanghai, Fuzhou, and Xian look fairly similar, with more than half the migrants self employed, while Wuhan has an even higher rate of self employment among both men and women migrants. 4.F: Changing Hukou Status The final variable explored in this section of the paper is the only direct indicator of intentional permanent settlement: changing one’s hukou status from rural to urban. While in the past only well-educated workers had a chance of changing hukou, some Chinese cities have been allowing migrants to obtain urban hukou for a fee. Table 9 shows substantial differences among the five cities in the probability of having changed hukou status. Wuhan has the highest rate of hukou status change, with Shanghai and Fuzhou being the lowest. It is also interesting to note that changing hukou status seems to be independent of time in the city. Thus, we should consider it to be a separate aspect of settlement. Cai and Wang (2007) found that those migrants who signal permanent migration intentions by declaring their willingness to give up their land are no different from their temporarily migrating fellow migrants in their desire to change their hukou status. Changing hukou status is not an urgent issue to them. 19 Of course, Tables 3 through 9 control for only one or two variables at a time. We know that migrants differ by age, sex, by city of destination, and by many other characteristics of their past. All of these variables potentially affect their length of stay, their propensity of have their spouse coresiding, and their propensity of having their child coresiding. These multivariate relationships are explored in the next section. 5: Multivariate Analysis of Three Aspects of Settlement We choose to analyze the CULS data because it provides several variables that can be considered aspects of permanent settlement. As we discussed above, the previous literature showed that migrants are more likely to settle the longer they stay in the same place, what we have called “backing into settlement”. This relationship is true regardless of whether the settlement is intentional or de facto. If it is intentional, then there may be some permanent settlers among the most recent migrants, but the proportion of migrants who are permanent settlers should increase with length of stay as the non-settlers return to their location of origin or move to another migration destination. If the settlement is de facto, then length of stay is, in part, the cause of settlement. Table 10 presents the OLS regression model of the determinants of length of time in the city. Two additional components of settlement are also analyzed; they are having one’s spouse in the same city and having a child in the same city.5 Both are analyzed using a 5 Originally we considered two additional aspects of migration as components of settlement, self employment and having changed one’s hukou status from rural to urban. However, in preliminary analysis of the data (not shown) we found that self employment and changing one’s hukou status from rural to urban were largely stochastic, at least in terms of the variables available in the CULS. We also tested whether including current self employment, hukou status, and having one’s spouse in the same city affects the other coefficients in the length of stay regression model, as one could be concerned about potential endogeneity of these variables in that equation. It turns out that the coefficients of the other variables are extremely robust to the addition of these “quasi-independent” variables. Tables comparing the results with and without self-employment status, hukou status and having one’s spouse in the city are available from the authors. 20 logistic model, with results presented in Tables 11 and 12 respectively. For each of the three aspects of settlement, we estimate the model for men and women separately. We know that empirically the pattern and timing of migration has been different for men and women. In addition, theory tells us that settlement may be more related to women’s migration than men’s migration. 5.A: Determinants of Length of Stay Table 10 shows that determinants of length of stay are qualitatively similar for men and women migrants. For both, the younger one was at the time of migration, the longer the duration in the city. Being currently married also increases length of stay, quantitatively more for men than women. Higher levels of education are correlated with shorter length of stay, though the effect is quantitatively small. For men, having a spouse with higher education reduces their length of stay, while there is no effect of spouse’s education on a wife’s length of stay. Having worked first in agriculture (as opposed to one’s first job being a migrant) increases the length of stay for both men and women by similar magnitudes. Also similar is the effect of having living parents, which substantially reduces length of stay in the city for both men and women. These latter two effects are likely related to current age of the migrant. Younger people are less likely to have worked in agriculture and more likely to have living parents. Those migrants whose location of origin is closer to the city are more likely to have been there longer, though the effect measured less precisely for women. It may be that being closer facilitates staying longer, but it is also true that the nature of migration in China has changed such that more recent migrants go farther from home than migrants who left their rural homes in the mid 1990s, with the percentage of migration that is interprovincial increasing steadily over time (Wang, Cai and Gao 2007). 21 Being able to speak the local language upon arrival increases both men’s and women’s length of stay. However, paradoxically for both men and women, self-reported poor Mandarin ability upon arrival also predicts more time in the city compared to those who reported good Mandarin skills. Since the five cities differ substantially in language spoken and in the provinces from which they are drawing migrants, it is possible that these variables reflect differences across places that are in addition to those being picked up with the location dummies. In terms of those location dummies, for both men and women, migrants in Shenyang and Xian have been resident for a shorter time than migrants in Shanghai. Wuhan and Fuzhou are not shown to differ from Shanghai in the base length of stay. Having a job arranged before one arrives has a different effect on women than on men. For women, having had their first job arranged before they arrived is associated with shorter time in the city, while for men the variable is insignificant. This result could be because of the nature of jobs that can be arranged ahead of time or may proxy for less assertive personalities. For women, having her husband in the city is associated with a longer stay in the city, but the same effect is not found for men. On the other hand, having changed one’s hukou status is associated with longer stays for men, but not for women. Finally, being currently self employed is associated with longer stays for both men and women. It is equally interesting to consider the variables that are not statistically significant determinants of length of stay, especially the number of children and the presence of other family members and relatives in the city upon arrival. These results indicate that children do not impede migration or even affect time in the city, consistent with the results of studies discussed earlier. The insignificance of the presence of other 22 family members may be because strong migrant networks now exist in most Chinese urban areas, so that even if one does not have family in the city upon arrival, there are other fellow villagers and commercial services available to help migrants find employment. 5.B: Determinants of Residing with One’s Spouse Tables 11 explore the determinants of another important aspect of settlement, residing with one’s spouse for the subset of migrants who are currently married. Table 11 reports the log odds instead of the coefficients, with log odds greater than one meaning that the characteristic is positively associated with the given aspect of settlement and values less than one meaning the characteristic is negatively associated with settlement. The results show that for both men and women, a younger age at migration reduces the odds that one currently lives with one’s spouse. This result is in keeping with Roberts, et al (2004), which found that many married women migrants migrate without their husbands during their first migration episode. The only other significant variables for both men and women are having both parents be peasants and living in either Wuhan or Shenyang. A migrant whose parents are both peasants is less likely to reside with his or her spouse. The labor demands for farming at home may be the explanation, or it may indicate a lack of the resources needed to move the family to the city. Migrants to Wuhan are more likely to coreside than those in Shanghai, while those in Shenyang and men in Xian are less likely to coreside than those in Shanghai. Self employment is a strong positive predictor of coresidence for men, supporting the hypothesis that self employment allows men to bring their wives to the city to earn 23 income by working together. Once again, the variables that are not significant predictors of coresidence with one’s spouse are interesting: education, number of children, distance to the city, language ability, having relatives in the city when one arrived and current hukou status do not significantly affect coresidence with one’s spouse. 5.C: Determinants of Coresiding with Children We saw in Table 6 that while the majority of men and women coreside with their spouse, many fewer coreside with their children. Table 12 examines the determinants of having one’s child in the city for the subsample of migrants who are both married and have at least one child. The specifications are identical to those in Table 11 except for the addition of a dichotomous variable which indicates if the oldest child is school age. School seems to be an important decision making point for migrants, with some migrants sending children back to their village when the children reach school age to avoid the higher school fees in the city, while others may elect to bring school age children to the city because they do not need day care arrangements while children are in school or to enroll them in higher quality schools (Connelly, et al 2008). For most variables, men and women appear similar in this decision, probably because both the husband and wife are usually together if the child is coresiding (86 percent of the households with a child present also have the spouse present). Migrants who are younger at the time of migration are less likely to coreside with their child. Having any relative in the city upon arrival positively predicts having a child coreside, probably because these relatives facilitate childcare. Migrant with parents who are peasants are less likely to have their child coreside with them. Paternal grandparents are 24 the primary source of childcare in rural China (Chen, Short and Entwisle, 2000), and many migrants leave their children with grandparents in the village (Roberts et al, 2004). The effect of grandparents as potential caregivers can also be inferred from the variable “any parent alive?” For male migrants, having any parent alive reduces the odds that their child resides with him in the city, as does having a school-age child. The effects are similar for female migrants, but are estimated less precisely. Thus, migrants appear to be more likely to bring very young children with them and then send them back to their rural homes for schooling. Connelly et al (2008) came to the same conclusion using data collected in rural areas of Sichuan and Anhui. Migrants in Wuhan are more likely than those in Shanghai to have children with them. For women, those in Xian are also more likely to have children with them. For men, those in Shenyang are less likely to have children with them. Recall that those in Shenyang were also less likely to have their wives with them. In Table 10 we saw that self employment increased the length of time the migrant spent in the city. For men, self employment also increased the probability that their wife lived with him in the city. Now, we find in Table 12 that for men self employment also increases the probability that their child lives in city. Thus, self employment appears to be a very important economic and social path for Chinese rural to urban migrants, quite different from a migrant who is an employee. The ability to use additional labor productively and the gain from contacts gathered over time means that self-employed migrants tend to stay longer and live with family members. While some may ultimately go home, as a group they appear more settled than other migrants. In sum, the three aspects of settlement explored here show a varied pattern of determinants. Standard demographic characteristics, such as education and number of 25 children, do not appear to matter. Language ability, current hukou status and relatives in the city also do not appear to be strong predictors of behavior. Variables that do matter consistently are age at migration and current self-employment status. Differences among the five cities regularly emerge, indicating that institutional structures and local labor markets are important considerations in understanding settlement behavior. Section 6: Concluding Remarks This paper has explored, both theoretically and empirically, the phenomenon of permanent settlement among Chinese rural-to-urban migrants. While naïve economic theory focuses its attention on the decision to migrate permanently, more sophisticated theoretical explorations of migration model return migration as well. In fact, return migration may be the goal, making settlement the unintended outcome. In order to explore migration decision making in China, researchers have until recently focused exclusively on the phenomenon of circular migration; both Chinese government policy and de facto institutional structures insured that most migrants were short-term temporary migrants. But the massive economic reforms since the mid-1980s have reduced many of the barriers that were keeping migrants from settling in urban areas. While the hukou system is still official policy, being in a place other than one’s place of registration has been decriminalized. The availability of food and housing for purchase means that migrants can now buy that which they need to stay in the cities. However, education for their children is still a substantial barrier, and we find that migrants with school age children are less likely to bring their children to the city. We can get an overview of changing settlement patterns in China through comparison of the 2000 Census with the 2005 One-percent National Population Survey. 26 The overall percent of migrants who have been in the receiving location for five or more years has increased during these five years. More importantly, because the absolute numbers of migrants has increased by much more, there has been a substantial increase in the population of long-term migrants. The 2000 Census and the 2005 One-percent National Population Survey do not allow us to distinguish between medium-term migrants and very long-term migrants; for that we turned to data from the 2001 Chinese Urban Labor Survey. While the CULS sampling strategy was weighted toward longer-term migrants and cannot be considered representative of all migrants, the data can give us a detailed look at the length of stay, living arrangements, occupations, and remittances of the more settled migrants in five cities. Most migrants in the CULS sample are married and more than half have been in the city for 4 or more years. Fifty-six percent of the men and 76 percent of the women are living with their spouse, but only 22 percent of the men with children and 28 percent of the women with children are living with their children. Remittances are substantial, even among those men and women with spouses in the city. Both the number leaving their children and the size of the remittances indicate that there continue to be strong ties with rural areas, and that full permanent settlement has not yet occurred for the majority of migrants to these five cities in 2001. The most settled group appears to be selfemployed migrants, who are shown in the multivariate analysis to have longer durations in the cities and are more likely to reside with their spouse and children. As the length of time migrants are spending in cities grows and most migrants live with their spouse in the urban areas, China needs to rethink the assumption that labor migration is temporary, and examine the ramification of the shift towards settlement in 27 terms of the delivery of health and education services. While in the past women returned home upon marriage and men returned a few years later, over the last ten years a generation of rural Chinese children is being raised in the countryside without their parents or in the cities with substantially less access to education than that afforded urban dwellers. The working migrants until they get hurt or can not longer physically take the extremely long work hours and difficult conditions of migrant jobs seems inefficient for a country at the level of development that China is at today. As many Chinese migrants are now “backing into settlement,” the costs of the unintentionality of this decision will remain in terms of increased inequality in the urban areas for at least another generation. 28 Table 1: Percent of migrants 16 years or older who have lived in their current place of residence for five or more years 2000 Hainan Chongqing Sichuan Guizhou Yunnan Tibet Shaanxi Gansu Qinghai Ningxia Xinjiang Men 37.1 25.2 27.1 32.0 22.2 28.8 17.4 18.3 28.1 31.2 45.4 20.3 41.5 23.1 27.5 24.8 25.9 23.2 32.7 28.5 20.8 31.2 30.0 23.6 33.0 10.2 26.1 32.3 28.8 25.2 34.9 Total 31.1 Beijing Tianjin Hebei Shanxi Inner Mongolia Liaoning Jilin Heilongjiang Shanghai Jiangsu Zhejiang Anhui Fujian Jiangxi Shangdong Henan Hubei Hunan Guangdong Guangxi Women 33.1 29.8 22.9 15.2 20.6 20.3 19.8 19.4 24.8 27.5 39.9 17.8 38.5 16.0 25.3 16.7 21.7 25 32.7 27.9 23.5 19.4 32.6 25.9 30.5 12.1 21.7 25.6 27.9 17.0 24.1 28.5 2005 Men 36.4 28.7 38.8 42.5 41.3 41.3 34.2 53.1 36.4 30.9 24.8 32.6 33.2 36.3 30.4 38.7 41.6 28.6 29.8 30.0 40.7 35.1 32.2 42.0 36.8 43.1 34.2 37.4 39.1 33.6 44.5 33.3 Women 36.1 27.6 35.1 45.2 42.5 38.9 33.8 48.9 32.9 26.5 23.5 31.2 28.3 36.4 26.1 35.9 40.4 27.3 24.9 34.8 37.4 31.5 28.2 40.3 35.0 45.3 32.9 37.2 34.3 32.6 40.4 Ranking by size of 2005 migrant pop. 3 4 21 12 11 10 18 17 2 6 5 22 7 29 9 28 13 19 1 23 20 25 15 24 8 31 14 26 27 30 16 30.3 Source: The 0.095% Micro Sample of the 2000 Population Census of China and the 20% percent sample of the One-percent National Survey of Population, 2005. Table 2: Percent of migrants by time in city by sex and city, from the 2000 Chinese census and the 2001 CULS 2000 Census 2001 CULS Men 0-1 years 2-4 years 5+years Men Shanghai 49.7 25.8 24.5 Wuhan 30.2 30.9 36 Shenyang 46.4 15.6 38.0 Fuzhou 56.5 26.6 16.9 Xian 56.7 18.9 24.4 Shanghai 47.1 26.6 26.3 Wuhan 25.8 29.7 32.1 Shenyang 30.5 23.7 45.8 Fuzhou 48.7 27.6 23.6 Xian 47.9 23.4 28.7 Women 0-1 years 2-4 years 5+years 0-1 years 2-4 years 5+years Shanghai 15.6 19.8 64.7 Wuhan 14.1 19.0 66.9 Shenyang 32.0 27.8 40.2 Fuzhou 18.1 23.2 58.7 Xian Shanghai 19.7 29.2 51.1 Wuhan 22.7 21.6 55.7 Shenyang 46.3 32.8 20.9 Fuzhou 19.5 27.5 53.0 Xian 24.4 24.1 51.5 Women 0-1 years 2-4 years 5+years Source: 2001 CULS and 0.095% Micro Sample of the 2000 Population Census of China 33.1 26.4 40.5 Table 3: Percent of migrants by duration in city 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years Mean years Total Sample 23.3 24.5 35.0 17.3 5.3 Shanghai 17.1 23.2 39.8 19.9 5.8 Wuhan 18.5 20.3 39.9 21.3 5.8 Shenyang 36.1 29.3 24.7 9.9 3.9 Fuzhou 18.8 25.2 33.6 22.4 6.0 Xian 27.2 24.9 36.0 11.9 4.6 Source: 2001 CULS Table 4: Mean age of migrants by duration, sex and city Men Total Sample Shanghai Wuhan Shenyang Fuzhou Xian 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 28.2 28.6 31.8 36.5 26.7 30.3 32.5 35.1 28.5 31.0 33.1 35.4 28.0 25.7 30.7 39.1 28.2 29.9 30.7 37.7 29.1 28.1 31.8 36.2 Total 31.2 31.8 32.6 29.4 31.9 30.8 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 25.9 26.6 30.3 34.8 27.7 26.4 30.4 35.2 25.6 28.1 30.3 33.0 22.9 25.2 31.5 32.3 26.6 27.2 29.8 36.1 27.8 25.3 30.5 36.9 Total 28.7 29.3 29.1 25.5 29.6 28.8 Women Source: 2001 CULS Table 5: Percent of migrants who are currently married by duration, sex and city Total Sample Shanghai Wuhan Shenyang Fuzhou Xian Men 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 49.5 50.3 72.1 93.0 53.1 69.4 84.4 97.3 51.4 62.0 79.2 95.7 49.1 27.7 59.2 81.6 46.0 60.9 66.3 91.8 49.4 46.3 67.7 93.3 Total 66.4 79.6 76.4 49.7 68.1 61.5 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 42.7 51.7 76.0 91.2 48.6 50.0 79.4 91.3 45.2 67.8 73.1 97.7 19.4 27.3 57.9 77.8 59.2 55.1 79.5 88.9 48.1 51.2 78.4 86.7 Total 62.9 66.3 69.6 31.3 70.5 62.0 Women Source: 2001 CULS Table 6: Location of family members by duration and sex Panel A Percent of married migrants whose spouse is in the same city Men Women 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 36.4 57.6 57.7 66.1 62.5 72.5 79.9 86.3 Total 56.6 76.4 Percent of married migrants with children under age 16 Percent of married migrants with children under age 16 who have any of their children in the city Men Women Men 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 66.0 78.0 76.1 78.2 75.9 85.5 84.6 75.0 5.5 16.5 24.3 40.9 12.2 22.8 36.8 48.5 Total 75.4 81.4 21.8 28.2 Panel C Percent of migrants with at least one parent still alive Percent of migrants with a living parent who have a parent in the city Men Men Women Panel B Women Women 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 91.1 92.1 87.5 82.7 94.7 97.0 91.6 85.3 4.0 2.2 9.3 6.0 2.0 5.0 5.9 6.9 Total 88.4 93.0 5.8 4.7 Source: 2001 CULS Table 7: Remittances: Incidence and percent of income by location of spouse Panel A Percent of migrants sending remittances Percent of migrants with spouse in same city sending remittances Percent of migrants with spouse NOT in the same city sending remittances Men Women Men Women Men Women 0 to 2 years 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 56.9 66.2 61.7 61.1 45.4* 52.1* 62.0 39.7* 54.2 52.0 59.4 58.4 41.4 47.0 61.6 41.1* 71.8 84.0 64.9 69.5 47.6* 55.3* 56.9 35.3* Total 61.6 52.0* 57.2 51.0* 70.7 51.4* Panel B Percent of income remitted by migrants who send any remittances Percent of income remitted by migrants with spouse in same city sending remittances Percent of income remitted by migrants with spouse NOT in same city sending remittances Men Women Men Women Men Women 0 to 2 year 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 29.0 28.0 23.7 21.1 24.0* 22.5* 20.0* 20.9 15.8 18.0 18.4 17.4 19.1 20.9 18.6 18.5 33.5 37.9 30.0 26.7 34.3 24.9* 27.1 NA Total 25.3 21.7* 17.8 19.1 31.6 29.2 Source: 2001 CULS * significantly different between men and women at 95% level of confidence NA not available because cell size is too small Table 8: Percent of migrants who are is self employed by duration, sex and city Total Sample Shanghai Wuhan Shenyang Fuzhou Xian Men 0 to 2 year 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 33.3 42.9 56.3 70.3 46.9 51.6 58.3 73.3 61.1 70.0 84.8 91.4 16.7 26.6 33.0 47.4 42.0 53.1 53.4 70.8 29.6 30.5 50.8 51.1 Total 51.1 58.8 80.5 27.6 55.8 40.8 0 to 2 year 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 30.4 45.3 61.5 75.7 20.0 38.0 52.2 68.4 51.7 69.1 81.6 90.5 22.6 36.4 31.6 55.6 29.3 40.6 55.1 75.0 23.1 39.5 54.0 53.8 Total 50.5 43.3 73.5 30.6 48.8 39.9 Women Source: 2001CULS Table 9: Percent of migrants who have changed hukou status from rural to urban by duration, sex and city Total Sample Shanghai Wuhan Shenyang Fuzhou Xian Men 0 to 2 year 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 14.1 14.5 15.4 12.6 12.2 12.9 7.8 6.7 24.3 26.0 27.4 15.7 13.9 12.8 19.4 28.9 8.0 9.4 5.6 8.2 14.5 14.6 16.9 11.1 Total 14.4 9.2 23.6 16.9 7.6 15.0 0 to 2 year 2 to 4 years 4 to 10 years 10+ years 18.3 16.9 14.7 16.2 5.7 13.5 7.4 13.0 29.0 27.1 17.6 25.0 17.7 20.5 10.5 22.2 14.3 13.0 15.9 11.1 18.5 9.3 17.6 6.7 Total 16.4 9.6 23.4 17.9 13.9 14.7 Women Source: 2001 CULS Table 10: Comparison by sex of determinants of number of years lived in this city Female Age at migration Currently married Educational level Spouse’s education Number of children First job in agriculture? Distance to city Any parent alive? Could speak local language when arrived? Past Mandarin fair? Past Mandarin bad? Any family members in city when arrived? Any relatives in city when arrived? Job arranged when arrived? Both parents peasants? Wuhan? Shenyang? Fuzhou? Xian? Self employed? Hukou now urban? Spouse in city? Constant Observations R-squared -0.292*** (0.018) 3.259*** (0.642) -0.085** (0.040) 0.066 (0.050) -0.217 (0.191) 1.760*** (0.543) -0.015 (0.010) -3.732*** (0.477) 0.751*** (0.280) 0.208 (0.258) 0.779* (0.429) -0.244 (0.238) 0.020 (0.223) -0.402* (0.220) 0.071 (0.280) -0.286 (0.357) -0.992** (0.428) -0.376 (0.363) -0.768** (0.384) 0.875*** (0.257) -0.180 (0.298) 0.791** (0.333) 12.963*** (0.911) 930 0.36 Male -0.352*** (0.015) 6.791*** (0.519) -0.075* (0.038) -0.183*** (0.044) -0.254 (0.178) 1.764*** (0.505) -0.020*** (0.007) -4.778*** (0.379) 1.289*** (0.276) 0.484** (0.245) 1.079** (0.441) -0.167 (0.248) -0.007 (0.220) 0.247 (0.221) -0.252 (0.285) -0.328 (0.381) -1.041*** (0.388) 0.330 (0.371) -0.903** (0.355) 1.064*** (0.253) 0.602* (0.318) 0.424 (0.288) 15.278*** (0.810) 1510 0.40 Source: 2001 CULS Standard errors in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Table 11: Comparison by sex of spouse in same city Female Age at migration Education level Spouse’s education Number of children First job in agriculture? Distance to city Any parent alive? Could speak local language when arrived? Past Mandarin fair? Past Mandarin bad? Any relatives in city when arrived? Job arranged when arrived? Both parents peasants? Wuhan? Shenyang? Fuzhou? Xian? Self employed? Hukou now urban? Observations 0.942*** (0.015) 0.976 (0.035) 0.968 (0.038) 1.085 (0.168) 1.035 (0.461) 0.997 (0.008) 0.614 (0.234) 0.751 (0.209) 1.174 (0.314) 0.659 (0.279) 1.371 (0.300) 0.891 (0.194) 0.539* (0.178) 2.532** (0.983) 0.325** (0.146) 0.814 (0.278) 0.736 (0.261) 1.442 (0.333) 0.786 (0.240) 567 Male 0.980** (0.009) 0.977 (0.025) 0.991 (0.026) 1.097 (0.111) 0.896 (0.258) 0.998 (0.005) 0.898 (0.202) 1.362 (0.267) 1.144 (0.192) 0.890 (0.251) 1.154 (0.168) 0.921 (0.138) 0.600** (0.121) 1.837** (0.463) 0.236*** (0.063) 1.026 (0.243) 0.576** (0.125) 3.254*** (0.508) 1.169 (0.256) 1006 Source: 2001 CULS Standard errors in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1 Table 12: Comparison by sex of children in same city by migrants with children Female Age at migration Education level Spouse’s education Number of children First job in agriculture? Distance to city Any parent alive? Could speak local language when arrived? Past Mandarin fair? Past Mandarin bad? Any relatives in city when arrived? Job arranged when arrived? Both parents peasants? School aged child? Wuhan? Shenyang? Fuzhou? Xian? Self employed? Hukou now urban? Observations 0.937*** (0.020) 0.980 (0.037) 1.089** (0.045) 1.297 (0.286) 1.163 (0.511) 0.982** (0.009) 0.759 (0.325) 0.523** (0.154) 0.857 (0.224) 0.961 (0.381) 1.480* (0.311) 1.061 (0.223) 0.609* (0.180) 0.676 (0.178) 2.387*** (0.771) 1.368 (0.736) 1.439 (0.495) 1.932* (0.679) 1.050 (0.254) 0.829 (0.247) 458 Male 0.938*** (0.013) 0.963 (0.031) 0.956 (0.030) 1.087 (0.181) 1.186 (0.415) 1.008 (0.007) 0.515** (0.149) 1.116 (0.248) 0.958 (0.181) 0.796 (0.259) 1.394** (0.228) 1.156 (0.194) 0.620** (0.138) 0.711* (0.138) 2.980*** (0.781) 0.583* (0.183) 0.869 (0.229) 0.986 (0.250) 2.427*** (0.457) 1.155 (0.289) 761 Source: 2001 CULS Standard errors in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Literature Cited Bai, Nansheng and Yupeng He. 2003. “Returning to the Countryside versus Continuing to Work in the Cities: A Study on Rural Urban Migrants and Their Return to the Countryside of China,” Social Sciences in China 24, no. 4: 149-58. (in Chinese) Cai, Fang. 2001. “Institutional Barriers in Two Processes of Rural labor Migration in China,” Working Paper, Institute of Population Studies, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences. Cai, He and Jin Wang. 2007. “A Study on Migrant Workers’ Permanent Migration Intentions,” Sociological Research 6, 86-113. (in Chinese) Chen, Aimin. 2006. “Urbanization in China: The Case of Fujian Province,” Modern China 32, no. 1: 99-130. Chen, Baoliang. 1998. “To Be Defined as Liumang,” in Michael Dutton (ed.) Streetlife China. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 63-64. Chen, Feinian, Susan E. Short and Barbara Entwisle. 2000. “The Impact of Grandparental Proximity on Maternal Childcare in China,” Population Research and Policy Review 19: 571-90. Cho, Mun Young. 2009. “Forced Flexibility: A Migrant Woman's Struggle for Settlement,” The China Journal 61:51-76. Connelly, Rachel, Kenneth Roberts and Zhenzhen Zheng. 2008. “The Role that Children’s Education Plays in the Migration Decisions of Chinese Rural Women,” Presented at the 2008 IAFFE Conference, Turin Italy, June. Constant, Amelie and Douglas S. Massey. 2002. “Return Migration by German Guestworkers: Neoclassical versus New Economic Theories,” International Migration 40, no. 4: 5-36. Du, Yang, Albert Park and Sangui Wang. 2005. “Migration and Rural Poverty in China,” Journal of Comparative Economics 33: 688-709. Dustmann, Christian. 1996. “Return Migration: The European Experience,” Economic Policy 22: 214-450. Dustmann, Christian. 2003. “Children and Return Migration,” Journal of Population Economics 16: 815-30. Fan, C. Cindy. 2005. “Interprovincial Migration, Population Redistribution, and Regional Development in China: 1990 and 2000 Census Comparisons,” The Professional Geographer 57, no. 2: 295-311. Fan, C. Cindy (2004). “The State, the Migrant Labor Regime, and Maiden Workers in China. ” Political Geography, 23, no. 3: 283-305. Fudan University. 1997. “University Survey Assesses Migrant Population in Shanghai,” from Xinhua (Beijing) May 3. Ganga, Deianira. 2006. “From Potential Returnees into Settlers: Nottingham´s Older Italians,” Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 32, no. 8: 1395-413. Hondagneu-Sotelo, Pierrette. 1995. Gendered Transitions: Mexican Experiences of Immigration. Berkeley: University of California Press. Hu, Yuping. 2007. “Stay in Beijing or Go Home: The Analysis of Migrating Inclination of Floating Population in Beijing, ” Beijing Social Science, 5: 40-45. (in Chinese) Jacka, Tamara. 2006. Rural Women in Urban China: Gender, Migration, and Social Change. Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, Inc. Jacka, Tamara and Arianne Gaetano (eds.). 2004. On the Move: Women and Rural to Urban Migration in Contemporary China. New York: Columbia University Press. Johnson, D. Gale. 2000. “Agricultural Adjustment in China: Problems and Prospects,” Population and Development Review 26, no. 2: 319-34. Knight, John, Lina Song and Huaibin Jia. 1999. “Chinese Rural Migrants in Urban Enterprises: Three Perspectives,” The Journal of Development Studies 35, no. 3, Special Issue: The Worker's State Meets the Market: Labour in China's Transition, Sarah Cook and Margaret Maurer-Fazio (eds.): 73-104. Li, Bingqin and David Plachaud. 2006. “Urbanization and Social Policy in China,” AsiaPacific Development Journal 13, no. 1: 1-26. Liu, Shenghe, Xiubin Li and Ming Zhang. 2003. Scenario Analysis of Urbanization and Rural-Urban Migration in China. Institute of Geographic Sciences and Natural Resources Research, Chinese Academy of Sciences. Interim Report No. IR-03-036. Ma, Zhongdong. 2004. “Labor Migration as a New Determinant of Income Growth in Rural China,” paper presented at the annual meetings of the Population Association of America, Boston, Massachusetts, April 1-3. McCormick, Barry and Jackline Wahba. 2005. “Why Do the Young and Educated in LDCs Concentrate in Large Cities? Evidence from Migration Data,” Economica 72: 39-67. Moran-Taylor, Michelle and Cecilia Menjívar. 2005. “Unpacking Longings to Return: Guatemalans and Salvadorans in Phoenix, Arizona,” International Migration 43, no. 4: 91-119. Mu, Ren, and Dominique van de Walle. 2009. “Left Behind to Farm? Women's Labor Re-Allocation in Rural China,” The World Bank, Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 5107. Nielsen, Ingrid and Russell Smyth. 2007. “'Better City, Better Life' – For Whom?,” in Ingrid Nielsen, Russell Smyth, and Marika Vicziany (eds.), Globalisation and Labour Mobility in China. Victoria, Australia: Monash University Press, 101-17. No Place. 2007. “No Place to Call Home: China's Migrant Workers.” The Economist, June 9, 45. Orrenius, Pia Margareta. 1999. “Return Migration from Mexico: Theory and Evidence,” PhD Dissertation, University of California, Los Angeles. Pessar, Patricia. 2003. “Engendering Migration Studies: The Case of New Immigrants in the United States,” in Pierrette Hondagneu-Sotelo (ed.) Gender and U.S. Immigration: Contemporary Trends. Berkeley, California: University of California Press, 20-42. Qi, Changqing and Fan He. “Migrants Living in Urban Villages: a Case Study of Changfeng and Jinjiacao Village, Ningbo.” 2005. Reagan, Patricia B. and Randall J. Olsen. 2000. “You Can Go Home Again: Evidence from Longitudinal Data,” Demography 37, no. 3: 339-50. Ren, Yuan. 2006. “Gradually Settling Down: Analysis of Residence Patterns of the Floating Population in Shanghai,” Chinese Journal of Population Science (Zhongguo Renkou Kexue) no. 3: 67-72. Roberts, Kenneth. 2000. “Chinese Labor Migration: Insights from Mexican Undocumented Migration to the United States,” in Loraine A. West and Yaohui Zhao (eds.), Rural Labor Flows in China. Berkeley: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, 179-230. Roberts, Kenneth. 2002. “Female Labor Migrants to Shanghai: Temporary 'Floaters' or Settlers?” International Migration Review 36, no. 2: 492-519. Roberts, Kenneth, Rachel Connelly, Zhenming Xie and Zhenzhen Zheng. 2004. “Patterns of Temporary Migration of Rural Women from Anhui and Sichuan Provinces of China,” The China Journal no. 52: 49-70. Sassen, Saskia. 1999. Guests and Aliens. New York: The New Press. Sato, Hiroshi. 2006. “Housing Inequality and Housing Poverty in Urban China in the late 1990s,” China Economic Review 17: 37-50. Song, Lina. 1999. “The Role of Women in Labour Migration: A Case Study in Northern China,” in Jackie West, Mingua Zhao, Xiangqun Chang, and Yuan Cheng (eds.), Women of China: Economic and Social Transformation. New York: St. Martin's Press, 69-89. Sun, Zifa. 2005. “Hu Angang: Four Rural Issues Exist in China and the Issue of Migrant Peasant Workers is the Core.” Zhongguo Xinwen She, March 7. Taylor, J. Edward. 1999. “The New Economics of Labour Migration and the Role of Remittances in the Migration Process,” International Migration 37, no. 1: 63-86. UN-HABITAT. 2003. Guide to Monitoring Target 11: Improving the Lives of 100 Million Slum Dwellers. Global Urban Observatory, United Nations Human Settlements Programme. United Nations. 2006. World Urbanization Prospects: The 2005 Revision. United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. No. ESA/P/WP/200. Wang, Dewen, Fang Cai and Wenshu Gao. 2007. “Globalisation and the Shortage of Rural Workers: A Macroeconomic Perspective,” in Ingrid Nielsen, Russell Smyth, and Marika Vicziany (eds.), Globalisation and Labour Mobility in China. Victoria, Australia: Monash University Press, 19-38. Wang, Feng and Anan Shen. 2003. “Double Jeopardy? Female Rural Migrant Labourers in Urban China, the Case of Shanghai,” in Brígida García, Richard Anker, and Antonella Pinnelli (eds.), Women in the Labour Market in Changing Economies: Demographic Issues. International Studies in Demography, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 166-83. Wang, Shujun. 2006. “China's 2005 National 1% Population Sample Survey Shows Six Major Characteristics of the Country's Population Growth Over the Past Five Years,” from Renmin Ribao (Beijing) September 1, Cited in World News Connection, available at http://wnc.dialog.com/. Wu, Weiping. 2004. “Sources of Migrant Housing Disadvantage in Urban China,” Environment and Planning A 36, no. 7: 1285-304. Xinhua. 2005. “'Slums Sting Chinese Cities, Hamper Building of Harmonious Society,” from Xinhua (Beijing) September 8, Cited in World News Connection, available at http://wnc.dialog.com/. Xinhua. 2006a. “China's Law To Ensure Compulsory Education for Children of Migrant Workers,” from Xinhua (Beijing) August 31, Cited in World News Connection, available at http://wnc.dialog.com/. Xinhua. 2006b. “Public Schools Open Door To Migrant Students, But Many Reluctant To Go,” from Xinhua (Beijing) October 1, Cited in World News Connection, available at http://wnc.dialog.com/. Xinhua. 2006c. “Chinese Migrant Workers Earn Average Monthly Income of 120 Dollars,” from Xinhua (Beijing) October 22, Cited in World News Connection, available at http://wnc.dialog.com/. Xinhua. 2007. “Harmonising Hukou: Inequities in China's 'Hukou' Household Registration System,” from Xinhua (Beijing) May 3, Cited in World News Connection, available at http://wnc.dialog.com/. Zhang, Hong. 2009. “Labor Migration, Gender, and the Rise of Neo-Local Marriages in the Economic Boomtown of Dongguan, South China,” Journal of Contemporary China 18(61): 639-656. Zhang, Li. 2002. Strangers in the City: Space, Power, and Identity in China's Floating Population. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. Zhang, Linxiu, Alan de Brauw and Scott Rozelle. 2004. “China's Rural Labor Market Development and its Gender Implications,” China Economic Review 15, no. 2: 23047. Zhao, Yaowei. 2002. “Causes and Consequences of Return Migration: Recent Evidence from China,” Journal of Comparative Economics 30, no. 2: 376-94. Zhu, Yu. 2007. “China's Floating Population and their Settlement Intention in the Cities: Beyond the Hukou Reform,” Habitat International 31: 65-76.