Shared Fiscal Policy Challenges and Globalization: The Role of Cooperation Dennis Botman and Teresa Ter-Minassian1 May 2008 Abstract Spillover effects of macroeconomic policies become more pronounced as globalization proceeds. Externalities, and measures to address them, are particularly pronounced in the fiscal area, raising the question to what extent policy cooperation is desirable. We discuss three areas of increased fiscal interdependence: global aging, global warming, and tax competition. The world faces unprecedented demographic change over the next decades, which, if left unaddressed, leads to unsustainable debt trajectories. The fact that this is a global, rather than an individual country, challenge implies rapidly rising real interest rates. We show that an early, cooperated, fiscal response through a package of measures will minimize output and consumption losses, while complementary structural reforms are best handled at the individual country level. Similarly, climate change is a global externality requiring an early cooperative fiscal response, particularly regarding mitigation measures, while adaptation measures are best left to the private sector, possibly with support from individual governments. Globalization also puts pressure on the taxation of mobile factors of production. This can be observed in declining statutory corporate income tax rates in OECD economies, emerging markets, and developing countries. Some degree of tax competition may be beneficial and cooperation should not aim for harmonization of tax rates, but instead try to avoid harmful tax practices. These three challenges, and the measures to address them, pose important questions for social policy and coherence, within countries, between generations, and across nations. JEL Classification Numbers: E62, F41, F42, H30, H55, H62 Keywords: Global aging, global warming, tax competition, international fiscal policy cooperation. Author’s E-Mail Address: dbotman@imf.org and tterminassian@imf.org 1 Paper prepared for the conference on Social Policy: Vision and Reality, Jerusalem, May 2008. The authors would like to thank Steve Symansky, Michael Keen, and Sanjeev Gupta for many helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. 533571056 February 17, 2016 (4:13 PM) 2 I. INTRODUCTION This paper discusses recent work at the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in three areas of increased fiscal interdependence—global aging, global warming, and tax competition—and the potential role for international cooperation. The interactions between globalization and fiscal policy can be subtle and complex. With globalization, demographic change in one country has macroeconomic implications for its trading partners because of interactions through trade and financial market channels. International trade itself has been spurred by declining transportation costs, which in turn partly reflects that negative environmental externalities have not been priced properly into private sector decision-making. Finally, the process of globalization also directly affects the effectiveness and design of fiscal policy, as evidenced, for example, in tax competition and declining import tariff revenue following trade liberalization. That increased integration of goods and financial markets affects the effectiveness of fiscal policy is well understood. For example, in the classical Mundell-Fleming model, financial integration makes fiscal expansion more effective, as crowding out through higher domestic interest rates is reduced. Apart from a domestic risk premium, the interest rate in each country is highly correlated with the world real interest rate on which policies in an individual economy have little effect. In contrast, trade integration reduces the effectiveness of fiscal policy as part of the fiscal expansion falls on imported goods. Therefore, whether fiscal externalities are positive or negative depends critically on whether the financial or trade interaction dominates. In the first part of this paper, we discuss these interactions in the context of population aging using the IMF’s Global Fiscal Model (GFM). The GFM is largely a modified version of the Mundell-Fleming model in the new-open-economy-macroeconomics tradition. Often, the implications of demographic change are studied for individual countries, which tend to result in modest effects on real interest rates and debt service costs. However, taking into account that population aging will put pressure on public finances in all OECD economies—albeit not to the same extent and at the same moment—as well as emerging markets and developing countries, yields considerably larger effects on debt service costs. Indeed, as the world is a closed economy, one would expect that “global aging” would lead to considerable crowding out through higher interest rates, with little offset from increased international trade in goods and services. As such, the fiscal costs from aging give rise to negative international externalities, and measures to contain these costs are an international public good. In this context, we will analyze the effects of alternative fiscal measures, as well as supportive nonfiscal reforms that maintain public debt sustainability and the potential role for international cooperation. In addition to global aging pressures, global warming also has potentially significant macroeconomic effects. Emission of greenhouse gases poses a clear-cut negative externality, while measures to respond to it suffer from a classic “free-rider” problem. Dealing with 3 climate change is made difficult by its slow-moving, stock nature, by considerable uncertainty, coupled with the real possibility of catastrophe, by interactions with other market failures, and by the exhaustibility of fossil fuels. Nevertheless, it is widely recognized that an early, cooperative, policy response is required, with fiscal measures playing a key role. Indeed, the fiscal implications of climate change could be among its most powerful and immediate, affecting—in differing ways—all countries. This relates to the direct impact of global warming on tax bases and spending programs, but even more so to using fiscal instruments to mitigate the extent of climate change, and to adapt so as to limit the damage that remains. In this context, the paper discusses the role of alternative fiscal measures, the nature of international cooperation, and the potential macroeconomic effects of mitigating climate change. Globalization also directly affects the conduct of fiscal policy. For example, financial globalization can increase revenue volatility and give rise to contingent liabilities. Globalization could also have an impact on the expenditure side of budgets. There could be increased demand for public spending, in particular social protection to prevent rising income inequality, as well as further investment in human and physical capital to improve competitiveness. Some of these issues, however, do not require international cooperation. In this paper, we focus on the effects of globalization on the ability to tax mobile factors of production. There is evidence that tax competition has reduced statutory tax rates in OECD economies, emerging markets, and developing countries. At the same time, revenue from corporate income taxation in these countries has held up well, possibly pointing to base broadening, or to cyclical factors related to asset price developments. Tax competition is evidenced not only in reductions in statutory rates, but also in the proliferation of selective tax incentives, for example through tax holidays. The paper discusses these issues and the role for international cooperation to prevent harmful tax practices. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews the demographic trends in selected economies and their impact on debt sustainability; the pros and cons of alternative strategies to create fiscal space to accommodate aging-related spending pressures; and the spillover effects of global aging and fiscal consolidation. It also discusses the merits of international cooperation to put public finances on a sustainable footing, and the role and spillover effects of complementary structural reforms. Section III deals with possible fiscal measures for mitigating and adapting to climate change, their potential macroeconomic effects, and the role for policy cooperation. Section IV presents recent evidence on the extent and types of tax competition and the role for international policy cooperation. Section V concludes. 4 II. GLOBAL AGING2 A. The Analytical Framework To analyze the macroeconomic and spillover effects of demographic change, Botman and Kumar (2007) use the IMF’s Global Fiscal Model (GFM). GFM allows a quantification of the effects of population aging on interest rates, consumption, growth, and the spillover effects through trade and financial market channels. Specifically, GFM extends the newopen-economy-macroeconomics framework to incorporate sufficient non-Ricardian characteristics to allow for an analysis of the effects of fiscal policy and interdependence. GFM is described in more detail in Botman, Laxton, Muir, and Romanov (2006). There are three key reasons why full Ricardian equivalence does not hold in GFM. First, the model features overlapping generations in the spirit of Blanchard-Weil. The use of overlapping generations allows the assumption of Ricardian equivalence to be relaxed, implying that government debt is perceived as net wealth. Essentially, consumers have a short, and more realistic, planning horizon, which implies that even temporary changes in fiscal policy affect their incentives to consume and work as they discount any future fiscal policy reaction. Second, GFM incorporates the assumption that some consumers do not have sufficient access to financial markets to smooth their consumption over time. This is consistent with evidence that even in the advanced economies up to a third of the consumers are liquidity constrained. Liquidity-constrained agents consume their entire disposable income every period and therefore any change in fiscal policy that affects this disposable income will have real effects. Third, GFM allows labor supply and capital accumulation to be endogenous and respond to changes in incentives related to the after-tax real wage or the after-tax rate of return of capital. This in turn allows the model to incorporate distortionary taxes and analyze the consequences of changes in their rates. It should also be noted that capital mobility in GFM is perfect, implying that interest rates are set in world markets. As a result, especially for small open economies, the crowding-out effects of government debt via higher interest rates will tend to be smaller than with imperfect capital mobility. These features provide a useful benchmark for the analysis, especially regarding the medium- and long-term effects of fiscal policy. GFM also has a stylized financial sector block, with two types of assets, namely government debt (which can be traded internationally) and equity (which is assumed to be held domestically). Changes in the outstanding stock of debt have direct implications for long-term interest rates, which as a result of the perfect capital mobility assumption are transmitted internationally. 2 Most of the material in this section is drawn from Botman and Kumar (2007). 5 B. Global Demographic Pressures The budgetary challenges facing the EU countries from demographic trends have been analyzed extensively by the European Commission, country authorities, as well as a wide range of observers (see e.g., European Commission, 2006a and 2006b; Hauner, Leigh, and Skaarup, 2007). The assessment of the budgetary challenges is based on the projections by Eurostat that indicate on average a doubling of the old-age dependency ratio, defined as the ratio of population older than 65 relative to the working-age population, from 2005 to 2050 in the EU25 countries. Over this period, the modal age-cohorts move from mid-30s to late 50s. These changes are projected to exert significant upward pressure on age-related public expenditures, primarily for pensions and health care. For the EU25 as a whole, the average increase (weighted) in age related expenditures is projected at almost 3½ percent of GDP; for the EU15, it is 3¾ percent of GDP and for the new EU member states (EU10) it is ¼ percent of GDP. However, amongst the EU10, Poland has implemented a major pension reform that implies a marked decline in its pension expenditures—amounting to almost six percent of GDP. Excluding Poland, the average age related expenditures for EU10 are likely to increase by 4½ percent of GDP. If one considers separately the age related expenditures emanating from pensions and from health and long-term care, the following picture emerges. Pension expenditures are projected to increase by 2.3 percent of GDP on average in EU15 and by 0.3 percent of GDP in EU10 (excluding Poland the increase amounts to 4¾ percent of GDP). Health and long-term care spending is envisaged to increase by 2¼ percent of GDP in EU15 and by 1½ percent of GDP in EU10. The baseline scenario assumes that the increase in life expectancy will lead to some postponement of the need for additional care. The health care projection assumes an elasticity of demand higher than unity in the short-term, but this is expected to gradually decline to unity over the projection period. The projected increases in age-related spending and the sustainability gaps in other major countries and regions are also striking. In the case of the United States, in particular, the increase in age-related spending over 2005–50 is projected at about six percent of GDP, mostly on account of higher health care spending. Given the structural primary deficit of around 1¾ percent (2005), the U.S. faces a sustainability gap of around 7 percent of GDP (OECD, 2001; and Hauner, Leigh, and Skaarup, 2007).3 There are marked aging-related budgetary pressures also in Japan, where the initial conditions, both in terms of the large primary deficit and high debt levels, warrant substantial adjustment (Hauner, Leigh, and Skaarup, 2007, and Botman, Edison, and N’Diaye, 2007). Under announced policies, and taking into account current debt levels and structural fiscal positions, public debt dynamics appear unsustainable for all G-7 economies (Figure 1). 3 The estimated adjustment need is very sensitive to assumptions regarding the interest rate-growth differential. 6 Figure 1. G-7—Projected Cumulative Growth in Old-Age Population (dashed line, right-hand-side axis, in percent) and Increase in Age-Related Spending Relative to 2005 (in percentage points of GDP) 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 Source: Hauner, D., D. Leigh, and M. Skaarup, 2007. 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 0 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 20 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 2050 2050 2045 2040 2030 2035 160 United States 40 0 160 G7 average 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 2050 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 0 60 2045 20 80 2045 40 100 2040 60 120 2040 80 140 2035 100 0 160 United Kingdom 2035 120 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 20 2030 140 40 2030 160 60 2025 0 80 2025 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 20 100 2025 40 120 2020 60 140 2020 80 160 Italy 2020 100 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 2015 120 Japan 0 2005 140 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 20 2005 160 Germany 40 2005 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 0 60 2015 20 80 2015 40 100 2010 60 140 120 2010 80 160 France 2010 100 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 2010 140 120 2005 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 160 Canada 2005 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 7 Figure 2. Effects of Alternative Aging Cost Projections on Debt Dynamics in Germany 1/ (in percent of GDP) 350 Baseline: 4 percent of GDP aging costs by 2050 Maastricht debt limit 300 High aging costs (7.75 percent of GDP by 2050) Low aging costs (2.75 percent by 2050) 250 200 150 100 50 0 2007 2018 2029 2040 Source: Botman, D. and S. Danninger, 2007. 1/ Includes the estimated revenue from higher VAT rates in 2007 and revenue loss from lower social security contributions by workers and employers in 2007 and lower corporate income taxation in 2008. Aging is not limited to industrial countries: there are marked pressures in many major emerging markets also. Among the largest nine emerging markets,4 while the population in some is projected to grow substantially over the next four to five decades, the 65+ part of the populations is projected to increase significantly in all countries (between 150 and 400 percent), and the old-age dependency ratio is expected to, on average, triple by 2050. Korea faces the steepest increase, almost a five-fold increase, albeit from a favorable starting position with a sizable structural surplus (see Feyzioğlu, Skaarup, and Syed, 2007). There are also significant pressures in China and Russia, and the projected increase of the old-age dependency ratio in these countries is markedly higher than in the G7 countries, as are the projected age-related expenditures. 4 These include Argentina, Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Korea, Mexico, Russia, and Turkey. 8 There is considerable uncertainty surrounding these projections, not least arising from the impact of technology and the evolution of health care costs. In the case of Germany, according to EU estimates, the projected increase in age-related spending is somewhat below the EU average, rising by about 2¾ percent of GDP between 2004 and 2050. This is due to an increase in pension expenditures of around 1½ percent of GDP, which reflects the farreaching reforms that have been enacted (including the Agenda 2010 and Hartz reforms). The increase in health-care expenditure is projected to be 1¼ percent of GDP, lower than the EU average (see European Commission 2006b). In contrast, a more pessimistic view is expressed by the IFO Institute, with aging costs estimated at 7¾ percent (see Werding and Kaltschütz, 2005). Braumann and others (2006) employ a fiscal-aging cost profile in between these two scenarios. Figure 2 illustrates the sensitivity of the debt profile to these alternative aging costs assumptions. Despite this sensitivity, debt dynamics are unsustainable under current policies—even if we ignore the effect of population aging in other countries and the resulting pressure on real interest rates in Germany. C. Alternative Measures to Create Fiscal Space As debt seems unsustainable under current policies in a large number of countries, fiscal space needs to be created to address aging costs. Botman and Kumar (2007) discuss the macroeconomic effects of alternative fiscal measures to create this space, and the pros and cons of early versus delayed adjustment. Specifically, they find that revenue and expenditure measures have differing impacts on output and consumption. On the revenue side, Botman and Kumar (2007) quantify the required fiscal space to maintain debt below the Maastricht limit and the resulting output effects of these measures, using the GFM. The negative GDP growth impact of the different tax measures ranges from 0 to ¼ percent, with measures from most to least distortionary ranked as follows5: Raising corporate income taxation reduces incentives to save and invest, and is found to be the most distortionary form of taxation. Furthermore, it runs counter to recent trends to reduce taxation of capital and dividend (more on this in Section IV). Raising personal income taxation, possibly through base broadening, partly reduces incentives to save and invest and partly reduces labor supply. Raising payroll taxes on workers or employers negatively affects labor supply or demand, which runs counter to efforts to increase labor participation in many countries. 5 This ranking of revenue measures is consistent with Baylor (2005) and Bayoumi and Botman (2005). 9 Raising indirect taxes, for example the VAT, entails the smallest efficiency loss, and also protects the tax base in an aging society, but may be regressive compared to the other revenue measures (at least in the short term). Regarding measures on the expenditure side, entitlement reform (for example, raising the retirement age) have the smallest impact on growth. Reducing current government expenditure has the advantage of crowding-in private consumption, but nevertheless leads to a reduction in output, due to “home-bias” in government spending. Recent analysis has shown that the resulting welfare effects depend critically on the degree of substitutability between private and public consumption (Kumhof, Laxton, and Leigh, 2008). Reducing public investment entails the largest losses, given the relatively high social rate of return of public investment in most countries that face aging pressures. For Germany, achieving the required two percent of GDP adjustment during 2008–11 by relying exclusively on just one of the adjustment measures appears difficult, and the government likely will need to choose a combination of measures. For instance, reducing government spending—whether on goods and services or social security transfers—by 2 percentage points of GDP by 2011 implies unrealistically large cuts in discretionary spending. Similarly, further increases in the VAT rate are also limited (including as a result of EU regulations), although further base broadening would be possible by reducing the number of items under the lower (7 percent) VAT rate. Raising direct taxation is distortionary and runs counter to the government’s intentions to increase incentives for labor participation and investment. Therefore, these results suggest that in general, fiscal space should be created through a combination of measures (“package”), which should be gradually phased-in. Such a package should include raising indirect taxation combined with base broadening measures, entitlement reform (raising the retirement age, preventive care), and targeted expenditure cuts in social security transfers, and discretionary current government spending. Adjustment packages of this kind can maintain debt sustainability, while minimizing economic distortions. However, the details of the package will necessarily have to be country specific, depending on the size of tax distortions, the efficiency-equity trade-off, and political economy considerations. Prefunding future aging costs results in a reduction in real interest rates, by about 40 basis point in the medium term when government debt reaches a trough—the magnitude of this effect depends critically on how non-Ricardian consumers are. Although, given the size of the German economy, this effect is larger than would be observed in other euro area countries, it is relatively modest as Germany’s national savings rate still has only a limited effect on the global savings and investment balance. A higher VAT, and base broadening of income taxation imply reduced incentives for labor participation, and result in a decline in hours worked and an increase in the real wage. Investment responds positively through 10 “crowding-in” after debt starts to decline. Output gradually increases as a result, although it takes a long time before GDP returns to the level observed before the fiscal adjustment was initiated. As consumption declines, the real exchange rate depreciates, and the trade balance records stronger surpluses. Higher national saving results in increasing claims on the rest of the world through accumulation of net foreign assets. Higher interest earnings from the net foreign asset position imply that the current account remains above the initial steady-state level for a considerably longer period than consumption and the trade balance. D. Spillover Effects and the Role of International Cooperation In addition to analyzing debt dynamics under population aging in Germany in isolation, Botman and Kumar (2007) analyze simultaneous aging in Germany, the rest of the euro area, the U.S., and the rest of the world. For this purpose they calibrate GFM to these countries/blocks assuming aging costs by 2050 in Germany equal to four percent of GDP, in the rest of the euro area 4½ percent of GDP, and in the U.S. six percent of GDP, while assuming that the rest of the world faces no demographic change. This provides a lower bound estimate of the effect on real interest rates because, as discussed above, various other, large open economies will face aging pressures as well. The analysis assumes that each country implements a country-specific adjustment package to maintain debt below the Maastricht limit (euro area countries) or broadly at the current level (U.S.). The model is parameterized to reflect key macroeconomic features of Germany, as well as the rest of the euro area, the United States, and the rest of the world. In particular, the ratios of consumption, investment, wage income, and income from capital relative to GDP are set to their values in 2006. Similarly, key fiscal variables—revenue-to-GDP ratios from taxation of corporate and personal income, from VAT, and from social security contributions by workers and employers, as well as current government spending—have been calibrated to the fiscal structure of Germany, and that of the other regions. The macroeconomic effects of the simulations are presented relative to the baseline, which is the initial calibrated steady state. The key behavioral parameters are based on microeconomic evidence. These include parameters characterizing real rigidities in investment, markups for firms and workers, the elasticity of labor supply to after-tax wages, the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital, the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, and the rate of time preference. Taking into account aging pressures in the rest of the euro area and the United States adds a dramatic dimension to the debt dynamics due to Germany’s own aging profile (Figure 3). As the euro area and the U.S. face significant spending pressures from aging and, given weak starting fiscal positions, fiscal deficits increase, current account deficits emerge or increase, leading to higher real interest rates. Germany is an open economy implying that these higher rates will increase borrowing costs for the government on newly issued debt. This link between countries through international financial markets is the key spillover effect of global aging, and ignoring the interdependencies between countries will lead to a misleading 11 judgment about the macroeconomic outlook of a country, and the efficacy of a policy response. This pressure on global interest rates may be mitigated to some extent if entitlement reform occurs or is expected. In that case, optimizing, forward-looking, consumers—depending on the length of their planning horizons and on the expected magnitude of the reform—will save more today in anticipation of lower public pension benefits in the future. Also, in an aging society, the capital-labor ratio will likely increase, causing downward pressure on real interest rates. On the other hand, however, the debt trajectory in Figure 3 does not assume a positive risk premium—for example as a function of the level of government debt, or of net capital inflows—understating the likely effects of aging on real interest rates. Figure 3: Effects on German Debt Dynamics of Global Population Aging 1/ (in percent of GDP) 400 Aging in Germany alone Maastricht debt limit 350 Aging in Germany, euro area, and U.S. 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2007 2018 2029 2040 Source: Botman and Kumar, 2007. 1/ Includes the estimated revenue from higher VAT rates in 2007 and revenue loss from lower social security contributions by workers and employers in 2007 and lower corporate income taxation in 2008; aging-related expenditure costs are 4 percent of GDP by 2050. Increase in real interest rates consistent with evidence in Ford and Laxton (1999) who find that a 12.5 percent increase in debt in the OECD increased real interest rates by 100 basis points (on new debt) during the 1980s. Assumes aging costs of 4.5 percent of GDP by 2050 in the euro area and 6.0 percent in the U.S., with debt increasing by 17.5 percent by 2022. 12 Next, Botman and Kumar (2007) quantify whether the spillovers through financial market channels dominate those through trade channels and thus whether global aging gives rise to negative or positive international externalities. Specifically, they analyze a number of scenarios of early versus delayed creation of fiscal space. Figure 4. Effects on Real GDP in Germany of Fiscal Cooperation 1/ (Deviation from initial steady state in percentage points) Early cooperated adjustment 10 Germany delays Euro area delays US delays 6 2 -2 2007 2017 2027 2037 2047 Source: Botman and Kumar, 2007. First they consider all three countries/regions undertaking early joint action, and then each one delaying by 10 years, while the other two implement early adjustment. They also explore pair-wise delays (e.g., U.S. and rest of euro area delay by 10 years, while Germany continues with adjustment), and then all three delaying. A key result is that Germany benefits substantially from early fiscal adjustment in the rest of the euro area, and in the U.S. (Figure 4). Although exports decline relative to the initial steady state level following lower consumption in the two regions and therefore lower demand for imports from Germany, this is more than offset by the decline in real interest rates through financial linkages between 13 Germany and the euro area and the U.S. The result is an investment rebound and higher domestic demand in Germany.6 Delaying adjustment in Germany has short-term benefits, but substantial medium-term costs in terms of foregone output, as the adjustment will need to be more sizeable and interest rates increase during the intervening period. Similarly, while the euro area and the U.S. benefit, like Germany, in the short-run from delaying their respective adjustments and free riding on consolidation elsewhere, if all countries opt to postpone addressing this issue, each one loses. Under the early, cooperative, response, investment is significantly higher (through the interest rate channel), which initially also crowds in higher labor effort; consumption is also higher, and although there is now a weaker external balance, and correspondingly lesser accumulation of net foreign assets, there is a substantial benefit in terms of higher real output. Thus, the current account of each country improves less under the cooperative response than when an adjustment is initiated in isolation; the mirror image to these movements in the current account of reforming countries is a decline in the external balance of the rest of the world. However, there is a potential prisoner's dilemma: delaying adjustment avoids short-term output losses, while one benefits from others’ adjustment through lower interest rates (which more than offsets lower exports). Interestingly, political economy considerations can play an important role in determining whether a prisoner’s dilemma situation will emerge. If policymakers have a high discount rate, the non-cooperative solution in which all countries/regions delay adjustment could materialize, as this appears most attractive in the short term. The cooperative solution can be obtained as a decentralized equilibrium if policymakers aim to maximize the net present value of output and do not have a high discount rate. In this case, countries will optimally, individually, decide to prefund future aging costs. The adverse effects on Germany, the euro area and the U.S. of cooperative adjustment are not too pronounced—they are substantially less than a ¼ percentage point lower growth over the next decade, relative to all delaying.7 Although not negligible, the relatively small effects on 6 The differential effects on real interest rates between large and small economies implies an interesting hypothesis: large economies should have a greater incentive for prudent fiscal polices than small economies . Small economies with integrated capital markets have a smaller incentive to implement a fiscal contraction as the real interest rate will not decline much relative to larger open economies, or small closed or financially less integrated economies. On the other hand, and abstracting from the role of monetary policy, large open or relatively closed economies have a smaller incentive to use fiscal policy as a demand stabilizing instrument because of the stronger crowding out effects and smaller multipliers. 7 The short-term negative effects on growth of joint action could be larger if wages and prices are sticky, although for the U.S. and the euro area as a whole, monetary easing could mitigate output losses in that case. 14 global growth of early joint action also reflect the fact that the implementation of the package is assumed to be done in a gradual manner—about ½ percent a year, during six (Germany and the euro area) to ten years (for the U.S., which faces higher aging costs). The short-run negative effects of cooperative action would be much larger if all three implemented a significant adjustment over a very short period of time—although the benefits in terms of higher growth would then come sooner as well. Also, the adjustment does not occur in the whole world—the “rest of the world” (including Japan, China, India and other emerging markets accounting for over 40 percent of world GDP) is assumed not to undertake adjustment. Of course, if there were to be a slowdown in global growth because of other reasons, undertaking fiscal adjustment, even if gradual, would be procyclical. It should also be noted that the analysis in Botman and Kumar (2007) does not take into account the potential role of migration in maintaining debt sustainability. E. Complementary Structural Reforms Even under a cooperative, early, fiscal response, there will be short-term output and consumption losses. Botman and Kumar (2007) find that these losses can be mitigated, or even reversed, for the euro area countries if creating fiscal space is combined with expeditious implementation of the Lisbon Strategy. The Lisbon strategy adopted in 2000, entailed a wide-ranging program of economic, social and environmental reforms, designed to enhance growth and employment in the EU and allow it to compete more effectively in the global economy. The backdrop of the strategy was the exposure of EU countries to growing international competition, the needs of the knowledge-based economy, and demographic challenges. The strategy was reinforced in 2005 with a sharper focus on structural reforms to improve competitiveness, dynamism, and employment. Botman and Kumar (2007) analyze the macroeconomic effects of three key aspects of the Lisbon Agenda: increasing labor participation; higher R&D spending to help increase productivity; and greater product market competition to spur efficiency and higher growth: Increasing labor participation. In the simulations, stronger incentives for labor demand and especially labor supply together imply an increase in labor participation in Germany equal to 5 percent of the labor force over the five-year period. The participation rate for the euro area, excluding Germany, is around 62½ percent (see Central Planning Bureau, 2006). As a result, relatively more reform on both the demand and supply side will be needed to meet the target of a 70 percent participation rate for the euro area (compared to Germany where the starting position was 65 percent). Increasing labor participation by this amount has large positive effects on consumption and real GDP, offsetting most of the short-term costs from prefunding aging costs. However, because of the reduction in the real wage, overall consumption increases by less than output. 15 Higher R&D spending. In the simulations, Germany’s R&D intensity—defined as the share of R&D spending in GDP equal to 2½ percent in 2004—is assumed to increase to 3 percent by 2010. For the euro area, excluding Germany, R&D spending is about 2.1 percent of GDP and, to reach the goal of 3 percent of GDP spending by 2010, the required increase in R&D spending is 40 percent. The increase in productivity leads to lower consumer, producer, and export prices, causing a negative terms of trade effect. Consumption will therefore increase by less than the increase in GDP. Increasing product market competition. In the simulations, higher product market competition is formalized through a reduction in firms’ markups. Increasing competition across firms reduces the price markup as these firms increase output, since the demand curves they face have become more elastic. Product market reform has a significantly positive effect on output in the medium and long run. There is a marked increase in the capital stock, reflecting the reduced incentives to limit investment and labor demand to maintain monopolistic rents. The reform has large positive effects on the real wage. However, in the long run, the increase in output benefits capital more than labor effort (or hours worked) since labor is the less elastic resource (see also Bayoumi, Laxton and Pesenti, 2004). It is notable that output expands considerably if Germany implements the full Lisbon strategy and meets all its objectives (Figure 5). In addition, consumption, for both the “wealthy, optimizing” consumers and the “low-income, rule-of-thumb” consumers increases, more than compensating for any losses from the fiscal adjustment. As such, prefunding aging costs through fiscal cooperation and structural reform are complementary, as the near-term contractionary effects of adjustment are ameliorated by the reforms, which yield substantial benefits in their own right. Interestingly, most of the gains from structural reforms accrue to the reforming country (lefthand panel in Figure 5). Thus, spillover effects of such reforms appear to be modest and there will be less need for international cooperation in this area. Figure 5 (second panel) also shows an alternative scenario of partial and delayed achievement of the Lisbon objectives, which has the implication that the short-term output and consumption losses from prefunding of future aging costs cannot be reversed. Since the initial adverse effects of fiscal adjustment are not offset by reforms, policymakers may be inclined to postpone, or implement more gradual, fiscal adjustment, both in Germany and the rest of the euro area. This in turn reinforces the finding that, to avoid large negative consequences for output, and to maintain intra— and intergenerational equity, early cooperative fiscal adjustment and full implementation of country-specific structural reforms are essential. 16 Figure 5: Fiscal Cooperation and the Lisbon Agenda: Effects on real GDP in Germany (Deviation from initial steady state in percentage points unless otherwise noted) Achievement of Lisbon Strategy Delayed and Partial Achievement of Lisbon Strategy 35.0 Germany implements full Lisbon Agenda Cooperation only Euro area implements full Lisbon Agenda 30.0 34.0 Full implementation 30.0 Partial and delayed implementation 26.0 25.0 22.0 20.0 18.0 15.0 14.0 10.0 10.0 5.0 6.0 0.0 2.0 -2.0 -5.0 2007 2017 2027 2037 2047 2007 2017 2027 2037 2047 Source: Botman and Kumar, 2007. III. FISCAL IMPLICATIONS OF CLIMATE CHANGE8 A. Introduction Climate change (CC) is a global externality, and a uniquely complex one: Costs of mitigation come long before benefits (hence the discount rate is critical). Global temperature depends not on the current flow of emissions but on the cumulative stock, with emissions taking decades to have their full effect and decay. Thus, there is a strong intertemporal mismatch between the (early) costs and (late) benefits of reducing emissions. This raises issues of inter-generational distribution, with views on the appropriate discount rate, largely reflecting differing ethical judgments, becoming critical in assessing alternative policy responses (see for instance Stern and others (2007) and the collection of papers in the recent Journal of Economic Literature (Vol. 45, number 3)). Considerable uncertainty and risk of catastrophe, and irreversibilities. The relationships between emissions, policy interventions, market responses, and economic damage remain very uncertain. Interaction with other market failures, such as R&D, and the pre-existing tax system. Innovation in mitigation and adaptation, for example, may convey spillover benefits that the innovators cannot fully capture, which raises questions of policy 8 Most of the material in this section is drawn from International Monetary Fund (2008a and 2008b). 17 support. The design of mitigation instruments may be affected by their impact on government revenue and the wider tax system. Free-rider problem, requiring international cooperation. Countering global warming requires slowing and then (starting in 2020–40) cutting global greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions (by 60–80 percent). But each country would prefer others to shoulder the costs of doing so—a classic “free-rider” problem. The coordination challenge this poses is amplified by asymmetries in the physical impact of climate change and past emissions. Emissions have the same effects wherever they arise, but those effects differ greatly across countries (being most adverse in lower-income countries). So does responsibility for current concentration levels: high-income economies generated about 80 percent of past fossil fuel-based emissions, and hence account for much of the prospective damage. But, limiting that damage requires that others also cut emissions because, within a decade, most emissions will come from outside the OECD. Asymmetric interests and views on historical responsibility further complicate identifying generally acceptable policy responses. Climate change, and measures to respond to it, have potentially significant macroeconomic effects. The potential economic consequences include productivity changes in agriculture and other climate-sensitive sectors, damage to coastal areas, stresses on health and water systems, changes in trading patterns and international investment flows, financial market disruption (and innovation), increased vulnerability to sudden adverse shocks, and altered migration patterns—all with potential implications for external stability (International Monetary Fund, 2008a, p. 5). The fiscal implications of CC could be quite large, will affect all countries, but in different ways. Climate developments will directly affect fiscal positions, through their impact on tax bases and spending programs. But, potentially even more important, and urgent, is the case for purposive use of fiscal instruments in mitigating the extent of CC and adapting to it, so as to limit the damage that remains. Adaptation, for the most part, is a matter for local, national and regional responses – in strengthening sea defenses, for example, or improving management of water systems. While financing these expenditures raises important issues of burden sharing, the direct international spillovers thus appear to be limited. As a result, the discussion here focuses on the mitigation side. B. Fiscal Aspects of Mitigation and the Role for Cooperation Fiscal measures can play a key role in mitigating the extent of climate change and adapting to limit the damage that remains. Of course, fiscal instruments are not the only way to reduce GHG emissions, but can be particularly well targeted. Performance standards for cars, for example, limit fuel used per mile traveled but do not charge drivers for the emissions from the marginal mile traveled. Preferences and traditions in the relative use of regulatory and 18 fiscal instruments vary, but the best-targeted policy is to charge an appropriate price for GHG emissions. The classic prescription to deal with the externality at the heart of CC is to impose a ‘carbon price,’ equal to the marginal social damage from emissions. This ensures that emitters’ decisions reflect the full social consequences and, not least, serves as an efficient anchor for innovative activity. And what matters, as argued in International Monetary Fund (2008a, p.9) is not simply, or even mainly, the initial level of such a price, but the confident expectation of a modest but sustained increase over time. The future path of the carbon price, and its credibility, are critical, for several reasons. In particular, since energy investments are commonly made for the long term—possibly decades—and with substantial sunk costs, efficient decision-making requires confidence on the future course of carbon prices. So too do incentives to innovate. And current emissions are the counterpart of current extraction decisions by owners of fossil fuels, which depend on future as well as current prices. Pigovian policy requires a steady increase in the real carbon price. Efficiency requires—absent other market failures—that this carbon price be the same for all emissions, however and wherever they arise. The social damage from CO2 emissions being the same wherever in the world they arise, efficiency requires that marginal abatement costs also be the same. This requires identical carbon prices: otherwise the same emissions reduction could be achieved more cheaply by raising the carbon price on fuels, or in regions, where it is low, and decreasing it where it is high. As such, the fully cooperative approach involves a uniform carbon price in all countries, with cross-country transfers addressing equity concerns. Country-specific transfers may also be required within countries to address equity concerns as, in both developed and developing countries, increased fossil fuel prices are likely to have a regressive impact. It should be noted, however, that earmarking revenue from carbon pricing is generally undesirable—except that it may help overcome political resistance. A carbon price can be implemented in a number of ways: including through a carbon tax, by cap-and-trade—allocate a fixed total of rights to emit, but allow them to be bought and sold—or by hybrids combining features of each. There is a large literature on this instrument choice problem, reviewed in IMF (2008a). The choice has implications, not least, for international macroeconomic performance and adjustment. Under a global cap-and–trade scheme, for instance, faster growth in one country will tend to drive up the permit price and so have an adverse impact on other countries that tends to offset the traditional expansionary effect through the trade route; under a common tax scheme, there may be a similar effect through an increase in the price of the underlying resource, but the adverse spillover is likely to be much less (McKibbin and Wilcoxen, 2004). Depending on how rights are initially allocated across countries, moreover, cap-and-trade schemes can lead to significant international flows, or even to Dutch disease problems for large sellers of permits. 19 One important aspect of mitigation—especially given the fiscal challenges discussed elsewhere in this paper—is its potential as a source of government revenue. Receipts from carbon pricing—whether as tax revenue or from auctioning emission rights—can ease pressures on public finances, which could be used to support climate related R&D, prefund future aging costs, or as discussed in Section IV, offset pressure on tax revenue as a direct result from increased international competition. Revenue from carbon pricing may, for instance, assist governments to cope with revenue pressures from international tax competition or trade reform. How large this revenue might be remains uncertain. Estimates in IMF (2008a) suggest that it might in some regions amount to 1-2 percent of GDP: sizable, though by no means transforming the fiscal outlook. It might be tempting to suppose that carbon pricing can thus yield a “double dividend” in the sense of not only mitigating CC but also improving the overall efficiency of the tax system— in which case it would be optimal to set the carbon price above the Pigovian level. But this is much less clear-cut. For, in addition to the beneficial “revenue recycling” effect just described, there is a “tax interaction” effect: carbon pricing will affect the distortions caused by the pre-existing tax system. By raising the consumer price of energy-intensive goods, for instance, it would have effects similar to a reduction in the after-tax wage, and thus reinforce the distortionary impact of labor taxes—implying an optimal carbon price below the Pigovian level. In any event, the best use of additional revenue from carbon pricing, including to offset any adverse equity impact (discussed below) will vary with countries’ circumstances. While the case for some degree of cooperation in dealing with CC is clear, many obstacles to this remain (International Monetary Fund, 2008a): Competitiveness and leakage —at the heart of the free-rider problem is each country’s fear that unilateral action would disadvantage producers of energy-intensive products (such as aluminum, paper, steel, and international transport) in world markets. Furthermore, 25 countries cause about 80 percent of emissions, but wider agreement is likely to be needed for efficient and effective mitigation. “Leakage” (shifting of emissions to nonparticipants) is also a concern. Implementation—how to assure each participant that others are meeting their commitments? Furthermore, what account should be given to pre-existing taxes and other measures? There are a number of options to encourage cooperation in taking mitigation measures. Rather than adopting a uniform carbon price, countries could adopt minimum carbon tax rates. There has also been much discussion of border tax adjustments (BTA)— imposing a carbon charge on imports from countries not levying one, and perhaps remitting the carbon tax for exports. This has the merit of preserving mitigation in respect of domestic consumption without impacting international competitiveness. Moreover, it is one of the few credible devices by which countries implementing carbon pricing can encourage participation 20 by others: participants gain, presumably, from the BTA; and nonparticipants would then benefit by imposing a carbon price themselves, since by doing so they would capture revenue otherwise accruing to others. Against this, however, BTA risks hiding tariffs or export subsidies, and may be WTO-inconsistent. It also raises many practical issues, including the need to assess carbon prices implicit in taxes paid abroad (perhaps in a chain of production activities across several countries). Overarching the issue is a need for greater coherence in national energy tax policies. The diversity of fiscal and other instruments of energy policy complicates cross-country comparisons, impeding effective coordination. There is scope in many countries for taking inventory of significant measures in place, so as to assess their coherence, transparency, and effectiveness. C. Macroeconomic Effects of Mitigating Measures What would mitigation measures of the kind above mean for macroeconomic performance? The recent World Economic Outlook investigates this, using the 2007 version of the G-cubed model (see International Monetary Fund, 2008b). G-cubed is a dynamic intertemporal global general equilibrium model developed by McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1998) and is well suited for evaluating the short-, medium-, and long-term effects of mitigation policies across countries. Detailed modeling of regions helps account for differences in countries’ initial income levels and potential growth rates. Disaggregated production structures summarize the input-output relationships and sectoral cost structures. Forward-looking expectations underscore the importance of policy credibility for inducing changes in behavior (International Monetary Fund, 2008b, p.31). The simulations assume that the goal of policymakers is to keep global emissions 96 percent below the baseline of no-policy change, or achieve a 60 percent reduction from the 2002 level, in 2100. International Monetary Fund (2008b) compares the macroeconomic effects under either a uniform carbon tax, under a cap-and-trade policy, or under a hybrid policy. In addition to these main policy experiments, the model is used to explore implications of policy coordination, country participation, technological improvements, and the robustness of mitigation policies to macroeconomic shocks. The focus is on the costs rather than the potential benefits of mitigation policies during the three decades following their introduction. Simulation results in G-Cubed are largely driven by assumptions about countries’ technologies, particularly their ability to substitute away from emission-intensive inputs. Country-specific results in G-Cubed depend to a large extent on assumptions about elasticities of substitution in production, consumption, and trade, which jointly determine the incremental costs at which individual economies can reduce their emissions. In the policy experiment, all economies introduce a common carbon price in 2013 and credibly commit to keeping it in place over the long run, adjusting the rate as necessary to 21 achieve the profile of global emissions at the levels mentioned above. The results for the effects of a uniform carbon tax on real GDP are illustrated in Figure 6. There is considerable cross-region variation, with the output loss being modest in most regions, but sizable in China and the OPEC countries. After the imposition of the carbon tax, firms change their technology, substituting away from carbon-intensive inputs and into capital (including noncarbon alternative technologies), materials, and labor. Households alter their consumption patterns, also substituting away from carbon-intensive goods. With higher carbon prices raising costs for firms, productivity and output decline. Aggregate investment falls because the average marginal product of capital is lower in each region, while consumption declines, following real incomes. The levels of real activity fall permanently relative to the baseline. As discussed in more detail in International Monetary Fund (2008b), changes in national levels of GNP and consumption reflect countries’ costs of reducing emissions. Each economy’s marginal abatement costs (MACs) in G-Cubed depend on how intensely it uses carbon-based energy to produce goods for domestic consumption and for export, which in turn are driven by such factors as energy efficiency, factor endowments, and the production and export structure. The relatively high level of carbon intensity of the Chinese economy will be reduced as firms and households use energy more efficiently. The same is true for OPEC members and the United States, albeit to a lesser extent. Given a uniform carbon price, economies reduce emissions up to the point at which they have the same MACs. Economies with lower MACs undertake more emission reductions. China, in particular, reduces emissions by the most, followed by the United States and OPEC members. The macroeconomic effects of introducing a global cap-and-trade system—fixing a global emissions level corresponding to the same reductions as above—are similar, the main difference being in the international flows that arise as a consequence of international trade in permits. For most economies, these transfers are small, and hence the macroeconomic effects are similar to a uniform carbon tax; for China (a recipient), other emerging and developing economies (payers), and OPEC members (recipients), transfers reach about 10 percent, – 2 percent, and 1 percent of GDP, respectively, by 2040. China receives the largest transfers because it is comparatively inefficient in the use of energy and can reduce emissions at much lower costs than other economies. Advanced economies, as well as other emerging and developing economies, buy emission rights from China because emission reductions are very costly for these countries. 22 Figure 6. Effects on Real GDP of a Uniform Carbon Tax (Deviation from the baseline in percent) United States Japan Eastern Europe and Russia Western Europe OPEC China Other developing and emerging economies 0 -5 -10 -15 -20 -25 2013 20 30 40 Source: IMF, 2008b. IV. CORPORATE INCOME TAX COMPETITION A. Trends in Corporate Tax Rates and Revenue Globalization reduces the ability to tax mobile factors of production, creating incentives for tax competition (see International Monetary Fund, 2007). Specifically, as globalization proceeds, countries are pressured to reduce corporate income tax (CIT) rates, to attract/protect real investment and moderate incentives for tax avoidance (e.g., through transfer pricing). Although the debate on tax competition usually focuses on corporate income taxation, increased international mobility of labor (migration) could also lead over time to erosion of the tax base for social security contributions and other taxes levied on labor. Insofar as high-skilled labor is more mobile than low-skilled labor this would also reduce the ability to use payroll taxation for redistribution purposes. Indeed, there has been a marked decline in statutory corporate income tax rates in industrial countries (Figure 7), emerging markets in Asia, Latin America, and Europe (Figure 8), and in new EU member states (Figure 9). Nevertheless, corporate income tax revenue has held up well, which could reflect a number of reasons: Base broadening—indeed effective tax rates have declined less than statutory rates. This could reflect in particular a trend to reduce, or in some cases eliminate, a preferential tax treatment of debt financing. 23 The role of asset prices—asset prices can have a significant effect on revenue buoyancy, which is not fully reflected in the calculation of cyclically-adjusted balances. A higher share of profits in the economy, increased volatility of profits (which can affect favorably tax collection in the event of imperfect loss offset), and stronger incentives for firms to incorporate. Figure 7. Tax Competition in Industrial Countries Average Corporate Income Tax Rates and Revenue in Industrial Countries (Average across countries) (In percent) 5 50 12 Statutory Tax Rate In percent of total tax revenue (right scale) 45 4 10 40 35 8 Effective Average Tax Rate 3 6 30 2 In percent of GDP (left scale) 25 4 1 20 2 Effective Marginal Tax Rate 15 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 0 1980 Sources: Institute for Fiscal Studies and Fund staff calculations. 1985 1990 1995 2000 0 2005 Source: OECD Revenue Statistics 2006. Figure 8. Tax Competition in Emerging Markets Statutory Corporate Income Tax Rates and Revenue in Emerging Market Countries (Average across countries) (Averages across groups of countries, in percent) 10 35 In percent of total government revenue (right scale) 8 Latin America and Asia 30 20 15 6 Overall 25 10 Europe 4 20 15 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Sources: KPMG 's Corporate and Indirect Tax Rate Survey 2007 and University of Michigan. 2007 5 In percent of GDP (left scale) 2 0 1990 0 1992 1994 Source: FAD database. 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 24 Debrun (2008) evaluates the potential links between asset prices and corporate income revenue in G7 economies. The analysis is based on various econometric estimates of the short-term elasticity of revenues to house and stock price cycles (over and above the effect that the latter have on the business cycle). In general, the revenue effect is found to be quantitatively important, which could explain why corporate tax revenue has held up well despite lower statutory tax rates. In many regions, corporate income tax competition does not take the form of lowering statutory rates, but instead leads to the proliferation of special economic incentives, in particular tax holidays. Despite the lack of conclusive evidence on their effectiveness in attracting and sustaining investments (including FDIs), and despite their often significant cost in terms of foregone revenues, tax incentives and tax holidays continue to proliferate especially in developing countries.9 Figure 9. Tax Competition in Old and New EU Member States (In percent) Statutory Corporate Income Tax Rates in Old and New EU Member States, 1995-2006 40.0 35.0 30.0 25.0 20.0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 15 old member states 10 new member states Source: Keen, 2008. Botman, Klemm, and Baqir (2008) compare the general tax provisions and investment incentives in seven east-Asian economies—the Philippines, Malaysia, Indonesia, Lao, 9 Although there is considerable evidence that differences in international taxation affect the volume, location, and character of FDI in developed economies—see Gordon and Hines (2002)—the evidence on tax holidays in emerging markets is more negative, as detailed in Guin-Siu (2004). 25 Vietnam, Cambodia, and Thailand. To facilitate these comparisons, they calculate effective tax rates, which consider the overall structure of taxation including the manner in which a project is financed (debt versus equity), the length of tax holidays, the depreciation methods and allowances, interest-deductibility rules, the general corporate income tax rate, and the after tax profitability of an investment project in the different countries. The latter is assumed to equal zero percent (giving the effective marginal tax rate), twenty, respectively fifty percent. They find that investment incentives are broadly comparable in these countries and reduce effective tax rates considerably (Figure 10). In Sub-Saharan African countries too, corporate income tax rates have declined (although they remain high by international comparisons), while revenue has remained stable (Figure 11). The stability of revenue occurred despite a proliferation of incentives. In 1980, 3% of these countries had free zones with tax benefits, while in 2005, 45% did. During the same period, the proportion of countries offering tax holidays rose from 45% to 71%. Figure 10. Reduction in Effective Tax Rates From Receiving the Maximum Tax Holiday 1/ (In percentage points) Figure 10b. Debt financed; plant and machinery; Figure 10a. Equity financed; plant and machinery; 80 0 EMTR EATR p = .20 EATR p = .50 60 -5 40 -10 20 -15 EMTR EATR p = .20 EATR p = .50 -20 0 -20 Figure 10c. Equity financed; buildings; Vietnam Lao P.D.R. Indonesia Vietnam Lao P.D.R. Indonesia Vietnam Lao P.D.R. Indonesia Malaysia Thailand Cambodia Philippines Malaysia EATR p = .50 -35 Thailand -20 Cambodia -15 EATR p = .50 Philippines -5 -30 EMTR EATR p = .20 40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 -30 -40 -50 -10 EMTR EATR p = .20 Malaysia Figure 10d. Debt financed; buildings; 0 -25 Thailand Cambodia Philippines Vietnam Lao P.D.R. Indonesia Malaysia Thailand Cambodia -40 Philippines -25 Source: Botman, Klemm, and Baqir, 2008. 1/ EMTR refers to the effective marginal tax rate, which is calculated for an investment project that breaks even and which measures the size of the investment conditional on its location. EATR refers to the effective average tax rate, which determines the location of investment. As depreciation methods and rates vary between investments in plant and machinery respectively investment in buildings, these effective tax rates are calculated seperately. 26 Tax holidays are generally not well targeted, and are therefore regarded as the most damaging form of tax incentives, posing significant dangers to the wider tax system. One advantage of tax holidays—as opposed to other forms of tax subsidies—is that they provide benefits up front. Indeed, Doyle and van Wijnbergen (1984) show that an initial period of tax concessions followed by a gradually rising tax rate can be the outcome of a sequential bargaining process between firms that incur fixed costs of investment and the government. Nevertheless, although all forms of tax incentives carry some disadvantages, tax holidays in particular are generally not recommended for the following reasons. First, tax holidays are not cost effective because profits are exempted regardless of their amount. The most profitable investments, which would have taken place in any event, benefit most, as shown in Botman, Klemm, and Baqir (2008). Second, the same authors show that tax holidays are most attractive for footloose industries that tend to exit the country at the end of the holiday period. These industries are likely to bring the smallest benefit to the overall economy. Instead, firms investing in long-lived assets, whose revenues may not fully recover costs during the period of the holiday, benefit least from tax holidays. Third, tax holidays are open to abuse and provide many opportunities for tax avoidance (for instance by using transfer pricing or other devices to shift earnings into holiday companies). This is especially true for countries with weak revenue administrations and insofar as leakage occurs from special economic zones. Finally, if the home country of the foreign investor operates a worldwide system of taxation, without tax sparing, then the impact of the holiday may be diluted once profits are repatriated. Figure 11. Tax Competition in Sub-Saharan Africa (In percent) 20.0 3.0 15.0 2.0 10.0 1.0 5.0 0.0 0.0 CIT Revenue / GDP Source: Keen, 2008. Average CIT rate (right axis) 2004 4.0 2002 25.0 2000 5.0 1998 30.0 1996 6.0 1994 35.0 1992 7.0 1990 40.0 1988 8.0 1986 45.0 1984 9.0 1982 50.0 1980 10.0 27 Because of these reasons, it is frequently argued that it is more efficient to have a low uniform corporate income tax rate than selective incentives for companies through holidays. In case there is a need for further investment incentives, these are best targeted if directly conditioned on the investment activity, for example, by offering accelerated depreciation. However, as argued in Botman, Klemm, and Baqir (2008), without regional cooperation to move in this direction, it will be difficult to achieve unilateral reform, as replacing holidays with a general reduction in the CIT rate and offering accelerated depreciation will either not provide the same incentives for localization of new investment, or be very costly. B. Globalization, Tax Rates, and International Cooperation Are these trends of lower statutory corporate rates and the proliferation of special incentives likely to continue? Is there a race to the bottom, and is this good? In general, a certain degree of tax competition can be welfare-enhancing, but corporate revenue is still an important source of revenue for many countries, there are equity concerns, and there is a clear risk of beggar-thy-neighbor policies. Policy coordination has proven to be difficult not least because it is unclear what form it should take. Indeed, harmonization of tax rates may be unnecessary, while in principle a minimum rate could benefit all countries. However, acting on rates alone is not enough as the tax bases and/or procedures matter as well. Furthermore, some countries gain from tax competition, while others lose, and compensating international transfers may be hard to arrange. Rather than trying to achieve an international uniform corporate income tax rate, cooperation should aim to avoid harmful tax practices. In this regard, the main initiative is the OECD harmful tax practice project, which has come to focus on information sharing. In addition, codes of conduct, or treaties, proscribing certain practices have recently been adopted (or are under discussion) in the EU, Central America-Panama-DR, and other regions (see Keen, 2008). Globalization has not only been associated with a reduction in corporate income tax rates. Trade liberalization has also resulted in pressure on tariff revenue, which is still an important source of revenue in many developing and emerging market economies—about one-quarter of tax revenue in Sub-Saharan Africa, for example (Figure 12). In the early stages, trade liberalization may actually increase revenue from trade taxes as a result of tariffication, removal of exemptions, and cutting prohibitive tariffs. However, at some point further liberalization will reduce trade tax revenue. Trade liberalization may thus be blocked, or become less beneficial, unless revenue can be recovered from domestic sources. The conventional view has been that revenue recovery should occur by matching tariff cuts with increases in indirect taxes, so that consumer prices 28 are unchanged, production efficiency improves, and revenue increases. However, there are a number of qualifications to this argument, including the treatment of imported intermediates and recent suggestions that tariffs may be preferable to VAT in that they reach the informal sector, although it should be noted that VAT is also imposed at the border and is equivalent to an import tariff if the VAT is not credited (see Keen, 2008). Have countries in practice managed (or chosen) to recover lost trade tax revenues by increasing domestic taxes? Baunsgaard and Keen (2006) find for a large panel of low and middle-income countries during 1980-2000, that for middle-income countries, recovery from reductions in trade tax revenue is about one-for-one, but recovery is low—about 30 percent, at best—for low-income countries. Furthermore, there appears to be no systematic tendency for the presence of a VAT, by itself, to improve recovery. The choice of revenue recovery measures following trade liberalization does not require international cooperation, but instead is best left to the country implementing the reform. Figure 12. Trade Liberalization and Tax Revenue in Low and Middle-Income Countries (In percent) Low-income countries Middle-income countries 25 25 Total tax revenue Total tax revenue Trade revenue 20 20 15 15 10 10 5 5 Trade revenue 0 0 1975-79 1980-84 1985-89 1990-94 1995-2000 1975-79 1980-84 1985-89 1990-94 1995-2000 Source: Keen, 2008. V. CONCLUSIONS Spillover effects of macroeconomic policies become more pronounced as globalization proceeds. Externalities, and measures to address them, are particularly pronounced in the fiscal area, raising the question to what extent policy cooperation is desirable. This paper has discussed three areas of increased fiscal interdependence: global aging, global warming, and tax competition. 29 The world faces unprecedented demographic change over the next decades, which, if left unaddressed, will lead to unsustainable debt trajectories in advanced, emerging, and developed economies. The fact that this is a global, rather than an individual country, challenge implies rapidly rising real interest rates and therefore debt-service costs. Analyses using the IMF’s Global Fiscal Model suggest that spillover effects through financial market channels dominate those through trade channels, giving rise to negative externalities from population aging. Maintaining sustainable public finances requires creating fiscal space for age-related spending which should be gradual and broad based, relying on revenue (base broadening, indirect taxes) and expenditure measures (entitlement reform, rationalization of current government spending), while avoiding higher direct taxation. The composition of the package is best left to the country implementing the reform. However, international cooperation on the timing of implementing such a country-specific package would yield substantial benefits. We argued that an early, cooperative response through a package of fiscal measures will minimize output and consumption losses, while complementary structural reforms are best handled at the individual country level. Similarly, climate change is a global externality requiring an early cooperative fiscal response, particularly regarding mitigation measures, while adaptation measures are best left to the private sector, possibly with support from individual governments. The cooperative response should feature a uniform carbon price, increasing over time. Such a response would have significant and permanent macroeconomic implications, especially for countries with low marginal abatement costs. To encourage cooperation, rather than adopting a uniform carbon price, countries could adopt a minimum carbon tax rate, possibly in combination with selective border tax adjustments— imposing the tax on imports, and, perhaps, remitting the carbon tax for exports. Globalization also puts pressure on the taxation of mobile factors of production and on revenue from import tariffs. This can be observed in declining statutory corporate income tax rates or the proliferation of special incentives in OECD economies, emerging markets, and developing countries. Trade liberalization has also led to a decline in tariff revenue for lowand middle-income countries. Some degree of tax competition may be beneficial and realistically cooperation should not aim at harmonization of tax rates, bases, or procedures, but instead focus on the prevention of harmful tax practices. In addition, the implementation of revenue recovery measures following trade liberalization is best left to individual countries. These three challenges, and the measures to address them, pose important questions for social policy and coherence, within countries, between generations, and across nations. 30 VI. REFERENCES Baunsgaard, T. and M. Keen, 2006, “Tax revenue and (or?) trade liberalization,” Mimeo. (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Baylor, M., 2005, “Ranking Tax Distortions in Dynamic General Equilibrium Models: A Survey,” Working Paper 2005–06 (Ottawa: Department of Finance). Bayoumi, T., D. Laxton, and P. Pesenti, 2004, Benefits and Spillovers of Greater Competition in Europe: A Macroeconomic Assessment, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. No. 182. Bayoumi, T. and D. Botman, 2005, Jam Today or More Jam Tomorrow? On Cutting Taxes Now Versus Later, Canada-Selected Issues, IMF Country Report No. 05/116 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Botman, D., D. Laxton, D. Muir, and A. Romanov, 2006, “A New Open Economy Macromodel for Fiscal Policy Evaluation,” IMF Working Paper 06/45 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Botman, D. and S. Danninger, 2007, “Tax Reform and Debt Sustainability in Germany: An Assessment Using the Global Fiscal Model,” IMF Country Report No. 06/436 and IMF Working Paper 07/46 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Botman, D., H. Edison, and P. N’Diaye, 2007, “Strategies for Fiscal Consolidation in JapanSelected Issues,” IMF Country Report No. 06/276 and IMF Working Paper 07/37 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Botman, D., A. Klemm, and R. Baqir, 2008, “Investment Incentives and Effective Tax Rates in the Philippines: A Comparison with Neighboring Countries, IMF Working Paper, forthcomming (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Braumann, B. and others, 2006 “Germany: Selected Issues”, IMF Country Report No. 06/17, available through www.imf.org (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Central Planning Bureau, 2006, Five Lisbon Highlights: The Economic Impact of Reaching These Targets, Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis (paper prepared for the Directorate General Enterprise & Industry of the European Commission). Debrun, X, 2008, “Asset Price Fluctuations and Tax Revenues”, unpublished FAD Memo prepared for IMF Management (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Doyle, C., and S. van Wijnbergen, 1984, “Taxation of Foreign Multinationals: A Sequential 31 Bargaining Approach to Tax Holidays, CEPR Discussion Paper 25, August. European Commission (EC), 2006a, The Impact of Ageing on Public Expenditure: Projections for the EU25 Member States on Pensions, Health Care, Long-Term Care, Education and Unemployment Transfers (2004–2050) (Brussels). European Commission (EC), 2006b, Long-term Sustainability of Public Finances in the European Union (Brussels). Feyzioğlu, T., M. Skaarup, and M. Syed, 2007, “Achieving Long-Term Fiscal Sustainability in Korea, IMF Country Report 07/345, available through www.imf.org (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Ford, R., and D. Laxton, 1999, “World Public Debt and Real Interest Rates,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 15, pp. 77-94. Gordon, R.H. and J.R. Hines, 2002, “International Taxation”, in: A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein, Handbook of Public Economics, Vol. 4, pp. 1935-95 (Amsterdam: NorthHolland). Guin-Siu, M.T., (2004), “Tax Holidays”, FAD guidance note (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Hauner, D., D. Leigh, and M. Skaarup, 2007, “ Improving Fiscal Sustainability in G-7 Countries”, IMF Working Paper 07/187 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). International Monetary Fund, 2007, “Globalization, Financial Markets, and Fiscal Policy”, Board paper prepared by FAD, available through www.imf.org (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). ———2008a, “The Fiscal Implications of Climate Change”, Board paper prepared by FAD, available through www.imf.org (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). ———, 2008b, “Climate Change and the Global Economy”, World Economic Outlook, Chapter 4, available through www.imf.org (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Jones, B., M. Keen, J. Norregaard, and J. Strand, 2007, “Climate Change: Economic Impact and Policy Responses”, World Economic Outlook, October, available through www.imf.org (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). 32 Keen, M., 2008, “Revenue Policy and Administration”, Presentation at the World Bank Course on Revenue Policy and Administration, April. Kumhof, M., D. Laxton, and D. Leigh, 2008, “To Starve or Not to Starve the Beast”, IMF Working Paper, forthcomming (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund). McKibbin, W.J., and P.J. Wilcoxen, 1998, “The Theoretical and Empirical Structure of the G-Cubed Model”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 16 (January 1), pp. 123–48. ——— 2004, “Estimates of the Costs of Kyoto-Marrakesh versus the McKibbin-Wilcoxen Blueprint,” Energy Policy, Vol. 32, pp. 467–79. OECD, 2001, “Fiscal Implications of Age-Related Spending,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 305 (Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development). Stern, N. and others, 2007, The Economics of Climate Change (“The Stern Review”) (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Werding, M. and A. Kaltschütz, IFO, Munich, 2005, IFO Beiträge zur Wirtschaftsforschung—Modellrechnungen zur Langfristigen Tragfähigkeit der Öffentlichen Finanzen. Zee, H., J. Stotsky, and E. Ley, 2002, “Tax Incentives for Business Investment: A Primer for Policymakers in Developing Countries”, World Development, Vol. 30, No. 9, 14971516.