WELAFARE GAINS DUE TO IMPROVED SOLID WASTE MANAGEMENT. A case study of Bugoloobi flats,Kampala. Abbreviation CVM = Contingent Valuation Method KCC = Kampala City Council MSW = Municipal Solid Waste MSWM = Municipal Solid Waste Management SWM = Solid Waste Management SWS = Solid Waste Service WTP = Willingness To Pay OLS = Ordinary Least Square Abstract The aim of this paper is to determine the economic value of an improvement in environmental quality due to an alternative household garbage collection and selection system for the households of Bugoloobi flats a suburb of Kampala City. Welfare depends on the consumption of both market and non-market goods and services. Against this background, an improvement in the environmental sanitation will directly improve the welfare of the community. The basic understanding is that willingness to pay should reflect the value to the community of having a better environmental quality, according to the contingent valuation literature. A change in environmental quality should imply an increase in the individual utility level for which, in theory, they should be willing to pay. The methodology consists in asking people directly for their willingness to pay a fee to a private service provider to manage solid waste collection. The econometric model used income per capita of the household, family size, age of the respondent and education level as the independent variables and e willingness to pay for as the dependent variable. 1 1.0 Introduction 1.1 Background Generally, uncontrolled dumping, stock piling and inefficiency characterize Municipal Solid Waste (MSW) in Kampala. This often times results into water pollution, air pollution, air and water borne diseases, yet no drastic efforts are directed at necessary improvements. In many rapidly growing cities solid waste is a major source of concern owing to weak authorities, resource constraint and ineffective sanitary management. Solid waste is supply-driven limited only to local authorities, who are much slower in adjusting to the demands of the residential areas, industries, institutions and even streets and market places despite the various charges levied by the city council (). Solid waste management has a single problem – cost recovery. This is because, traditionally, solid waste services are financed by general revenues from city taxes and levies. Consequently, many municipalities in developing countries spend a large proportion of their budgets on the collection, transport and disposal of solid waste. Their solid waste management is a costly service that consumes between 20 and 50 percent of available operational budgets for municipal services, yet serves no more than 70 percent of the urban inhabitants (Bartone and Bernstein, 1993). Those who do not receive services are the low-income populations concentrated in the peri-urban areas, who either do not prioritize the importance of clean environment or are caught in the abyss of poverty and therefore have more pressing issues. Even those in decent housing areas are living next to mountains of heaps of garbage lying uncollected. The municipal authorities have not made sufficient efforts in educating them apart from asking for service charges. The changing economic trends and rapid urbanization complicate solid waste management (SWM) in developing countries. Consequently, solid waste is not only increasing in quantity but also changing in composition from less organic to more paper, packing waste, plastics, glass, metal wastes among other waste, a fact leading to the low collection rates (Bartone 1993). In order to cope up with these challenges and because of 2 the critical role in protecting the environment and public health, accomplishing effective municipal solid be a priority for emerging cities. However, in the past most attempts to improve solid management in cities have focused on the technical aspects of different means of collection and disposal (World Bank, 1992). Recently, more attention has been paid to enhancing institutional arrangements for service delivery, with a special emphasis on privatization (Cointreau, 1994). In Kampala city and in deed many major towns in Uganda, the standards of solid waste management (SWM) have always been gauged and evaluated on the role and performance of service providers such as local authorities and other alternative players. The policies and legal framework governing SWM have also been directed at these providers completely ignoring the demand side to the problem. This leaves the solid waste service providers not fully appreciated by service receivers – households, institutions, industries and commercial premises. With regard to this, the various players have directed less effort at investigating the demand side to solid waste management. This has however, circumvented the proper improvement of the service delivery in the past. The involvement of the service receivers especially households who are the primary producers and generators of significant proportion of solid waste, may not only allow them (households) determine their providers via some arrangements and participate in making of sound policy decisions including designing of effective joint solutions SWM but also help the providers to understand households’ willingness to participate, pay and neighborhood characteristics. The key question is: What policy recommendations, if any, can be suggested to ensure efficient delivery of SWS particularly to residential estates. 1.2 Benefits of Efficient SWM There is a wide range of benefits associated with efficient delivery of solid waste management services generated by households. However, the benefits hinge, to a large extent, on the categorization of the wastes into, say, household wastes, medical waste or industrial waste from factories. 3 Solid waste management benefits accrue to individuals (including households), production and/ or consumption, to economic assets and environmental assets. This categorization may also help us dichotomize benefits into health and non-health related effects. The benefits related to health include the direct health impacts due to reduced contact of the vulnerable populations with garbage in streets, reckless dumping and improved management of designated dumpsites. In addition, reduced treatment for illness such as diarrhea and cholera avert health costs and enhance productivity of the population. On the otherhand, non-health benefits resulting from efficient management of solid waste include a large saving in terms electricity costs in institutions where incineration is used such as hospitals and industries. Second, prompt solid waste collection reduces private costs to households associated with garbage disposal for instance purchase of large garbage containers. Overall, efficient SWM boosts environmental quality through increased amenity values such as cleaner air cleaner physical sanitation and increase in non-use value of the service. 1.3 SWM Status in Kampala. Kampala is the capital of Uganda with a population of approximately 1.5 million people. The city is riddled with numerous problems associated with solid waste management. Waste management is the sole responsibility of the Kampala City Council (KCC) through the city Environment Department. Waste management constitutes garbage collection and disposal from households, market areas, hospitals, industries, and city center. Efforts to manage garbage in the city are continuously overwhelmed and frustrated with the everincreasing population of city residents and levels of economic activity. As result ineptitudeness and low service coverage characterize KCC. Often times the service are not on schedule and only provides them in crucial areas such as market places, residential areas, as well as politically sensitive areas (JICA 1998). However, in the mid 1970s, KCC collected over 80% of the waste generated in the city. 4 The solid waste services in the city are mainly divided into subsystems- primary and secondary systems. KCC mainly concentrates on the latter, that is, the secondary system where it only engages in transportation and disposal of solid waste to the final dumping site – an open space in the outskirts of the city (Nalukolongo). The primary system, which is normally at source- households, industries and institutions, are often neglected despite the KCC levying property and utilities. The council has placed several garbage pits and containers that are emptied approximately once a week. Eventually heaps of garbage pile up around the residential areas. The study herein is limited to residential areas and specifically Bugoloobi flats. 1.4 Alternative Providers Due to rapid urbanization, high costs of municipal services, gross inefficiency and resource constraints, KCC is unable to cope with the rapidly expanding demand for solid waste services. Consequently, various alternative private providers have come in handy to provide the service more efficiently. The provision of services by the private groups is going on in Kampala city and in deed many major towns informally and without the legal sanction of the city council. In fact, the big for-profit private operators sometimes operate without regulatory framework or guidance. Unfortunately, they litter the city and devise illegal dumping sites. In most cases, the private providers are not well prepared and thus unable to cope especially when KCC denies recognition or does not devise systematic guidelines and direction. But on rare cases the provision of services by these groups have however, been approved and regulated by the KCC with regard to areas of operation, kinds of solid waste handled and manner of disposal. But sometimes these regulations are not implemented leading to non-compliance hence the private groups. 2.0 Studies on Solid Waste Management Emerging literature on solid waste management suggest that involvement of professional collector teams, resident committee workers, private institutions can prove effective in solid waste management rather than involving only public 5 institutions. Some literature argues that involvement of resident community and individuals brings about understanding of garbage management which has been a major source of failure (Olley and Olbina, 1999; Coker and Sikiru,1999;Osucha, 1999). If people know or are informed about the nature of improvement in environmental quality, that is, solid waste, the envisaged welfare improvement elicits people’s WTP.(Hartwick et al 1998). Households consider solid waste services as normal economic good that can alter household welfare. But this presupposes the need to understand the existence of a problem and appreciate the risks they pose before households can make a trade off decision with regard to WTP (Atlaf et al 1996). Public cleaning of streets and open area is critically important in areas where waste is indiscriminately dumped along roadsides and those inefficient collection techniques may exacerbate this problem (Ohnesorgen 1993). Use of uncovered trucks spill some of their loads back onto streets and roads thereby complicating the garbage collection (Ward and Li). Waste collection in developing countries maintained that in such countries the cost per metric ton of cleaning waste off the streets is estimated to be between two and three times the cost of collection. He therefore recommended that covered trucks or other more costly collection equipment that reduce spillage would probably be more efficient (Cointreau-Levine 1994). The rural folks expect the municipal cleaning and collection service hence their WTP is not only low but also negative at times. However, in a study on WTP for community based solid management and its sustainability in Bangladesh, Salequzzaman and co-authors (2000) maintain that where a community perceives that new facilities provide a service higher than the existing management they are more willing to pay higher contribution. This, according to them, is particularly the case, if the users are not satisfied with the current service they are receiving. However, this argument has one major setback because it assumes households have perfect 6 information about the envisaged alternative sanitation methods for them to be compelled to make higher payments. However, this does not apply to our rural folks, who may not understand the environmental implication leave alone alternative sanitation. The environment is considered to be normal with income elasticity of 0.13 using the contingent valuation of the environmental impact of SWM in San Pedro CholulaMexico (Viniegra et al, 2001). They also found a negative association between age and the WTP for quality change of the environment citing the lack of generation altruism among households. While investigating management of solid waste in Addis Ababa, (Beyene, 1999) found that environmental health does not depend on rising public awareness and on the creation of mechanism of controlling generation of waste at the source. Also, sharing of responsibilities between the public, institutions, private sector, nongovernmental organizations and the government. The above argument is internally consistent with Snel (1999) who argued that if responsibilities are shared social stigma on waste disposal could be mitigated. In developing countries, the least costly options of waste dumping in public spaces or burning it openly –are often the most popular (Bartone and Bertntein, 1993). They argue that although inexpensive in terms of out-of-pocket costs and environment effects to those that dump or burn waste, these acts may impose large costs on society. Aesthetic, environmental and health problems may result, especially in densely populated urban areas. 3.0 Statement of the problem: A major implication of the pattern of urbanization in developing countries relates to providing adequate infrastructure. The rapid pace of urbanization would presuppose an increase in the provision of infrastructure. This has not been the case, as many cities lack the financial resources and institutional capacity to provide the most basic infrastructure. 7 The problems are likely to become even more pronounced as the level and as the pace of urbanization continue to grow rapidly. Due to the overwhelming volumes of solid waste, the Kampala city council can not be able to satisfactorily collect and dispose. Consequently there has been gradual degeneration in the management of household waste in residential areas. Service recipients notably households in Bugoloobi flats have not been given a chance to evaluate and choose providers of their own or involved in the effective management of solid waste around their residential area. Linkages exist between deficient infrastructure and health outcomes of urban residents. For instance, inadequate provision of proper sanitation account for 7% of all deaths and diseases worldwide, with children and women being more at risk. Respiratory infections and diarrheal diseases are the two biggest causes of death among the poorest 20 percent of the worlds countries ranked by national GDP per capita (Gwatkin and Guillot 1999). The solid waste problem has become one of the major concerns for a number of environmental events. Solid waste management is an important element of public health and environmental protection: protection against short-term direct and indirect health risks due to improper waste collection and disposal. 4.1 Privatization Commonly proposed necessary even though not sufficient solutions include the contracting of the private sector on the premise that service efficiency and coverage can be improved, costs lowered and recovered, new ideas, technologies and skills can be injected (Bartone 1999). Today's consumers want high-quality services at lower costs. To meet this demand, ways should be sought to improve operations and make them more cost-efficient. For some, privatization may offer the best solution to operations efficiency. But before making a 8 decision to privatize operations, public operators must evaluate the impacts that privatization will have on a facility's overall operations. In the solid waste industry, municipal landfill operators must consider privatization's impact on the complete suite of solid waste services that a municipality provides. This involves evaluating what services a private company will provide and for what fee, as well as the associated impacts to solid waste customers. Privatization does have numerous advantages. First, it can increase the pool of staff and equipment that a municipality can draw upon for various activities. Some municipal landfill operators realize great financial benefits by turning over their facilities to a private company that provides more extensive resources. While a private firm may offer an attractive lower tipping fee, public officials must take into account that the higher municipal tipping fee may have also funded those other solid waste services typically demanded by the public, such as garbage recycling and landfill operation (Hauser 2000). 5.0 Objectives of the study The theory of the measurement of welfare change has been discussed a lot both at rigorous levels of abstraction and in practical terms of application. Using the already established tools, this paper therefore proceeds to estimate economic value of welfare gain with improvement in the SWM. Theoretically changes in SWM can affect individuals’ welfare through any of the following ways: Changes in the prices they pay for goods and services bought in markets. Changes in the prices they receive for their factors of production. Changes in the quantities or qualities of non marketed goods And changes in the risk individuals face. Focus is on measurement of welfare change due changes in the non-marketed service efficient SWM, using the Contingent Valuation method (CVM). Specific objectives: To find the mean WTP by households to attain a specified standard of SWM. To find the determinants of WTP for a specified standard of SWM. 9 6.0 Theoretical Framework and Methodology 6.1 Conceptual Framework 6.1.1 Economic Consumer Theory The basic approach to the mathematical theories of individual preferences is that of microeconomic consumer theory (Ben-Arkiva and Lerman, 1985). The objective of the theory is to provide the means for transformations of assumptions about desires into a demand function expressing the action of the consumer under given circumstances. According to this theory, consumer demand as measured by the quantity of the environmental quality consumed is a function of the prices faced, real income and a set of consumer characteristics. These consumer characteristics are proxies for his tastes and preferences. The consumer is faced with a budget that defines the consumption possibilities, or the choice set. He therefore has to choose among alternatives the specific goods and services that best satisfies him and that he can afford to buy given his limited income. The satisfaction is the utility he derives from the services. The consumer’s goal is there to maximize utility given his budget constraint. For a fixed income, Y, and vector of prices p1 and p2. Pi (X, ) = Y i=1,2 ………………………(1) Where X= environmental quality = Other goods and services P is vector of prices (P = P1, P2) P1= Price of waste collection. P2 = Price of other goods. Y = income of the household. It is assumed that the household has the ability to compare all the possible alternatives. 10 Thus there exists an ordinal utility function. U = U (X, )……………………………………………..(2) This is the household’s preference expressed mathematically. The household’s selection of the most preferred bundle that satisfies the budget constraint. Mathematically, utility of a household is maximized subject to the budget constraint. Maximize U = U (X, ) Subject to Pi (X, ) = Y P,Y >0; 6.1.2 Random Utility Theory The basic problem confronted by discrete choice analysis is the modelling of choice from a set of mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive alternatives (Ben-Arkiva and Lerman, 1985). A decision-maker is modeled as selecting the alternative with the highest utility among those available at the time choice is made. It is impossible to specify and estimate a discrete choice model that will always succeed in predicting the chosen alternatives by all households. We therefore adopt the concept of Random utility. The true utilities of the alternatives are considered random variables, so the probability that the alternative is chosen is defined as the probability that it has the greatest utility among the available alternatives. Though the individual is assumed to select the alternative with the highest utility, the analyst of random variables does not know the utilities. From this perspective, the choice probability of alternative k is equal to the probability that the utility of alternative k, Ukn is greater than all other alternatives in the choice set. P(k/Cn) = P(Uin > Ujn) for all j &Cn. 6.2 Contingent Valuation Method (CVM) 11 Contingent Valuation method (CV) is a survey method to elicit consumers’ valuation of goods and services not sold in the market place, by calculating their Willingness To Pay (WTP). The method has extensively been used in the valuation of non-market resources such as recreation, wildlife and environmental quality. In this method, the researcher creates a hypothetical market in a non-market or new good, invites a group of subjects (survey respondents or experimental subjects) to operate in that market, and records the results. The values generated through use of the hypothetical market are treated as estimates of the hypothetical market. 6.3 Willingness To Pay. A rational consumer will, due to the constrained maximization facing him, give preference to alternatives that give him higher utility. A good or service associated with highest WTP would be the one that yields highest WTP would be the yields utility to the consumer and vice versa. Subsequently, a high willingness and ability to pay indicates high utility derived from the commodity and hence such a good would be given preference, implying its high demand. Logically, a service that satisfies one most is also highly valued. The value of a service would be expressed through WTP for the service. Generally there are two approaches for assessing demand or WTP. The first is the demand curve approach, which entails making observations on prices and quantities in a market. A demand curve is estimated and WTP can be inferred. The other approach is the CVM. This survey-based method uses responses to some questions posed to the consumer to their preferences and WTP for a hypothetical product or service. This is the method in this study since environmental quality is not available in the market. According to theory, if demand for this service exists, then this must be reflected by WTP. A high WTP is logically a proxy for its demand. Thus the value placed by a consumer on a service can be expressed as WTP to obtain it. An appropriate approach is to directly ask households or individuals to state their willingness to pay for improved solid waste management using the survey techniques. Despite the arguments that strategic bias will invalidate survey results, the survey 12 technique is most relevant to this study. Also results of using the survey approach for estimating the value of public goods or services are internally consistent, replicable and consistent with demand theory. This method has the chief advantage in that it considerably reduces strategic bias (Arrow et al, 1993). Strategic bias arises when respondent attempts to influence the results of a WTP survey by answering in such a way as to serve his own interest rather than reveal his true valuation of the good or service. For instance, the respondent might give very low amount of WTP if felt that the answer would influence by lowering the amount he would be charged for the improved SWM. Econometric Model Double-Bounded Logit Model Assume there be N survey respondents. Respondent I is offered an initial bid amount Bi and one of the follow-up bids (Bi d , Bi u), where id i iu . if di is a binary indicator variable for the yes-no response probabilities. The probability of a represent say yes to the initial bid value offered (i). Pi y prob( yes ) Then we consider the double-bounded format, where each participant is present with two sequential bid values and the second bid value is conditional on the first bid value. Following Hanemann et al (1991), the response probabilities are: yy 1 G ( Biu ; ) nn G ( Bid ; ) iyn G ( Biu ; ) G ( Bi ) iny G ( Bi ; ) G ( Bid ; ) G will be represented by the cumulative logistic function ) (pxe ) ;B ( G ) (pxe 1 where B 13 the log-likelihood function for the double-bounded model, parameterized by n ln LD ( ) {d iyy ln yy ( Bi , Biu ; ) d inn ln nn ( Bi , Bid ; ) d iyn ln yn ( Bi , Biu ; ) d iny ln ny ( Bi , Bid ; )} i 1 The ML estimator for the double-bounded model , is the solution to the equation ln LD ( ) / 0 Measuring Goodness of Fit Goodness-of-fit measures are used to assess how well an econometric model explains the observed data or how well fitted values of the response variable compare to the actual values. There are several options for measuring goodness of fit when using binary discrete choice data: the McFadden pseudo R2, the Pearson chi-square test, and the classification procedure. McFadden Pseudo R2 A popular goodness-of-fit measure for binary discrete response data is the McFadden pseudo R2, which is written as R2 = 1 – L0/Lmax The above model is used to estimate the predict model Analytical Model From past studies, WTP of individuals is related to income level of households, socioeconomic and demographic factors. Studies by Knetsch and Davis (1966), and Whittington (1993) in particular single out such factors as the cost of obtaining the evironmental good or service, educational level, age of the respondent, family size, religion, marital status among others, explain the variations in respondent’s WTP for environmental goods/services. 14 WTPi = f(Y, FS, Educ, Age, ES, Di ) WTPi = willingness to pay for efficient SWM. WTP/Y>0; WTP/FS><0; WTP/Educ>0 WTP/Age>0 (1) On the basis of theoretical exposition and data we specified two models. First, a multiplicative model (3) that assumes constant differential effects among the variables and second, one that takes into account interaction among variables (2). WTPi = 0(Ypc) 1(FS) 2(Educ) 3(Age) 4(ES) 5Dii (2) WTPi = willingness to pay for improved solid waste management by household i Ypc = Per capita income (monthly household income divided by the family by the household size) FS = Family Size Age = Age of the respondent Educ = Education level of the respondent Di = a vector of dummy variables Dummies; ee = Environmental Ethics gnd = gender ms = Marital Status. Logarithms are introduced on both sides of the above to make the log-log equations below. This was basically done because of two reasons. First, it was dictated by the data and secondly because of the need to capture elasticity of WTP for improvement in solid waste management in Bugoloobi flats with respect to household income, increases in years of schooling, increases in family size and age of the respondents among other variables. 15 lnwtpi = 0 + 1lnYpc + 2FS + 3Educ + 4Age + ln (3) D-optimal Design for the Double-Bounded. The choice a particular bid design affects the efficiency of the survey experience. In both single and double-bounded model, (Kanninen 1993) shows that the D-optimal bid designs is superior to the c-optimal and Fiducial method design and hence its choice. In the double-bounded case, there are three bid amounts specified for each observation. Although each person is asked only two bids, all three bids enter the log-likelihood function apriori, it is not known which response any household will give to the initial bid. The D-optimal design utilize a number of restrictions to avoid solving simultaneous problem. According to this design, the initial bid is the median value which given by expression -/. Expected Results Assessment of the prevailing SWM situation in Bugoloobi flats indicates that KCC is inefficient due to large diseconomies of scale. As highlighted in chapter 1, it is expected that private service providers are somewhat relatively efficient and offer quality service as opposed to the KCC. This means that generally, are willing to pay more than what they are currently incurring in SWM. A positive WTP implies that households demand SWM in which the improvement in the solid waste management will directly improve their welfare also. The analytical model is likely to generate a positive coefficient for the per capita income of households. Theoretically, a low-income household is willing to pay less than tha higher income household. This is as incomes increase, households tend to have more “discretionary income “ and hence more scope of choice about the disposition is a luxurious good. 16 On the hand, it is expected the coefficient of the environment ethics dummy will be negative. Households that take sanitational precaution such as proper solid waste disposal are less willing to pay for the service via this arrangement. This can supported by the following hypotheses; Many households may not want to participate in communal arrangements. Others cannot afford the services or are simply acting strategically or exhibiting free riding behavior. From previous studies carried out elsewhere the factors envisaged in the analytical model may as well significant in the determination of the WTP in Bugoloobi flats. References Arrow, K., Solow, R., Leamer, E., Portney, P., Radner, R. and Schuman, H. 1993. Report on the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation. Federal Register, 58:10. Department of Commerce, USA. Bartone, C.L., Luiz, L., Thelma, T & Schetenleis (1991). “Private Sector Participation in Municipal Solid waste services: Experiences in Latin America” Waste Management &Research 9:495-509. Bartone, C.L & Bernstein, J.D (1993). “ Improving Municipal Solid Waste Management in Third World Countries". Resources, Conservation and Recycling; 8; 43-45. Baud, I.S.A. (2000) Collective Action, Enablement and Partnerships: Issues in Urban Development; Amsterdam. Ben-Arkiva, M. and Lerman, S.R 1985. Discrete Choice analysis: theory and application to travel demand. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. 17 Bishop, R.C and Heberlein, T.A. 1990. The contingent valuation method. In Economic Evaluation of National resources: issues, theory and applications, eds. R.L Johnson and G.V Johnson. West view Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 81-104. Boadway, R.W (1975) “Cost-Benefit Rules in General Equilibrium.” Review of Economic studies, 42, 361 – 73. Boadway, R.W and Bruce N (1984) “Welfare Economics.” Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Freeman Myrick A (193) “The Measurement of Environment and Resources Values; Theory and Methods.” Resource for the future, Washington D.C. Fullerton, Don & T.C. Kinnamon (1993). “Garbage Recycling and Illicit Burning or Dumping, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge. Gravelle, H. and R. Ress (1992) “Microeconomics.” Longman. Gwartkin, D.R., and M. Guillot. 1999. “The Burden of Diseases Among the Global Poor: Current Situation, Future Trends and Implications for strategy.” Global Forum on Health Research Working Paper. July Hanemann (1994): “Valuing the Environment Through Contingent Valuation”; Journal of Economic perspectives 8(4): 19-43. Hanley N and Spash C.L (1993). Cost-Benefits analysis and the Environment. London Edward Elgar. Johansson Per-Olov (1987) “the economic Theory and Measurement of Environmental Benefits.” Cambridge University Press. 18 Mitchell R.C 4 Carson R.T (1989). “Using surveys to Value goods/service: The Contingent Valuation Method.” Washington DC, Resources for the future. Ohnesorgen, F (1993): sorting out solid waste: Developing Countries Need Management Expertise.” Public Management, 75; 9-12. Olley, J and Olbina R. (1999) “Innovative solid waste management in China” in Pickford John (1999) integrated development for water and sanitation, 25th WEDC conference. Osuocha, C.P (1999). Improving refuse management in urban Nigeria, in Pickford John (1999) integrated development for water and sanitation. Salequzzaman M.D, Sqadiqul A, Mostafa A (2000): “Willingness-to-pay for communitybased.Solid Waste Management and its sustainability in Bangladesh; Research institute for Sustainabilty and Technology Policy, Murdoch University, Austraulia. Snel M (1999). Social Stigma and the waste collection scheme, in Pickford John (1999) integrated development for water and sanitation, 25th WEDC conference. Viniegra, M.E., T.T Cortes and E.M Cuevas (2001) “Economic Valuation of Environment Impact of Solid Waste Management”; university de la America, Puebla. Whittington, D., Laura, D.T., Wrght, A.M., Choe, K., Hughes, J.A and swarna, V., (1992): “Household Demand for Improved sanitation Services in Kumasi, Ghana: A Contingent Valuation Study.” Water Resources and Research, Vol.29 (6) 1539-156 Whittington, D., Laura, D.T., Wrght, A.M., Choe, K., Hughes, J.A and swarna, V., (1992): “Household Demand for Improved sanitation Services in Kumasi, Ghana: A Contingent Valuation Study.” Water Resources and Research, Vol.29 (6) 1539-1560. 19 Whittington, D., Lauria, D.T., Wrght, A.M Choe, K., Hughes, J.A., and Swarna, V., (1993): “Household Sanitation in Kumasi Ghana-A Description of current practices, attitudes and Perceptions, World Development report 1992. Whittington, D., Pearce, D.W & Moran, D. (1993) Economic values and the Environment in the developing World: A Report Prepared for United Nations Environment Programme, Nairobi, Kenya. World Bank (1992) World Development Report “ Development and Environment New York. Appendices The CVM question put to the households Currently the SW is managed by the KCC and as it is, garbage is collected once in two weeks. The garbage that piles up during that period attracts a lot of houseflies. Furthermore, the waste pits are near the children’s playgroup, which exposes them to health hazards. As a result households incur health costs to treat family members. Besides the sight of stockpiles near the residences is unpleasant. Therefore, if SW is managed a private firm so that garbage is collected every three days, are you willing to pay Ushs……. Per month for your household to participate in the solid waste management program? 1.Yes 2.No This is a dichotomous choice format, which gives the respondents specific amounts and asks them whether they are willing to pay that amount or not. The respondent answers with a “no” or a “yes”. The yes-no answers are then used along with the required payment to estimate a discreet model from which expected WTP is calculated. 20 21