Manufacturing for Overseas Private Label: A Win-Win Strategy for Retailers and Producers 2 Manufacturing for Overseas Private Label: A Win-Win Strategy for Retailers and Producers Yaron Timmor* * Yaron Timmor is the Academic Head of the International Business Studies and Marketing Communication Program at the Arison Business School, the Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya. Address for correspondence: Dr. Timmor Yaron The Arison School of Business The Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya P.O.B. 167 Herzliya 46150 Tel: 972-9-960-2716, Fax: 972-9-956-8605 E-mail: timmor@idc.ac.il 3 ABSTRACT The study discusses the use of private labels, both for retailers and manufacturers, within the context of international markets. It is proposed that agreements between manufacturers and retailers from different markets may solve or mitigate some abiding frictions and serve the interest of both parties. Using data collected through 101 in-depth interviews among marketing managers, qualitative and quantitative procedures were used to explore producers’ attitudes and behaviour in regard to agreements to manufacturing for overseas retailers’ private labels. The study revealed that lower transaction costs, quicker penetration into new markets and retailers’ reputations among customers are the dominant motivators while short-term strategy, appropriate mainly for grocery items, increases dependency on retailers and deters manufactures from contracting with overseas retailers’ private labels. The study also found that gaps exist between manufacturers’ perceptions and actual behaviour, mediated particularly by firm size and product categories. The findings, which reflect observed practice, are interpreted through theoretical propositions related to earlier studies. Managerial implications are provided. KEYWORDS: retailers, private label, manufacturers, brands, overseas agreements. 4 Introduction Private labels are of primary interest both for retailers and for manufacturers as they are concerned with power relationships and affect sales volumes, market share and the profits of manufacturers as well as retailers (Cheng Wu and Jen Wang, 2005; Obina et al., 2006; Quelch and Harding, 1996; Verhoef et al., 2000). The intensive growth and development of private label products over the last two decades in terms of market share, quality and promotion have encouraged a growing number of scholars to explore the phenomena. Nonetheless, most studies have focused on retailers’ and consumers’ perspectives, with very few paying attention to manufacturers’ points of view. The minority of researchers who incorporated manufacturers’ considerations into their studies examined local producers’ behaviors in domestic markets (Cheng Wu and Jen Wang, 2005; Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999; Mills, 1999; Obina et al., 2006). The rapid globalization of manufacturers as well as of retailers has opened new business opportunities and alternative ways of coping with private labels and their apparent influence on producer–seller relationships. For instance, brand cannibalization may be of less concern when the product is manufactured for an overseas private label of different market retailers. Likewise, when a retailer sets up a production agreement for its private label with an overseas producer, this can mitigate the conflict with the national brand manufacturer. This study focuses on producers that are manufacturing for the international markets and examines their perceptions and attitude toward private labels and overseas retailers, as well as their actual behaviour in terms of their export strategy. Distributors and mainly retailers can benefit from this study by gaining an understanding of overseas producers’ attitudes toward their private labels and learn when it is more advisable, and more beneficial to both sides, to manufacture private labels. In addition, retailers can learn when overseas agreements are preferable to local contracts with domestic manufacturers. Many studies have examined mass commodity products (Burt 2000, Burt and Sparks, 2003; Calvin and Cook, 2001; Heraud et al., 2006; Obina et al., 2006). While private labels have appeared in most traditional industries, they are also increasingly showing up in other categories such as home appliances, electronics, plastics and even computers and communications. Part of this is the result of greater reliance on producers in East and South Asia—for example, in India, China and Thailand. The present study is cross-sectional and incorporates different product categories both in the more traditional and in the newer industries. The main objectives of this study are: To examine private labels and their associated dilemmas both for manufacturers and retailers within the context of international marketing; To explore producers’ attitudes and viewpoints regarding manufacturing agreements with overseas distributors for their private labels; and To examine producers’ actual behaviour in regard to overseas private labels. The study started by addressing the main dilemmas both for producers and the retailers who own the private labels when drafting agreements to produce the private labels. This is done by reviewing some of the relevant literature. Next, the alternatives to formal agreements among overseas players are introduced and the major advantages for both parties are discussed. Following this the research that examines 5 manufacturers’ attitudes and behaviours regarding producing for overseas private labels and the related propositions are presented. A discussion of the research findings follows and the study concludes with a review of the academic and managerial implications. Private label agreements – strategic dilemmas The increasing prevalence of private labels, stimulated by the growing force of distributors, mainly retailers, has put the dispute about private labels’ business and marketing impact on the main agenda of both retailers and manufacturers (Cheng Wu and Jen Wang, 2005; Kim and Parker, 1999; Quelch and Harding, 1996; Verhoef et al., 2002). Private labels, known variously as store brands, own brands, and retailers’ brands, have dramatically developed in the last three decades in terms of quality, packaging, variety of shelf presentation and communication (Ailawadi and Harlam, 2004; Apelbaum et al., 2003; Burt and Sparks 2003 Richardson et al., 1994). Consequently, the positive reputation of private labels has grown, their prices have risen and their “value for money” positioning in consumers’ minds and in comparison to manufacturers’ brands has improved (Burt, 2000; Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999; Fearne, 1998; Richardson et al., 1994,). Private labels’ market shares have increased rapidly. For instance, in the American apparel market in 1998 they held 20% of aggregate unit sales and in 2002, this had jumped to 36% (Cheng Wu and Jen Wang, 2005; Sayman et al., 2002) In Spain in 2002 the retail brand share in the mass commodity market accounted for 30.6% in value in supermarkets (Obina et al., 2006,) and In the U.K., Belgium, Germany France and Italy private labels reached up to 30% and more in total grocery stores sales in 2002 (Tarzijan, 2004) Accompanied by structured marketing strategies, private labels increased their competitive strength in relation to manufacturers’ brands (Burt, 2000; Calvin and Cook, 2001; Kim and Parker, 1999; Fernandez and Gomez, 2005; Mills 1999). There are numerous advantages for retailers in developing their own brands, for example, higher mark-ups, control in managing and promoting the brand, exclusivity in selling to customers and hence increasing customer loyalty to the store, improved bargaining positions vis-à-vis national brand producers and establishing closer contacts with consumers (Corstjen and Lal, 2000; Chinlagunta et al., 2002; Fearne, 1998; Narashimhan and Wilcox, 1998; Sayman et al., 2002). However, problems arise when manufacturers are also producing and developing their own brands. Moreover, manufacturers use retailers to distribute, to sell and in many cases, to promote their brands at the points of sales. Hence for the manufacturer, the retailer who owns a private label becomes a double agent (both a client and a competitor): on the one hand, serving as the seller, providing the manufacturers’ brands to the consumer, while on the other hand, competing with manufacturers with the retailer’s store brands (Obina et al., 2006). Therefore, it is not surprising that the growth of private labels has generated friction and dilemmas for both manufacturers and retailers (Cheng Wu and Jen Wang, 2005; Cotterill et al., 2000; Pustis and Dhar, 1999; Quelch and Harding, 1996). For retailers, the main dilemma, once having decided to develop and sell their own brands, is who will be their supplier, i.e., their manufacturer? Contracting with the big manufacturers or market leaders may better promise a continuous supply, as their manufacturing capability is higher than small market players. Large manufactures or market leaders can also mean good quality products, demonstrated by their customers’ repeated purchases, as well by their extensive 6 manufacturing experience. However, there are many drawbacks to such agreements, mostly deriving from manufactures’ market positions that affect their channel power (Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999, Heide and John, 1988; Kale 1986; Lal and Narasimhan, 1996). Probably the main obstacle to initiating such agreements is the negative attitude and reactions that market leaders tend to have toward private labels. Most studies have suggested that national brand manufacturers and market leaders should refrain from producing retailer’ brands. Rather they should fight back by enhancing their brands’ equity, presenting another, lower-priced brand and developing promotional strategies (Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999; Hoch, 1996; Kim and Parker, 1999; Mills, 1999; Puelles, 1995; Quelch and Harding, 1996). Cheng Wu and Jen Wang (family name only in references) (2005) proposed a positive manoeuvre (when competing with another producer) whereby national brand manufactures should produce private labels in a duopoly market. However, their theory has yet to be examined by empirical studies. The conflicts between retailers and manufacturers may grow when quality gaps between private labels and manufacturers’ brands decrease. Moreover, manufactures can experience cannibalization when customers discover that the private label is actually the same product as the manufacturer’s brand in terms of quality and ingredients, and is even produced by the same manufacture (Obina et al., 2006). In addition, if the private label is sold at a lower price, consumers may feel they have been deceived by the manufacturer for having paid a premium price “for no reason”. Retailers’ dilemmas may increase if the manufacturer’s brand, with which they hope to compete, is highly popular with customers and its marketing communication is a massive pull strategy. In such cases, retailers are more dependent on the manufacturer and any counter-actions such as supply shorts can damage their business strongly. Retailers, after taking into consideration the potential consequences of initiating private label agreements with the big market players, may contact small manufacturers. For small manufacturers, producing for private labels can be an opportunity to increase their sales with no need for extensive investments in promotion (Burt, 2000; Burt and Sparks, 2003; Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999; Puelles 1995,). Nonetheless, such a move raises other and somewhat different dilemmas for retailers. The main issue is whether a small manufacturer can supply the quantities the private label will require and in a continuous manner. While this problem may be minor when contracting with big producers, it becomes particularly relevant when a small or new producer is involved. As argued before, today many retailers view private labels as a long term strategy, increasing their variety and quality, hence supply problems would not only damage their sales but also their customers relations and customers’ evaluation of these brands. Another dilemma regards the know-how and experience of these manufacturers. Can they guarantee quality products and product assortments on time? Though retailers can switch producers if the latter does not meet their standards, in an ongoing business this is not a simple proposition, especially once customers get used to a product. Loyalty, it must be remembered, is an important factor in retail sales (Corstjen and Lal, 2000; Puelles et al., 1997). In addition, and particularly when the producer’s name appears on the packaging, either because of regulations or because the retailer prefers a transparency policy to increase credibility, using a small local producer can be perceived as a compromise and less attractive to customers. This can be an even greater drawback when the retailer opts for premium positioning (Burt, 2000) and intends to offer his private label as a good alternative to the leading brands. 7 Contracting with overseas counterparts Moving to the international arena means changes and new situations. It offers fresh opportunities and considerations for private label cooperation both for retailers and for manufacturers. Below the focus is on the differences between agreements with local and international counterparts and their apparent effects on both partners’ considerations. Two main dilemmas for national brands producers were addressed: 1. Should they produce for private labels? 2. And if so, under what conditions and terms? (Glemet and Mira, 1993; Hoch, 1996; Verhoef et al., 2002). It has been recommended that manufacturers of brand name products should refrain from producing for private labels as they may damage the perceived value of their own brands and, consequently, their profits (Quelch and Harding, 1996). When firms are active in international markets, they can more easily diversify their marketing strategy between their domestic strategy of selling branded products and their overseas strategy of selling private labels. While such a dual strategy may increase brand cannibalization for a firm that sells its own brand alongside private labels to the same market, it is of less concern when dealing with different markets. Moreover, in many cases the manufacturing firm does not need to identify itself by putting its commercial name or trademark on the package. Thus even if consumers move or travel they are not likely to recognize it. In domestic marketing, it was noted above that a firm’s brand image as well as its credibility can be negatively affected when consumers recognize that they can buy the same product for a lower price (Obina et al., 2006). However, this problem is of minor concern when products are sold in different markets. International reputation is still a privilege of global and multinational firms. The lack of an international reputation will be a formidable barrier for companies wishing to extend their sales into foreign markets with their own brand (Angelmar and Pras, 1984, Terpstra and Sarathy, 1997). Many national brand manufacturers, while leaders in their own domestic markets, are unknown or barely known by customers in other nations and hold small market shares or apply a niche strategy in global markets. For example, Elite is the market leader in the Israeli chocolate market where even Nestlé holds a substantially lower market share; yet in other countries it is a small player, mainly producing for private labels. Efes Turkish beer is another example of a local market leader and brand that is less recognized globally. Hence, the economic advantages that producing for a private label offer local small manufactures—such as being able to increase their sales without needing to make extensive investments in promotions—can be of benefit for national brand manufacturers and market leaders in the global markets (Burt 2000; Burt and Sparks, 2003; Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999; Puelles 1995). There are many advantages for retailers who contract with overseas regional national brand manufacturers for private label production. First, they can get experienced partners, and less reason to fear for production incapacity or quality. Second, they can keep their good relations with their local suppliers and avoid frictions that may stem from pressuring national brand manufacturers to produce for their private labels. Third, relying on overseas producers can decrease the perceived threat by the national brand producers when a well-known and identified producer is recognized by consumers as the manufactures of a private label. In broader views, an agreement with an overseas producer can also increase a retailer’s channel power since it reduces his dependency on local producers. This may be a sounder argument when there are few local potential manufacturing sources. 8 International retailers operating in different countries can benefit from such agreements in terms of physical distribution and shipments since the goods can be delivered directly to specific markets. In other cases where there are trade contracts between the producer’s nation and the targeted country’s market or when the two are geographically close, it can be of economic and financial benefit to both parties. Producers have been advised to consider manufacturing for private labels if the market shares of the private labels are considerably high and the main competitors are already in the business (Verhoef et al., 2002). While this may be the rationale and justification for national brand manufacturers to produce for local private labels, it may affect producers in the international arena less, especially if their brands are not well recognized by the foreign markets. Moreover, if there are fewer competitors to supply the overseas private labels, producers may have a strategic advantage when willing to cooperate with the exporting market retailers and produce for their private labels. Retailers, on the other hand, can more easily find manufacturers for product categories that are less common in the private label business or when private labels sales are still in low volumes. Johanson and Vahlne (1990) suggested that the internationalization of the firm could be seen as a process in which the enterprise gradually increases its international involvement. This process evolves through the interplay between the firm’s acquired knowledge regarding the foreign markets and its commitment of resources to these markets. Local retailers can more easily provide their suppliers with information regarding their customers’ preferences and tastes and direct them to produce the required adaptations that are essential for product sales. Moreover, retailers that already have their own brands will be more familiar with customer tastes since they have the marketing and producing information of their private labels and are better aware of customer responses to any changes or promotional activities. Launching new markets can be a long and difficult task, especially where there are many competitors or the market is dominated by a major firm. Other crucial barriers are cultural differences, differences in legal regulations, and conditions of product use (Timmor and Zif 2005, Walters 1986). Joining forces with a retailer can mean quicker penetration and sales for new firms looking to enter the market by manufacturing for private labels. Multinational or big domestic retailers can also be attractive for overseas market leaders due to their ability to get solid orders. Multinational retailers can also enable producers to enter several markets in parallel, with no need for massive promotional efforts other than some adaptation of product packaging or meeting of regulation requirements. From the transaction cost perspective (Bello et al.,1991), a firm’s decision about distribution and integration are geared to minimize the sum of transaction and product costs (Aulakh and Kotabe, 1997; Klein et al., 1990). When a firm exports its own brand, e.g., Heinz, Toshiba, Orbit, substantial costs accrue due to marketing communication expenses, for example advertising, sales promotions and presentations at points of sales. In this manner, producing for overseas private labels can be efficient in terms of cost saving, since the firm transfers a major portion of the marketing function to another firm – the retailer. This can be more cost-effective for short-term cash flow issues. Being flexible and supporting the overseas distributor (wholesaler, retailer) have been shown to have a positive affect on the export result (Bello & Williamson, 1985; Cavusgil et al., 1994; Fiegenbaum and Karnani, 1991; Timmor and Zif, 2005). Such supports can be expressed through financing the marketing activity, supplying advertising and sales promotion materials or producing for their private labels. 9 Based on the literature reviews and strategic dilemmas discussion, and in the light of in-depth preliminary interviews, the following propositions were formulated and addressed: P1. The more the firm’s managers believe that overseas customers know the retailer, the more they tend to manufacture for its private labels. P2. The more the managers believe entering a new market is quicker through private labels, the more they opt to manufacture for overseas private labels. P3. The more the managers believe that manufacturing for overseas private labels means lower costs than exporting their own brand, the more they tend to sign private label agreements. P4. The more the managers believe manufacturing for overseas private labels is for small firms, whereas they consider themselves to be big players, the less they tend to adopt a private label manufacturing strategy. P5. The more the managers believe the strategy increases dependence on retailers, the less they opt to manufacture for overseas private labels P6. The more the managers believe the strategy is for the short and medium terms only, the less they opt to manufacture for overseas private labels P7. Managers will prefer manufacturing for overseas private labels since they believe it reduces the chances for future lawsuits due to product defects. P8. Manager will prefer to refrain from manufacturing for overseas private labels when they believe the strategy is mainly suitable for grocery items and their business is not in this field. The Exploratory Study Methodology This research is based on personal interviews with international marketing managers of Israeli firms with at least five years of export experience. These managers were responsible for and directly involved in the export of a specific product line for a foreign target market. Interviewees managed the marketing aspects of the firm’s activities including distribution and promotion. Two main procedures were used. First, in-depth interviews were conducted with the relevant position holders in six firms that are involved in the international markets either by producing for overseas retailers or by exporting their own brands. This was important to better understand the strategic considerations and motivations for manufacturing for overseas private labels. The interviews were intended to provide more insight regarding the driving forces and perceived barriers in forming production agreements with retailers for their private labels. The interviews were conducted with those in charge of international business affairs, three of them in firms that manufacture for overseas private labels and three in firms that export their own brands. In order to get as much variety as possible, small, medium and large firms in terms of sales and which operated in different industries were studied. In the second phase, a semi-structured questionnaire was built, followed by a pre-test. A final structured questionnaire was used at the end. Unit of Analysis The unit of analysis in this study is a product–market venture (Cavusgil et al., 1993; Timmor and Zif, 2005), whereby a manufacturer exports a specific product line to a 10 chosen country (target market). The requirements for inclusion were that each venture must have already lasted a minimum period of five years, and only final products were considered (no raw materials or products in process). Population, Sample, and Data Collection The study population consisted of product–market export ventures of Israeli firms that had been manufacturing and exporting final products for at least five years. The sample was taken from the database of the Dun and Bradstreet International Business Guide. None of the studied firms was engaged in producing private labels for the local market. Each firm was contacted by telephone to identify the manager responsible for and personally involved in the export marketing strategy. A telephone call to the potential interviewee then confirmed that the case conformed with the research requirements and, after eliciting consent to participate in the study, the interview date was set. 180 firms were contacted and 126 (70%) positively responded. For each refusal, another firm, similar in terms of size and industry, was chosen. 106 cases answered the research criteria (59%); for technical reasons, five interviews could not be conducted. Thus the final sample consisted of 101 product–market export ventures from various industries (see the appendix) across different export markets Operational measures and analysis For the actual testing of the propositions in the exploratory research, 11 statements were developed through the in-depth interviews in the first phase and the theoretical reviews (see Table 1 in the Appendix). Interviewee responses were measured on a Likert scale: 1. disagree, 2. somewhat disagree, 3. somewhat agree, and 4. agree. Logistic regression was used to examine the relations between the statement (variables) scores and the applied strategy: manufacturing for overseas private labels or exporting the firm’s brand. Correlation analysis was conducted to assess the relations among the various statements (variables) and a chi square test was used to find out if there was a correlation between a firm’s size and its reported strategy: manufacturing for overseas private labels or exporting the firm’s brand. Findings The findings are reported separately for each of the methodological approaches. An integrative discussion is presented in the discussion section. Interviews – qualitative results Six in-depth interviews were conducted with the relevant international marketing managers. The firms can be categorized as one of two types: First, a large firm, in the food and beverage industry, a medium sized one in the communications industry and a small one in the textile industry. These were all manufacturing for overseas private labels. A second group were exporting their own brands and comprised a small firm, in the computer and software business, a medium sized firm in the textile industry, and a large firm in the plastics and rubber field. In general, all six interviewees thought that the private label markets had increased a great deal and that firms’ considerations regarding international vs. local markets can often be different, especially due to variations in competition (number and sort of 11 competitors), culture (tastes, habits, and manners) and regulation (legal requirements and standards). However, various arguments were made by the interviewees in regard to production agreements for overseas private labels. In many cases, interviewees from firms manufacturing for overseas private labels held similar views, as opposed to those from firms exporting their own brands. Some interviewees from the manufacturers for overseas private labels appeared to feel uncomfortable or as if they were trying to justify their firms’ actions. The major findings of the interviews regarding manufacturing for overseas private labels fall into two categories: Motivators that are the perceived positive aspects and barriers that are the perceived drawbacks. Motivators – Perceived positive aspects It is cheaper, requires far less investment than exporting your own (the firms’ brand). Many times it is quicker because you get an immediate order and you are in the market. If the overseas retailer is well known to consumers, it can be better than trying to penetrate the market using your own brand and building a reputation. It may be the only way to enter new markets, especially if the private label sales volume is high and there are already strong competitors in the market. For small and medium-sized firms, the chances of succeeding can be better if they agree to manufacture for overseas private labels. A somewhat interesting argument raised by one interviewee was that there are fewer risks when manufacturing for overseas private labels in regard to lawsuits regarding the product. Barriers – perceived drawbacks Manufacturing for overseas private labels increases the dependency on the retailer, and if it is a big client, you may have a serious problem if anything goes wrong. It is mainly for grocery items. It is more appropriate if you are a small player. Such a strategy may be good for the short or medium terms but not for the long run. Many times, it is the overseas retailers that are trying to impose these agreements. Quantitative analysis based on the 101 personal interviews It was found that the firms studied did not have dual strategies, whereby they were manufacturing for a private label and simultaneously exporting the firm’s brand to the same export market. This finding is interesting and supports the theoretical argument regarding the difference between local and international strategic options—diversified strategies. A logistic regression analysis was applied in which the dependent variable 12 was the behaviour of the manufacturer—manufacturing for overseas private labels or exporting their own brands. ****************** Put table 2 about here ****************** The logistic regression is significant (P< .01), as is the prediction validity of 77.4%. The correlation analysis (see Table 3 in the Appendix) indicates that though some correlations were significant, none of them was .5 or more. In line with proposition P1, manufacturers for overseas private labels believe more strongly that doing this is a better strategy than exporting the firm’s brand if the overseas customers know the retailer well. Proposition P2, which stated that entering a new market is quicker if manufacturing for private labels, was not significantly supported. However, the mean score for the total sample (see Table 1 in the Appendix) and each of the groups, private label manufacturers and brand exporters separately, is 3 or higher (3.11, 3.20, 3.00, respectively), indicating that manufacturers do believe that when manufacturing for overseas private labels the penetration may be quicker. Supporting P3, manufacturers for overseas private labels significantly more than brand exporters perceive their strategy as a lower cost one in comparison to exporting your own brand. P4 suggested that if managers think that manufacturing for overseas private labels is for small firms, they tend to avoid this strategy mainly because of the fear of the negative connotation being carried over to their firm. The study findings support this proposition. Those who export their own brands expressed significantly higher agreement with this statement. Nonetheless, looking at Table 4 (see the Appendix) no significant relations were found between firm size in terms of sales and its overseas strategy. No significant differences were found between the perceptions of the two groups of manufacturers in regard to the dependency on the retailer (when manufacturing for an overseas private label, dependency on the retailer increases). The statement raised by interviewee in the first phase of the study that it is sometimes the only way to enter new market and it is imposed by the retailer was examined, and no significant differences between the two groups were found. Thus P5 was not supported by this study. However, both groups strongly agreed with the “increased dependency” and “sometimes the only way” to enter the market statements (mean scores 3.30 and 3.04, respectively). In line with P6, manufacturers that use their own brand for overseas markets believe significantly more (P< .1) than those who manufacture for overseas private labels that the latter strategy is suitable for the short term only. P7 suggested that manufacturing for overseas private labels reduces the risk of lawsuit due to a product not being supported. Most interviewees disagreed with this statement. In line with P8, manufacturers that export their own brand believed, more than the private labels producers, that manufacturing for overseas private labels was best suited for grocery items. However, looking at Table 5 (see the Appendix) reveals that though a higher percentage of manufacturers for overseas private labels were found in the food and beverage and textile industries, many others were from less traditional industries such as communication and electronics. 13 Discussion The main objectives of this study were to discuss and explore private labels and their associated dilemmas both for manufacturers and for retailers within the context of international marketing. It has been proposed that international markets open new options for both retailers and manufacturers and can affect their considerations and decisions in regards to private label agreements. Leveraging strategic variations between home and overseas markets was suggested as a policy that may overcome or mitigate some manufacturers’ concerns such as brand cannibalization, and enable retailers to sign agreements with new players and decrease the apparent frictions with the national brand manufacturers. The empirical study supports this argument, finding that all the firms that manufacture for overseas private labels were not engaged in the private label business in Israel despite its rapid growth in the last decade. Most previous studies examined the dilemma in the context of domestic markets and suggested that manufacturing for private labels is mainly for small firms (Burt, 2000; Burt and Sparks, 2003; Dunne and Narasimhan, 1999; Puelles, 1995,). In line with its theoretical arguments, this study found no differences in terms of firm size between those who used their own brands and the ones that manufacture for overseas private labels. Moreover, some of the Israeli market leaders that hold strong brands in the local market with greater market shares than global competitors are also manufacturing for overseas retailers. The empirical study focused on manufacturers’ views, so as to explore their attitudes toward manufacturing agreements with overseas retailers, and to examine what can advance and hinder such contracts. As expected, manufacturers for overseas private labels believed that having agreements to produce overseas private labels means lower costs than exporting the firm’s own brands. This can be a counterconsideration to the argument of higher mark-ups, which is given many times to the retailers for products that are being sold under the retailer’s private label as opposed to as a manufacturer’s brand. Moreover, it can be an attractive option for small and medium-sized firms that lack the resources to compete globally (Timmor and Zif, 2005) and also for big firms that focus more on their local markets and are less known by foreign customers. The latter consideration leads us to another important finding: manufacturers for overseas private labels believe more than brand exporters that this is a preferable strategy if customers are familiar with the retailer. Hence, retailers that invest in building their reputations and contacts with their clients may find it easier to get international manufacturers to agree to produce private labels. Though the actual firms’ sizes were found to be similar, when examining their perceptions support was found for the proposition that when managers believe manufacturing for overseas private labels better suits small firms, they will opt to avoid doing so. The rationale can be better understood by looking at the reactions of managers in the first set of personal interviews. The managers, in spite of the good points they found in being involved with private labels overseas, tried somewhat to justify this strategy and thought it is less appropriate for big firms. They associated it more with small firms, firms that are more oriented to domestic markets and those that view the international markets as an option for using up excess capacity. Hence, it appears that there is a gap between firms’ actual behaviour and their perceptions regarding manufacturing for overseas private labels. The quantitative study also showed that as managers perceived manufacturing for overseas private labels to be appropriate for the short term only, they tend to avoid it. It may be that it is perceived more as a tactical action 14 or that manufacturers are less engaged or aware of long-term agreements for manufacturing of overseas private labels. It was hypothesized that there is an advantage in being involved with manufacturing for overseas private labels because it allows quick penetration of the market. In the empirical examination, all interviewees agreed strongly with this statement. Further, there were no significant differences between those manufacturing for overseas private labels and those that do not. It appears that this feature—quicker launching—is more essential for “pioneers” and products with a relatively short life cycle. As the private label phenomenon is now moving beyond its traditional industries (see below), new firms may now be more motivated to enter into overseas private label agreements. Most studies of private labels have been conducted among the more traditional industries and product categories such as food, hygiene and textiles (Cheng Wu and Jen Wang 2005; Heraud et al., 2006; Obina et al., 2006). Though private labels have increased their market shares in many other industries e.g., computers, communication, electronics and home appliances (Timmor and Zif, 2005), it appears that they are still associated mainly with the older industries. Supporting the study proposition, it was found that manufactures who exported their own brand perceived private labels as suitable for grocery items more than those who are already engaged in manufacturing for overseas private labels. This study also supports earlier studies regarding the popularity of private labels in the more traditional industries. Nevertheless, this study found private label ventures in various and newer industries such as communication, plastics and electronics. Hence, it seems that there is a perception gap and perhaps if manufacturers were more familiar with private labels’ new categories and developments they would consider the private label option more seriously. Managerial Implications Private labels are a growing business that is permeated, as shown in theory and practice, with continuous friction between producers and distributors—mainly retailers. Many of the confrontations and dilemmas derive from the very fact that the retailers, which are the manufacturers’ clients, after developing and selling their private labels, become their competitors. Manufacturers, though they wish to keep on good terms with retailers, are afraid of losing market share, increasing their dependency on retailers, losing customer loyalty and damaging their own brands. More retailers, on the other hand, seeing the potential of private labels, are looking for reliable manufacturing sources and at the same time trying to avoid clashes with brand manufacturers. This study suggests that having agreements between manufacturers and retailers from different markets/countries may solve or mitigate some of the problems and serve the interest of both parties. The study found that different sized manufacturers, some of whom are market leaders, are already partners in agreements to produce private labels for overseas retailers. The study revealed several factors that enhance/reduce producers’ willingness to cooperate with overseas private label retailers. Following this study’s findings, retailers should be aware that their reputation, trust and familiarity among consumers are strong motivators behind manufacturers’ readiness to sign private label agreements. While domestic manufacturers of private labels are highly concerned with lower mark-ups, overseas producers see the lower costs as one of the main advantages in exporting their own brands. Quicker penetration of new markets is 15 another positive feature that is repeatedly cited by overseas manufacturers. Hence substantial orders in due time may encourage overseas agreements. This study found that the dominant perceived drawbacks for private label agreements are their apparent short-term lifecycles, appropriate mainly for grocery items, and the fact that they increase dependency on retailers. Some private label manufacturers also felt uneasy with their production strategy and tried to justify it using different excuses. It seems that retailers can benefit greatly if they increase manufacturers’ trust for the medium and long terms. This can be done by purchasing commitments, longer term contracts and cooperation in developing private label variety and categories. Demonstrating to private label manufacturers that market shares of traditional industries have grown steadily, and that private labels have entered new categories, may reinforce their willingness to cooperate with the retailers’ private labels. Limitations and future research This study is a pioneer in empirically testing the subject of private label manufacturing agreements in the international context. As such, it is difficult to compare it to other studies on the subject. The study discusses the strategic dilemmas and implications both for manufacturers and for retailers. The empirical study focuses on the international producers—their behaviour and perceptions. Thus, an examination of retailers’ views of international agreements could add important input to the topic. Since the study was conducted in one country, testing of its findings to other regions should be conducted. Replicating the study in other countries and regions would enrich the discussion as well as the theoretical and practical implications. The sampling cannot be considered random, since the interviews were conducted with managers who a priori agreed to participate in the research. This study tested a particular set of variables derived from the theoretical discussion and qualitative analysis. Other factors, such as firms’ global orientation and goals, and retailers’ concerns for continuous supply and control, may affect overseas private label agreements. Future research can also concentrate on different industries and include factors that are more industry specific such as guidance qualifications that are needed to promote technological items. 16 References Ailawadi, K. L. and Harlam, B. (2004). ‘An empirical analysis of the determinants of retail margins; the role of store-brand share’, Journal of Marketing, 68(1), pp. 147165. Angelmar, R. and Pras, B. (1984). ‘Product acceptance by middlemen in export channels’, Journal of Business Research, 12, pp. 227-240. Apelbaum, E., Gerstner E. and Prasad, A. N. (2003). ‘The effects of quality evaluations versus brand name on price premiums’, The Journal of Product and Brand Management, 12(2/3), pp. 154-165. Aulakh, S. P. and Kotabe, M. (1997). ‘Antecedents and performance implications of channel integration in foreign markets’, Journal of International Business Studies, 28(1), pp. 145-175. Bello, D. C. and Williamson, N. C. (1985). ‘Contractual arrangement and marketing practices in the indirect export channel’, Journal of International Business Studies, 16(Summer), pp. 65-82. Bello, C., Daniel, D., Urban, J., and Verhage, B. J. (1991). ‘Evaluating export middlemen in alternative channel structures’, International Marketing Review, 8(5), pp. 49-64. Burt, S. (2000). ‘The strategic role of retail in British grocery retailing’ European Journal of Marketing’, 34(2), pp. 875-890. Burt, S. and Sparks, L, (2003). ‘Power and competition in the UK retail grocery market’, British Journal of Management, 14(3), pp. 237-254. Calvin, L. and Cook, R. (2001). ‘U.S. fresh fruit and vegetable marketing; emerging trade practices, trends and issues’, Agriculture Economic Report, 795.ERS-United State Department of Agriculture, Washington. 52p. Cavusgil, T. S. and Zou, S. (1994). Marketing strategy–performance relationship: an investigation of the empirical link in export market ventures’, Journal of Marketing, 58(1), pp. 1-21. Cavusgil, T.S., Zou, S. and Naidu, G. M. (1993). ‘Product and promotion adaptation in export ventures: An empirical investigation’, Journal of International Business Studies, 24(3), pp. 479-506. Cheng Wu, C. and Jen Wang C. (2005). ‘A positive theory of private label: a strategic role of private label in a duopoly national-brand market’, Marketing Letters, 16(2), pp. 143-161. Chintagunta, P. K., Bonfrer, A. and Song, I. (2002). ‘Investigating the effects of store-brand introduction on retailer demand and pricing behavior’, Management Science, 48(10), pp. 1242-1267. Corstjen,, M. and Lal, R. (2000). ‘Building store loyalty through store brands’, Journal of Marketing Research, 37(August), pp. 281-291. Cotterill, R. W., Dhar, R. and Putsis, W. (2000). ‘Assessing the competitive interaction between private labels and national brand’, Journal of Business, 73(1), pp. 109-137. 17 Dunn, D. and Narasimhan, C. (1999). ‘The new appeal of private labels’, Harvard Business Review, 77(3), pp. 41-52. Fearne, A. (1988). ‘The evolution of partnership in the meat supply chain: insights from the beef industry’, Supply Chain Management, 3, pp. 214-231. Fernandez, A. and Gomez, M. (2005). ‘Shelf space management of private labels: a case study in Spanish retailing’, Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 12(3), pp. 205-216. Fiegenbaum, A. and Karnani, A. (1991). ‘Output flexibility – a competitive advantage for small firms’, Strategic Management Journal, 12, pp. 101-114. Glemet, F and R., Mira (1993). ‘The brands leader’s dilemma’, The Mckinsey Quarterly, 2, pp. 3-15. Heide, J. B. and John, G. (1988). ‘The role of dependence balancing in safeguarding transaction-specific assets in conventional channels’, Journal of Marketing, 52(1), pp. 20-35. Heraud, E. G., Rouached, L. and Soler, L, G. (2006). ‘Private labels and public quality standards: How can consumer trust be restored after the mad cow crisis?’, Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 4, pp. 31-55. Hoch, S.J (1996). ‘How should national brands think about private labels?’, Sloan Management Review, 37(2), pp. 89-102. Hoch, S, J. and Shumeet, B. (1993). ‘When do private label succeed?’, Sloan Management Review, 37(winter), pp. 89-102. Johanson, J and Vahlne, J. E. (1990). ‘The mechanism of internationalisation’, International Marketing Review, 7(4), pp. 11-24. Kale, S. (1986). ‘Greater perceptions of manufacturer power and influence strategies in a developing country’, Journal of Marketing Research, 23(4), pp. 387-393. Kim, N. and Parker, M. P. (1999). ‘Collusive conduct in private label markets’, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 16(2), pp. 143-155. Klein, S., Frazier, G. L. and Roth, V. J. (1990). ‘A transaction cost analysis model of channel integration on international markets’, Journal of Marketing Research, 27(5), pp. 196-208. Lal, R and Narasimhan, C. (1996). ‘The inverse relationship between manufacturer and retailer margins: a theory’, Marketing Science, 15(2), pp. 132-151. Mills, D, E. (1999). ‘Private labels and manufacturer counterstrategies’, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 26(2), pp. 125-145. Narishman, C, and Wilcox, R, T. (1998). ‘Private labels and the channel relationship: a cross-category analys’,. Journal of Business, 71(4), pp. 573-600. Oubina, J. Rubio, N. and Yague, J. M. (2006). ‘Relationship of retail brand manufacturers with retailers’, International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 16(2), pp. 257-275. Puelles, J. A. (1995). ‘Analisis del fenomeno de las marcas de distribuidor en Espana y de su tratamiento estragico’, Informacion Comercial Espanola, 739, pp. 117-129. 18 Puelles, J, A., Fernandez de Larrea, P. and Albert, R. (1997). ‘Marcas de distribuidor, Especial referencia al precio. Distribucion y Consumo’, 33, pp 112-129. Quelch, J. A. and Harding, D. (1996). ‘Brand versus private labels: fighting to win’, Harvard Business Review, 74 (1), pp. 99-110. Richardson, P, S., Dick, A. S. and Jain, A. (1994). ‘Extrinsic and intrinsic cue effects on perceptions of store brand quality’, Journal of Marketing, 58(4), pp. 28-36. Sayman, S. S., Stephen, J. H. and Jagmohan, S, R (2002). ‘Positioning of store brands’, Marketing Science, 21(4), pp. 378-397. Terpstra, V. and Sarathy, R. (1997). International Marketing. (UK: Harcourt Brace The Dryden Press, 7th Edition). Tarzijan, Jorge. (2004). ‘Strategic effects of private labels and horizontal integration’, International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 14(3), pp. 321335. Timmor, Y and Zif, J. (2005). ‘A typology of marketing strategies for export’, Journal of Global Marketing, 18, 3(4), pp. 37-78. Verhoef, C. P., Nijssen, E. J. and Sloot, L. M. (2002). ‘Strategic reactions of national manufacturers towards private labels, an empirical study in the Netherlands’, European Journal of Marketing, 36, pp. 1309-1326. Walters, P. G. P. (1986). ‘International marketing policy: a discussion of the standardization construct and its relevance for corporate policy’, Journal of International Business Studies, 17(summer), pp. 55-69. 19 Appendix Table 1 – Manufacturers’ Perceptions of “Manufacturing for Overseas Private Labels”—Means and S.D. scaling from 1 “disagree” to 4 “agree” The Measured Statements (Variables) Perception N=101 Manufacturing for overseas private labels means lower 2.62 (1.19) costs than exporting the firm’s own brand. Manufacturing for overseas private labels increases 3.30 (.99) dependence on the overseas retailer Manufacturing for…is sometimes the only way to enter 3.04 (.96) the exported market Is preferable if the consumers know the retailer 3.14 (1.00) Is a strategy that suits the short and medium terms 2.05 (1.20) Is a strategy that is imposed by the retailers 2.44 (1.12) Is a strategy that mainly suits grocery products 1.93 (1.16) Is a strategy mainly for small and medium-sized firms 1.96 (1.08) When manufacturing for overseas private labels launching 3.11 (.93) to the markets is quicker For small/medium-sized firms chances of succeeding 3.02 (.99) overseas are greater when manufacturing for private labels Decreases the chances for lawsuits due to the product 1.69 (.96) 20 Table 2: Logistic Binominal Regression Results Categorical Dependent Variable = Manufacturing for Overseas Private Label vs. Exporting Manufacturer’s Brand Predictor Variables (Statements) Unstandardized Coefficient Constant -2.546 Lower Costs .633b Increased dependence on overseas retailer -.084 Sometimes the only way to enter the target export market -.089 Preferable if the consumers know the retailer 1.1590a A strategy that suits the short and medium terms .524b A strategy that is imposed by the retailers -.143 A strategy that mainly suits grocery products -.633b A strategy mainly for small and medium-sized firms -1.249a Launching in overseas markets is quicker -.242 Greater chances of succeeding for small/medium-sized .453 firms Decreases the chances for lawsuits due to the product Note: coefficient signs are for manufacturing for overseas a - P < .01, b – P< .05 Model Statistics -2 log of the likelihood function = 79.647 Chi square (11 d. f.) 36.039 (P . 01) Correct classification = 77.4% .317 private labels 21 Table 3: Spearman’s Correlation Coefficients Lower Costs Tested variable Lower costs Increased dependence The only way to enter If consumers know the retailer For short/medium terms Imposed by the retailers Mainly for grocery items For small/medium-sized firms Launching is quicker Greater chances for success Lower chances of lawsuits Increases dependence 1.000 .237* -.091 .002 .090 -.033 .103 -.012 .200* .124 .055 Only way to enter If consumers know the retailer 1.000 -.086 1.000 .029 .292* .237* .078 .196* .198* .260* -.166 .159 .233* .094 .064 .156 .094 .083 -.056 1.000 -.316* .292* -.141 .088 .167 .482* .131 For short /medium terms Imposed by the retailers 1.000 .134 .376* .249* .003 .025 -.024 1.000 .178 .031 .079 .315* -.048 Correlation Coefficient (continue) Tested variable Mainly for grocery items For small/medium-sized firms Launching is quicker Greater chances for success Lower chances of lawsuits Mainly for grocery items 1.000 -.020 .055 .092 .153 For small/ medium size firms 1.000 -.134 .168 .020 Launching is quicker 1.000 .292* .232* Greater chances for success 1.000 -.027 *Correlation is significant at p < .05 Table 4: Annual Sales in Millions of Dollars and manufactures strategies Range % of firms within % of firms within manufacturing for exporting under overseas private firms'\brand labels Total 1 - 10 13.2 20.8 16.8 11 - 30 37.7 29.2 33.7 31 - 100 18.9 25.1 21.7 101 - 300 20.8 10.4 15.8 301+ 9.1 14.6 11.9 100.0 100 100 Total Chi Square = 4.116, 4 df, non significant. Lower chances of lawsuits 1.000 22 Table 5: Distribution of Firms by Industry According to Manufacturing for Overseas Private Labels (in numbers) and Percent of Firms by Industry Industry Exporting Manufacturing Percent of Row under for Overseas Manufacturing for Total firms'\brand Private Labels Overseas Private Labels (row %) Food and beverage 3 11 78.6% 14 Jewellery 1 2 66.7% 3 Medical equipment 5 0 0 5 Rubber and plastic products 4 8 66.7% 12 Chemical and petroleum 6 6 50% 12 Metals and metal products 7 5 42% 12 Machinery 4 1 20% 5 Electronic and electrical 6 5 45.5% 11 Textiles and clothing 2 11 84.6% 13 Optical instruments 3 0 0 3 Computers and software 4 1 20% 5 Communication and 3 3 50% 6 48 53 /measuring instruments products equipment telecommunications Column total 101